You are on page 1of 21

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT

Amarendra Sharma and Cassondra Bruce,

The Relationship between Energy and U.S. Gross Domestic Product: A Multivariate Vector Error-Correction Model,
Volume 38, Number 1

Copyright 2013

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ENERGY AND U.S. GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT: A MULTIVARIATE VECTOR ERROR-CORRECTION MODEL
Amarendra Sharma and Cassondra Bruce*

Introduction

long-standing economic question is that of the relationship between energy consumption and the gross domestic product (GDP) growth rate. The goal of this study is to expand the scope of previous studies conducted on the economy of the United States. While previous research has been conducted, the results are often inconclusive; however, in several studies, when causality is found to be significant, it appears to run from energy consumption to GDP.

*Amarendra Sharma, Assistant Professor of economics at Elmira College (New York), holds Masters and Ph.D. degrees in economics from the University of Cincinnati, as well as a Masters in economics from the Delhi School of Economics, and a B.A. with Honors in economics from Ramjas College, University of Delhi, India. Dr. Sharma has previously taught various courses in economics at the Farmer School of Business, Miami University (Oxford, Ohio) and the Department of Economics, University of Cincinnati. The author also has held an academic position at the Queensland University of Technology, Australia. Dr. Sharma, whose areas of research specializations include applied econometrics, international trade theory, and industrial organization, has published articles in the subfields of Development Economics, Public Economics, and International Economics. His research has appeared in The Journal of Socio-Economics, Public Budgeting and Finance, Research in Applied Economics, International Journal of Economic Practices and Theories, and The Journal of International and Global Economic Studies. He also serves on the editorial board of the journal, Microeconomics and Macroeconomics. Cassondra Bruce is a Teaching Fellow in Economics; she is currently pursuing degrees in economics, business administration, and mathematics at Elmira College. Her expertise lies in the field of time series econometrics. The Journal of Energy and Development, Vol. 38, Nos. 1 and 2 Copyright 2013 by the International Research Center for Energy and Economic Development (ICEED). All rights reserved.

45

46

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT

The U.S. industrial revolution often is associated with great advancements not only in manufacturing but also in the new economy. Logically, a shift from handmade products to machine-made products greatly boosted productivity, and higher standards of living soon followed. As entrepreneurs and inventors began to look toward machinery, a new need for energy soon ensued. This, however, became a cycle: with increasing availability of energy and power sources, innovations in production rose, which fed into new energy developments. This cycle can still be seen in todays modern world. With each passing day and attention to the depletion of nonrenewable energy sources, there is a greater need for renewable energy. This search, however, also has given rise to new technological advancements. As such, the relationship and the direction of causality between energy consumption and economic growth are uncertain and quite important. Understanding this relationship can provide policy makers with vital information while trying to promote economic growth and energy conservation.

Background Literature In past studies on the U.S. economy, researchers have come to several different conclusions about the relationship between energy consumption and GDP growth. Those relationships include: a uni-directional causation of energy consumption to economic growth, a bi-directional causation between energy consumption and GDP growth, and a uni-directional causation from GDP to energy consumption (see, for example, D. Stern, and B.-N. Huang et al.).1 J. Kraft and A. Kraft were the first to determine causality with gross national product Granger causing energy consumption.2 A. Akarca and T. Long, however, found these results to be spurious due to the non-stationarity of the data.3 They also did not find any causality between the two variables when a lag period of two years was included. J. Kraft and A. Krafts conclusion was validated by S. Abosedra and H. Baghestani.4 They relied on U.S. data from 19471987 upon which they performed Granger causality tests. Other notable studies in the U.S. context that did not find any causal relationship between the two variables are E. Yu and B. Hwang, E. Yu and J. Choi, E. Yu and J. Jin, and B. Cheng.5 These later studies employed various advanced time-series econometric techniques. While there have been many studies on the U.S. economy, there also has been much research on other developed and developing nations. As in the case of the research on the United States, when studying the effects of energy consumption on economic growth for these countries, several relationships have been identified. The main cause of such differing relationships, particularly for the same country, is likely due to the differences in data, variables, years of study, and political or other such factors.6

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH

47

D. Stern conducted a time-series, multivariate cointegration analysis on the relationship of energy for the U.S. economy.7 His study updated a previous analysis that was published seven years earlier. This first study tested GDP, energy use, capital, and labor inputs, addressing the relationship between energy use and economic growth; however, he concluded that the relationship could not be identified with certainty. The newer study included data from 1948 to 1994, on which D. Stern runs unit root tests for stationarity as well as Cobb-Douglas production functions to test one single equation, and Engle-Granger cointegrating regressions that correspond to several vector autoregression models. This single equation cointegration analysis showed that energy is a significant variable in understanding GDP growth; likewise, the multivariate dynamic cointegration analysis supported the same conclusion. D. Stern also determined that GDP, capital, labor, and energy are cointegrated. The latter multivariate analysis also indicated that energy Granger causes GDP either uni-directionally or perhaps through a mutually causative relationship.8 D. Stern ultimately concluded that energy was a limiting factor in economic growth and that energy supply shocks tended to result in a reduction in output.9 The research of B. Huang et al., which uses a dynamic panel data approach, suggests that there is a negative Granger causal relationship running from GDP to energy consumption for high-income nations, such as the United States.10 Their study is based on panel data of 82 countries from the year 1972 to 2002. Dividing the countries into four groups, low income, lower-middle income, upper-middle income, and high income, the researchers contribute detailed results. Using one equation for all 82 countries, the researchers conclude that there is a positive bi-directional feedback relationship between economic growth and energy consumption.11 Probing further, however, they determine that there is no causal relationship for low-income countries, a uni-directional positive causal relationship from economic growth to energy consumption for middle-income countries, and a negative, uni-directional, causal relationship from economic growth to energy consumption for high-income countries. As the United States is classified as highincome, it can be inferred that an increase in GDP would cause a reduction in energy consumption. The researchers attribute this negative relationship to a conservative and environmentally friendly consumption policy.12 Another study on panel data for 25 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries (including the United States) for years 1981 to 2007 was conducted by A. Belke et al.13 Understanding the importance of knowing the relationship between energy consumption and economic growth, the researchers sought to make conclusive findings on the direction of causality by including the price of energy as a variable. From the analysis, it was determined that energy consumption is relatively price-inelastic, implying that energy is considered a necessity in todays society. Also established is a long-run causal relationship in the energy demand equation, implying that global energy policies

48

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT

have a greater impact on energy consumption and economic growth as opposed to national policies. Using unit root, cointegration, and Granger causality tests, the analysis suggests that energy consumption and economic growth are bi-directionally related in the long run. As such, if energy or GDP increase, the other variable also will increase. A meta-analysis is a type of statistical analysis that addresses several studies collectively in hopes of identifying a trend or conclusion. C.-W. Song Zan and K. Chu-Chun investigated 30 manuscripts in three parts: economic development status, short run versus long run, and total energy consumption versus single electricity consumption.14 Analyzing the first topic of interest, the researchers conclude that the relationship between energy consumption and economic growth fluctuates. For instance, observing Turkey from 19502000 as a developing country and from 19702006 as a more developed nation, the same country represents differing relationships; as such, the researchers conclude that a nation may yield different results based on its stage of development. Studying multivariate data, comprised of capital, labor, energy, and GDP for Korea from 19701999, it becomes evident that the time periodi.e., short run and long runmay have a significant effect on causality.15 The aforementioned study by W. Oh and K. Lee discovers that Koreas long-run causal relationship between energy consumption and GDP is bi-directional, while its short-run relationship is uni-directional, running from energy consumption to GDP. In application, this implies that it is crucial for policy makers to remember long-run implications, not just the short-run effects. The researchers also conclude that bidirectional causality exists between electricity consumption and economic growth based upon several studies in Korea.16 These researchers determine that for most developing countries, the causal relationship does not run from energy consumption to economic growth but, rather, the relationship varies with the degree of development. J. Payne conducted a similar survey of past studies, in which he determined that there is no general consensus on a causal relationship for energy consumption and economic growth.17 Despite the lack of continuity for the global economy, once breaking the studies into results, he was able to find that 29.2 percent of the studies yield a neutrality hypothesis. This neutrality hypothesis implies that there is an absence of Granger causality. J. Payne also discovered that 28.2 percent, 23.1 percent, and 19.5 percent of the studies suggested feedback, growth, and conservative hypotheses, respectively. As such, less than one in every four studies suggests that energy consumption Granger causes economic growth, and even fewer suggest that economic growth Granger causes energy consumption. K. Imran and M. Siddiqui conducted a study similar to the one being reported; however, the two researchers analyzed panel data from the developing nations of Bangladesh, India, and Pakistan.18 The researchers first determined the order of integration, using unit root tests, and then tested for cointegration. Concluding that

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH

49

cointegration was present, a panel-based error-correction model was applied to determine short-run and long-run causality and a Granger causality test was run. These statistical techniques determined that energy consumption Granger caused GDP in the long run, but not in short run, and that no causal relationship between GDP and energy consumption existed in the short run.19 The researchers went on to suggest that there would be an increase in output, given a continuous use of energy. Using similar methodology, A. Aqeel and M. Butt determine that for the developing nation of Pakistan GDP Granger causes total energy consumption and petroleum consumption, while GDP has no Granger causal relationship with gas consumption, electricity consumption Granger causes GDP, and energy consumption Granger causes employment.20 Also closely following the same methodology, U. Soytas and R. Sari determine the causal relationship between energy consumption and GDP for 16 countries.21 Finding the data to be stationary after taking the first difference for all nations, the researchers use a vector error-correction model for Granger causality. For Turkey, France, Germany, and Japan, energy consumption Granger causes GDP. In Argentina, there is bi-directional causality. In Italy and Korea, the researchers find GDP to Granger cause energy consumption. A summary of studies in the U.S. context is provided in table 1.

Data, Methodology, and Results Previous studies have chosen to include only the variables of interest, representing energy consumption and economic growth; however, in this study we will examine both bivariate and multivariate models. The multivariate models will include non-agricultural labor hours and net domestic investments in addition to real GDP and two measures of energy consumption. These variables have been obtained from the Bureaus of Labor Statistics and of Economic Analysis and the U.S. Energy Information Administration.22 The multivariate model is advantageous over the bivariate model in the sense that it allows us to see how other, more specific, macroeconomic indicators affect economic growth and energy consumption. The summary statistics of all variables used in this study are given in table 2. Establishing the direction of causality between real GDP and the two measures of energy consumption, namely, total energy consumption and fossil fuel consumption, involves three steps. In the first step of the analysis, we employ two standard unit root tests, namely, the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test and Phillips-Perron (PP) test, to determine the order of integration for each variable in our study.23 Testing for stationarity ensures that our regression results are not spurious. Additionally,

50

Table 1

SUMMARY OF ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH a STUDIES FOR THE UNITED STATES Period 19481994 19492006 19471979 19731984 19501992 19731979 Co-integration, Causality Causality Bivar. Sims Causality Bivar. Granger Test Bivar. Granger Test Bivar. VECM Country Methodology Results EC / GDP EC / GDP Growth / EC EC  Growth EC  Growth EC )/ Growth EC  Growth

Authors (Year)

D. Stern (2000) N. Bowden and J. Payne (2009) J. Kraft and A. Kraft (1985) U. Erol and E. Yu (1987) E. Yu and J. Jin (1992) U. Soytas and R. Sari (2003)

A. Akarca and T. Long (1980)

United States United States United States United States United States Canada, United States, and United Kingdom United States

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT

EC = energy consumption; GPD = gross domestic product; bivar. = bivariate; and VECM = vector error-correction model. Sources: D. Stern, A Multivariate Cointegration Analysis of the Role of Energy in the US Macroeconomy, Energy Economics, vol. 22, no. 2 (2000), pp. 26783; N. Bowden and J. Payne, The Causal Relationship between U.S. Energy Consumption and Real Output: A Disaggregated Analysis, Journal of Policy Modeling, vol. 31, no. 2 (2009), pp. 1808; J. Kraft and A. Kraft, On the Relationship between Energy and GNP, The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 3, no. 2 (spring 1978), pp. 4013; U. Erol and E. S. H. Yu, On the Causal Relationship between Energy and Income for Industrialized Countries, The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 13, no. 1 (autumn 1988), pp. 11322; E. S. H. Yu and J. C. Jin, Cointegration Tests of Energy Consumption, Income, and Employment, Resources and Energy, vol. 14, no. 3 (1992), 25966; U. Soytas and R. Sari, Energy Consumption and GDP: Causality Relationship in G-7 Countries and Emerging Markets, Energy Economics, vol. 25, no. 1 (2003), pp. 337; and A. T. Akarca and T. V. Long, On the Relationship between Energy and GNP: A Reexamination, The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 5, no. 2 (spring 1980), pp. 32631.

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH Table 2


SUMMARY STATISTICS Variable Total energy Fossil fuel Labor GDP Net investment Observations 56 56 56 56 56 Mean 7.60x10 7 6.70x10 99,190.57 4,946.49 729.16
7

51

Standard Deviation 1.88x10 7 1.45x10 28,580.23 4,514.57 645.52


7

Minimum 4.02x10 7 3.74x10 55,722 414.7 63.5


7

Maximum 1.01x10 7 8.63x10 143,952 14,526.5 2,178.5


8

cointegration requires that the variables are integrated of the same order. Testing each variable in the levels form allows us to determine the degree of integration. The ADF test makes a parametric correction for higher-order autocorrelation by including the lagged differences of the dependent variable as explanatory variables. The following regression is used for the ADF test: Xk u Dytj + et 1 yt = b0 xt + ayt1 + j=1 j where xt is a vector of deterministic terms (constant, trend, etc.). The k lagged difference terms, Dytj, are used to approximate the autoregressive moving-average (ARMA) structure of the errors, and the value of k is set such that the error et is serially uncorrelated. The error term also is assumed to be homoskedastic. The Phillips-Perron (PP) unit root test differs from the ADF test primarily in terms of its treatment of error-specific serial correlation and hetereskedasticity. In particular, the PP test ignores any serial correlation in the test regression, whereas the ADF test tries to mimic the ARMA structure of the error terms through parametric autoregression, The test regression for the PP test is: Dyt = b0 M t + pyt1 + ut 2

where ut is I(0) and may be heteroskedastic. The PP test corrects for any serial correlation and heteroskedasticity in the error ut by directly modifying the test statistics. One advantage of the PP test over the ADF test is that it is robust to general forms of heteroskedasticity in the error term ut. The above descriptions of ADF and PP tests are borrowed from A. Sharma.24 The second step of analysis consists of cointegration test, which may be tested by using either the Engle-Granger or the Johansen-Juselius procedure.25 We opt for the Johansen-Juselius test since it has been shown to have superior properties to the Engle-Granger two-step procedure.26 The Johansen-Juselius cointegration test allows us to compare trace statistics to a critical value. If the trace statistic is greater than the critical value, then we can reject the null hypothesis of at most r

52

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT

cointegrating relationships among the specified variables. This allows us to determine cointegration among the variables. While cointegration can establish causal relationship, it cannot tell us the direction of causality, so we must use the Granger causality test. In the third step of the analysis we consider the Granger causality test, which crucially depends on the degree of integration of variables. If all variables are stationary in the levels or I(0), then the standard Granger causality test can be applied. But if they are I(1), then the Granger causality test can be implemented within a vector error-correction model.27
Unit Root Tests: The results of the augmented Dickey-Fuller and PhillipsPerron tests on the series in levels are provided in table 3; table 4 displays the results of these unit root tests performed on the series after first differencing. According to the results in table 3, we cannot reject the null hypothesis of unit root for any variable in the levels using the augmented Dickey-Fuller and PhillipsPerron tests. However, when we first difference these variables and then perform

Table 3
Level Augmented Dickey-Fuller 2.204 1.093 2.790 2.255 3.492 1.652 2.192 3.352 0.962 2.116 1.615 2.061 0.671 1.706 1.379 (1) (4) (3) (3) (4) (1) (4) (3) (3) (4) (1) (4) (3) (3) (4)

UNIT ROOT TESTS IN LEVELS

Phillips-Perron 2.928 1.881 8.922 4.618 1.160 1.857 2.050 5.146 0.846 0.273 1.247 1.413 1.019 1.653 2.339 (1) (4) (3) (3) (4) (1) (4) (3) (3) (4) (1) (4) (3) (3) (4)

With no constant and no time trend Energy Fossil Real GDP Labor Investment With a constant and no time trend Energy Fossil Real GDP Labor Investment With a constant and a time trend Energy Fossil Real GDP Labor Investment

GPD = gross domestic product; lag lengths are provided in the parentheses and have been selected by the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC).

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH

53

the two tests again, we are able to reject the null hypothesis of unit root in each case. Thus, we conclude that the variables are integrated of first order or I(1).
Cointegration: First we present the Johansens cointegration test results for the bivariate cases and thereafter the multivariate cases. Tables 5 and 6 display the results of the bivariate cases. The optimal lag lengths have been determined by the Akaike Information Criterion and in both cases it is 4. The null hypothesis is that there are at most r cointegrating relationships among the specified variables. For real GDP and energy consumption we cannot reject the null hypothesis that there is at most one cointegrating relationship. Similarly, we cannot reject the null hypothesis of at most one cointegrating relationship between real GDP and fossil fuel consumption. Thus, we conclude that these variables are cointegrated. Table 7 and 8 present the results of the multivarite cases where we have added labor hours and net investment to the bivariate cases. When we consider cointegration among real GDP, energy consumption, labor hours, and net investment,

Table 4
UNIT ROOT TESTS AFTER FIRST DIFFERENCING First Differenced Augmented Dickey-Fuller

Phillips-Perron

With no constant and no time trend Energy Fossil Real GDP Labor Investment With a constant and no time trend Energy Fossil Real GDP Labor Investment With a constant and a time trend Energy Fossil Real GDP Labor Investment

3.808 2.312 1.237 1.864 3.587 5.111 2.832 2.540 3.959 5.027 5.451 3.243 6.180 3.846 6.100

(1)*** (3)** (1) (2)* (3)*** (1)*** (3)* (1)* (2)*** (3)*** (1)*** (3)* (1)*** (2)** (3)***

4.639 4.871 1.470 3.069 5.387 5.656 5.411 3.084 4.518 5.622 5.816 5.564 5.363 4.518 5.572

(1)*** (3)*** (1) (2)*** (3)*** (1)*** (3)*** (1)** (2)*** (3)*** (1)*** (3)*** (1)*** (2)*** (3)***

GDP = gross domestic product;***significant at 1-percent level; **significant at 5-percent level; *significant at 10-percent level; lag lengths are provided in the parentheses and have been selected by the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC); z(t) test statistics for Phillips-Perron.

54

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT Table 5


JOHANSENS TEST FOR COINTEGRATION VARIABLES: GDP a AND TOTAL ENERGY CONSUMPTION

Maximum Rank 0 1

Trace Statistic 29.3989 1.7417*

5-Percent Critical Value 15.41 3.76

GDP = gross domestic product; * indicates the maximum number of cointegrating relationships (4 lags according to the Akaike Information Criterion).

the null hypothesis of at most one cointegrating relationship cannot be rejected at the 5-percent level. Similarly, we cannot reject the null hypothesis of at most one cointegrating relationship among real GDP, fossil fuel consumption, labor hours, and net investment at the 5-percent level. In the light of this evidence, we conclude that these variables are cointegrated.
Granger Causality: It is well known that if the variables are integrated of the first order, a vector error-correction model (VECM) is a better representation of the data than a vector autoregression (VAR) model. Since we have already established cointegration among variables, this means that there exists a causal relationship. However, cointegration does not reveal the direction of causality. In order to determine the direction of causality, we have to resort to a VECM. One advantage of VECM over VAR is that it establishes both short- and long-run causality. Thus, the next step is to apply the Granger causality test. Granger causality is a two-step procedure. The first step involves obtaining the residuals from the long-run equation. In the second step the residuals are used as an explanatory variable in the error-correction model. Thus, we estimate the following error-correction models.

Table 6
JOHANSENS TEST FOR COINTEGRATION VARIABLES: GDP a AND FOSSIL FUEL CONSUMPTION Maximum Rank 0 1 Trace Statistic 28.3053 3.0638* 5-Percent Critical Value 15.41 3.76

GDP = gross domestic product; * indicates the maximum number of cointegrating relationships (4 lags according to the Akaike Information Criterion).

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH Table 7


JOHANSENS TEST FOR COINTEGRATION VARIABLES: GDP, TOTAL a ENERGY CONSUMPTION, LABOR, AND INVESTMENT Maximum Rank 0 1 2 Trace Statistic 79.1668 19.5996* 7.8336 5-Percent Critical Value 47.21 29.68 3.76

55

GDP = gross domestic product; * indicates the maximum number of cointegrating relationships (3 lags according to the Akaike Information Criterion).

Bivariate Cases:

Xn DGDPt = a0 + l0 ECT t1 + b DGDPtk k = 1 11;k Xm + b DEnergytk + u1;t k = 1 12;k Xn DEnergyt = a1 + l1 ECT t1 + b DGDPtk k = 1 21;k Xm + b DEnergytk + u2;t k = 1 22;k Xn DGDPt = a0 + l0 ECT t1 + b DGDPtk k = 1 11;k Xm + b Dfossiltk + u1;t k = 1 12;k Xn Dfossilt = a1 + l1 ECT t1 + b DGDPtk k = 1 21;k Xm + b Dfossiltk + u2;t k = 1 22;k

Table 8
JOHANSENS TEST FOR COINTEGRATION VARIABLES: GDP, FOSSIL a FUEL CONSUMPTION, LABOR, AND INVESTMENT Maximum Rank 0 1 2 Trace Statistic 52.9380 24.1510* 8.2546 5-Percent Critical Value 47.21 29.68 15.41

GDP = gross domestic product; * indicates the maximum number of cointegrating relationships (4 lags according to the Akaike Information Criterion).

56

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT


Multivariate Cases:

Xn Xm DGDPt = a0 + l0 ECT t1 + b D GDP + b DEnergytk t k 11 ; k k=1 k = 1 12;k Xp Xq + b DLabortk + b DNet Investmenttk + u1;t k = 1 13;k k = 1 14;k

Xn Xm DEnergyt = a1 + l1 ECT t1 + b D GDP + b DEnergytk t k 21 ; k k=1 k = 1 22;k Xp Xq + b DLabortk + b DNet Investmenttk + u2;t 8 k = 1 23;k k = 1 24;k Xn Xm DLabort = a2 + l2 ECT t1 + b DGDPtk + b DEnergytk k = 1 31;k k = 1 32;k Xp Xq + b DLabortk + b DNet Investmenttk + u3;t 9 k = 1 33;k k = 1 34;k Xn DNet Investmentt = a3 + l3 ECT t1 + b DGDPtk k = 1 41;k Xm Xp + b D Energy + b DLabortk 42 ; k t k =1 k = 1 43;k Xk q + b DNet Investmenttk + u4;t k = 1 44;k Xn Xm DGDPt = a0 + l0 ECT t1 + b D GDP + b Dfossiltk t k 11 ; k k=1 k = 1 12;k Xp Xq + b DLabortk + b DNet Investmenttk + u1;t k = 1 13;k k = 1 14;k

10

11

Xn Xm Dfossilt = a1 + l1 ECT t1 + b D GDP + b Dfossiltk t k k = 1 21;k k = 1 22;k Xp Xq + b DLabortk + b DNet Investmenttk + u2;t 12 k = 1 23;k k = 1 24;k Xn Xm b D GDP + b Dfossiltk Dlabort = a2 + l2 ECT t1 + t k 31 ; k k=1 k = 1 32;k Xp Xq + b DLabortk + b DNet Investmenttk + u3;t 13 k = 1 33;k k = 1 34;k Xn b DGDPtk DNet Investmentt = a3 + l3 ECT t1 + k = 1 41;k Xm Xp + b D fossil + b DLabortk 42 ; k t k =1 k = 1 43;k Xk q + b DNet Investmenttk + u4;t 14 k = 1 44;k Equations (3) through (6) represent the bivariate cases, whereas, equations (7) through (14) represent the multivariate cases. The term ECT in all equations represents the error term. If the coefficient of the error-correction term is statistically significant, then we can conclude that there is a long-term causal relationship among the variables. In order to establish the short-term Granger causality, we need to use the F-test. If the coefficients of energy in equation (3) are jointly significant and the

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH

57

coefficients of GDP in equation (4) are jointly insignificant, then we can conclude that energy causes GDP. Analogously, if the coefficients of energy in equation (3) are jointly insignificant and the coefficients of GDP in equation (4) are jointly significant, then we can conclude that GDP Granger causes energy. And, if both of them are jointly significant, then there is bi-directional causality. If none of them are jointly significant, then we can conclude that there is no short-term causality between the variables. The estimates of these equations are presented in tables 9 and 10.
Vector Error-Correction Model: The estimate of equation (3) is presented in column 1 of table 9. The F-test suggests that energy consumption does not Granger cause GDP. GDP, however, does Granger cause energy consumption according to the estimate of equation (4) presented in column 2 of table 9. We have a similar conclusion based on the estimates of equations (5) and (6) presented in columns 3 and 4 of table 9, respectively. The estimates suggest a uni-directional causality from GDP to fossil fuel consumption. Table 10 presents the estimates of equations (7) through (10). We conclude, on the basis of these estimates, that GDP Granger causes total energy consumption. These estimates also suggest that there is a bi-directional causality between GDP and net investments, a uni-directional causality between net investments and labor where the direction of causality runs from net investments to labor, and net investments causing energy consumption. GDP also causes labor. In table 11 we present the estimates of equations (11) through (14). These results are very similar to the previous cases. On the basis of these estimates, we conclude that GDP Granger causes fossil fuel consumption. We also conclude that there is a bi-directional causality between GDP and net investments, a unidirectional causality between net investments and labor, where the direction of causality runs from net investments to labor and net investments causing fossil fuel consumption. Additionally, GDP Granger causes labor.

Conclusions In this paper we examine the relationship between energy consumption and real GDP in the United States. We employ a multivariate vector error-correction model to determine causality, which in itself is an improvement over the previous studies. Using Johansens multivariate cointegration procedure, we find that the variables are cointegrated. The multivariate VECM suggests that there is a uni-directional causality running from real GDP to total energy and fossil fuel consumption, implying a change in GDP is the driving force behind the changes in energy consumption, and not the other way around. This study provides vital information to the policy makers who design policies to conserve energy and promote economic growth.

58

Table 9
a

BIVARIATE VECTOR ERROR-CORRECTION MODEL RESULTS D_ENERGY (II) 0.0234344 (0.0324023) 103.7965 (2574.887) 6957.154* (4029.324) 3639.78 (2858.875) 0.1916193 (0.170324) 0.0000179 (0.0000158) 1794038*** (508484) GDP F(3, 46) =3.34 Prob>F= 0.0272 101.4808* (51.12278) Fossil F(1, 46)=1.28 Prob>F= 0.2633 0.4732305 (0.3759056) 0.3920799 (0.2817526) 0.7955076*** (0.2379972) 0.0010795 (0.0123181) D_GDP (III)

D_GDP (I)

D_FOSSIL (IV) 0.0427002 (0.0367732) 680.2597 (2520.167) 7842.918* (3941.521) 4124.411 (2848.926)

D_ECT_1

0.0033295 (0.0133421)

D_GDP_1

0.7816533*** (0.2399639)

D_GDP_2

0.4729458 (0.3789246)

D_GDP_3

0.4261752 (0.275278)

D_ENERGY_1

0.0000179 (0.000016)

D_FOSSIL_1

0.2281081 (0.1658861) 1531406*** (480548) GDP F(3, 46) =3.47 Prob>F= 0.0236

INTERCEPT

99.47581** (51.1213)

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT

F-TEST

Energy F(1, 46) =1.26 Prob>F= 0.2684

***significant at 1-percent level; **significant at 5-percent level; and *significant at 10-percent level.

Table 10

MULTIVARIATE VECTOR ERROR-CORRECTION MODEL RESULTS: VARIABLES USED ARE GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT (GDP), ENERGY, LABOR, a AND INVESTMENT (INVEST) D_ENERGY (II) 0.0703519 (0.0611746) 6895.777 (7703.413) 20168.35*** (7299.875) 22308.42*** (7311.116) 0.4722935** (0.1996913) -447.8354 (366.3928) 262.8837 (327.6772) 142.3909 (327.5039) 9138.764 (11402.24) 17.77786*** (5.201374) 0.0002091 (0.0001419) 0.0118229 (0.2600821) 0.2322663 (0.2310994) 0.1800196 (0.2315501) 10.03534 (8.042118) 17.52482*** (5.133905) 2.692694 (5.428733) 0.0327966 (0.0453719) D_LABOR (III) D_INVEST (IV) 0.2492202 (0.2289021) 0.2090096 (0.4046228) 1.342213*** (0.3649022) 1.55195*** (0.397142) 2.74e-06 (9.90e-06) 0.0232125 (0.0184472) 0.0120906 (0.0164401) 0.0229906 (0.0173542) 1.004315* (0.5718396)
(continued)

D_GDP (I)

D_ECT_1

0.002374 (0.0493547)

D_GDP_1

.2688196 (0.6177538)

D_GDP_2

1.561974** (0.5823305)

D_GDP_3

2.766068*** (0.5830984)

D_ENERGY_1

6.24e-06 (0.0000166)

D_LABOR_1

0.0304088 (0.0299265)

D_LABOR_2

0.0053752 (0.0264647)

D_LABOR_3

0.045062* (0.0261611)

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH

D_INVEST_1

1.622981* (0.9170368)

59

Table 10 (continued)

60

MULTIVARIATE VECTOR ERROR-CORRECTION MODEL RESULTS: VARIABLES USED ARE GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT (GDP), ENERGY, LABOR, a AND INVESTMENT (INVEST) D_ENERGY (II) 32762.92*** (10024.61) 17510.2** (8587.262) 2991.618 (5227.875) 2249603*** (807445.4) 1677.744*** (581.0392) 4.686093 (3.689598) 13.87852** (6.197868) 26.16777*** (7.053169) D_LABOR (III) D_INVEST (IV) 2.129864*** (0.5044649) 1.882364*** (0.5302154) 0.2920198 (0.2801936) 36.45782 (40.63718)

D_GDP (I)

D_INVEST_2

2.774423*** (0.7989367)

D_INVEST_3

3.497289*** (.6880476)

D_INVEST_4

0.5168192 (0.4208082)

INTERCEPT

26.04808 (67.01391)

F-TEST

Energy F(1, 38) = 0.14 Prob>F= 0.7096 Labor F(3, 38) = 1.53 Prob>F= 0.2233 Investment F(3, 38) = 8.92 Prob>F= 0.0001

Labor F(3, 38) = 1.09 Prob>F= 0.3653 Investment F(3, 38) = 3.76 Prob>F= 0.0186 GDP F(3, 38) = 4.66 Prob>F= 0.0072

GDP F(3, 38) = 5.55 Prob>F= 0.0029 Energy F(1, 38) = 2.17 Prob> F= 0.1487 Investment F(3, 38) = 5.10 Prob> F= 0.0046

Energy F(1, 38) = 0.08 Prob>F=0.7835 GDP F(3, 38) = 6.54 Prob>F=0.0011 Labor F(3, 38) = 1.51 Prob>F=0.2265

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT

***significant at 1-percent level; **significant at 5-percent level; and *significant at 10-percent level.

Table 11

MULTIVARIATE VECTOR ERROR-CORRECTION MODEL RESULTS: VARIABLES USED ARE GROSS DOMESTIC a PRODUCT (GDP), FOSSIL FUEL CONSUMPTION (FOSSIL), LABOR, AND INVESTMENT (INVEST) D_FOSSIL (II) 0.068707 (0.0564346) 7600.239 (7812.168) 17432.83** (7416.104) 20200.01* (7405.575) 0.5179883** (0.1987462) 451.6503 (364.8164) 391.4331 (331.299) 257.0285 (335.1306) 9797.057 (11543.56) 17.24164*** (5.256978) 0.0001769 (0.0001406) 0.0212535 (0.2576101) 0.2468435 (0.2318647) 0.17072 (0.2361831) 9.261031 (8.108333) 17.42872*** (5.175979) 2.24671 (5.475896) 0.0342902 (0.03657) D_LABOR (III) D_INVEST (IV) 0.2747705 (0.2324934) 0.2033695 (0.4043551) 1.33401*** (0.36534) 1.54126*** (0.3951476) 3.59e-06 (9.75e-06) 0.0242287 (0.0181485) 0.012343 (0.0163785) 0.0227868 (0.017534) 1.008956* (0.5700038)
(continued)

D_GDP (I)

D_ECT_1

0.0018327 (0.0481999)

D_GDP_1

0.2631849 (0.6179773)

D_GDP_2

1.560314** (0.585448)

D_GDP_3

2.76091*** (0.582127)

D_FOSSIL_1

5.15e-06 (0.0000163)

D_LABOR_1

0.0291057 (0.0293584)

D_LABOR_2

0.005596 (0.0263915)

D_LABOR_3

0.0453091* (0.0264515)

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH

D_INVEST_1

1.61567* (0.9201502)

61

62

Table 11 (continued)

MULTIVARIATE VECTOR ERROR-CORRECTION MODEL RESULTS: VARIABLES USED ARE GROSS DOMESTIC a PRODUCT (GDP), FOSSIL FUEL CONSUMPTION (FOSSIL), LABOR, AND INVESTMENT (INVEST) D_FOSSIL (II) 30124.22*** (10082.49) 14463.82* (8678.809) 3915.097 (5287.195) 2098786** (813491) 5.066781 (3.702672) 1768.117*** (586.6656) 13.05634** (6.289143) 25.5012*** (7.03463) D_LABOR (III) D_INVEST (IV) 2.137947*** (0.5002836) 1.852596*** (0.5302275) 0.2893147 (0.2794598) 36.18944 (40.30212)

D_GDP (I)

D_INVEST_2

2.756288*** (0.7957488)

D_INVEST_3

3.48962*** (0.6868857)

D_INVEST_4

0.5311273 (0.4223463)

INTERCEPT

27.01026 (66.72048)

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT

F-TEST

Fossil (1, 38) = 0.10 Prob>F= 0.7536 Labor F(3, 38) = 1.45 Prob>F= 0.2432 Investment F(3, 38) = 8.92 Prob>F= 0.0001

GDP F(3, 38) = 3.86 Prob>F= 0.0166 Labor F(3, 38) = 1.52 Prob>F = 0.2254 Investment F(3, 38) = 3.24 Prob>F= 0.0325

Fossil F(1, 38) = 1.58 Prob>F= 0.2160 GDP F(3, 38) = 5.30 Prob>F= 0.038 Investment F(3, 38) = 4.84 Prob>F= 0.0060

Fossil F(1, 38) = 0.14 Prob>F=0.7147 GDP F(3, 38) = 6.51 Prob>F=0.0012 Labor F(3, 38) = 1.56 Prob>F=0.2153

***significant at 1-percent level; **significant at 5-percent level; and *significant at 10-percent level.

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH


NOTES

63

1 David. I. Stern, A Multivariate Cointegration Analysis of the Role of Energy in the US Macroeconomy, Energy Economics, vol. 22, no. 2 (2000), pp. 26783, and Bwo-Nung Huang, M. J. Hwang, and C. W. Yang, Causal Relationship between Energy Consumption and GDP Growth Revised: A Dynamic Panel Data Approach, Ecological Economics, vol. 67, no. 1 (2008), pp. 4154. 2 John Kraft and Arthur Kraft, On the Relationship between Energy and GNP, The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 3, no. 2 (spring 1978), pp. 4013.

A. T. Akarca and T. V. Long, On the Relationship between Energy and GNP: A Reexamination, The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 5, no. 2 (spring 1980), pp. 32631. S. Abosedra and H. Baghestani, New Evidence on the Causal Relationship between United States Energy Consumption and Gross National Product, The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 14, no. 2 (spring 1989), pp. 28592.
5 E. S. H. Yu and B. K. Hwang, The Relationship between Energy and GNP: Further Results, Energy Economics, vol. 6, no. 3 (1984), pp. 18690; E. S. H. Yu and J. Y. Choi, The Causal Relationship between Energy and GNP: An International Comparison, The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 10, no. 2 (spring 1985), pp. 24972; E. S. H. Yu and Jang C. Jin, Cointegration Tests of Energy Consumption, Income, and Employment, Resources and Energy, vol. 14, no. 3 (1992), 259 66; and B. S. Cheng, An Investigation of Cointegration and Causality between Energy Consumption and Economic Growth, The Journal of Energy and Development, vol. 21, no. 1 (autumn 1995), pp. 73 84. 6 Chiou-Wei Song Zan and Ko Chu-Chun, A Meta-Analysis of the Relationships between Energy Consumption and Economic Growth, Proceedings of the 14th Conference on Interdisciplinary and Multifunctional Business and Management, Taiwan, June 25, 2011, pp. 52845. 7 8 9 4

David. I. Stern, op. cit. Ibid. Ibid. Bwo-Nung Huang et al., op. cit. Ibid. Ibid.

10 11 12 13

Ansgar Belke, Frauke De Haan, and Christian Dreger, Energy Consumption and Economic Growth: New Insights into the Cointegration Relationship, Energy Economics, vol. 33, no. 5 (2011), pp. 78289.
14 15

Chiou-Wei Song Zan and Ko Chu-Chun, op. cit.

W. Oh and K. Lee, Causal Relationship between Energy Consumption and GDP Revisited: The Case of Korea 19701999, Energy Economics, vol. 26, no. 1 (2004), pp. 519.
16

Ibid.

64

THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT

17 James E. Payne, Survey of the International Evidence on the Causal Relationship between Energy Consumption and Growth, Journal of Economic Studies, vol. 37, no. 1 (2010), pp. 5395.

K. Imran and M. Siddiqui, Energy Consumption and Economic Growth: A Case Study of Three SAARC Countries, European Journal of Social Sciences, vol. 16, no. 2 (2010), pp. 20624.
19 20

18

Ibid.

Anjum Aqeel and Mohammad S. Butt, The Relationship between Energy Consumption and Economic Growth in Pakistan, Asia-Pacific Development Journal, vol. 8, no. 2 (2001), pp. 10110. U. Soytas and R. Sari, Energy Consumption and GDP: Causality Relationship in G-7 Countries and Emerging Markets, Energy Economics, vol. 25, no. 1 (2003), pp. 337.
22 U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration (EIA), also available at http:// www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/annual/showtext.cfm?t=ptb0103. 21

D. Dickey and W. Fuller, Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with A Unit Root, Journal of the American Statistical Association, vol. 74, no. 366 (June 1979), pp. 42731, and P. C. B. Phillips and P. Perron, Testing For Unit Root in Time Series Regression, Biometrika, vol. 75, no. 2 (1988), pp. 33546. A. Sharma, The Long Run Determinants of the U.S. Trade Balance: A Reexamination Using Bi & Multivariate Cointegration Approach, Research in Applied Economics, vol. 4, no. 1 (March 2012), pp. 1632. R. Engle and C. Granger, Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing, Econometrica, vol. 55, no. 2 (1987), pp. 25176, and S. Johansen and K. Juselius, Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on Cointegration with Applications to the Demand for Money, Oxford Bulletin of Statistics, vol. 52, no. 2 (1999), pp. 169210. J. Gonzales, Five Alternative Methods of Estimating Long-Run Equilibrium Relationships, Journal of Econometrics, vol. 60, nos. 12 (1994), pp. 20333.
27 26 25 24

23

Walter Enders, Applied Econometric Time Series (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 2010).

You might also like