You are on page 1of 24

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL.

_ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

Creamskimming and Competition


JIM CHEN

INTRODUCTION
The concept of creamskimming routinely arises in the law of regulated industries. As a rhetorical weapon, the term creamskimming readily conjures images of putatively destructive competition, the precise phenomenon that regulatory commissions are charged with patrolling. As a result, allegations of creamskimming have become a standard weapon in the legal arsenal of incumbent firms seeking to resist competitive entry. At an extreme, incumbent firms will characterize all forms of competitive entry as creamskimming. Sound regulatory responses to these allegations therefore depend on a proper understanding of the creamskimming concept. This Article proposes a definition of creamskimming that will help state and federal regulatory agencies distinguish genuine objections to proposed competitive entry from reflexive (and often improper) efforts to shield incumbent firms from competition. Creamskimming should be defined as the practice of targeting only the customers that are the least expensive and most profitable for the incumbent firm to serve, thereby undercutting the incumbent firms ability to provide service throughout its service area. Moreover, regulatory approaches to this practice should make clear that creamskimming can occur only when a competitive firm proposes to serve only a portion of an incumbent firms service area. In other words, when a competitive entrant proposes to serve an incumbents entire service area, creamskimming by definition cannot occur. I. Creamskimming Across the Historical and Regulatory Landscape

In 2008, the Regulatory Commission of Alaska set forth a definition of creamskimming in connection with proposed regulations governing the

Justin Smith Morrill Professor of Law, Michigan State University; Of Counsel, Technology Law Group of Washington, D.C. This Article originally arose from work I performed on behalf of GCI Communications Corp. in response to Consideration of Regulations Governing the Designation of Eligible Telecomm. Carriers, Docket R-06-3, Order No. 5, 2008 WL 2427219 (Regulatory Commn of Alaska June 10, 2008). I thank Linda Katz Ain and Neil Ende for comments and suggestions. Special thanks to Heather Elaine Worland Chen.

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

designation of eligible telecommunications carriers (ETCs) under section 214(e) of the Communications Act of 1934.1 ETC designations under section 214(e) hold the key to competitive entry in areas where high costs, low incomes, or both prevent carriers from serving all customers in the absence of universal service subsidies.2 The Regulatory Commission defined creamskimming as the practice of targeting the customers that are the least expensive to serve, thereby undercutting the incumbent local exchange carriers ability to provide service throughout the area. 3 The Commissions proposed definition omitted several crucial details. First, because creamskimming undermines the income stream of an affected carrier, the definition of that practice must include not only low cost but also high profit. Second, a proper creamskimming analysis must focus on the incumbent carriers costs and revenues, rather than the financial terms on which a competitive carrier proposes to enter a contestable telecommunications market. Finally, the service area at issue in an appropriate creamskimming analysis is the study area served by an incumbent rural telephone company.4 All three of these considerations should be reflected in the Commissions definition of creamskimming so that evaluations of alleged instances of this practice will accurately identify and remedy behavior that undermines universal service goals. I therefore recommend that regulators define creamskimming as the practice of targeting only the customers that are the least expensive and most profitable for the incumbent local exchange carrier to serve, thereby undercutting the incumbent carriers ability to provide service throughout its study area. Creamskimming emphatically is not synonymous with competition. Whereas competition is a socially desirable and legally privileged economic practice, creamskimming is a very specific behavior with potentially negative consequences. As Alfred Kahn recognized in The Economics of Regulation, a treatise whose analysis of creamskimming remains the definitive scholarly treatment of the subject, parties seeking to ban the practice often use the term cream-skimming to the exclusion of the more accurate term competition, evidently choosing the more
1 See 47 U.S.C. 214(e) (2006). On the process for designating an eligible telecommunications carrier under section 214(e), see generally Jim Chen, Subsidized Rural Telephony and the Public Interest: A Case Study in Cooperative Federalism and Its Pitfalls , 2 J. ON TELECOMM. & HIGH TECH. L. 307 (2003). 2 See Chen, supra note 1, at 34445. 3 See, e.g., Consideration of Regulations Governing the Designation of Eligible Telecomm. Carriers, No. R-06-3, Order No. 5, 2008 WL 2427219 app. (Regulatory Commn of Alaska June 10, 2008) (Proposed Rule 3 AAC 53.490(3)). 4

Cf. 47 C.F.R. 54.202(c), 54.207(b) (2012).

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

colorful designation . . . because it has a more negative connotation.5 Regulators must therefore take care to distinguish robust, lawful competition from creamskimming as a special kind of rivalrous behavior that may indeed produce a special kind of undesirable result.6 The use of the term creamskimming in legal proceedings apparently originated in Panhandle Eastern Pipe Line Co. v. Michigan Public Service Commission.7 Appellant Panhandle, an interstate gas pipeline company, launched a program to secure for itself large industrial accounts from customers . . . already being served by the Michigan Consolidated Gas Company, a local distribution company franchised under Michigan law. 8 The Supreme Court of the United States refused to grant Panhandle a purported right to compete for the cream of the volume business within Consolidateds customer base without regard to the local public convenience or necessity.9 The Court expressed particular concern that Panhandles selective targeting of the local gas utilitys most lucrative customers would no doubt be reflected adversely in Consolidated s overall costs of service and its rates to customers whose only source of supply is Consolidated.10 Since Panhandles original articulation of the creamskimming principle, judicial treatments of this concept have reached a stable consensus across a wide range of regulatory settings, jurisdictions, and historical periods.11 Federal and state authorities have consistently recognized four distinct and indispensable elements of creamskimming.12 This practice consists of (1) exclusively targeting only a fraction of customers (2) who are served by an incumbent utility (typically a franchised monopolist) and who are both (3) low in cost and (4) high in profit from the perspective of the affected incumbent. The United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit succinctly summarized these principles in its characterization of the

5 2 ALFRED E. KAHN, THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION: PRINCIPLES AND INSTITUTIONS 223 (2d ed. 1988).

Id. See 341 U.S. 329, 334 (1951). 8 Id. at 333. 9 Id. at 334 (emphasis added). 10 Id. 11 See, e.g., Southern Pac. Communications Co. v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 740 F.2d 980, 988 n.7 (D.C. Cir. 1984) (recognizing a comment, made by a federal district judge, regarding the practice of creamskimming). 12 See Consideration of Regulations Governing the Designation of Eligible Telecomm. Carriers, No. R-06-3, Order No. 5, 2008 WL 2427219 app. (Regulatory Commn of Alaska June 10, 2008) (Proposed Rule 3 AAC 53.490(3)).
7

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

10

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

Private Express Statutes13 as having been designed specifically to prevent private mail services from cream-skimming the most profitable mail services by undercutting the Postal Service on low cost, high-profit routes, thereby leaving the Service with less revenue to fulfill the requirement of providing service throughout the nation at uniform rates.14 Creamskimming, in postal regulation as elsewhere, consists of [l]imiting entry to lucrative markets, while neglecting low-profit markets, to the detriment of other regulatory goals, such as uniform ratesetting or universal service.15 Federal and state courts have repeatedly emphasized these same elementsthe exclusive or primary targeting of a regulated incumbents low-cost, high-profit customers in such a way as to undermine the incumbents ability to cross-subsidize other interests or servicesin a wide area of other regulatory contexts. These cases span a regulatory spectrum covering waste disposal, cable television franchising, natural gas transmission and distribution, railroad reorganization, maritime transportation, health care and health insurance, and public education. A. Waste Disposal In the context of waste disposal, the Ninth Circuit has observed that [c]ream-skimming occurs when an unregulated business offers low rates to attract those customers who are the least costly to service, leaving the regulated companies to service the remaining customers.16 When this practice takes place within service territories where state regulators attempt[] to ensure universal service at reasonable rates by issuing certificates . . . and by regulating rates,17 private opportunistic behavior undermines regulatory efforts to ensure that certified carriers remain financially able to serve all of their customers.18 In this setting, creamskimming disrupts the regulatory strategy of allowing access to
18 U.S.C. 16931696 (2006); 39 U.S.C. 601606 (2006); see also 39 C.F.R. 310.1 320.9; cf. Regents of the Univ. of Cal. v. Pub. Empt Relations Bd., 485 U.S. 589, 594 (1988) (describing the Private Express Statutes as designed to provide prompt, reliable, and efficient services to [postal] patrons in all areas through nationwide delivery of mail at uniform rates (alteration in original) (quoting 39 U.S.C. 101(a) (2006))). Am. Postal Workers Union v. U.S. Postal Serv., 891 F.2d 304, 310 (D.C. Cir. 1989). Peter Hettich, Governance by Mutual Benchmarking in Postal Markets: How State-Owned Enterprises May Induce Private Competitors to Observe Policy Goals, 32 U. DAYTON L. REV. 199, 24546 (2007).
15 16 Kleenwell Biohazard Waste & Gen. Ecology Consultants, Inc. v. Nelson, 48 F.3d 391, 399 n.9 (9th Cir. 1995). 17 18 14 13

Id. at 399. Id. at 399400.

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

11

more profitable, densely populated areas as a way to subsidize service to rural areas.19 Along similar lines, a federal district court in West Virginia has observed that [c]ream skimming results when a new entrant provides service to only the users in the high population density [low cost] areas, with the incumbent left to provide service to users in the low population density [high cost] areas.20 This sort of conduct, properly described as creamskimming, jeopardize[s] the concept of universal service and produce[s] higher rates for the remaining customers of the certified waste hauler.21 In A.G.G. Enterprises, Inc. v. Washington County ,22 the federal district court for Oregon recognized that creamskimming can take place when a waste hauler targets the most profitable jobs, those for commercial customers, to the exclusion of service [for] less profitable residential customers.23 Critically, A.G.G. Enterprises recognized that such creamskimming takes place within the[] exclusive territories for which haulers receive certificates of public convenience and necessity. 24 Universal service through rate regulation remained the paramount governmental interest: All rates are regulated so that services the County and the City deem essential, such as less profitable residential recycling, are provided to all customers while haulers maintain a reasonable profit margin.25 B. Cable Television Franchising In City Communications, Inc. v. City of Detroit ,26 the City of Detroit expressed great concern over cream skimming, which the Sixth Circuit described as the practice (in its extreme) of installing cable service in affluent subdivisions, where installation costs are low, equipment damage is minimal and customers typically order extra services and pay their bills regularly, and slighting inner-city areas.27 If left unchecked, creamskimming threatened to unravel Detroits decision to award a

Id. at 400 n.10. Harper v. Pub. Serv. Commn of W. Va., 416 F. Supp. 2d 456, 462 ( S.D. W. Va. 2006) (alteration in original).
20

19

Id. No. CIV. 99-1097-KI, 2000 WL 361892 (D. Or. Apr. 6, 2000), revd, 281 F.3d 1324 (9th Cir. 2002).
22 23 24 25 26 27

21

Id. at *3. Id. Id. 888 F.2d 1081 (6th Cir. 1989). Id. at 1084 (internal quotation marks omitted).

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

12

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

single, city-wide non-exclusive franchise as a means of ensur[ing] that the franchisee could and would provide equal services to all residents. 28 Although other franchising cases have recognized that cable operators may be inclined to serve more affluent, and therefore more profitable, portions of the franchise area,29 courts have not consistently concluded that competitive operators have engage[d] in the prohibited practices of cream skimming and redlining, that is, operating in the most lucrative markets while avoiding the burden of building in less lucrative markets. 30 For instance, the Connecticut Supreme Court has acknowledged but ultimately rejected an argument by incumbent cable operators that Connecticut regulators had allowed a competitive operator to engage in creamskimming by operat[ing] first in less densely populated regions where higher incomes prevail.31 Likewise, the Ninth Circuit, despite acknowledging municipal governments asserted intere st[] in preventing cream skimmingwiring only affluent, and therefore more profitable, portions of the franchise areaultimately declined to accept that interest [o]n the present state of the record before it.32 C. Natural Gas Transmission and Distribution Contemporary allegations of creamskimming have arisen in the context that sparked the 1951 Panhandle controversy. In the immediate wake of the D.C. Circuits 1989 decision in Michigan Consolidated Gas Co. v. FERC (MichCon),33 which upheld the Federal Energy Regulatory Commissions issuance of a certificate of public convenience and necessity for direct transportation of gas from an interstate pipeline to an industrial customer,34 similar requests to bypass local distribution companies and their state-law regulators prompted many charges of creamskimming. 35

Id. (emphasis removed). E.g., Century Fed., Inc. v. City of Palo Alto, 648 F. Supp. 1465, 1469, 1476 (N.D. Cal. 1986).
29 30 See, e.g., New Eng. Cable Television Assn, Inc. v. Dept of Pub. Util. Control, 717 A.2d 1276, 129192 (Conn. 1998); see also Preferred Communications, Inc. v. City of Los Angeles, 754 F.2d 1396, 1406 n.9 (9th Cir. 1985). 31 32 33 34

28

New Eng. Cable Television Assn, Inc., 717 A.2d at 129192. Preferred Communications, Inc., 754 F.2d at 1406 n.9. 883 F.2d 117 (D.C. Cir. 1989).

Id. at 125. 35 See Martin V. Kirkwood, Comment, Distributor Bypass in the Deregulated Natural Gas IndustryAre Consumers Being Left in the Cold?, 39 CATH. U. L. REV. 1157, 115859, 118185 (1990); Note, Preemption and Regulatory Efficiency in Federal Energy Statutes , 103 HARV. L. REV. 1306, 131417 (1990).

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

13

Even before MichCon effectively deregulated direct sales of natural gas by pipelines to industrial customers, the D.C. Circuit anticipated the variety of powers by which state regulators can control the risk of bypass of a local gas distribution company and any resulting effort by pipelines to skim the cream from among a distributors customers.36 Persuaded that unrestricted entry of interstate pipelines into [their states] for the purpose of cream skimming major industrial customers does significant harm to remaining captive customers,37 state regulators remain committed to the consideration of the economic impact of . . . cream skimming operation[s] upon the regulated rate structure in selling only to the most profitable large customers of public utilities.38 Despite the tools available to regulators, bypass and creamskimming continue to pose significant challenges to state public utility commissions. The observations of the Delaware Supreme Court are apt:
It is impossible for the Public Service Commission to monitor and effectively control the extent of competition in the provision of traditionally regulated commodities if an unregulated firm with no obligation to serve all similarly situated customers and without a general obligation to provide service to all who require it in a specific territory can essentially enter the public utility business and cherry pick or cream skim away the existing utilitys highest volume customers.39

D. Rail and Maritime Transportation Forms of surface transportation with highly variable classes of customers, each with different elasticities of demand, access to alternative modes of transport, and service cost profiles, invite creamskimmingor, at the very least, allegations of creamskimming. The challenges of regional rail reorganization40 prompted one special court to opine at length on creamskimming:
The [government parties] further response to the [terminals] passenger cases is a variant of their general argument that, so long as substantial profits were projected on the main freight lines, public bodies would have refused to buy any lines on which those profits were dependent. Just as public bodies would have opposed the erection of an artificial firewall

36 Associated Gas Distribs. v. FERC, 824 F.2d 981, 1035 (D.C. Cir. 1987) (internal quotation marks omitted). 37 Interstate Natural Gas Pipeline Supply & Capacity, 35 Cal. P.U.C. 2d 196, 250 (1990); accord Destec Energy, Inc. v. Southern Cal. Gas Co., 5 F. Supp. 2d 433, 461 (S.D. Tex. 1997). 38 In re Southern Jersey Gas Co., 561 A.2d 561, 563 (N.J. 1989). 39 E. Shore Natural Gas Co. v. Del. Pub. Serv. Commn, 637 A.2d 10, 18 (Del. 1994). 40 See generally Ry. Labor Execs. Assn v. Gibbons, 455 U.S. 457 (1982); Regional Rail Reorganization Act Cases, 419 U.S. 102 (1974).

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

14

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

between the main freight lines and the predominantly freight lines in the [joint terminals], so would they have resisted the establishment of an inner firewall between privately owned, profitable freight lines and publicly owned, losing passenger lines. Rather than acquiesce in such cream-skimming, public bodies would have sought to persuade the private purchasers of the [terminals] main freight lines to buy and operate the passenger properties as well. If necessary, public bodies would have offered to raise their passenger service subsidies above the avoidable cost level. If that effort failed, states would have proceeded to petition the ICC to condition approval of a sale of the main freight lines on inclusion of [the terminals] passenger properties.41

Maritime transportation poses very similar issues.42 As long ago as 1966, one federal court observed, with respect to an order permitting a steamship carrier to double its California-Hawaii sailings, that although States would offer available service for some high profit cargo, there was no basis to conclude that States would (in its increased California-Hawaii service) engage in an extensive cream-skimming operation to Matsons detriment.43 In a dispute over passenger ferries, a Rhode Island court addressed creamskimming allegations in far more colorful but substantively comparable terms:
New Shoreham and Interstate claim that this Court cannot allow HiSpeed Ferry to cream-skim customers from Interstate with its peakseason, passenger-only ferry. Cream-skimming occurs when common carriers, finding themselves either losing or suffering reduced returns on the profitable part of the business [are] forced increasingly to subsist on a diet of skimmed milk [and] will be unable to carry on in the thinner geographic and seasonal markets, with consequent destruction of service to large areas of the country and bodies of customers.44

E. Health Care and Health Insurance Health care is rife with allegations of cross-subsidization across classes of patients differentiated by their wealth and their willingness or ability to pay. In health care delivery, as in other industries, [c]ream skimming is a common phenomenon in which private providers primarily target good-

41 In re Valuation Proceedings Under Sections 303(c) & 306 of the Regional Rail Reorganization Act of 1973, 531 F. Supp. 1191, 1371 (Regional Rail Reorg. Ct. 1981).

See Joseph Monteiro & Gerald Robertson, Shipping Conference Legislation in Canada, the European Economic Community, and the United States: Background, Emerging Developments, Trends and a Few Major Issues, 26 TRANSP. L.J. 141, 162 (1999). Matson Navigation Co. v. Connor, 258 F. Supp. 144, 156 (N.D. Cal. 1966). Interstate Navigation Co. v. Div. of Pub. Utils. & Carriers, Nos. C.A. 98-4804, C.A. 984766, 1999 WL 813603, at *5 n.6 (R.I. Super. Ct. Aug. 31, 1999) (alteration in original).
44 43

42

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

15

risk individuals.45 The sorting of patients within the health care industry exacerbates itself over time as hospitals, physicians, and insurers are all divided into starkly contrasting camps, pitting relatively healthy and wealthy patients against their sicker, poorer counterparts. The effect of this specialized care delivery model on traditional primary care practices may be to remove some patients and services from the doctors office, leaving a sicker population behind. 46 Whenever physicians engage in cherry-picking or cream skimming the most profitable patients away from full service community hospitals, those hospitals find it increasingly difficult . . . to cover their costs in providing the communitys full array of needed services, including charity care, emergency services, [and] standby capacity required for community disaster response.47 Creamskimming ultimately jeopardize[es] the ability of hospitals to make facility improvements and keep up with new technology.48 For similar reasons, nonprofit hospitals, private and public, harbor considerable antipathy toward proprietary hospitals, regarding them as cream skimmers who lure away the affluent patients that nonproprietary hospitals need to defray the costs of serving the less affluent.49 Primary care physicians likewise perceive cream skimming [as] a threat to their revenue, particularly if they rely on income from short appointments for simple cases to subsidize the cost of more timeconsuming appointments for more complex cases.50 The ultimate expression of creamskimming in health care lies in the market for health insurance. When insurance companies compete by cream-skimming the good risks and shutting out the bad risks, they destroy the safety net that insurance is supposed to provide.51 Though understandable as a natural defensive reaction to adverse selection,52

Denis Drechsler & Johannes Jtting, Different Countries, Different Needs: The Role of Private Health Insurance in Developing Countries, 32 J. HEALTH POL., POLY & L. 497, 507 (2007), available at http://hespa.net/sites/hespa.net/files/oecd2007_different_countries_different_needs.pdf (last visited Nov. 17, 2013). 46 David A. Hyman, When and Why Lawyers Are the Problem, 57 DEPAUL L. REV. 267, 272 (2008). Suzanne Strothkamp, Understanding the Physician-Owned Specialty Hospital Phenomenon: The Confluence of DRG Payment Methodology and Physician Self-Referral Laws, 38 J. HEALTH L. 673, 68485 (2005). 48 Id.
49 50 51 47

45

Hosp. Corp. of Am. v. FTC, 807 F.2d 1381, 1391 (7th Cir. 1986). Hyman, supra note 46, at 272. Tom Baker, Embracing Risk, Sharing Responsibility, 56 DRAKE L. REV. 561, 568 (2008).

52 See generally, e.g., BANKS MCDOWELL, DEREGULATION AND COMPETITION IN THE INSURANCE INDUSTRY 39 (1989); EMMETT J. VAUGHAN & THERESE M. VAUGHAN,

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

16

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

cherry-picking or creamskimming by health insurers threatens inadequate coverage for individuals with poor health, modest means, or both. It is no stretch to describe the landmark Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, especially its controversial individual mandate that all individuals acquire health care coverage, as an exercise in deflecting the effects of creamskimming on health insurance and on the health care industry at large.53 F. Public Education

The provision of primary and secondary schooling, perhaps the most important function of state and local governments, 54 has also witnessed its share of creamskimming. In this context, the line of demarcation between haves and have-nots is drawn in terms of race and class:
Bluntly stated, the Tenafly Board has adopted a tuition policy which has the clear effect of enticing white and Asian students away from a nearby public high school already experiencing racial imbalance, thereby contributing to a polarized situation. To accomplish its own ends, the Tenafly Board has instituted selective admissions requirements, including what is tantamount to an income test since only those who can afford to pay are eligible for admission. In what could accurately be called creamskimming, the Tenafly tuition policy achieves its intended purpose by attracting more highly motivated and academically competent students from its neighboring school district, at the expense of educational quality at DMHS.55

In short, definitions of creamskimming in the broader body of regulatory law emphasize a wide range of factors, including both low cost and high profit, often seen from the incumbent utilitys or carriers perspective, as indispensable elements of creamskimming. If anything, most authorities regard the incumbents revenue as the centerpiece of creamskimming analysis. Against this backdrop, to define creamskimming through an indefinite reference to the customers that are the least
FUNDAMENTALS OF RISK AND INSURANCE 2122 (10th ed. 2007); Kenneth S. Abraham & Lance Liebman, Private Insurance, Social Insurance, and Tort Reform: Toward a New Vision of Compensation for Illness and Injury, 93 COLUM. L. REV. 75, 102 n.82 (1993) (defining adverse selection as the disproportionate tendency of those who are more likely to suffer losses to seek insurance against those losses). But see Peter Siegelman, Adverse Selection in Insurance Markets: An Exaggerated Threat, 113 YALE L.J. 1223 (2004). See generally Natl Fedn of Indep. Bus. v. Sebelius, 132 S. Ct. 2566 (2012). Brown v. Bd. of Educ., 347 U.S. 483, 493 (1954). 55 Bd. of Educ. of Borough of Englewood Cliffs v. Bd. of Educ. of the City of Englewood, 788 A.2d 729, 736 (N.J. 2002) (emphasis added). See generally James Forman, Jr., Do Charter Schools Threaten Public Education? Emerging Evidence from Fifteen Years of a Quasi-Market for Schooling, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 839 (2007).
54 53

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

17

expensive to serve is not only substantively misguided, but also exceptionally lazy. Decent regulation deserves better. II. Creamskimming in Telecommunications Law A. Creamskimming Controversies Before the Telecommunications Act of 1996 Creamskimming figures very prominently in telecommunications precisely because this industry, by virtue of its economic circumstances and regulatory history, is uniquely susceptible to suppression of competition by incumbent firms. Definitions of creamskimming are consistent with the treatment of this phenomenon in other regulated industries. Creamskimming arguments frequently arose during the decades-long struggle to reconcile conventional rate design with competition for telecommunications services, especially long-distance carriage. Indeed, two of the most important early long-distance decisions by the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) are the celebrated MCI orders that opened the door to facilities-based competition against the original Bell monopoly.56 These decisions hinged on the FCCs characterization of specialized point-to-point, private line carriage over microwave radio systems as permissible and desirable competition, as opposed to unlawful creamskimming.57 For much of the quarter-century after MCI, the Bell system contended that its competitors [would] concentrate their intercity services on routes where the volume of business is high and the costs of service are low. 58 The Bell operating companies alleged that specialized carriers without general service responsibilities would cream-skim the [incumbents] existing averaged rate structure by selectively competing only along the most profitable long distance routes, thus imposing a heavier rate burden on low density and local telephone users.59 Competitive entry into these contested markets often proceeded on the strength of arguments that competitive carriers offered new services, proposed to serve all affected customers, and in all events posed no material threat to the core business of

56 Jim Chen, The Legal Process and Political Economy of Telecommunications Reform, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 835, 84447 (1997).

See Microwave Communications, Inc., 18 F.C.C.2d 979, 100310 (1967), affd, 18 F.C.C.2d 953 (1969), modified, 27 F.C.C.2d 380 (1971); Specialized Common Carrier Servs., 29 F.C.C.2d 870, 91920 (1971), affd sub nom. Wash. Utils. & Transp. Commn. v. FCC, 513 F.2d 1142 (9th Cir. 1975).
58 59

57

United States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F. Supp. 131, 161 n.126 (D.D.C. 1982). MCI Commns Corp. v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 708 F.2d 1081, 1094 n.12 (7th Cir. 1983).

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

18

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

Bell affiliates.60 The contemporary approach to creamskimming in telecommunications regulation builds on foundations laid throughout the law of regulated industries. [P]romot[ing] competition, after all, was the first of many statutory promises made by the Telecommunications Act of 1996.61 Extensive legislative reform has shifted the focus of creamskimming analysis in telecommunications after 1996 from the regulatory concerns that prevailed before the breakup of the Bell system to modern methods of sustaining universal service.62 Any regulatory definition of creamskimming should likewise reinforce the 1996 Acts emphasis on competition, innovation, and universal service.63 Historic definitions of creamskimming assumed that cross-subsidies within a protected incumbents rate structure would finance universal

See, e.g., MCI Telecomms. Corp. v. FCC, 561 F.2d 365, 371 (D.C. Cir. 1977) (noting that most specialized carriers have successfully obtained authorization for private line services where they are not competing to a high degree with established general service carriers); Am. Tel. & Tel. Co. v. FCC, 539 F.2d 767, 770 (D.C. Cir. 1976) (affirming the lower courts determination that microwave radio stations provided by specialized private line carriers were non-duplicative and would not divert revenues from existing general carriers); Wash. Utils. & Transp. Commn v. FCC, 513 F.2d 1142, 1156 n.21 (9th Cir. 1975) (recognizing that a charge [of creamskimming was] unfounded primarily because applicants propose[d] to serve special service markets that have not yet been developed, and because they propose[d] to serve all such markets excluding none that ha[d] a significant need); Bell Tel. Co. of Pa. v. FCC, 503 F.2d 1250, 1261 n.13 (3d Cir. 1974) (affirming an FCC order to provide interconnection services to specialized private carriers and rejecting AT&Ts concern that total revenues would be materially affected); United States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 524 F. Supp. 1336, 1358 & n.98 (D.D.C. 1981) (noting that the FCC has expressly considered authorizations of interconnection as not materially affecting rates). See generally Southern Pac. Communications Co. v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 556 F. Supp. 825, 85466 (D.D.C. 1982) (reviewing decisions that introduced competition into markets for local exchange telephone service). 61 Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, 110 Stat. 56 (1996) (preamble) (describing the Act as designed [t]o promote competition and reduce regulation in order to secure lower prices and higher quality services . . . and [to] encourage the rapid deployment of new telecommunications technologies). 62 See United States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F. Supp. 131, 161 (D.D.C. 1982); John W. Berresford, The Future of the FCC: Promote Competition, Then Relax , 50 ADMIN. L. REV. 731, 760 61 (1998). Cf. Pa. Dept of Corrections v. Yeskey, 524 U.S. 206, 212 (1998) ([T]he fact that a s tatute can be applied in situations not expressly anticipated by Congress does not demonstrate ambiguity. It demonstrates breadth. (internal quotation marks omitted)); accord Massachusetts v. EPA, 549 U.S. 497, 52830 (2007) (rejecting the EPAs argument that the agency does not have the authority to regulate carbon dioxide emissions under the Clean Air Act because Congress did not explicitly include carbon dioxide in the Acts definition of air pollutant).
63

60

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

19

service.64 Traditional rate structures extracted a disproportionate share of joint costs from certain customers. 65 Creamskimming allegations before 1996 hinged on the FCCs endorsement of national rate averaging in the interest of promoting the goal of universal service. 66 AT&T blamed creamskimming on the system of rate-averaging that calculate[d] rates on a per-mile basis regardless of demand for service over a particular route, and regardless of differences in costs over different routes.67 Until its dissolution, the Bell system contended that competition would harm consumers by raising prices and undermining universal service. 68 The Bell systems complaint, if not legally meritorious, was at least factually accurate. National rate averaging at once invited and justified competitive entry. Alfred Kahn recognized that MCI entered long-distance telephone markets in response to national average-cost pricing policies.69 To the extent that profitable lines of business, such as backup and interconnection services[,] had previously been subsidized by revenues from the portion of the business that MCI tried to serve, MCIs decision to enter, far from meriting the derogatory label of cream-skimming[,] represented a healthy competitive reaction to an improperly discriminatory rate structure.70 Creamskimming arguments in favor of monopoly-based rate structures persisted beyond the Bell breakup. For instance, the Florida Supreme Court in 1987 upheld toll monopoly areas granting incumbent carriers exclusivity

64 See Sutapa Ghosh, The Future of FCC Dominant Carrier Rate Regulation: The Price Caps Scheme, 41 FED. COMM. L.J. 401, 410 (1989); see also Alexander C. Larson & Douglas R. Mudd, Collocation and Telecommunications Policy: A Fostering of Competition on the Merits?, 28 CAL. W. L. REV. 263, 289 (1991). 65 Jordan J. Hillman, Telecommunications Deregulation: The Martyrdom of the Regulated Monopolist, 79 NW. U. L. REV. 1183, 1185 (1984). 66 United States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F. Supp. 131, 161 (D.D.C. 1982); see also, e.g., KAHN, supra note 5, at 229 (propos[ing] [that] cream-skimming represented a healthy competitive reaction to an improperly discriminative rate structure).

United States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 524 F. Supp. 1336, 1358 (D.D.C. 1981). See Jean-Jacques Laffont & Jean Tirole, Optimal Bypass and Cream Skimming, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 1042, 1042 (1990). 69 KAHN, supra note 5, at 229. 70 Id.; see also Microtel, Inc. v. Fla. Pub. Serv. Commn, 483 So. 2d 415, 418 (Fla. 1986) (Within each [equal access exchange area (EAEA)], local exchange companies must provide their customers with equal access to competing [interexchange carriers] for long distance calls outside the EAEA, i.e., inter-EAEA long distance calls. Each customer, thus, has an opportunity to select the [interexchange carrier] which will handle inter-EAEA, and therefore, inter-LATA and interstate long distance calls.).
68

67

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

20

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

over short-haul intra-LATA (intra-local access and transport area) 71 toll calls within Equal Access Exchange Areas, 72 ostensibly out of concern that interexchange carriers might cream-skim the most profitable, high volume routes while still leaving the LECs [(local exchange companies)] with the obligation to provide uniform service to all customers and to average rates statewide in order to ensure relatively inexpensive local service to all customers.73 B. Creamskimming Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996 Traditional rate design attempted to guarantee universal service by enabling an incumbent utility to cross-subsidize unprofitable services through revenues from creamy customers rendered captive not so much by market forces, but by law.74 Creamskimming arguments figured prominently in disputes over competitive entry, particularly in markets perceived to be rich in revenues needed for cross-subsidization. Any diversion of revenue from low-cost customers to competitive carriers would drain the pool of revenue that could be used to guarantee universal service.75 But this observation simply restates a larger and more important point: creamskimming is primarily an artifact of rate structures that use internal cross-subsidies to finance universal service and other regulatory goals. The apparent creaminess of disfavored customers is an artifact of conventional rate regulation, a by-product of internal cross-subsidization. This is the sense in which cream-skimming is caused . . . by regulation, and not by greedy, profit-maximizing private companies.76 The Telecommunications Act of 1996 fundamentally altered conventional methods of financing universal service in

71 Local, Local Toll, and Long Distance Calling, FED. COMMUNICATIONS COMMN, http://www.fcc.gov/guides/local-local-toll-and-long-distance-calling (last visited Nov. 17, 2013).

Id. U.S. Sprint Communications Co. v. Marks, 509 So. 2d 1107, 1110 (Fla. 1987). 74 See, e.g., Hettich, supra note 15, at 24446. 75 See, e.g., Associated Gas Distrib. v. FERC, 824 F.2d 981, 1035 (D.C. Cir. 1987); ERNEST GELLHORN & RICHARD J. PIERCE, JR., REGULATED INDUSTRIES IN A NUTSHELL 27576 (2d ed. 1987); cf., e.g., Remus v. Amoco Oil Co., 794 F.2d 1238, 1239 (7th Cir. 1986) (A system under which one group of customers subsidizes another (cross-subsidization) is difficult to sustain under competition, because the customers who are charged the higher prices to subsidize the customers who are charged the lower prices are an inviting target for new competitors . . . .); Illinois v. Interstate Commerce Commn, 722 F.2d 1341, 1347 (7th Cir. 1983) ( arguing that the cross-subsidization of railroads unprofitable operations had become unwise).
73 76

72

Hettich, supra note 15, at 246.

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

21

telecommunications.77 This transformation of universal service mechanisms in telecommunications alleviated (but did not eliminate) creamskimming concerns. The shift to a universal service mechanism based on a competitively neutral, external source of subsidies demands very close attention to the place of creamskimming arguments in telecommunications law. Among its crowning achievements, the 1996 Act decoupled universal service from internal cross-subsidies.78 The Act dramatically revamped universal service mechanisms that had relied upon a combination of explicit monetary payments to local phone companies and implicit subsidies through rate designs, particularly those imposing uniform rates throughout a companys service area so that the company [could] charge above-cost rates in urban areas to support below-cost rates in rural areas.79 Under the 1996 Act, universal service support must be explicit and sufficient to achieve the [statutes] purposes . . . .80 The requirement that subsidies be explicit effectively bans implicit support. 81 The shift from implicit support through rate design to explicit, competitively neutral subsidies effected tremendous transparency and positive change in the financing of universal service82precisely what Congress intended in abolishing implicit support mechanisms.83 Even more broadly, the passage of the 1996 Act and the emergence of its model for financing universal service under competitive conditions represents the triumph of competition over monopoly as the economic foundation of telecommunications regulation.84 The durability of creamskimming allegationsand regulators receptivity to those argumentsis one reason that legal authorities persisted in treating nearly the entire

See generally Chen, supra note 1. PHYLLIS BERNT, THE NATL REGULATORY RES. INST., THE ELIGIBLE TELECOMMUNICATIONS CARRIER: A STRATEGY FOR EXPANDING UNIVERSAL SERVICE 3 (1996), available at http://www.nrri.org/documents/317330/054e57a5-cca4-46ce-9acf-a70dc2b05425?version=1.1 (last visited Nov. 17, 2013).
78

77

See Qwest Corp. v. FCC, 258 F.3d 1191, 1196 (10th Cir. 2001). 47 U.S.C. 254(e) (2006). 81 See, e.g., Comsat Corp. v. FCC, 250 F.3d 931, 938 (5th Cir. 2001); see also Alenco Communications, Inc. v. FCC, 201 F.3d 608, 623 (5th Cir. 2000); Tex. Office of Pub. Util. Counsel v. FCC, 183 F.3d 393, 425 (5th Cir. 1999); Sw. Bell Tel. Co. v. FCC, 153 F.3d 523, 537 38 (8th Cir. 1998).
80

79

See Berresford, supra note 62, at 761. See H.R. REP. NO. 104-458, at 131 (1996), reprinted in 1996 U.S.C.C.A.N. 124, 142. 84 See Howard A. Shelanski, Adjusting Regulation to Competition: Toward a New Model for U.S. Telecommunications Policy, 24 YALE J. ON REG. 55, 64 (2007).
83

82

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

22

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

telecommunications industry as a natural monopoly.85 In addition to opening the door to competition for all telecommunications services, in rural as well as urban markets, the 1996 Acts mechanisms for financing universal service enhanced technological innovation. In the related context of using cross-subsidies to promote new industries or to spur technological innovation within an existing industry, Alfred Kahn recognized decades ago that competition may be a much more effective and powerful promoter than monopoly.86 He touted external subsidies (a category to which todays Universal Service Fund belongs) as a far more efficient method than the protection of monopoly for promoting a more rapid industrial development, because they can directly provide such additional incentives as may be required while taking full advantage of the promotional effects of competition as well.87 Although the transformation of universal service mechanisms did not totally eliminate creamskimming concerns, the 1996 Act s creation of a new financial mechanism for universal service did prompt a new approach to creamskimming. Throughout their experience in interpreting and implementing the 1996 Act, the FCC and the Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service have identified a battery of legal measures that minimize or even eliminate creamskimming concerns. 88 To receive federal universal service funds, eligible telecommunications carriers (ETCs) must be common carriers and must offer supported services throughout the service area for which the designation is received . . . . 89 ETCs must also advertise the availability of such services and the charges therefor using media of general distribution.90 In concert, these statutory obligations suppress a competitive ETCs motivation and opportunity to engage in creamskimming.91 Because eligible carriers receive universal service support only to the extent that they serve customers, they have strong economic incentives . . . , in addition to the statutory obligation, to advertise the[ir] universal service offering[s].92

See Susan P. Crawford, The Internet and the Project of Communications Law, 55 UCLA L. REV. 359, 405 (2007). 86 KAHN, supra note 5, at 235. 87 Id. 88 See Fed.-State Joint Bd. on Universal Serv., 20 FCC Rcd. 6371, 6372, 6392 93 (2005). 89 47 U.S.C. 214(e)(1) (2006). 90 Id. 214(e)(1)(B). 91 See, e.g., Fed.-State Joint Bd. on Universal Serv., 19 FCC Rcd. 4257, 4277 (2004); Cellco Pship d/b/a Bell Atl. Mobile, 16 FCC Rcd. 39, 4344 (2000); Fed.-State Joint Bd. on Universal Serv., 12 FCC Rcd. 87, 17071, 180, 239 (1996).
92

85

W. Wireless Corp., 16 FCC Rcd. 18133, 18137 (2001).

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

23

In regulations governing ETC petitions filed by a common carrier . . . not subject to the jurisdiction of a State commission, 93 the FCC has prescribed an examination of creamskimming in connection with its determination of the public interest:
In instances where an eligible telecommunications carrier applicant seeks designation below the study area level of a rural telephone company, the Commission shall . . . conduct a creamskimming analysis . . . . In its creamskimming analysis, the Commission shall consider other factors, such as disaggregation of support to [47 C.F.R.] 54.315 by the incumbent local exchange carrier.94

In the 2005 report and order promulgating 47 C.F.R. 54.202 (among other new regulations), the FCC discussed a trio of ETC designation petitions affecting rural telephone markets. 95 The 2005 ETC Order and the trio of rural ETC petitions that it discussedVirginia Cellular, LLC;96 Highland Cellular, Inc.;97 and Advantage Cellular Systems, Inc.98warrant close examination. In Virginia, Highland, and Advantage, the FCC granted in part and denied in part an ETC petition by a competitive wireless provider. Each denial involved the study area of at least one rural telephone company. Using similar language and analysis, these three orders articulated a set of interrelated principles regarding creamskimming: 1. The FCC defined rural creamskimming as follows: Rural creamskimming occurs when competitors seek to serve only the low-cost, high revenue customers in a rural telephone company s study area.99 Notably, the FCC used precisely the same language in the body of each of these orders. 2. The FCC recognized that creamskimming cannot occur when a competitive carrier serves a rural incumbents entire study area.100
93 47 U.S.C. 214(e)(6). See generally Procedure for Designation of Eligible Telecommunications Carriers Pursuant to Section 214(e)(6) of the Communications Act, 63 Fed. Reg. 162 (Jan. 5, 1998).

47 C.F.R. 54.202(c) (2011). See generally Fed.-State Joint Bd. on Universal Serv. (2005 ETC Order), 20 FCC Rcd. 6371 (2005). 96 19 FCC Rcd. 1563 (2004). 97 19 FCC Rcd. 6422 (2004). 98 19 FCC Rcd. 20,985 (2004). 99 Virginia Cellular, LLC, 19 FCC Rcd. at 1578; Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 6434; Advantage Cellular Systems, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 20,993.
95 100 See Virginia Cellular, LLC, 19 FCC Rcd. at 1578; Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 643435; Advantage Cellular Systems, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 20,993.

94

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

24

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

3. The Advantage order concluded, [c]onsistent with the Commissions findings in the Virginia order and Highland order, that it is appropriate to designate a competitive carrier as an eligible telecommunications carrier below the study area level of rural telephone companies when such designation is unlikely to create creamskimming concerns.101 4. As additional support for the FCCs general policy of requiring a competitive ETC to serve entire communities, Highland observed that a competitive carrier so designated is less likely to relinquish its ETC designation at a later date. 102 5. Finally, the Virginia and Highland orders observed that a rural incumbent LEC can mitigate creamskimming concerns by invoking 47 C.F.R. 54.315 to disaggregate universal service support to the higher-cost portions of its study area. 103 Service area rate averaging, comparable to the ratemaking practices that once made Bell system affiliates vulnerable to creamskimming on a broader geographic scale, is not an inexorable regulatory command. A rural carrier that elects to redirect per-line support according to high- and low-cost areas within its study area as a whole (such as discrete wire centers) can thereby dampen its competitors incentive to target high-density areas where per-line support, if averaged over the entire study area, would exceed the real cost of service. The 2005 ETC Order embraced many of the principles articulated in the Virginia, Highland, and Advantage orders. The ETC Order explicitly ruled out the possibility of creamskimming when a competitor serves an entire rural study area: When a competitive carrier requests ETC designation for an entire rural service area, it does not create creamskimming concerns because the affected ETC is required to serve all wire centers in the designated service area.104 Mindful of [t]he potential for creamskimming that arises when an ETC seeks designation in a
Advantage Cellular Systems, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 20,99394; cf. Virginia Cellular, LLC, 19 FCC Rcd. at 157880 (deciding that Virginia would not be designated as an ETC because there were creamskimming concerns in an area below the study area level); Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 643437 (deciding that Highland would not be designated as an ETC because there were creamskimming concerns in an area below the study area level). Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 6438; cf. 47 C.F.R. 54.205 (requiring that in order to relinquish ETC designation, it must be ensured that the entire community will continue to be served).
103 See Virginia Cellular, LLC, 19 FCC Rcd. at 1580 & n.112; Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 6437 & n.96. 104 102 101

2005 ETC Order, 20 FCC Rcd. 6371 (2005).

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

25

disproportionate share of the higher-density wire centers in an incumbent LECs service area, the ETC Order endorsed a creamskimming analysis that examines the extent to which an ETC applicant would be serving only the most densely concentrated areas within a rural service area, and whether the incumbent LEC has disaggregated its support at a smaller level than the service area (e.g., at the wire center level).105 The 2005 ETC Order recognized the ability of rural incumbent carriers to mitigate creamskimming concerns through disaggregation of universal service support.106 Finally, the Order reasserted the FCCs belief, first stated in the Highland . . . Order, that requiring a competitive ETC to serve an entire wire center will make it less likely that the competitor will relinquish its ETC designation at a later date and will best address creamskimming concerns in an administratively feasible manner.107 One of the earliest decisions by a state commission in response to the creamskimming analysis that the FCC began formulating in Virginia, Highlands, and Advantage confirmed this understanding of the 2005 ETC Order. In the 2005 case of American Cellular Corp.,108 the Kentucky Public Service Commission analyzed three factors bearing on the prospect of creamskimming.109 First, the Kentucky Commission recognized that an entrant seek[ing] to be designated within its entire FCC-licensed service area is not intentionally creamskimming.110 Second, [t]he risk of unintentional creamskimming has been virtually eliminated by the FCC s implementation of the disaggregation mechanisms set forth in 47 C.F.R. 54.315.111 Finally, the Kentucky Commission applied the FCC-endorsed method of population density analysis as a proxy to assess the risk of unintended creamskimming.112 One point of agreement firmly connects all four of the FCC s creamskimming orders, from Virginia to the 2005 ETC Order. The FCC has consistently limited creamskimming analysis to instances in which a competitive carrier would not serve an incumbents entire study area. In proceedings for the designation of eligible telecommunications carriers, and in other settings where controversies over alleged creamskimming

105 106 107 108

Id. at 639293. See id. at 639394. Id. at 6405. Am. Cellular Corp., No. 2005-00130, 2005 WL 2660983 (Ky. Pub. Serv. Commn Sept. 21, Id. Id. Id. Id.

2005).
109 110 111 112

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

26

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

may arise, regulators should declare that creamskimming cannot occur when a competitive entrant would serve the entire service area of the affected incumbent. Indeed, the Regulatory Commission of Alaska rejected a contrary argument by rural local exchange carriers and accordingly acknowledged that a commitment by a competitive carrier to serve an entire study area does effectively address . . . creamskimming concerns.113 Rather remarkably, however, neither the 2005 ETC Order nor the creamskimming regulation it promulgated114 defines creamskimming. The FCC left this task to the Virginia, Highland, and Advantage orders. In the body of each of these orders, the FCC defined creamskimming: Rural creamskimming occurs when competitors seek to serve only the low-cost, high revenue customers in a rural telephone companys study area.115 In each of the orders, the FCC then appended an immediate footnote that recast the definition in different language: Creamskimming refers to instances in which a carrier serves only the customers that are the least expensive to serve, thereby undercutting the ILEC s ability to provide service throughout the area.116 The definition of creamskimming that appears in the bodies of the Virginia, Highland, and Advantage orders differs from the definition that appears in the footnotes of those orders in two significant respects: 1. The body definition refers not only to low-cost but also to high revenue. By contrast, the footnote definition omits any mention of high revenue or profit, referring solely instead to customers that are the least expensive to serve.117 2. The body definition refers expressly to customers in a rural telephone companys study area, as opposed to the footnote
113 GCI Communication Corp. d/b/a Gen. Communication, Inc., No. U-05-4, Order No. 6, at 13 (Regulatory Commn of Alaska Feb. 2, 2006), available at http://rca.alaska.gov/RCAWEB /ViewFile.aspx?id=35324403-0535-46a9-91ce-54347d13a444 (last visited Nov. 17, 2013).

47 C.F.R. 54.202(c) (2005) (discussing creamskimming but not defining it); 2005 ETC Order, 20 FCC Rcd. 6371 (2005).
115 Virginia Cellular, LLC, 19 FCC Rcd. 1563, 1578 (2004); Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. 6422, 6434 (2004); Advantage Cellular Systems, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. 20,985, 20,993 (2004); accord, e.g., Pub. Util. Commn of Tex. v. Tex. Tel. Assn, 163 S.W.3d 204, 215 (Tex. App. 2005). 116 Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 6434 n.80; Advantage Cellular Systems, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 20,993 n.62; cf. Virginia Cellular, LLC, 19 FCC Rcd. at 1578 n.102 (Creamskimming refers to the practice of targeting only the customers that are the least expensive to serve, thereby undercutting the ILECs ability to provide service throughout the area.). 117 Virginia Cellular, LLC, 19 FCC Rcd. at 1578 & n.102; Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 6434 & n.80; Advantage Cellular Systems, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 20,993 & n.62.

114

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

27

definitions more general phrase, service throughout the area.118 In each instance, the body definition is more complete than the footnote definitionand, critically, more consistent with the understanding of creamskimming that regulatory authorities developed in communications law and in the broader law of regulated industries. Both cost and revenue, from the incumbent carriers perspective, are essential in a creamskimming analysis. Moreover, by incorporating a reference to the rural incumbent s study area, the body definition reinforces all the FCC orders from Virginia to the 2005 ETC Order: creamskimming can occur only where a competitor serves an area less than the study area of a rural incumbent. In 2008, the Regulatory Commission of Alaska proposed a definition of creamskimming that echoed the language of the FCC s footnote definition: creamskimming means the practice of targeting the customers that are the least expensive to serve thereby undercutting the incumbent local exchange carriers ability to provide service throughout the area.119 Indeed, the Alaska Commissions definition departs from the more complete body definition in one more crucial respect: it omits the adverb only, which appears in every version of the FCCs definition of creamskimming, including both variants of the footnote definition.120 Unadorned with the adverb only, or an equivalent such as exclusively, the word targeting may invite inappropriate creamskimming analysis in instances where a competitive carrier, consistent with its statutory obligation, advertises its services throughout its service areaalbeit not to the satisfaction of an incumbent who believes (if only for understandably, but ultimately selfish, anticompetitive reasons) that the new entrant is nevertheless skimming cream or picking cherries within the contested customer base. The most charitable reading of the FCCs footnote definition is that the FCC offered what it believed to be a succinct restatement of its more complete body definition. Under regulatory conditions that prevailed before 1996, and certainly before the dissolution of the Bell system, a shorthand reference to cost as a surrogate for a more comprehensive analysis of both cost and profitability might have been acceptable, given what was then the common practice of financing universal service through

Virginia Cellular, LLC, 19 FCC Rcd. at 1578 & n.102; Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 6434 & n.80; Advantage Cellular Systems, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. at 20,993 & n.62. 119 Consideration of Regulations Governing the Designation of Eligible Telecomm. Carriers, No. R-06-3, Order No. 5, 2008 WL 2427219 (Regulatory Commn of Alaska June 10, 2008) (Proposed Rule 3 AAC 53.490(3)).
120

118

See supra notes 11518 and accompanying text.

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

28

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

cross-subsidies embedded within an average-cost rate structure. The 1996 Act, however, has emphatically committed the United States to a financial mechanism that decouples universal service from the prior practice of extracting disproportionate contributions from disfavored customers.121 At the same time, the 1996 Act and its universal service mechanism are committed to balancing sensitivity to rural incumbents bona fide revenue needs with Congresss expressed desire for competitive telecommunications markets that bring lower prices, superior services, and technological innovation to consumers, in rural as well as urban communities.122 After the competitive reforms of the 1996 Act, state commissions should aim to patrol creamskimming without impairing competitive carriers access to markets or undermining the Acts overall goal of providing universal service within a competitive environment. Consequently, any definition of creamskimming must reflect considerations of revenue as well as cost, both from the perspective of the affected incumbent carrier. One further set of considerations counsels regulators to focus creamskimming analysis on the costs and revenue-generating opportunities of the incumbent carrier, and not of the petitioning competitive carrier. As currently framed, the proposed regulations do not specify whether costs and revenues should be examined from the perspective of the incumbent or that of the competitor.123 Absent an explicit instruction directing a creamskimming analysis to the costs borne by the incumbent and to the incumbents sources of revenue, something nominally designated as a creamskimming analysis has the potential to become a backdoor vector by which an incumbent invites undue and anticompetitive scrutiny of its competitor. At an extreme, questioning the costs incurred by a competitor can perversely punish its efforts to enter rural markets on the basis of lower-cost, higher-efficiency technological

121 H.R. REP. NO. 104-458, at 1 (1996), reprinted in 1 FED. TELECOMM. LAW: A LEGISLATIVE HISTORY OF THE TELECOMM. ACT OF 1996: PUB. L. NO. 104-104, 110 STAT. 56 (1996) INCLUDING THE COMMUNICATIONS DECENCY ACT, doc. 5 (Bernard D. Reams, Jr. & William H. Manz eds., 1997).

See generally Connecting the Globe: A Regulators Guide to Building a Global Information Community: Universal Service, FED. COMMUNICATIONS COMMN, http://transition.fcc.gov/ connectglobe/sec6.html (last visited Nov. 17, 2013) (discussing the goals of the 1996 Act and the support provided to the telecommunications carriers in rural areas).
123 See Tim Rupp, The Effect of the Telecommunications Reform Act of 1996 on the Local Exchange: A Significant Step in the Right Direction, 70 S. CAL. L. REV. 1085, 110406 (1997) (discussing how the interconnection of incumbents and competitors telecommunications facilities is intended to reduce creamskimming and free-riding, while noting that state regulators remain responsible for analyzing interconnection costs).

122

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

2013

Creamskimming and Competition

29

platforms. Alas, regulated incumbents have long exhibited a tendency to condemn lawful, desirable competition simply by invoking the pejorative label of creamskimming. Alfred Kahn diagnosed the urge long ago: if one defines as creamy whatever business is worth competing for, one will reach the absurd conclusion that all competition is by definition cream-skimming.124 Therefore, if [creamskimming] is to define an independent phenomenon it must be confined in its application to competition for customers that are making a disproportionately large contribution to [the] overheads that an incumbent utility must cover in order to fulfill its service obligations.125 In short, creamskimming analysis must take care not to undermine telecommunications laws commitment to competitive neutrality.126 Training the focus of proper creamskimming analysis on the incumbents costs and opportunities for revenue provides a safeguard against transforming a legitimate public interest inquiry into an unlawful call for incumbent protection without regard to consumer welfare, competition, technological innovation, or universal service.

CONCLUSIONS AND SPECIFIC RECOMMENDATIONS


The legal definition of creamskimming should address legitimate regulatory concerns without inviting improper scrutiny into bona fide efforts at competition by new entrants into regulated markets. The Federal Communications Commission adopted a comprehensive and appropriate analysis in the body of its Virginia, Highland, and Advantage orders.127 Creamskimming can occur only when a competitor serves exclusively the customers that are low in cost and high in revenue from the perspective of the affected incumbent carrier. Moreover, the FCCs more complete body definition expresses, in a way that neither the footnote definition nor the definition proposed by the Alaska Regulatory Commission does, that creamskimming cannot occur where a competitive carrier serves the entire study area of a rural incumbent. In light of the FCC s own commitment to a
124 125

KAHN, supra note 5, at 225. Id. at 22526 (applying the term cream-skimming to competition that reduces the contribution of some portions of a public utility business to joint or common costs and therefore . . . endangers the service to other customers).
126 See Fed.-State Joint Bd. on Universal Serv., 12 FCC Rcd. 8776, 8801 (1997) (adopting competitive neutrality as a seventh principle under the authority granted to the FCC and Joint Board by 47 U.S.C. 254(b)(7)). 127 See Virginia Cellular, LLC, 19 FCC Rcd. 1563, 157885 (2004); Highland Cellular, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. 6422, 642438 (2004); Advantage Cellular Systems, Inc., 19 FCC Rcd. 20,985, 20,993 97 (2004).

7_CHEN.JCI.FINAL._ON REMANDDOCX (DO NOT DELETE)

2/15/2014 2:58 PM

30

New England Law Review

v. 48 | 7

nuanced approach that take[s] into account variations in population distributions, geographic characteristics, and other individual factors that could affect the outcome of a rural service area creamskimming effects analysis,128 state public utility commissions should embrace a definition of creamskimming that reflects all of these considerations. The regulatory definition of creamskimming should specifically address the practice of targeting only the customers that are the least expensive and most profitable for the incumbent local exchange carrier to serve, thereby undercutting the incumbent carriers ability to provide service throughout its study area. Regulators should take further steps to make clear, in accord with every FCC pronouncement on this issue, that creamskimming can occur only when a competitive carrier serves an area less than that of an incumbents study area. A sentence to the following effect should suffice: Creamskimming does not occur when a competitive carrier is prepared to serve the entire study area of an incumbent carrier. Regulators may also consider other factors demonstrating whether a proposed network deployment plan is consistent with the public interest, including (in instances where the plan does not serve the entire study area of an incumbent carrier) whether an opportunity for creamskimming exists. Finally, in settings such as the designation of a new eligible telecommunications carrier within the study area of an incumbent rural carrier, all regulatory treatments of creamskimming should consider the extent to which disaggregation of the affected incumbents support may mitigate or eliminate the competitive entrants opportunity for creamskimming.

128 2005 ETC Order, 20 FCC Rcd. 6371, 639495 (2005); see also Fed.-State Joint Bd. on Universal Serv., 70 Fed. Reg. 29,960, 29,966 (May 25, 2005).

You might also like