You are on page 1of 44

ADB Economics Working Paper Series

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility?


Hyun-Hoon Lee, Cyn-Young Park , Hyung-suk Byun No. 302 | September 2012

ADB Economics Working Paper Series

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility?


Hyun-Hoon Lee, Cyn-Young Park , Hyung-suk Byun No. 302 September 2012
Hyun-Hoon Lee is Professor of Economics at the Department of International Trade and Business at Kangwon National University. Cyn-Young Park is Assistant Chief Economist at the Asian Development Bank. Hyung-suk Byun is Researcher at Kangwon National University. The authors are grateful to Aitor Erce, Rebecca Neumann, and Won Joong Kim for comments and suggestions. The authors would also like to thank Lea Ortega for her excellent research assistance.

Asian Development Bank 6 ADB Avenue, Mandaluyong City 1550 Metro Manila, Philippines www.adb.org 2012 by Asian Development Bank September 2012 ISSN 1655-5252 Publication Stock No. WPS124993

The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views and policies of the Asian Development Bank (ADB) or its Board of Governors or the governments they represent. ADB does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this publication and accepts no responsibility for any consequence of their use. By making any designation of or reference to a particular territory or geographic area, or by using the term country in this document, ADB does not intend to make any judgments as to the legal or other status of any territory or area. Note: In this publication, $ refers to US dollars.

The ADB Economics Working Paper Series is a forum for stimulating discussion and eliciting feedback on ongoing and recently completed research and policy studies undertaken by the Asian Development Bank (ADB) staff, consultants, or resource persons. The series deals with key economic and development problems, particularly those facing the Asia and Pacific region; as well as conceptual, analytical, or methodological issues relating to project/program economic analysis, and statistical data and measurement. The series aims to enhance the knowledge on Asias development and policy challenges; strengthen analytical rigor and quality of ADBs country partnership strategies, and its subregional and country operations; and improve the quality and availability of statistical data and development indicators for monitoring development effectiveness. The ADB Economics Working Paper Series is a quick-disseminating, informal publication whose titles could subsequently be revised for publication as articles in professional journals or chapters in books. The series is maintained by the Economics and Research Department.

Printed on recycled paper

CONTENTS

ABSTRACT I. II. INTRODUCTION DESCRIPTIVE ANALYSIS A. B. C. III. Data on Capital Flows Measurement for Volatility of Capital Flows Trend of Volatility by Different Types of Capital Flows

v 1 3 3 6 7 13 13 13 13 16 16 16 20 23 28 28 29 35

EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION A. B. C. D. The Model Dependent Variable Explanatory Variables Specification

IV.

RESULTS A. B. C. D. Global Contagion Effects Intraregional versus Extra-regional Contagion Effects Results for Sub-sample Period: 19952009 Robustness Checks

V.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

APPENDIXES REFERENCES

ABSTRACT

The paper aims to assess what influences volatility of capital flows to emerging countries and whether or not there is a spillover or contagion effect in the volatility. The empirical results suggest strong and significant contagion effects from global and regional volatilities on the volatility of capital flows in different types to individual economies. The evidence of contagion from global and regional volatilities implies that there is a strong need for global and regional policy cooperation to contain the spillover or contagion effects. However, other policy variables have a differential and time-varying effect on volatility of different types of capital inflow, presenting policy dilemma and challenge to producing coordinated efforts by global and regional policy makers.

I. INTRODUCTION Volatility of international capital flows and the limited ability of developing economies to deal with it continue to be a major international policy concern. Multiple episodes of financial crisis in the 1990s highlighted the disruptive potential of capital flow volatility beyond a national border, prompting the global talk about reforming the international monetary and financial system. Fischer (1998) noted two important reasons for the reform. First, international capital flows to emerging markets tend to be too large and volatile, frequently disrupting their economic activity. Second, international financial systems are often subject to contagion. As the global financial crisis of 2008/2009 has renewed interest in the reform of the international monetary system, there is a great sense of dj vu. The spillover or contagion effects first caught the attention of the global financial community, as the Mexican devaluation in December 1994 brought an abrupt end to capital flows to many Latin American economies and triggered speculative attacks on their currenciesdubbed as the tequila effect afterwards. The next crisis that hit many Asian economies in 1997 spread beyond the regional boundary, triggering a debt default and ruble depreciation by Russian Federation and pushing the United States (US) hedge fund Long-Term Capital Management to the brink of bankruptcy. The spillover or contagion effect culminated in the global financial crisis of 2008/2009, which rattled financial markets worldwide and pushed the world economy into the worst recession since World War II. Contagion refers to the cross-border transmission of financial shocks, through comovements of asset prices and capital flows. The causes of contagion fall into broadly two categories: similar fundamentals and herding behaviors of financial agents (Calvo and Reinhart, 1996; and Dornbusch, Park, and Claessens, 2000). First, co-movements may arise when economies share similar fundamentals and have strong macroeconomic interdependence through trade and financial linkages. Asset prices and capital flows may respond similarly to a shock given the similar fundamentals while the shock can be transmitted rapidly through trade and investment channels. It may be natural to expect that these similar fundamentals lead to strong co-movements in asset prices and capital flows. Second, co-movements may result from the behaviors of financial agents regardless of economic fundamentals. A crisis in one country may prompt investors to withdraw from other countries without properly examining the fundamental linkage. Eichengreen, Rose, and Wyplosz (1997) also find that the odd of a speculative attack in one country increases when there was a speculative attack elsewhere in the world, suggesting the existence of the herding or bandwagon effects in currency crises. Behaviors of indiscriminating investors and speculators may seem irrational. However, seemingly irrational behaviors, driven by herding, panics, a loss of confidence, and swings in investor sentiment can still result from individually rational choices. Hence, Karolyi (2003) suggests the third category of irrational co-movements or contagion in a much more puristic sense. Empirical studies in search for the evidence of contagion have largely focused on co-movements of asset prices, with some extensions to examine excess or excessive co-movements; yet evidence of contagion is at best controversial depending on the arbitrary definition of the purely contagious effects (Karolyi, 2003). Many speculated on the connection between herding/contagion and volatility of capital flows (Calvo and Reinhart, 1996; and Dornbusch, Park, and Claessens, 2000). However, very few examined the effect of contagion on capital flow volatility.

2 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

With increased capital mobility, studies proliferated to investigate why capital flows, especially to developing economies, are volatile and what determines the level of cross-border flows. Only recently, however, some began to focus more explicitly on volatility of capital flows. Broner and Rigobon (2006) and Alfaro, Kalemli-Ozcan, and Volosovych (2007) try to explain why foreign capital flow is more volatile in emerging economies than in advanced economies. Broner and Rigobon (2006) find that the higher volatility in developing countries can be explained by their relatively high exposures to occasional crises, contagion, and more persistent shocks to capital flows compared with developed economies, rather than by the volatility of their economic fundamentals. Alfaro, Kalemli-Ozcan, and Volosovych (2007) emphasize the importance of institutional quality and the soundness of macroeconomic policies in explaining these volatility differences by focusing on total equity flows (foreign direct investment [FDI] and portfolio flows). Recent studies also note the different patterns of volatility exhibited by different types of capital flows and explore the factors behind the volatility dynamics. Neumann, Penl, Tanku (2009) examine how different types of capital flows respond to the opening of financial markets. Specifically, they show that a further opening of financial markets tends to increase the volatility of FDI in emerging economies, while it does not lead to any meaningful change in the volatility of portfolio investment flows. This, however, stands in contrast to the findings of the International Monetary Funds (IMFs) 2007 Global Financial Stability Report that financial market openness and institutional quality are negatively associated with the volatility of capital flows in both emerging and developed economies. Broto, Diaz-Cassou, and Erce (2011) suggest global conditions have differential impacts on FDI, portfolio investment, and other investment flows. Based on Engle and Gonzalo Rangel (2008), they estimate conditional volatilities of different types of capital flows to investigate the impact of various domestic and global factors on volatility. Their results show that global factors have become increasingly significant relative to country specific factors since 2000, underlining the volatility of portfolio and other investment flows and that the institutional framework has important implications for capital flow volatility. In a similar fashion, Mercado and Park (2011) investigate the impact of a set of domestic and global factors on the level and volatility of different types of capital flows to developing economies, using the standard deviation of these flows (as a % of gross domestic product [GDP]) in 5-year rolling windows as the volatility estimates. Their findings suggest that better institutional quality is important for attracting more and stable capital inflows while pull factors in general seem more relevant than push factors for capital flow volatility. They also report that a regional factor plays an important role in determining the volatility of capital inflows to emerging Europe and emerging Latin America. This paper aims to assess the effects of spillover or contagion in the volatility of capital flows to developing countries. As in Broto, Diaz-Cassou, and Erce (2011); Mercado and Park (2011); and Neumann, Penl, and Tanku (2009), this paper focuses on volatility of capital flows. However, three major differences set our paper apart from the previous studies. First, this paper, while adopting the most commonly used measure of volatilitystandard deviation of capital flows in a moving window, employs a more rigorous normalization procedure. Second, this paper examines how volatility of capital flows to individual emerging economy responds to the volatility of capital flows (i) to all developing countries, (ii) to the neighboring countries in the same region, and (iii) to all the other developing countries outside the region. Third, in addition

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 3

to the usual three types of capital flows, FDI, portfolio investment, and other investment flows from IMFs International Financial Statistics (IFS), this study includes the net flows of long-term 2 and short-term external debt in its analysis, drawn from World Banks World Development 3 Indicators-Global Development Finance (WDI-GDF) online database.

As noted in Broto, Diaz-Cassou, and Erce (2011), measuring volatility of capital flows is not straightforward. In this paper, we use the standard deviation in rolling windows to estimate time-varying volatilities. But recognizing some important drawbacks of the standard deviation, we adopt a standardization methodology similar to the concept of coefficient of variation over different sub-periods to estimate more accurate measure of volatility. Using a new measure of volatility, we estimate the effects of spillover or contagion more specifically, by regressing the volatility of capital flows to individual economies against the volatility of capital flows to all developing economies, their regional neighbors, and all the other developing countries outside the region. This is in addition to a battery of domestic factors drawing on the previous studies. We also estimate inter- and intraregional contagion effects for the sub-sample period of 1995 2009 separately from the whole sample period of 19802009 to assess whether the effects have changed in recent years. The empirical results can also confirm the argument of Broto, Diaz-Cassou, and Erce (2011) that since 2000 global factor beyond the control of emerging economies have become increasingly significant relative to country-specific drivers (p.1). This paper presents evidence for strong contagion effects of intraregional volatilities and that in recent years the intraregional effects have become stronger, in some types of capital flows. We find that policy variables such as financial openness, macroeconomic stability, and accumulation of foreign exchange reserves have a differential and time-varying effect on the volatility of different types of capital flows. The findings of the varying impacts suggest difficulty in designing a universal policy framework to reduce capital flow volatility. The only exception is institutional quality that turns out to be the only significant factor that seems to reduce the volatility of certain types of capital flows without increasing that of others. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. After a brief discussion on the data and accurate measure of volatility of capital flows, Section II presents the trend of volatilities for different types of capital flows in different country groups. In Section III, we describe the empirical framework and the key variables. In Section IV, we report and discuss our main results. Section V offers a summary and some policy implications.

II. DESCRIPTIVE ANALYSIS A. Data on Capital Flows


4

For this paper, we collected annual data on capital inflows for the period 19902009 from the IMFs International Financial Statistics (IFS) and World Banks World Development IndicatorsGlobal Development Finance (WDI-GDF) online database. Earlier studies suggest the
1 2

Other investment consists mostly of cross-border bank lending. Net flows of long-term and short-term external debt during the year are disbursements minus principal repayments. Long-term external debt is defined as debt that has an original or extended maturity of more than one year. Shortterm external debt is defined as debt that has an original maturity of one year or less. Broner and Rigobon (2006) and IMF (2007) analyze only total inflows, while other authors focus exclusively on one type of investment flows. For instance, Alfaro, Kalemli-Ozcan, and Volosovych (2007) focus on equity flows only. For many countries in the sample, quarterly series of capital flows were not available.

4 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

composition of capital flows matter in terms of financial volatility. Empirical evidence also points to the relatively high volatility of short-term capital flows such as bank lending and portfolio investments compared with long-term flows such as FDI. Wei and Wu (2001), Ju and Wei (2006), Levchenko and Mauro (2007), and Tong and Wei (2009) also find that the economy is more vulnerable to a financial crisis if the composition of capital flows is skewed toward short term flows that are more likely to be reversed than FDI in times of financial stress. In order to evaluate the differential impacts of contagion on volatility by different types of capital flows, our data is divided into FDI, portfolio investment, and other investment flows based on IFS as well as short- and long-term debt flows from the WDI-GDF online database. We include 50 emerging and developing economies in our sample dataset. Following the wave of financial liberalization in late 1980s and 1990s, capital flows to emerging economies have increased dramatically. However, the composition of capital flows varies significantly across different regions and economies as well as over time. Figures 1A1D present net capital flows to emerging economies (in % of GDP) by different regional groups. FDI flows constitute the most positive important category of capital flows to emerging economies, averaging 1.8% of GDP for the whole sample period compared with portfolio investment flows at 0.4% and other investment flows at 0.4%. Emerging Asia attracts the least capital flows relative to its GDP but with the relatively high share of more stable FDI flows compared with other developing regions. Consistent with the earlier studies, swings in net other investment flows are the largest, particularly pronounced in emerging Asia during the Asian financial crisis of 1997/1998 and in emerging Europe in 1990, 1994, and 2007. The composition of capital flows is also changing over time, gradually shifting toward long-term flows.

Figure 1: Net Capital Flows (% GDP) (A) Total Emerging Economies


10 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

Direct Investments

Portfolio Investments

Other Investments

Note: Other investments include financial derivatives. Data for Estonia and Latvia start in 1992; data for Belarus, Czech Republic, Lithuania and Slovakia start in 1993; data for Moldova, Russian Federation, and Ukraine start in 1994; data for Hong Kong, China; and Viet Nam start in 1998 and 1996, respectively. Source: Author's calculations using data from International Financial Statistics, and World Economic Outlook Database, International Monetary Fund.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 5

(B) Emerging Asia


10 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
2007

2008
2008

Direct Investments

Portfolio Investments

Other Investments

Note: Other investments include financial derivatives. Data for Hong Kong, China; and Viet Nam start in 1998 and 1996, respectively. Source: Author's calculations using data from Internatioal Financial Statistics, and World Economic Outlook Database, International Monetary Fund.

(C) Emerging Europe


10 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2009

Direct Investments

Portfolio Investments

Other Investments

Note: Other investments include financial derivatives. Data for Hong Kong, China; and Viet Nam start in 1998 and 1996, respectively. Source: Author's calculations using data from Internatioal Financial Statistics, and World Economic Outlook Database, International Monetary Fund.

2009

6 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

(D) Emerging Latin America


10 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

Direct Investments

Portfolio Investments

Other Investments

Note: Other investments include financial derivatives. Source: Author's calculations using data from International Financial Statistics, and World Economic Outlook Database, International Monetary Fund.

B.

Measurement for Volatility of Capital Flows

The standard deviation of capital flows in a rolling window is a widely used measure of volatility. This measure of capital flow volatility for country i in year t, it, is given by the following expression:

V it

1 nk

2 ( flowik  P ) 2 t  ( n 1)

(1)

Where P

1 nk

t ( n 1)

flowik , and flowik denotes capital inflows (or capital inflows relative to

country is GDP) to country i and in period k. While the standard deviation is a popular measure of volatility, this measure has some important drawbacks. First, technically, the standard deviation shows dispersion from the mean, so different means will generate different dimensions to the standard deviation. That is, the standard deviation will give very different estimates of volatility depending on the means (in this case, the size of capital flows) and does not necessarily correspond to the actual magnitude of variation. For instance, let us consider two hypothetical cases of capital inflows to two different countries during the period of 20052009, which are (2, 4, 1, 3, 5) for country i and (20, 40, 10, 30, 50) for country j. While the variation of capital inflows appears to be the same for both countries, the standard deviation for country i is 1.58 and it is 15.8 for country j. With steady increases in capital flows to developing economies since 1990s, the use of the standard

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 7

deviation may well exaggerate the size of volatility over time. Recognizing such drawback, this paper normalizes the size of capital flows in each rolling window. That is, we set the largest capital flows in absolute terms at 100 and adjust the rest of capital flows series accordingly. In the above example, for country i, 5 will be set to 100 and others will be adjusted accordingly to generate a normalized capital flow series (40, 80, 20, 60, 100). The appropriate normalization for country j, with 50 set to 100 would generate the same set. The normalized standard 5 deviation is now 31.6 in both cases. Second, the choice of the length of a rolling window is arbitrary. Recent studies including IMF (2007); Neumann, Penl, and Tanku (2009): and Mercado and Park (2011) used 5-year rolling windows to calculate the standard deviation of capital inflows. The standard deviation using a longer window will provide more information about volatility, but the number of observations will be reduced as a result. In this paper, we also use the 5-year moving window, but the estimates using the 3-year moving window will be provided as a robustness check. We also tried to better match the volatility to each year. For example, we use the standard deviation of capital flows during a 5-year rolling window for the volatility value in the mid-year of this window. That is, the above equation is not considered as the standard deviation of time t, but of time t-(n-1)/2. Therefore, in the above example, 31.6 will be considered as the volatility of capital inflows in 2007. Third, the standard deviation of a rolling window is strongly persistent. The standard deviation of each rolling window is highly related to the standard deviations of the previous and next rolling windows to the extent that these windows overlap. Therefore, when the standard deviation of capital flows in a rolling widow is used as the dependent variable in a regression analysis, the error term is serially correlated by construction. In order to overcome this drawback, this study utilizes the system generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator for dynamic panel data models of Blundell and Bond (1998), which combine moment conditions for the model in first differences with moment conditions for the model in levels. C. Trend of Volatility by Different Types of Capital Flows

This section compares the relative size of volatility by different types of capital, measured as normalized standard deviation of 5-year moving window for the period of 19802009. Figure 2A shows the trend of volatility by five different types of capital inflows (relative to GDP) to all developing countries included in the sample of this study: FDI, portfolio investment, other investment, long-term external debt, and short-term external debt. It is worthwhile to note that FDI has the lowest volatility and short-term external debt has the highest volatility. This finding is consistent with the previous studies that FDI is relatively more stable and resilient to shocks compared with other types of capital flows, and short-term external debt is least stable. Another interesting point is that the volatilities of most capital flows remain stable over time, except the volatility of long-term external debt that shows an upward trend since the early 1980s.

One may wish to employ coefficient of variation to get dimensionless volatility by dividing standard deviation by the mean of each window. However, when the mean value is less than 1.0, the coefficient of variation becomes very large and sensitive to small changes in the mean value. For example, consider another two series of capital flows of (20, 40, 5, 20, 40) and (20, 40, 2.5, 20, 40). In these two series, the only difference is 5 and 2.5 at each midpoint and hence their volatilities should be similar. Indeed, our preferred method of normalization would produce the volatility of 79.254 and 79.068 for each series, respectively. But the coefficient of variation will produce very different volatilities for these two series at 63.285 and 126.992, respectively.

8 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

Figure 2: Volatilities of Different Types of Capital Inflows to All Developing Countries in the World (A) Calculation Based on 5-year Moving Average
90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0

(B) Calculation Based on 3-year Moving Average


90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0
19801982 19811983 19821984 19831985 19841986 19851987 19861988 19871989 19881990 19891991 19901992 19911993 19921994 19931995 19941996 19951997 19961998 19971999 19982000 19992001 20002002 20012003 20022004 20032005 20042006 20052007 20062008 20072009

Note: FDI, FPI, and IOI refer to the standard deviation of foreign direct investment, portfolio investment, and other flows (mostly bank lending) in % of GDP, respectively. NFED_LT and NFED_ST refer to the standard deviation of net flows on long-term external debt and on short-term external debt in % of GDP, respectively. Source: Calculated by the authors using the IMFs International Financial Statistics and World Banks World Development Indicators-Global Development Finance (WDI-GDF) online database.For a comparison, Figure 2B illustrates the trend of volatilities measured as standard deviation of a 3-year moving window. Using the 3-year moving window gives more variability in the volatility trend, as the smoothing effect of a longer window is reduced. Nonetheless, the above two observations remain valid; FDI has the lowest volatility and short-term external debt the highest.

19801984 19811985 19821986 19831987 19841988 19851989 19861990 19871991 19881992 19891993 19901994 19911995 19921996 19931997 19941998 19951999 19962000 19972001 19982002 19992003 20002004 20012005 20022006 20032007 20042008 20052009
VIFDI VIFPI VIOI VNFED_LT VNFED_ST
VIFDI VIFPI VIOI VNFED_LT VNFED_ST

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 9

For a comparison, Figure 2B illustrates the trend of volatilities measured as standard deviation of a 3-year moving window. Using the 3-year moving window gives more variability in the volatility trend, as the smoothing effect of a longer window is reduced. Nonetheless, the above two observations remain valid; FDI has the lowest volatility and short-term external debt the highest. Figure 3 depicts the trend of volatility of the three different types of capital flows into three different regional groups of developing countries: (i) East Asian developing countries; (ii) 6 Latin American developing countries; and (iii) Eastern European developing countries. As seen in the Figure 3, the volatility of FDI flows is the lowest in all three different regions, while portfolio and other investment flows (mostly bank lending) show similar levels of volatility. The figure also shows that volatilities of all three types of capital flows to Asian and Eastern European developing countries picked up during the period of the global financial crisis of 20072009, while those to Latin America appear to have remained stable or rather declined during the same period. Given that our data coverage is limited until 2009, the full crisis impact may not have been captured. Nonetheless, the results suggest that the crisis effects might have been delayed in Latin American developing countries.

Figure 3: Volatilities of FDI, Portfolio Investment, and Other Investment to Different Country Groups (A) Asian Developing Countries
90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10

A complete list of countries in each region is shown in Appendix 1.

19801984 19811985 19821986 19831987 19841988 19851989 19861990 19871991 19881992 19891993 19901994 19911995 19921996 19931997 19941998 19951999 19962000 19972001 19982002 19992003 20002004 20012005 20022006 20032007 20042008 20052009
FDI FPI IOI

10 10 20 30 40 50 0

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

60

70

80

90

10 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

(B) Latin American Developing Countries

(C) Eastern European Developing Countries

FDI FDI FPI IOI

FPI

IOI

Source: Calculated by the authors using the IMFs International Financial Statistics online database.

Note: FDI, FPI, and IOI refer to the 5year standard deviation of foreign direct investment, portfolio investment, and other flows (mostly bank lending) in % of GDP, respectively.

19801984 19811985 19821986 19831987 19841988 19851989 19861990 19871991 19881992 19891993 19901994 19911995 19921996 19931997 19941998 19951999 19962000 19972001 19982002 19992003 20002004 20012005 20022006 20032007 20042008 20052009

19801984 19811985 19821986 19831987 19841988 19851989 19861990 19871991 19881992 19891993 19901994 19911995 19921996 19931997 19941998 19951999 19962000 19972001 19982002 19992003 20002004 20012005 20022006 20032007 20042008 20052009

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 11

Figure 4 depicts the trend of volatility of two different types of net foreign debt flows to the three different regions: (i) long-term debt; and (ii) short-term debt. In general, net flow of long-term debt appears to be more stable than that of short-term debt in all regions, but the gap has narrowed in recent years, as the volatility of long-term external debt increased in all regions.

Figure 4: Volatilities of Long-term and Short-term Foreign Debts to Different Country Groups Asian Developing Countries
90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10

19801984 19811985 19821986 19831987 19841988 19851989 19861990 19871991 19881992 19891993 19901994 19911995 19921996 19931997 19941998 19951999 19962000 19972001 19982002 19992003 20002004 20012005 20022006 20032007 20042008 20052009
NFED_LT NFED_ST

12 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

(B) Latin American Developing Countries


90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10
19801984 19811985 19821986 19831987 19841988 19851989 19861990 19871991 19881992 19891993 19901994 19911995 19921996 19931997 19941998 19951999 19962000 19972001 19982002 19992003 20002004 20012005 20022006 20032007 20042008 20052009

NFED_LT

NFED_ST

(C) Eastern European Developing Countries


90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10

Note: NFED_LT and NFED_ST refer to the 5year standard deviation of net flows on long-term external debt and on short-term external debt in % of GDP, respectively. Source: Calculated by the authors using World Banks World Development Indicators-Global Development Finance online database.

19801984 19811985 19821986 19831987 19841988 19851989 19861990 19871991 19881992 19891993 19901994 19911995 19921996 19931997 19941998 19951999 19962000 19972001 19982002 19992003 20002004 20012005 20022006 20032007 20042008 20052009
NFED_LT NFED_ST

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 13

Tables in Appendix 2 provide the estimated volatilities for different types of capital flows into the 50 individual countries included in the sample of the study.

III. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION A. The Model

This paper constructs a panel data set using the volatility measures obtained in the previous section as the dependent variable. Explanatory variables are grouped in three categories: external variables, policy variables, and control variables. The equation to be estimated is VMit = 0 + EVit 1 + PVit-1 2 + CVit-1 3 + it. (2)

Where VM is a volatility measure of the five different types of capital inflows, EV is a vector of external variables, PV is a vector of policy variables, and CV is a vector of control variables. is a vector of unknown coefficients and it is an error term. As will be explained, except for external variables, all other explanatory variables are one-year lagged to minimize endogeneity problem. B. Dependent Variable

We use volatility of capital inflows measured by standard deviation of capital flows relative to GDP (drawn from IMFs IFS database). First, this paper compares the volatilities of the following three types of capital flows: x x x VFDI : 5-year standard deviation of net foreign direct investment inflows in % of GDP VFPI: 5-year standard deviation of net portfolio investment inflows in % of GDP VOI: 5-year standard deviation of net other investment inflows in % of GDP

Second, the following two definitions of external debt (drawn from World Banks WDIGDF) online database) will also be used as dependant variables. x x VED_LT: 5-year standard deviation of net inflows on long-term external debt in % of GDP VED_ST: 5-year standard deviation of net inflows on short-term external debt in % of GDP

As noted above, we also compute standard deviations over moving window of 3 years to check the robustness of the empirical results. C. Explanatory Variables

External Variables: The dearth of theory to predict volatility dynamics of capital flows explains a wide spectrum of models and variables used to determine the capital flow volatility. As the main purpose of this paper as asserted in the introduction is to assess the effects of spillover or contagion in the volatility of capital flows to emerging economies, we construct two separate variables to evaluate the impact of regional and global volatilities on the volatility of capital flows to individual

14 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

economies. First, intraregional volatility is constructed as the simple average volatility of capital flows to the neighboring countries in the same region when an individual economy belongs to 7 each of three regional groupsEast Asia, Latin America, and Eastern Europe. Second, global volatility is constructed as the simple average of volatilities of capital flows to all emerging countries in the sample. Global volatility can be further refined to extra-regional volatilities of capital flows to emerging countries. That is, extra-regional volatility is constructed as the simple average volatility of capital flows to all other emerging countries outside each of the three regional groups. 1. Global Volatility ALL: Simple average of the world-wide volatilities of net capital inflows to all emerging countries 2. Intraregional Volatility East_Asia_Intra: Simple average volatility of net capital inflows to other neighboring countries in East Asia Latin_America_Intra: Simple average volatility of net capital inflows to other neighboring countries in Latin America East_Europe_Intra: Simple average volatility of net capital inflows to other neighboring countries in Eastern Europe Extraregional Volatility East_Asia_Extra: Simple average volatility of net capital inflows into other emerging countries outside East Asia Latin_America_Extra: Simple average volatility of net capital inflows into other emerging countries outside Latin America East_Europe_Extra: Simple average volatility of net capital inflows into other emerging countries outside Eastern Europe As contagion can occur in very short-term, the above global and regional volatility variables enter in regression contemporaneously. Policy Variables: We also include some policy variables in the regression analysis to assess how these variables are associated with the volatility of capital flows to emerging economies. Four policy variables are considered: financial market openness, institutional quality, macroeconomic stability, and accumulation of foreign exchange reserves. Financial openness is measured as Chin and Itos (2010) financial openness index which is the extensity of capital controls based on the information from the IMFs Annual Report
7

The whole sample also includes the developing countries located in Africa, Middle East, South Asia, and the Pacific, but the average volatility of capital inflows to these countries is not included as these countries do not reveal regional identity as compared with Asia, Latin America, and Eastern Europe. See Appendix 1 for the list of the countries in each regional group.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 15

on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions. Institutional quality is measured as 8 Worldwide Governance Indicators developed by Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi. This includes measures for voice and accountability, political stability and absence of violence, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law; and control of corruption. It is expected that volatility of capital flows is negatively related with institutional quality. On the other hand, macroeconomic stability is approximated by consumer price index (CPI)-based inflation rate and countries with high inflation rate are expected to have higher volatility of capital flows. Finally, the stock of foreign exchange reserves in months of imports is to measure vulnerability to balance of payment crises. But the relationship is not straightforward: low stock of foreign exchange reserves may lead to liquidity crises and therefore, higher volatility, while larger foreign reserves may reflect countries need to self-insure and therefore, higher volatility. Countries also build up foreign exchange reserves as a cushion for abrupt outflows of foreign capital. Therefore, we also use the amount of short-term foreign debt as percentage of the stock of foreign exchange reserves in lieu of the stock of foreign exchange reserves in months of imports. x x x x x KOPEN (+)9: Chin and Itos financial openness index INSTITUTION (): Institutional quality INF (+): CPI-based inflation rate RESIMP (+ or ): Stock of foreign reserves in months of imports SDEBT_RES (+): Short-term foreign debt as percentage of the stock of foreign exchange reserves.

To minimize problems of endogeneity and to meet the requirement of exogeneity, all of the above variables are one-year lagged. Control Variables: We also include some control variables such as country-specific factors including GDP per capita, real GDP growth rates, and size of capital account balance. GDP per capita (constant in 2000 US dollars) is to capture the level of economic development. As argued by Broto, DiazCassou, and Erce (2011), the relationship between GDP per capita and volatility of capital inflow may not be linear as the least developed countries are likely to display lower levels of volatility because they rely primarily on official development assistance flows, while among the emerging countries which do not depend much on official flows, high-income countries are also likely to display lower levels of volatility. Therefore, not only the level of GDP per capita but also its squared value is included as an explanatory variable to allow for a non-linear relationship. GDP growth rate is expected to show a negative relationship with the volatility of capital inflows as it is the proxy for the dynamism of the recipient countries. Finally, the size of current account balance is included to capture countries trade performance. Current account balance is expected to correlate negatively with volatility. These variables are all taken from the World Banks World Development Indicators Online database.

8 9

See by Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2010) for a detailed explanation of methodology. Expected signs are in parentheses.

16 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

x x x x

GDP_PC (+): log of GDP per capita (constant in 2000 US dollars) GDP_PC_SQ () : GDP_PC squared PGDP (): Change in GDP_PC (i.e., growth rate): CABL (+): Current account balance (% of GDP)

Similarly to the policy variables, the control variables are also one-year lagged. D. Specification

As mentioned in the previous section, the standard deviation of a moving window is strongly persistent as it leans on previous periods. That is, the standard deviations using overlapping rolling widows are highly correlated by construction. Therefore, when the standard deviation of capital flows over a rolling widow is used as the dependent variable in a regression analysis, the error term is serially correlated by construction. In order to overcome this drawback, this study utilizes the system GMM estimator for dynamic panel data models of Blundell and Bond (1998).

IV. RESULTS A. Global Contagion Effects

Table 1a reports the results for the contagion effects of all other emerging countries, the impact of the policies, and the country specific condition. The sample covers the period of 19802009. Note that the dependant variable is the standard deviation of inflows of different types of capital as ratio of GDP over the 5-year rolling windows. Columns (1)(3) report the results for FDI, portfolio investment, and other investments, respectively, when RESIMP is included, while Columns (4)(6) report the corresponding results when RESIMP is replaced with SDEBT_RES. The estimated value for each moving window is assigned as the volatility of capital flows for the midyear in each rolling window, and as previously noted, except for the external variable, all policy and control variables are one-year lagged. The estimated results are described here by the type of variables. Control Variables Before turning to the contagion effect variable, let us first consider the estimates for GDP per capita in Table 1a. Both GPD per capita in its level (GDP_PC) and quadratic term (GDP_PC_SQ) yield statistically significant estimates in Columns (1(3) but their signs are not consistent and yield insignificant results in Columns (4)(6). Therefore, the impact of GDP per capita on capital flow volatility does not seem to be robust and consistent. GDP growth rate (PGDP) reveals negative and significant results for FDI flow volatility (in Columns 1 and 4) and other investment (in Column 4), suggesting that countries with fast economic growth tend to incur lower FDI inflow volatilities. In contrast, GDP growth rate is positively and significantly associated with portfolio investment flow volatility (in Columns 2 and 5), which is inconsistent with the common wisdom. Size of current account balance (CABL) is found to be consistent with our expectation for FDI and other investments. That is, in the case of FDI and other investments, size of current account balance is negatively correlated with their volatilities.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 17

Table 1a: Determinants of Volatility of Foreign Capital Inflow to Emerging Countries: 5-Year Moving Windows, Full Sample
Full Sample (19802009) VFDI (1) Lag of Dep Variable 1.030*** (0.021) ALL 0.655*** (0.084) KOPEN 0.018 (0.279) INSTITUTION 1.278* (0.745) INF 0.004*** (0.000) RESIMP 0.337*** (0.070) SDEBT_RES VFPI (2) 0.832*** (0.021) 0.740*** (0.065) -0.967*** (0.323) 11.116*** (2.492) 0.001*** (0.000) 0.224*** (0.080) VOI (3) 0.845*** (0.008) 0.493*** (0.038) 1.158*** (0.357) 2.413 (2.074) 0.001*** (0.000) 0.106 (0.195) 0.001*** (0.000) GDP_PC 12.370*** (3.898) GDP_PC_SQ 0.875*** (0.256) PGDP 0.127*** (0.014) CABL 0.060*** (0.019) Constant 20.786 (15.632) Number of observations Number of groups Arellano-Bond test AR(1) p-value AR(2) p-value Overidentification test (Sagan) Chi-squared p-value 4.475 0.000 0.358 0.720 3.867 0.000 2.028 0.042 5.087 0.000 1.478 0.139 3.462 0.000 0.342 0.750 3.022 0.002 2.023 0.043 4.715 0.000 1.282 0.199 957 49 42.936*** (12.366) 2.656*** (0.861) 0.164*** (0.025) 0.056 (0.056) 193.997*** (44.367) 719 45 46.011*** (11.575) 2.983*** (0.769) 0.141*** (0.039) 0.231*** (0.044) 187.592*** (42.449) 989 49 15.234 (19.574) 1.215 (1.373) 0.163*** (0.021) 0.001 (0.028) 57.902 (68.472) 722 35 0.007*** (0.001) 40.606 (24.970) 2.848 (1.752) 0.272*** (0.056) 0.027 (0.079) 169.597* (90.019) 537 32 0.000*** (0.000) 0.064 (39.441) 0.536 (2.757) 0.083 (0.080) 0.375*** (0.050) 50.603 (137.452) 747 35 VFDI (4) 0.764*** (0.066) 0.841*** (0.071) 0.714*** (0.247) 1.694 (3.788) 0.003*** (0.000) VFPI (5) 0.834*** (0.035) 0.780*** (0.089) 1.022 (2.208) 3.199 (6.806) 0.000 (0.000) VOI (6) 0.885*** (0.048) 0.478*** (0.094)

1.400
(1.166) 12.938* (7.231) 0.001* (0.000)

39.368 0.777

36.963 0.853

41.810 0.686

25.081 0.996

22.366 0.999

23.612 0.998

Note: Shown in parentheses are standard errors. ***, **, and * denote one, five, and ten percent level of significance, respectively.

18 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

External Variables We find strong contagion effects. The estimates for ALL, or the average value of capital flow volatilities of all emerging countries in the world show positive and significant coefficients in all three equations. That is, capital flows to a developing country become more volatile when capital flows to other developing countries become more volatile. This finding suggests two things. First, a developing country can fall into a difficult situation when other developing countries are experiencing unstable financial turmoil. Second, therefore, there is a need for developing countries to cooperate to reduce the contagion effect of financial turmoil. Policy Variables As for the policy variables, we find that greater financial market opening (KOPEN) does not lead to a consistent impact on the volatilities of different types of net capital inflows to developing countries. For example, in the case of other investments, countries with greater degree of financial market openness appear to suffer from greater degree of capital volatility, while in the case of portfolio investment, countries with greater degree of financial market openness tend to enjoy lower degree of volatilities of capital inflows. However, when we control for the effect of reserves in relation to short-term debt levels, financial openness has a significant and positive effect only on foreign direct investment flow volatility. This finding is similar to earlier findings [Neumann, Penl, and Tanku (2009); and Mercado and Park (2011)] that financial openness affects different types of capital flows differently. Interestingly, these studies also find that financial openness reduces volatility of portfolio investment flows, while it may increase the volatility of FDI flows. Institutional quality (INSTITUTION) appears to have significant and negative effects on all three types of capital flows (FDI, portfolio, and other investments). Consistent with earlier studies [Broner and Rigobon (2006), IMF (2007), Wei (2011), and Mercado and Park (2011)], this result suggests that better institutional quality is associated with more stable flows. Indeed, this is the only policy variable that reduces the volatility of certain capital flows without increasing that of others. The INF is negative and significant for all three types of capital flows, suggesting that countries with high inflation rates tend to have lower capital inflow volatility, which is at odds with some earlier findings. Broto, Diaz-Cassou, and Erce (2011) argue that investors might view domestic inflation as a signal of macroeconomic mismanagement in emerging economies, hence inducing an increase in the volatility of capital flows. But Mercado and Park (2011) find no significant effect of inflation on the size and volatility of capital inflows. In any case, this result is puzzling and deserves further investigation in the future studies. Lastly, RESIMP enters with positive and significant coefficient in the case of FDI, but with negative and significant coefficients in the case of portfolio investment. On the other hand, SDEBT_RES has a significantly positive effect on all three types of capital flows. While the level of foreign exchange reserves, per se, may not have universal impact on the volatilities of different types of capital flows, its adequacy in relation to the level of short-term debt seems to have a clear implication on capital flow volatility. For example, large short-term debt relative to the level of foreign exchange reserves suggests imprudence in fiscal management, hence increasing the volatility of capital flows.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 19

Table 1b reports the corresponding results for long-term and short-term external debt. Per capita GDP in the level term appears to have a negative influence on the volatilities of longand short-term debts while its quadratic term seems to have a positive one, although most of these coefficients are insignificant except for the level of per capita GDP on the volatility of longterm debt flows in equation (2). The results suggest high-income economies have generally low volatility of external debt flows to a certain extent, although there is no significant evidence for non-linearity of the relationship. Indeed, high-income economies with relatively healthy credit ratings may be able to attract more stable (and long-term) debt flows. Table 1b: Determinants of Volatility of Foreign Capital Inflow to Emerging Countries: 5-Year Moving Windows, Full Sample (with Short-term Debt)
Full Sample (19802009)

Lag of Dep Variable ALL KOPEN INSTITUTION INF RESIMP SDEBT_RES GDP_PC GDP_PC_SQ PGDP CABL Constant Number of observations Number of groups Arellano-Bond test AR(1) p-value AR(2) p-value Overidentification test (Sagan) Chi-squared p-value

VED_LT (1) 0.815*** (0.091) 0.025 (0.134) 3.511* (1.863) 3.453 (7.563) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.832** (0.379)

VED_ST (2) 0.512*** (0.065) 0.951*** (0.075) 0.906 (1.455) 6.310 (6.124) 0.002*** (0.001) 0.369 (0.609)

VED_LT (3) 0.940*** (0.036) 0.053 (0.094) 0.045 (1.033) 0.384 (2.742) 0.002*** (0.000)

VED_ST (4) 0.526*** (0.063) 0.959*** (0.076) 0.798 (1.480) 6.489 (7.083) 0.002*** (0.001)

1.612 (48.350) 0.378 (3.534) 0.105** (0.049) 0.179** (0.083) 4.891 (162.275) 757 35 4.050 0.000 0.001 0.999

58.089 (62.466) 3.374 (4.078) 0.032 (0.051) 0.147* (0.086) 215.107 (236.819) 709 35 4.205 0.000 0.929 0.353

0.001*** (0.000) 38.418* (22.663) 2.469 (1.553) 0.092** (0.041) 0.005 (0.060) 152.265* (83.138) 753 35 3.880 0.000 0.276 0.782

0.000*** (0.000) 26.420 (55.768) 1.359 (3.650) 0.035 (0.052) 0.183*** (0.050) 93.804 (212.411) 709 35 4.373 0.000 0.834 0.404

15.830 0.996

27.399 0.999

18.637 1.000

29.112 0.981

Note: Shown in parentheses are standard errors. ***, **, and * denote one, five, and ten percent level of significance, respectively.

20 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

Among the control variables, only the CABL is found to have a relatively consistent and significant relationship with the volatilities of both long-term and short-term external debt flows. However, the finding suggests that higher CABL is positively related to higher volatility of external debt flows. This finding is not only at odds with our expectation but also different from the previous results for the volatilities of other types of capital flows. This is also puzzling and requires further investigation in future studies. We find significant global contagion effect on the volatility of short-term external debt flows (Columns 2 and 4). That is, short-term debt flows to a developing country can become more volatile when short-term external debt flows to other developing countries become more volatile. In contrast, we find no significant global contagion effect on the volatility of long-term external debt flows. As for the policy variables, KOPEN is negatively associated with the volatility of longterm external debt flows. INSTITUTION appears to have no significant effect on the volatilities of both short- and long-term external debt flows. Unlike the significant effects on other types of capital flows, this result may reflect that debt financing has relatively more legal and institutional protection, such as creditor rights. INF appears to have a significantly negative effect on long-term external debt volatility but a significantly positive effect on short-term external debt volatility. High inflation rates would discourage long-term external debt inflows, affecting their volatility negatively. On the other hand, countries with high inflation rates may offer higher returns on short-term debts, which could increase short-term debt inflow and its volatility. Finally, the RESIMP has a significant and negative effect on the volatility of long-term debt flows. SDEBT_RES has a significant and negative effect on long-term external debt volatility and a significant and positive effect on short-term volatility. B. Intraregional versus Extra-regional Contagion Effects

We divided the contagion effect into intraregional contagion effects and extra-regional contagion effects. Tables 2a and 2b report these contagion effects for the volatilities of the three types of capital inflows and of two different types of external debt inflows to the regions of East Asia, Latin America, and Eastern Europe.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 21

Table 2a: Regional Contagion Effects on Volatility of Foreign Capital Inflow: 5-Year Moving Windows, Full Sample
VFDI Lag of Dep Variable East_Asia_Intra Latin_America_Intra East_Europe_Intra East_Asia_Extra Latin_America_Extra East_Europe_Extra KOPEN INSTITUTION INF RESIMP GDP_PC GDP_PC_SQ PGDP CABL Constant Number of observations Number of groups AR(1) p-value AR(2) p-value Overidentification test (Sagan) Chi-squared p-value (1) 1.112*** (0.038) 0.098* (0.052) 0.004 (0.044) 0.035 (0.046) (2) 1.086*** (0.030) Full Sample (19802009) VFPI (3) (4) 0.877*** 0.879*** (0.013) (0.016) 0.203*** (0.037) 0.125** (0.049) 0.162*** (0.060) 0.196*** (0.072) 0.158** (0.076) 0.057 (0.069) 0.746 1.053 (0.732) (0.766) 13.570*** 11.079*** (3.035) (3.607) 0.002*** 0.003*** (0.000) (0.000) 0.158 0.115 (0.313) (0.139) 0.883 13.190 (12.720) (21.744) 0.104 1.110 (0.898) (1.467) 0.116*** 0.098*** (0.026) (0.027) 0.087 0.175*** (0.068) (0.057) 12.183 37.651 (42.411) (77.262) 713 719 45 45 3.907 0.000 1.899 0.057 38.817 0.796 3.781 0.000 2.040 0.041 36.440 0.867 VOI (5) 0.822*** (0.027) 0.162*** (0.055) 0.325*** (0.046) 0.341*** (0.051) (6) 0.837*** (0.013)

0.024 (0.046) 0.184*** (0.040) 0.151*** (0.045) 0.395 0.135 (0.334) (0.490) 2.394 0.761 (1.706) (1.093) 0.005*** 0.004*** (0.000) (0.000) 0.283*** 0.056 (0.077) (0.064) 16.011 6.121 (10.283) (7.674) 1.133* 0.453 (0.680) (0.501) 0.115*** 0.091*** (0.027) (0.017) 0.054*** 0.026 (0.017) (0.022) 49.606 19.276 (37.137) (29.242) 957 957 49 49 Arellano-Bond test 4.377 4.533 0.000 0.000 0.429 0.482 0.668 0.629 34.924 0.903 36.225 0.873

1.435* (0.804) 3.132 (2.424) 0.001*** (0.000) 0.172 (0.107) 11.873 (19.883) 0.890 (1.380) 0.038 (0.077) 0.165*** (0.052) 36.139 (69.588) 989 49 5.151 0.000 1.592 0.111 40.233 0.748

0.119* (0.064) 0.063 (0.076) 0.002 (0.064) 0.356 (0.699) 5.333* (3.067) 0.001*** (0.000) 0.138 (0.167) 36.207*** (11.658) 2.260*** (0.821) 0.083 (0.057) 0.224*** (0.050) 132.507*** (39.648) 989 49 5.093 0.000 1.407 0.159 40.852 0.723

Note: Shown in parentheses are standard errors. ***, **, and * denote one, five, and ten percent level of significance, respectively.

22 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

Table 2b: Regional Contagion Effects on Volatility of Foreign Capital Inflow: 5-Year Moving Windows, Full Sample
VED_LT (1) 0.853*** (0.109) 0.058 (0.061) 0.188 (0.206) 0.282*** (0.094) Full Sample (19802009) VED_LT VED_ST (2) (3) 0.852*** 0.606*** (0.084) (0.046) 0.499** (0.243) 0.500** (0.237) 0.042 (0.236) 0.415* (0.223) 0.199 (0.170) 0.486 (0.311) 5.242*** 0.534 (1.689) (1.542) 4.206 0.865 (5.027) (8.863) 0.001*** 0.003*** (0.000) (0.001) 0.161 0.710 (0.358) (1.000) 75.156 42.448 (56.044) (79.273) 4.508 2.498 (3.711) (5.436) 0.064 0.049 (0.075) (0.073) 0.107 0.050 (0.080) (0.143) 290.998 171.633 (208.097) (278.217) 757 704 35 35 3.948 0.000 0.130 0.896 14.923 1.000 4.352 0.000 0.952 0.341 26.840 0.999 VED_ST (4) 0.190 (0.130)

Lag of Dep Variable East_Asia_Intra Latin_America_Intra East_Europe_Intra East_Asia_Extra Latin_America_Extra East_Europe_Extra KOPEN INSTITUTION INF RESIMP GDP_PC GDP_PC_SQ PGDP CABL Constant Number of observations Number of groups Arellano-Bond test AR(1) p-value AR(2) p-value Overidentification test (Sagan) Chi-squared p-value

1.819 (1.704) 15.366* (9.003) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.336 (0.596) 6.301 (104.509) 0.222 (6.936) 0.093*** (0.031) 0.098 (0.079) 68.847 (381.157) 757 35 3.993 0.000 0.442 0.658 18.030 1.000

0.970*** (0.277) 0.848*** (0.276) 0.553*** (0.112) 0.132 (1.848) 26.179*** (9.533) 0.001* (0.001) 0.419 (0.793) 302.434** (129.209) 19.105** (8.549) 0.001 (0.077) 0.051 (0.150) 1,181.579** (478.465) 709 35 1.081 0.080 2.198 0.028 16.408 1.000

The empirical results show intraregional contagion effects in all three regions of East Asia, Latin America, and Eastern Europe, for some specific types of capital flows. Among these three regions, East Asias intraregional contagion effects seem strongest as its coefficients are statistically significant in all types of capital flows except for long-term external debt flows. Among the different types of capital inflows, intraregional contagion effects seem strongest for portfolio investment, other investments, and short-term external debt flows.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 23

On the other hand, extra-regional contagion effects are observed only for portfolio investment flows and short-term external debt flows to East Asian and Latin American countries. In some cases, the coefficients for extra-regional contagion effects are negative. Strong intraregional contagion effects may reflect the investors herding behavior perhaps due to their perception of similarities of these economies and therefore, regional policy coordination may be an important element in designing a policy framework to manage capital inflows. C. Results for Sub-sample Period: 19952009

Broto, Diaz-Cassou, and Erce (2011) argued that since 2000, global factors beyond the control of emerging economies have become increasingly significant relative to country-specific drivers (p.1). As an attempt to test their argument, we also estimate the global and regional contagion effects for the sub-sample period of 19952009 separately from the whole sample period of 1980 2009. Note that we cover the sub-sample period from 1995 instead of 2000 in order to allow for more variation. Tables 3a, 3b, 4a, and 4b report the corresponding results for the sub-sample period of 19952009. Here we focus on the contagion effects. During the sub-sample period, the size of ALL, the average of capital flow volatilities, is larger than that of the whole period in most types of capital flows, suggesting that global contagion effects have gained weight. Policymakers in developing countries may face greater challenges of ensuring financial stability in recent years as capital flow volatility in their economies seems to be more easily influenced by the volatility of capital flows to all other developing countries. Tables 4a and 4b generally confirm that intraregional contagion effects remain strong. However, the size of coefficients varies depending upon the types of capital and the regions. A noticeable finding is that intraregional contagion effect seems generally stronger than extraregional contagion effect for most types of capital flows and for most regions, with the exception of volatility of FDI flows to emerging Asia. In emerging Asia, intraregional contagion is strong for FDI and foreign portfolio investment (FPI) low volatility. But in both Latin America and Eastern Europe, volatilities of FPI and other investment flows are more exposed to intraregional contagion than that of FDI flows. In terms of debt flows, intraregional contagion is significant for both long-term and short-term debt flows in emerging Asia. However, in Latin America, intraregional contagion is significant and negative only for short-term debt flow volatility, while it is significant and positive only for long-term flows in Eastern Europe. Institutional quality continues to have a strong, negative relationship with the volatilities of other investments and short-term external debt inflows. This result is quite impressive as it is difficult to believe that institutional quality changed dramatically for many countries in the sample during this shorter period of the sub-sample. There is a strong need for developing countries to enhance their institutional quality while the international community needs to find ways to reduce the contagion effect of financial turmoil among developing countries. Again, other policy variables have differential impacts on the volatilities of capital inflow depending on the different types and the different regions/economies. Institutional quality seems to be the only policy variable that reduces the volatility of certain capital flows without increasing that of others.

24 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

Table 3a: Determinants of Volatility of Foreign Capital Inflow to Emerging Countries: 5-Year Moving Windows, Sub-sample
Sub-sample (19952009) VOI VFDI (3) (4) 0.865*** 0.899*** (0.044) (0.036) 1.071*** 0.897*** (0.298) (0.201) 3.498*** 1.043** (1.160) (0.464) 6.576** 0.603 (3.265) (1.685) 0.010*** 0.001** (0.002) (0.001) 0.058 (0.296) 0.012*** (0.002) 48.913** 13.908 (22.990) (13.244) 3.270** 1.050 (1.438) (0.872) 0.155 0.011 (0.159) (0.066) 0.237** 0.097** (0.101) (0.047) 223.473** 66.591 (90.005) (47.511) 558 402 49 35 4.719 0.000 0.647 0.517 15.721 0.785 3.361 0.000 0.175 0.861 25.081 0.996

Lag of Dep Variable ALL KOPEN INSTITUTION INF RESIMP SDEBT_RES GDP_PC GDP_PC_SQ PGDP CABL Constant Number of observations Number of groups Arellano-Bond test AR(1) p-value AR(2) p-value Overidentification test (Sagan) Chi-squared p-value

VFDI (1) 0.907*** (0.041) 0.705*** (0.214) 0.352 (0.591) 2.224 (1.475) 0.000 (0.001) 0.243** (0.105)

VFPI (2) 0.939*** (0.049) 0.730*** (0.189) 0.535 (0.837) 6.213 (3.817) 0.003** (0.002) 0.542** (0.246)

VFPI (5) 0.858*** (0.033) 1.110*** (0.165) 0.829* (0.447) 1.715 (1.873) 0.010*** (0.003)

VOI (6) 0.956*** (0.028) 0.883*** (0.284) 2.163** (1.100) 4.430* (2.362) 0.016*** (0.002)

18.479** (8.799) 1.217** (0.569) 0.015 (0.073) 0.116** (0.048) 49.925 (31.321) 558 49 3.925 0.000 0.004 0.997 25.743 0.216

35.995 (24.052) 2.364 (1.617) 0.161** (0.081) 0.264*** (0.093) 161.518* (89.123) 490 45 4.563 0.000 1.813 0.069 22.132 0.391

0.008 (0.013) 66.707*** (15.214) 4.747*** (1.084) 0.200*** (0.072) 0.094 (0.122) 273.673 (56.322) 354 32 4.033 0.000 1.701 0.088 23.666 0.309

0.011 (0.009) 33.729 (31.681) 2.176 (2.173) 0.407*** (0.114) 0.313*** (0.070) 169.369 (113.954) 402 35 4.203 0.000 0.508 0.611 19.340 0.563

Note: Shown in parentheses are standard errors. ***, **, and * denote one, five, and ten percent level of significance, respectively.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 25

Table 3b: Determinants of Volatility of Foreign Capital Inflow to Emerging Countries: 5-Year Moving Windows, Sub-sample (with Short-term Debt)
VED_LT (1) 0.878*** (0.032) 0.390** (0.168) 0.784 (0.800) 0.116 (2.517) 0.011*** (0.001) 0.041 (0.156) Sub-sample (19952009) VED_ST VED_LT (2) (3) 0.663*** 0.834*** (0.061) (0.029) 1.073*** 0.329* (0.101) (0.177) 0.907 1.460 (0.673) (0.917) 11.504*** 0.322 (3.607) (2.345) 0.010*** 0.009*** (0.003) (0.001) 0.241 (0.192) 0.000 (0.008) 58.200* 0.602 (34.917) (17.590) 3.497 0.437 (2.322) (1.154) 0.009 0.266*** (0.083) (0.098) 0.122 0.121 (0.098) (0.084) 189.801 34.573 (127.336) (69.660) 396 408 35 35 4.342 0.000 0.563 0.573 23.119 0.337 3.366 0.000 0.043 0.966 21.789 0.411 VED_ST (4) 0.648*** (0.055) 1.121*** (0.108) 1.227* (0.668) 9.316** (4.270) 0.010*** (0.002)

Lag of Dep Variable ALL KOPEN INSTITUTION INF RESIMP SDEBT_RES GDP_PC GDP_PC_SQ PGDP CABL Constant Number of observations Number of groups Arellano-Bond test AR(1) p-value AR(2) p-value Overidentification test (Sagan) Chi-squared p-value

0.232 (16.420) 0.375 (1.101) 0.341*** (0.101) 0.153** (0.071) 33.105 (64.099) 412 35 3.310 0.000 0.031 0.975 17.756 0.664

0.033*** (0.003) 45.488 (30.350) 2.761 (2.023) 0.080 (0.078) 0.057 (0.111) 138.880 (111.166) 396 35 4.323 0.000 0.204 0.838 24.979 0.248

Note: Shown in parentheses are standard errors. ***, **, and * denote one, five, and ten percent level of significance, respectively.

26 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

Table 4a: Regional Contagion Effects on Volatility of Foreign Capital Inflow: 5-Year Moving Windows, Sub-sample
Sub-sample (19952009) VFPI (3) (4) 0.900*** 0.848*** (0.042) (0.038) 0.419*** (0.074) 0.389*** (0.070) 0.172** (0.086) 0.050 (0.123) 0.204* (0.108) 0.116 (0.096) 2.077*** 1.331* (0.724) (0.762) 0.993 2.393 (4.444) (4.238) 0.005*** 0.005*** (0.002) (0.002) 0.874*** 0.530* (0.216) (0.281) 23.190 28.430 (21.321) (31.903) 1.457 1.887 (1.432) (2.085) 0.163** 0.222*** (0.071) (0.074) 0.258*** 0.219** (0.092) (0.089) 90.435 95.851 (75.808) (116.901) 490 490 45 45 4.302 0.000 1.937 0.052 29.659 0.099 4.252 0.000 1.782 0.074 29.098 0.111

VFDI Lag of Dep Variable East_Asia_Intra Latin_America_Intra East_Europe_Intra East_Asia_Extra Latin_America_Extra East_Europe_Extra KOPEN INSTITUTION INF RESIMP GDP_PC GDP_PC_SQ PGDP CABL Constant Number of observations Number of groups AR(1) p-value AR(2) p-value Overidentification test (Sagan) Chi-squared p-value (1) 0.944*** (0.060) 0.211*** (0.082) 0.036 (0.161) 0.110 (0.106) (2) 0.925*** (0.054)

VOI (5) 0.834*** (0.066) 0.023 (0.148) 0.370*** (0.117) 0.410*** (0.090) (6) 0.893*** (0.047)

0.271*** (0.087) 0.036 (0.157) 0.183 (0.132) 0.119 0.005 (0.529) (0.507) 1.092 1.524 (1.871) (2.215) 0.000 0.001 (0.001) (0.001) 0.211 0.370*** (0.140) (0.128) 22.714** 10.522 (10.898) (11.726) 1.492** 0.719 (0.701) (0.782) 0.068 0.013 (0.077) (0.072) 0.056 0.127** (0.068) (0.054) 83.444** 34.927 (41.914) (43.755) 558 558 49 49 Arellano-Bond test 3.840 3.831 0.000 0.000 0.016 0.001 0.987 0.998 27.917 0.142 22.106 0.393

3.460*** (1.139) 3.942 (3.270) 0.006*** (0.002) 0.318 (0.295) 17.639 (29.945) 0.677 (1.833) 0.104 (0.154) 0.299*** (0.095) 91.772 (120.292) 558 49 4.572 0.000 0.613 0.539 28.438 0.128

0.255 (0.206) 0.008 (0.182) 0.044 (0.108) 2.478** (1.191) 10.975*** (3.995) 0.010*** (0.002) 0.540* (0.313) 36.034 (39.926) 2.097 (2.452) 0.267* (0.160) 0.437*** (0.104) 153.085 (160.160) 558 49 4.764 0.000 0.431 0.666 34.239 0.034

Note: Shown in parentheses are standard errors. ***, **, and * denote one, five, and ten percent level of significance, respectively.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 27

Table 4b: Regional Contagion Effects on Volatility of Foreign Capital Inflow: 5-Year Moving Windows, Sub-sample
Sub-sample (19952009)

Lag of Dep Variable East_Asia_Intra Latin_America_Intra East_Europe_Intra East_Asia_Extra Latin_America_Extra East_Europe_Extra KOPEN INSTITUTION INF RESIMP GDP_PC GDP_PC_SQ PGDP CABL Constant Number of observations Number of groups Arellano-Bond test AR(1) p-value AR(2) p-value Overidentification test (Sagan) Chi-squared p-value

VED_LT (1) 0.936*** (0.043) 0.216*** (0.061) 0.070 (0.084) 0.489*** (0.104)

VED_LT (2) 0.872*** (0.035)

VED_ST (3) 0.672*** (0.070) 0.176** (0.074) 0.395** (0.154) 0.108 (0.098)

VED_ST (4) 0.659*** (0.062)

1.619** (0.717) 0.915 (3.076) 0.011*** (0.002) 0.206 (0.209) 27.992 (17.536) 2.329** (1.152) 0.237*** (0.084) 0.072 (0.068) 75.477 (67.797) 412 35 3.158 0.001 0.133 0.894 10.920 0.964

0.213*** (0.077) 0.118 (0.147) 0.221 (0.179) 1.034* (0.617) 1.159 (2.795) 0.011*** (0.002) 0.311* (0.177) 10.000 (16.312) 0.359 (1.078) 0.174* (0.096) 0.062 (0.068) 42.918 (61.264) 412 35 3.147 0.001 0.168 0.866 22.199 0.388

0.888* (0.466) 15.776*** (4.079) 0.006*** (0.002) 0.071 (0.207) 94.144*** (35.142) 6.718*** (2.490) 0.139 (0.100) 0.038 (0.096) 342.982*** (122.154) 396 35 4.497 0.000 0.521 0.602 28.415 0.128

0.113 (0.073) 0.230* (0.135) 0.332 (0.224) 0.767 (0.529) 11.533*** (3.802) 0.004* (0.002) 0.365* (0.211) 43.099* (24.038) 2.947* (1.627) 0.078 (0.097) 0.064 (0.104) 177.964** (88.064) 396 35 4.313 0.000 0.407 0.683 28.172 0.135

28 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

D.

Robustness Checks

The moving window of 5 years may not be the right length of window to capture the volatility of capital flow. Therefore, this paper also uses the 3-year moving window as a robustness check. The results are not reported here due to space constraint, but two points are noteworthy. First, global contagion effect continues to prevail in both whole sample and sub-sample, although it does seem to gain weight in the sub-sample period of 19952009. Second, a strong intraregional contagion effect is also observed in all three regions for most types of capital inflows As another robustness check, we also tried a 2-year lag for the explanatory variables and found similar results.10 The results for global and intraregional contagion effects are robust and strong among all the emerging countries. Similar to our main results, all other explanatory variables (policy and control) again have different effects on capital inflow volatility depending on the type of flow.

V. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS The purpose of this paper was to assess how the volatility of different types of capital flows to emerging countries is affected by the volatility of capital flows elsewhere as well as other economic and policy factors. For this purpose, this paper suggests adopting more rigorous normalization procedure to the usual standard deviations to provide more accurate measures of capital flow volatility than past studies. The paper estimates volatilities of net capital flows in three different forms (foreign direct investment, foreign portfolio investment, and other investment) as well as net flows on short-term and long-term external debt to individual, regional, and global economies. Then, the volatilities in individual economies have been regressed against the global and regional volatilities as well as a battery of domestic factors. The empirical results suggest strong and significant contagion effects from intraregional volatilities in different types of capital flows to emerging economies. The evidence of contagion from regional volatilities implies that there is a strong need for regional policy cooperation to contain the spillover or contagion effects. However, other policy variables have differential and time-varying effects on volatility depending on different types of capital inflow, presenting policy dilemma and challenge to producing coordinated efforts by global and regional policy makers.

10

The results are available from the authors upon request.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 29

Appendix 1: List of Countries in Each Regional Group


East Asia HKG Hong Kong, China INO Indonesia KOR Korea, Rep. of MAL Malaysia PHI Philippines PRC Peoples Republic of China SIN Singapore TAP Taipei,China THA Thailand VIE Viet Nam Latin America ARG Argentina BRA Brazil CHI Chile COL Colombia ECU Ecuador MEX Mexico PAN Panama PER Peru URU Uruguay VEN Venezuela Eastern Europe BUL Bulgaria CRO Croatia CZE Czech Republic EST Estonia HUN Hungary LAT Latvia LIT Lithuania POL Poland RUS Russian Federation SLK Slovak Republic SLV Slovenia TUR Turkey UKR Ukraine Others BOS COTE GEO GHA IND ISR JOR KAZ KEN NIG OMA PAK PNG SAF SAU SLV SRI

Botswana Cote d'Ivoire Georgia Ghana India Israel Jordan Kazakhstan Kenya Nigeria Oman Pakistan Papua New Guinea South Africa Saudi Arabia Slovenia Sri Lanka

Source: Authors definition.

30 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

Appendix 2: Volatilities of Different Types of Capital Inflows to Developing Countries: 5-year Moving Windows
Year ARG BAN BOS BRA BUL CHI COL COTE CRO CZE ECU EST GEO GHA HKG HUN IND INO ISR JOR KAZ KEN KOR LAT LIT MAL MEX NIG OMA PAK PAN PER PHI PNG POL PRC RUS SAF SAU SIN SLK SLV SRI TAP THA TUR UKR URU VEN VIE 19801984 24.6 37.4 14.0 29.3 31.0 25.7 (A) Volatility of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) Inflows 19851989 19901994 19951999 39.7 15.4 31.4 37.7 47.1 39.8 50.6 26.0 34.0 28.4 35.8 37.9 38.7 36.2 24.2 24.8 32.3 18.5 31.2 31.4 59.2 17.7 34.6 32.3 32.4 31.6 19.6 25.7 28.7 41.3 23.8 15.6 15.9 65.1 27.5 43.4 18.0 29.4 37.6 21.9 33.8 17.3 6.9 14.2 24.7 17.3 33.2 20.7 23.1 36.6 15.8 10.7 25.4 33.6 62.5 21.5 25.4 26.7 32.3 33.9 36.0 9.5 22.8 17.8 32.4 20002004 31.0 36.9 46.8 24.5 22.1 18.1 12.3 20.1 24.0 32.8 43.0 23.0 28.4 26.4 33.4 24.5 16.9 52.5 32.3 32.5 19.7 37.2 32.0 28.8 29.2 34.2 18.0 12.9 41.6 30.0 34.8 22.3 37.9 39.2 29.4 7.6 28.2 40.0 38.9 25.8 36.2 6.2 39.9 16.6 31.8 17.8 27.5 31.9 6.2 20052009 23.2 18.5 27.7 19.3 26.8 17.8 20.6 7.7 25.7 32.9 32.7 25.5 28.2 36.1 12.2 42.7 26.7 25.8 30.4 21.6 29.5 40.0 31.3 39.4 33.9 31.9 16.3 14.5 20.1 23.2 17.6 25.4 43.4 24.3 23.0 25.1 37.7 24.3 32.2 36.7 53.0 23.1 35.4 26.5 25.9 20.7 17.4 56.8 30.0

15.9

38.0

30.2 31.2 35.7 35.2

25.3 17.7 40.4 35.8 20.8

10.1 28.3 72.1 41.1 23.4

22.1 15.2 76.2 23.3 27.1 56.5 69.0 64.1 21.5 23.1

26.9 17.6 35.7 29.7 16.2 54.0 34.1 38.0 15.3 10.7 12.7 44.7 87.7 24.1

16.7 25.4 36.8 22.3 11.1 26.0 43.6 34.2 32.0 42.9 37.1 53.9 43.8 27.1

45.7 20.3

23.5 19.8 32.9

26.3 23.1 36.1 34.2

31.1 22.3 24.9 13.9

37.3

38.4

33.2

Data: 5-year standard deviation of foreign direct investment calculated by the authors using the IMFs International Financial Statistics online database. Source: Authors calculation.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 31

Year ARG BAN BOS BRA BUL CHI COL COTE CRO CZE ECU EST GEO GHA HKG HUN IND INO ISR JOR KAZ KEN KOR LAT LIT MAL MEX NIG OMA PAK PAN PER PHI PNG POL PRC RUS SAF SAU SIN SLK SLV SRI TAP THA TUR UKR URU VEN VIE

19801984 36.5

73.6

28.4

(B) Volatility of Foreign Portfolio Investment (FPI) Inflows 19851989 19901994 19951999 20002004 26.2 40.5 57.7 37.9 42.6 42.1 77.2 69.1 55.8 47.1 20.8 39.1 31.3 72.6 73.6 45.3 29.7 40.9 40.5 26.2 47.4 22.3 47.5 50.9 31.7 27.8 32.9 41.6 44.8 40.7 35.8 26.5 35.5 34.6 66.0 40.7 90.6 28.5 45.9 36.3 35.2 41.5 48.4 72.1 25.9 54.7 67.4 68.7 47.8 39.3 43.2 48.4 33.5 42.9 41.3 37.5 18.6 41.1 45.2 71.5 70.1 27.4 57.8 33.5 44.2 37.1 37.5 67.0 52.3 32.1 53.5 71.6 26.3 41.3 28.0 52.1 61.2 66.0 58.7 42.2 43.5 46.1 31.9 40.7 49.1 63.2 57.9 48.0 27.7 30.4 66.9 65.8 40.6 32.5 50.6

38.9

46.3

61.6 44.4

46.2 50.9

44.7

50.4

35.1

37.1 85.5

47.7 71.8

46.5 33.1 46.5 38.7 37.3 47.0

20052009 69.2 37.1 76.7 43.8 61.9 46.5 48.0 37.6 68.3 39.2 49.6 48.4 40.7 47.2 44.2 54.7 52.1 27.9 23.1 41.1 48.9 39.5 53.4 44.5 38.5 62.8 39.2 33.7 66.0 39.6 45.5 56.6 50.6 32.5 69.6 48.9 68.1 44.8 39.4 11.5 57.3 47.1 47.5 62.2 46.2 80.4 42.5

75.0

36.4 26.5 40.2

34.3 52.9 38.4 55.9 35.9 44.3

25.7

48.3 43.1

42.2 42.2 37.4 32.9 43.6

44.9

27.2

Data: 5-year standard deviation of foreign portfolio investment calculated by the authors using the IMFs International Financial Statistics online database. Source: Authors calculation.

32 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

Year ARG BAN BOS BRA BUL CHI COL COTE CRO CZE ECU EST GEO GHA HKG HUN IND INO ISR JOR KAZ KEN KOR LAT LIT MAL MEX NIG OMA PAK PAN PER PHI PNG POL PRC RUS SAF SAU SIN SLK SLV SRI TAP THA TUR UKR URU VEN VIE

19801984 60.9 16.0 18.9 68.7 71.2 22.1 52.3

62.3

(C) Volatility of Other Inflows (OI) 19851989 19901994 19951999 46.0 56.6 37.8 16.9 21.3 13.8 36.8 29.7 23.3 16.8 38.6 69.9 37.8 70.5 65.4 34.2 64.6 34.0 48.0 76.4 49.7 34.0 35.9 37.5 30.4 40.5 25.6 64.3 52.9 33.3 34.5 28.2 16.9 28.2 51.3 31.0 32.3 46.9 21.0 38.1 21.9 54.3 27.8 53.6 53.6 41.8 24.6 69.7 33.9 44.9 29.4 75.1 29.6 43.2 82.9 28.6 29.1 44.3 69.1 70.0 40.6 94.4 75.6 50.1 51.6 35.4 65.8 61.6 72.7 60.4 62.8 46.2 59.6 30.4 32.9 50.0 76.7 19.8 26.5 43.2 59.3

37.1

29.4 30.7 21.5 22.1 32.9

35.8 44.7 69.0 38.0 17.4 71.9 56.7 49.8 36.0 68.1

54.1 49.2 29.4 46.7 28.5 46.1 20.3 77.1 25.4 35.5 29.5 46.2 30.1 40.7

48.6 42.8 36.3 76.2 21.7 31.8 59.2 15.0 54.7 43.5 65.2 46.4 59.6 56.1

62.8 30.3

20002004 40.5 25.3 62.8 40.6 39.7 80.6 46.0 39.0 36.4 59.2 51.9 29.9 57.7 51.9 76.9 66.1 35.5 28.7 48.0 70.9 41.3 43.7 55.6 24.6 39.5 49.2 43.0 24.7 66.0 28.4 47.0 49.9 28.7 55.9 59.0 46.8 55.9 72.5 66.9 39.6 25.2 79.2 41.1 28.4 64.9 47.9 54.9 66.5 34.4

20052009 66.2 30.0 48.4 44.3 40.8 71.7 44.3 77.5 20.4 54.9 59.2 48.5 34.8 56.3 45.5 34.5 29.2 68.9 60.0 75.3 46.3 20.3 55.4 47.6 57.8 53.4 58.6 49.9 41.5 35.0 50.6 80.0 68.5 42.2 44.5 47.1 48.9 53.5 37.5 59.2 50.2 36.7 54.0 59.4 49.2 44.7 71.0 61.0 28.2

22.2 20.0 26.4 38.2 61.2

21.6 49.3 42.4 73.7 54.5 58.1

17.6 34.1 17.8 64.2 44.8 47.8

Data: 5-year standard deviation of other investment calculated by the authors using the IMFs International Financial Statistics online database. Source: Authors calculation.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? 33

Year ARG BAN BOS BRA BUL CHI COL COTE CRO CZE ECU EST GEO GHA HKG HUN IND INO ISR JOR KAZ KEN KOR LAT LIT MAL MEX NIG OMA PAK PAN PER PHI PNG POL PRC RUS SAF SAU SIN SLK SLV SRI TAP THA TUR UKR URU VEN VIE

19801984 42.6 16.6 31.3 18.3 19.6 15.3 22.3

(D) Volatility of Net Flows of Long-term External Debt 19851989 19901994 19951999 43.3 58.4 25.8 15.0 21.8 22.3 37.0 74.9 42.6 69.5 44.6 59.2 21.2 51.3 80.1 24.4 29.3 32.8 46.0 64.4 39.2 44.0 23.7 61.1

20002004 61.4 21.0 30.2 55.6 34.4 38.9 60.6 27.4

20052009 48.2 26.1 45.6 41.4 38.4 40.3 43.6 41.0

44.9

24.3

77.5

40.5 16.2 27.4

45.5 38.4 37.8

48.0 44.6 29.0

25.2

19.9

6.2

16.4 23.1 18.5 21.9

17.6 27.0 25.6 25.3

23.7 49.4 49.8 58.0

44.3 78.8 37.1 25.6 75.1

70.6 17.1 52.9 29.4 39.9

39.5 52.2 46.5 34.5 60.3

26.2 36.1 43.1 29.0 27.7 38.5 15.4 35.2

44.8 52.5 75.5 24.4 37.4 17.2 39.8 33.9 17.7

71.9 37.7 40.0 18.9 29.7 40.7 34.9 63.7 24.4

39.3 24.2 36.2 24.2 30.0 57.8 67.4 37.0 57.9 45.5 40.8 54.9

49.4 56.0 63.7 26.2 62.6 32.1 4.6 41.7 50.5 76.9 56.7 47.3

41.3 69.6 76.7 49.9 14.9 43.9 64.0 77.7 57.5 60.0 40.3 52.4

16.1 18.0 27.9 33.6 50.0

25.8 48.6 33.0 41.6 49.7

31.1 19.5 45.1 58.6 43.2

35.2 61.9 40.4 42.5 36.1 43.7

29.4 36.2 43.1 48.7 42.5 44.8 41.5

27.7 59.0 50.2 45.0 56.8 69.1 29.0

Data: 5-year standard deviation of net flows on long-term external debt calculated by the authors using World Banks World Development Indicators-Global Development Finance online database. Source: Authors calculation.

34 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

Year ARG BAN BOS BRA BUL CHI COL COTE CRO CZE ECU EST GEO GHA HKG HUN IND INO ISR JOR KAZ KEN KOR LAT LIT MAL MEX NIG OMA PAK PAN PER PHI PNG POL PRC RUS SAF SAU SIN SLK SLV SRI TAP THA TUR UKR URU VEN VIE

19801984 64.9 57.5 51.9 66.5 74.4 74.7 64.9

(E) Volatility of Net Flows of Short-term External Debt 19851989 19901994 19951999 41.8 46.3 49.6 70.7 51.2 70.4 61.7 42.6 65.6 52.2 60.8 58.1 55.4 47.1 48.7 55.4 38.4 54.3 58.4

20002004 43.4 35.4 72.4 55.4 58.0 57.0 66.3 32.4

20052009 56.9 46.8 44.0 50.3 38.0 42.3 76.0

75.8

47.1

45.3

52.8 44.4 41.0

67.7 66.4 56.7

72.5 73.7 51.4

85.9

62.7

35.5

29.4 27.1 41.1 78.0

16.5 40.5 64.9 63.3

54.9 46.2 69.5 73.5

76.8 53.3 81.0 48.6 54.1

60.9 74.5 91.3 20.7 84.4

39.8 62.6 56.2 49.0 70.7

49.2 69.0 47.3 53.2 59.2 76.7 75.4 73.1

70.3 54.4 46.8 28.9 57.5 57.4 57.5 62.6

51.5 36.7 77.2 55.7 72.4 58.0 63.4 24.7

42.6 60.7 35.0 75.5 57.6 44.9 60.1 58.9 64.0 61.8 49.4 52.6

35.0 69.8 45.0 77.6

79.4 45.3 48.2 65.2 64.8

48.4 73.1 73.7 39.0 47.3 58.1

49.0 79.6 69.3 47.3 69.1 63.2

68.8 38.7 77.0 39.4 60.6

58.6 55.7 70.9 65.2 65.3 27.0 64.9 66.7 54.7

50.1 78.0 32.6 70.9 29.3 65.5

50.9 41.3 57.3 43.2 49.7 49.6 49.3

53.3 26.5 72.8 52.7 75.9 50.0 44.3

Data: 5-year standard deviation of net flows on short-term external debt calculated by the authors using World Banks World Development Indicators-Global Development Finance (WDI-GDF) online database Source: Authors calculation.

REFERENCES Alfaro, L., S. Kalemli-Ozcan, and V. Volosovych. 2007. Capital Flows in a Globalized World: the Role of Policies and Institutions. In S. Edwards, ed. Capital Controls and Capital Flows in Emerging Economies: Policies, Practices and Consequences. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press. Blundell, R., and S. Bond. 1998. Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models. Journal of Econometrics, 68. 2951. Broner, F. A., and R. Rigobon. 2006. Why are Capital Flows So Much More Volatile in Emerging than in Developed Countries? In R. J. Caballero, C. Calderon, and L. F. Cespedes, eds., External Vulnerability and Preventive Policies. Santiago: Central Bank of Chile. Broto, C., J. Diaz-Cassou, A. Erce. 2011. Measuring and Explaining the Volatility of Capital Flows to Emerging Countries. Journal of Banking and Finance, Article in press. Calvo, S., and C. Reinhart. 1996. Capital Flows to Latin America: Is There Evidence of Contagion Effect?. In Guillermo Calvo, Morris Goldstein, and Eduard Hochreiter, eds., Private Capital Flows to Emerging Markets after the Mexican Crisis. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Chinn, M., and H. Ito. 2010. The Chinn-Ito Index: A De Jure Measure of Financial Openness. Available at: http://web.pdx.educ/~ito/Chinn-Ito_website.htm Karolyi, G. A. 2004. Does International Financial Contagion Really Exist?. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 16: 136146. Dornbusch, R., C. Y. Park, and S. Claessens. 2000. Contagion: Understanding How It Spreads. World Bank Research Observer. Oxford University Press. Eichengreen, B., A. K. Rose, and C. Wyplosz. 1997. Contagious Currency Crises. NBER WP 5681; CEPR DP 1453, July 1996. Revised in March 1997. Part of this paper was published in the Scandinavian Journal of Economics 98, 1996. Engle, R., and J. Gonzalo Rangel. 2008. The Spine GARCH Model for Unconditional Volatility and Its Global Macroeconomic Causes. Review of Financial Studies, 21: 11871222. Fischer, S. 1998. Reforming the International Monetary System. Draft paper prepared for the David Finch Lecture, Melbourne, Australia, presented November 9. Available at <http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/1998/110998.htm> International Monetary Fund. 2007. The Quality of Domestic Financial Markets and Capital Inflows. Global Financial Stability Report 2007. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Ju, J., and S.-J. Wei. 2006. A Solution to Two Paradoxes of International Capital Flows. NBER Working Paper No. 12668. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Karolyi, G. A. 2003. Does International Financial Contagion Really Exist? International Finance, 6: 179199.

36 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 302

Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. 2010. The Worldwide Governance Indicators: A Summary of Methodology, Data and Analytical Issues. World Bank Policy Research. Levchenko, A., and P. Mauro.2007. Do Some Forms of Financial Flows Help Protect from Sudden Stops? IMF Working Paper No. 06/202. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund (IMF). Mercado, R., and C.-Y. Park. 2011. What Drives Different Types of Capital Flow and Their Volatilities in Developing Asia? International Economic Journal 25: 4. 655680. Neumann, R. M., R. Penl, and A. Tanku. 2009. Volatility of Capital Flows and Financial Liberalization: Do Specific Flows Respond Differently. International Review of Economics and Finance, 18, 488501. Tong, H., and S.-J. Wei. 2009. The Composition Matters: Capital Inflows and Liquidity Crunch During a Global Economic Crisis. NBER Working Paper No. 15207. Cambridge, MA: NBER. Wei, S.-J., and W. Wu.2001. Negative Alchemy? Corruption, Composition of Capital Flows, and Currency Crises. NBER Working Paper No. 8187. Cambridge, MA: NBER. Wei, S-J (2011), Not All Financial Integration is Created Equal: The Composition Matters. M. Devereux, P. Lane, C.Y. Park, and S. J. Wei, eds. In The Dynamics of Asian Financial Integration. London and New York; Routledge Studies in the Modern World Economy.

Do Contagion Effects Exist in Capital Flow Volatility? Hyun-Hoon Lee, Cyn-Young Park, and Hyung-suk Byun examine how the volatility of different types of capital flows to emerging countries is affected by the volatility of capital flows elsewhere as well as other economic and policy factors. The authors find strong and significant contagion effects from global and regional volatilities on the volatility of capital flows to developing economies.

About the Asian Development Bank ADBs vision is an Asia and Pacific region free of poverty. Its mission is to help its developing member countries reduce poverty and improve the quality of life of their people. Despite the regions many successes, it remains home to two-thirds of the worlds poor: 1.8 billion people who live on less than $2 a day, with 903 million struggling on less than $1.25 a day. ADB is committed to reducing poverty through inclusive economic growth, environmentally sustainable growth, and regional integration. Based in Manila, ADB is owned by 67 members, including 48 from the region. Its main instruments for helping its developing member countries are policy dialogue, loans, equity investments, guarantees, grants, and technical assistance.

Asian Development Bank 6 ADB Avenue, Mandaluyong City 1550 Metro Manila, Philippines www.adb.org/economics
Printed on recycled paper Printed in the Philippines

You might also like