You are on page 1of 101

Options to

Bring Down the


Cost of
Electricity in
Jamaica


Final Report
23 June 2011
Co

























opyright Casta
C
alia Limited. Al
document. C
Optio
Cost o
ll rights reserve
astalia is a part

ons to
of Ele
Fi
23
Confidentia
ed. Castalia is n
t of the worldw
o Bring
ctricit
inal Rep

3 June 2
al
not liable for a
wide Castalia A
g Dow
ty in J
port
2011
any loss caused
Advisory Group
wn the
Jamaic
d by reliance on
p.
e
ca

n this
Confidential

Disclaimer
This report was financially supported by Jamaica Public Service Company Limited (JPS) and
prepared following interviews conducted with staff members of JPS, as well as several
members of the private sector, and Government agencies in Jamaica. However, the views,
findings, and conclusions expressed herein are entirely those of Castalia, and should not be
attributed to JPS, the Government of Jamaica or any of its agencies, or to any of the
individuals interviewed.
Confidential

Table of Contents

Executive Summary i
1 Introduction 1
2 Electricity Tariffs in Jamaica 2
3 Option 1: Changing the Main Fuel 4
3.1 Using a Cheaper Fuel 4
3.2 Change in Cost of Electricity Generation Resulting from
Using a Cheaper Fuel 5
3.2.1 Unit cost of generation from NGCC plant 5
3.2.2 Reduction in total cost of electricity generation
when using NGCC plant and converted combined
cycle plant 7
3.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity 14
4 Option 2: Increasing the Use of Renewable Energy 16
4.1 Description of the Reform 16
4.2 Evidence of Benefits and CostsUtility-Scale Technologies 17
4.2.1 Economic viability of adding utility-scale renewables
to the current system 21
4.2.2 Economic viability of renewables once LNG is used
as the main fuel 25
4.2.3 Reduction in electricity costs from implementing
utility-scale renewable energy technologies 28
4.3 Evidence of Benefits and CostsDistributed Scale
Technologies 35
5 Option 3: Reducing System Losses 40
5.1 Description of the Reform 40
5.1.1 Definition of system losses 40
5.2 Potential for Electricity Loss Reduction in Jamaica 41
5.2.1 Net electricity losses in Jamaica 41
5.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity 44
6 Option 4: Increasing the Use of Energy Efficient
Technologies 48
6.1 Description of the Reform 48
6.2 Evidence of Benefits and Costs 48
Confidential

6.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity to Consumers 52
7 Option 5: Forcing Vertical and Horizontal Disaggregation of
the Electricity Sector 55
7.1 Description of the Reform 55
7.2 Evidence of Benefits and Costs 59
7.2.1 Experience with Wholesale and Retail Competition
in Island Countries 59
7.2.2 Estimation of Wholesale Electricity Prices in
Jamaica with a Disaggregated Sector Structure 61
7.2.3 Other Costs and Possible Problems Arising from
Restructuring the Jamaican Electricity Sector 70
7.3 Summary 74
8 Option 6: Enabling Competition in Generation and Supply to
Large Users 75
8.1 Description of the Reform 75
8.2 Evidence of Benefits and Costs 75
8.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity 77
9 Option 7: Creating an Independent System Operator 79
9.1 Description of the Reform 79
9.2 Benefits and Costs of the Proposed Reform 82
9.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity 83
10 Conclusion and Recommendations 84


Tables
Table 1.1: Summary of Reform Options iv
Table 3.1: Estimation of Unit Cost of Electricity Generation for the
New NGCC Plant (constant 2010 US$, no escalation) 6
Table 3.2: Estimation of Unit Cost of Electricity Generation using the
Converted Combined Cycle Plant at Bogue 7
Table 3.3: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants Currently on the
System (March 2011 Fuel Prices) 10
Table 3.4: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Generation Plants Planned for
2014 (with LNG) 13
Table 4.1: Renewable Energy TechnologiesDescription, Costs and
Potential in Jamaica 19
Confidential

Table 4.2: System Weighted Average Marginal Cost of Generation 24
Table 4.3: Weighted Average Marginal Cost of Combined Cycle and
Slow Speed Diesel Plants 27
Table 4.4: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants (March 2011 Fuel
Prices) 30
Table 4.5: Marginal Cost of Plants on the System (with Renewables
and LNG plants) 33
Table 4.6: Key Information on Distributed Renewable Energy
Technologies 35
Table 6.1: Energy Efficient Technologies and Estimated Costs 49
Table 6.2: Potential Net Financial Savings for Different Customer
Classes from Energy Efficient TechnologiesCurrent Tariff Levels 51
Table 6.3: Potential Net Financial Savings for Different Customer
ClassesProjected Tariff Levels 52
Table 6.4: Potential Net Saving in Electricity Bills from Increased
Use of Energy Efficient Technologies 53
Table 7.1: Size of Electricity Markets 61
Table 7.2: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants on the System (March
2011 Fuel Prices) 63
Table 7.3: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants on the System in 2014
(Based on Average Projected Fuel Prices for the Period 2010-2029) 67
Table 8.1: Estimation of Unit Cost of Electricity Generation using a
Small Diesel Generator 76
Table 10.1: Reducing Electricity Costs in JamaicaCurrent Efforts
and Recommendations 85


Figures
Figure 2.1: Electricity Tariffs in the Caribbean, Mauritius, Hawaii
and Florida (Dec. 2010) 3
Figure 3.1: Merit Order Dispatch for Typical Week Day (Based on
2009 Load Profile) 11
Figure 3.2: Merit Order Dispatch for Typical Week Day (Based on
2009 Load Profile)Capacity Planned for 2014 14
Figure 4.1: Avoided Cost for Firm Renewable Energy Technologies,
Wind Power and Solar Photovoltaic (2011-2014) 21
Confidential

Figure 4.2: Dispatching of Generation Capacity on a Typical Week
Day in Jamaica and Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants 22
Figure 4.3: Economic Viability of Utility-Scale Renewable Energy
Technologies in Jamaica 25
Figure 4.4: Merit Order Dispatch on a Typical Week Day in Jamaica 26
Figure 4.5: Economic Viability of Utility-Scale Renewables Given
Capacity Planned for 2014 28
Figure 4.6: Merit-Order Dispatch with Viable Utility-Scale
Renewables 31
Figure 4.7: Merit-Order Dispatch with Viable Utility-Scale
Renewables 34
Figure 4.8: Commercial Viability of Distributed Renewable Energy
Technologies 36
Figure 4.9: Comparison of Avoided Costs Provided under Different
Contracts 39
Figure 5.1: System Losses in Jamaica (Rolling Average for 2005-2010) 41
Figure 5.2: Composition of JPSs Electricity Losses, December 2010 42
Figure 5.3: Recent Trends in System Losses at JPS 43
Figure 5.4: Impact of Net Electricity Losses on the Fuel Cost Pass
Through Component of Electricity Tariffs in Jamaica 46
Figure 7.1: Possible Structure of the Electricity Sector under Vertical
and Horizontal Disaggregation 57
Figure 7.2: Dispatching Profile for Typical Week Day 64
Figure 7.3: Wholesale Electricity Prices under Single Buyer (Current
System) and Wholesale Competitive Power Markets, US$/kWh 65
Figure 7.4: Dispatching Profile for Typical Week Day 68
Figure 7.5: Wholesale Electricity Prices under Single Buyer (Current
Market Structure) and Wholesale Competitive Power Markets,
US$/kWh 69
Figure 9.1: Current Arrangement for System Dispatch in Jamaica 79
Figure 9.2: Dispatch of Electricity with a New, Independent System
Operator 81


Boxes
Box 3.1: Assumptions for Calculating the Cost of Electricity
Generation 8
Confidential

Box 4.1: Net Billing vs. Net Metering 37
Box 5.1: Residential Automated Metering Infrastructure 43
Box 6.1: Assumptions for calculating potential net savings from using
more energy efficient technologies in Jamaica 50
Box 6.2: How can the Government help achieve these savings? 54
Box 7.1: Price Spikes in Wholesale Electricity Markets 58
Box 7.2: Electricity Sector Disaggregation in Dominican Republic 73
Box 9.1: Is JPS manipulating dispatch out of merit-order? 81



Confidential
Copyright Castalia Limited. All rights reserved. Castalia is not liable for any loss caused by reliance on this
document. Castalia is a part of the worldwide Castalia Advisory Group.
Acronyms
ADO Automotive Diesel Oil
CEO Chief Executive Officer
HFO Heavy Fuel Oil
FSRU Floating Storage & Re-gasification Terminal
IPP Independent Power Producer
JEP Jamaica Energy Partners
JPS Jamaica Public Service Company Limited
JPPC Jamaica Private Power Company Limited
kVA Kilovolt-ampere
kW Kilowatt
kWh Kilowatt-hours
LRMC Long-Run Marginal Cost
LNG Liquefied Natural Gas
MMBtu Million British Thermal Unit
MW Megawatt
NGCC Natural Gas Combined Cycle
O&M Operation and Maintenance
OUR Office of Utilities Regulation
SAIDI System Average Interruption Duration Index
SAIFI System Average Interruption Frequency Index
SRMC Short-Run Marginal Cost
US$ United States Dollar
WKP West Kingston Power


All figures in this report are in US$ (unless specified otherwise), using the following
exchange rate: 1US$=85.75 J$ (March 2011).

Confidential
i
Executive Summary
High electricity prices are a concern in Jamaica, and impact on the life of residents, as well as
the competitiveness of businesses and industries throughout the country. Amid such
concerns, JPS engaged Castalia to provide an independent evaluation of a range of possible
reforms as suggested by various stakeholders, from improving current electricity system
operations to restructuring the electricity sector. In this report we identify the reform options
that would enable an effective reduction in electricity prices in Jamaica, and provide
recommendations on what can be done to implement these reforms effectively.
Table 1.1 below summarizes the reform options we evaluate, as well as our estimates
regarding the potential impact of implementing each option on electricity costs to consumers
in Jamaica, and our recommendations as to which options should be prioritized in order to
reduce costs. Sections 1 to 9 of this report demonstrate how we arrived at each of these
estimates and recommendations.
The results shown in the table indicate that there are four things that can be done to reduce
electricity costs to consumers in Jamaica:
1. Changing the main fuel for generating electricity to Liquefied Natural Gas
(LNG), or coalwe find that this could reduce electricity costs by around
US$0.10 per kWh for all customers
2. Implementing viable renewable energy projectsbagasse cogeneration, wind
power and landfill gas-to-energy all have a cost lower than the short-run marginal
cost of most oil-based generation plants that are currently on the system.
Implementing these projects could reduce electricity costs by around US$0.02 per
kWh, compared to the current generation capacity mix, and could still be
economic if LNG was used as a fuel for electricity generation
3. Reducing system losseswhen considering the effect of target system losses
on the fuel cost pass-through component of electricity tariffs, we find that each
percentage point reduction in system losses could reduce electricity tariffs by 0.8
percent on average (given a target heat rate of 10,470 kJ per kWh, and given the
current fuel mix).
1
A reduction in system losses percent of 5 percentage points
could reduce electricity tariffs by around US$0.01 per kWh for all customers if the
current fuel mix is maintained. A reduction in system losses of 5 percentage
points could reduce tariffs by about US$0.006 per kWh if a large LNG plant was
commissioned and if the existing combined cycle plant was converted to LNG,
keeping all else equal
4. Increasing the use of energy efficient technologies amongst end-users
there are many technologies that would enable residential, commercial and

1
This is estimated using the OUR formula examining the sensitivity of the fuel cost component of the tariffs to system
losses. This estimate does not account for other effects of decreasing system losses on tariffs. For example, a reduction in
system losses and particularly non-technical losses would result in an increase in electricity sales, as some people who
used to steal electricity would become customers and start paying for their own consumption. The increase in electricity
sales would mean that fuel costs for electricity generation would be spread across more customers. Over time, these
savings should translate into lower tariffs to consumers through the performance-based rate setting mechanism
contained in the JPS licence. Therefore, our estimate is conservative and likely underestimates the true potential
reduction in tariffs from reducing system losses.
Confidential
ii
industrial customers to reduce their consumption of electricity at a cost lower
than the current electricity tariffs. In other words, using these technologies will
save customers money by reducing their electricity bills and expenses. We find
that residential customers could achieve net savings equivalent to 16 percent of
their electricity bills, given current electricity tariffs. Commercial customers could
achieve net savings equivalent to 14 percent of their current electricity bills, and
large commercial and industrial customers could achieve net savings equivalent to
8 percent of their current electricity bills.
In this report, we also analyze other options for reforming the sector, but find that these
options would not lead to a reduction in electricity costs in Jamaica. These options are:
Forcing vertical and horizontal separation of electricity services with open
accessthis would involve restructuring the market similarly to what has been done
in New Zealand, the Philippines and Dominican Republicnamely to unbundle the
generation, transmission and distribution of electricity, and letting various firms trade
electricity in a wholesale power market through bilateral contracts and a spot market.
Introducing competition in the electricity sector has proven successful in several
countriesincluding the United Kingdom, the United States and Australia.
However, the benefits from implementing such reform can only be achieved in
markets that are large enough to accommodate sufficient generators to compete with
each other. With a small system of the size of Jamaicas, there is little scope for
attracting more than a few generators; thereby resulting in an oligopoly, with prices
much higher than under competition. In fact, we find that restructuring Jamaicas
electricity sector as a competitive market would lead to higher costs than under the
current regulatory and market structurewe estimate that costs could increase by
US$0.11 per kWh, compared with current costs, under a market structure similar to
New Zealands. Implementing this reform would also entail a risk of increasing
system losses, and prevent investment in new capacitysuch problems have
occurred in electricity markets in New Zealand, the Philippines, and Dominican
Republic
Enabling competition in generation and supply to large usersthis would
enable large commercial and industrial electricity customers to buy electricity from
suppliers other than JPS, and pay JPS a wheeling charge for the power transmitted
and distributed. This type of reform would be unlikely to lead to large or widespread
reductions in costs for large electricity users. Perhaps more importantly, any
reduction in JPSs energy sales would be to the detriment of smaller residential and
commercial customers. Electricity tariffs are determined in a way that allows JPS to
recover the cost of operating the electricity network, given a determined level of
performance and efficiency, from all the end users. If several large customers opted
out of buying power from the JPS system, the company would still have to maintain
the same transmission and distribution system and almost the same generating
capacity and therefore, any loss in its revenue would eventually result in a rise in
tariffs to all of the remaining customers
Creating an independent system operatorthis would involve setting up a new
entity that would be responsible for dispatching the power produced by independent
power producers and JPS unto the JPS-owned transmission and distribution system
Confidential
iii
for distribution to customers. It is crucial to ensure that electricity in Jamaica is
supplied in a way that minimizes costs. However, creating an independent system
operator would entail transaction costs and increased overheads that would need to
be borne by customers. Additionally, that independent operator would still need to
be monitored to ensure that it was in fact fulfilling its mandate. Ensuring least-cost
dispatch can be achieved at lower cost by simply making small additions to the OUR
current monitoring practices.
In this report we examine each of these options in detail, and provide some practical
recommendations regarding what stakeholders can do to effectively reduce electricity costs
in Jamaica.
We recommend all parties to concentrate their efforts on four things: changing the main fuel
for electricity generation, implementing cost-effective renewable energy projects, reducing
system losses, and improving energy efficiency at the consumer end.

Confidential
iv
Table 1.1: Summary of Reform Options
Option Description
Impact on electricity costs
Recommendations
With current capacity With NGCC plant*
1. Change main
fuel for
electricity
generation
Using LNG or coal to
generate a large portion of the
electricity in Jamaica
n/a
Reduction of US$0.10/kWh across
all customer categories from the
commissioning of 360MW Natural Gas
Combined Cycle (NGCC) plant,
conversion of the combined cycle plant
at Bogue to LNG, and assuming that
JPSs oil-fired steam units are no
longer used for regular dispatch
Top priority to
pursue
2. Increasing the
use of
renewable
energy
Implementing economically
viable utility-scale renewable
energy projects, and increasing
or enabling the use of
commercially viable
distributed generation
technologies
Reduction of US$0.02/kWh across all
customer categories
Reduction of US$0.001/kWh across
all customer categories
Second priority
3. Reducing
system losses
Reducing technical and non-
technical losses in the
electricity system
A reduction in losses by 5 percentage
points would enable a reduction of
US$0.01/kWh in electricity tariffs
across all customer categories
A reduction in losses by 5 percentage
points would enable a reduction of
US$0.006 per kWh in electricity tariffs
across all customer categories
Third priority
4. Increasing the
use of energy
efficient
technologies
Promoting the use of
technologies that would
enable customers to save
electricity at a cost lower than
the electricity tariff
Net savings equivalent to:
16% of electricity bills for residential
customers
14% of electricity bills for
commercial customers
8% of electricity bills for large
commercial and industrial customers
Net savings equivalent to:
6% of electricity bills for residential
customers
6% of electricity bills for
commercial customers
2% of electricity bills for large
commercial and industrial customers
Fourth priority
Confidential
v
Option Description Impact on electricity costs Recommendations
5. Forcing
vertical and
horizontal
separation of
electricity
services with
open access
Separating the generation,
transmission and distribution
of electricity, and introducing
competition in electricity
generation and retailing
Increase of US$0.11/kWh across all
customer categories if competition was
introduced amongst current generation
assets
Increase of US$0.12/kWh across all
customer categories
Implementing this reform may prevent
financing of the NGCC plant, thereby
forfeiting the potential saving of
US$0.10 per kWh
Do not implement
Electricity costs would also increase further due to transaction and restructuring
costs, and increased overhead and administration costs
6. Enabling
competition in
generation
and supply
for large
electricity
users
Enabling large electricity users
to buy electricity from
suppliers other than JPS, and
pay JPS a wheeling charge for
transmitting and distributing
the power
Unlikely reduction in cost for large
industrial users
Increase in costs for residential and
small commercial customers
No reduction in cost for large
industrial users
Increase in costs for residential and
small commercial customers
Do not implement
7. Creating an
independent
system
operator
Creating a new, separate entity
that would be responsible for
the dispatch of the various
generators on the system
No impact or increase:
There is no evidence to confirm that JPS is manipulating the dispatching to its
advantage
The OUR is already monitoring the dispatching
Setting up a new system operator would involve transaction costs and increase
in overheads and administration costs, in order to achieve the same result as
what can be done with effective monitoring.
Do not implement

Confidential
1
1 Introduction
High electricity prices are a concern in Jamaica, and affect the life of residents, as well as the
competitiveness of businesses and industries throughout the country. Amid such concerns,
JPS engaged Castalia to provide an independent evaluation of a range of possible reforms as
suggested by various stakeholders, from improving current electricity system operations to
restructuring the electricity sector. The aim of this report is to identify the reform options
that would enable an effective reduction in electricity prices in Jamaica, and provide
recommendations on what can be done to implement these reforms effectively.
In this report we start by reviewing current electricity tariffs in Jamaica, and benchmarking
these against tariffs in other countries. We then examine seven possible reform options and
evaluate their effectiveness in reducing electricity costs in Jamaica. These options are:
1. Changing the main power fuel to a cheaper fuel, such as Liquefied Natural Gas
(LNG) or coal (Section 3)
2. Increasing the use of renewable energy (Section 4)
3. Reducing system losses (Section 5)
4. Increasing the use of energy efficient technologies (Section 6)
5. Forcing vertical and horizontal separation of electricity services with open access
(Section 7)
6. Enabling competition in generation for large electricity users (Section 8)
7. Creating an Independent System Operator (Section 9).
For each of these options, we describe the reform, explain what it would look like if
implemented, and what it would change in the sector. We then evaluate the costs and
benefits of each option compared to the status quo, and determine the impact on electricity
costs and service in Jamaica.
Finally, in Section 10 we summarize the results and provide practical recommendations on
what stakeholders can focus on to effectively reduce electricity costs in the country.

Confidential
2
2 Electricity Tariffs in Jamaica
The current electricity tariffs in Jamaica (including fuel rates and non-fuel rates, and
excluding taxes) are:
US$0.35 per kWh for residential customers with a monthly consumption of 100
kWh
US$0.39 per kWh for residential customers with a monthly consumption of 300
kWh
US$0.39 for small commercial customers (R20 rate) with a monthly consumption
of 1,000
US$0.33 for large commercial and industrial customers (R40 rate) with a monthly
consumption of 35,000 kWh and a maximum demand of 100 kVA
US$0.32 for industrial customers (R50 rate) with a monthly consumption of
500,000 kWh and a maximum demand of 1,500kVA.
2

Stakeholders within the Government and the residential, commercial and industrial sectors
are concerned about electricity tariffs levels and their impact on the national economy. High
electricity tariffs are affecting the countrys entire population from small, low income
households, to small businesses and large firms.
Some people in Jamaica think that electricity tariffs in Jamaica are the highest in the
CaribbeanFigure 2.1 below shows that this is not true. The figure compares electricity
tariffs for residential, commercial and industrial customers across various countries of the
Caribbean, as well as Hawaii (for the island of Oahu), Mauritius and Florida, in December
2010. Electricity tariffs have increased in Jamaica and other countries since (due to increases
in fuel costs), but the latest data available across all countries dates from December 2010
we use it for consistent comparison.

2
Tariffs levels estimated based on the new tariffs provided in: Office of Utilities Regulation (2011). Jamaica Public Service
Company Limited Annual Tariff Adjustment 2011; and adjusted using the fuel and IPP charge and exchange rate adjustment
for April 2011, given a base exchange rate of US$1:J$86, actual exchange rate of US$1:US$85.7, a target heat rate of
10,470 kJ/kWh, and target losses of 17.5%.
Confidential
3
Figure 2.1: Electricity Tariffs in the Caribbean, Mauritius, Hawaii and Florida (Dec.
2010)

Note: The tariffs shown for Florida represent tariffs for March 2011
Source: Carilec Tariff Survey (December 2010), Central Electricity Board (http://ceb.intnet.mu/), Florida
Power and Light Company (http://www.fpl.com/), Castalia

The figure above shows that electricity tariffs in Jamaica are in fact about the same as tariffs
in several countries of the Caribbean, including Barbados, the Bahamas, and Saint Lucia. For
example, the residential tariff in Jamaica in December 2010 (US$0.30 per kWh) was the same
as the residential tariff in the Bahamas (also US$0.30 per kWh), and slightly lower than the
residential tariff in Barbados (US$0.31 per kWh). Tariffs in Jamaica were lower than the
tariffs in Dominica, Cayman and Turks and Caicos. For example, in Cayman Island the
residential tariff in December 2010 was US$0.41 per kWh. In Turks and Caicos the
residential tariff was US$0.44 per kWh and the commercial tariff was US$0.50 per kWh,
compared to a commercial tariff of US$0.35 in Jamaica.
This does not change the fact that tariff levels are a problem in Jamaicaand the figure
shows that this could be a problem particularly for firms competing against other firms
located in Trinidad and Florida, for example.
The reason that electricity costs are high in Jamaica and most countries of the Caribbean is
that these countries are heavily reliant on oil-based fuels, such as Heavy Fuel Oil and diesel
oil. There are opportunities for reducing costs by changing the main fuel used for electricity
generation to cheaper fuels, such as coal or natural gas. For example, although Mauritius has
a smaller power system than Jamaica (with a peak demand of about 380MW in 2008), it has
been able to achieve much lower power costs by opting for bagasse and coal generation.
In the following sections we examine how Jamaica could reduce its power costs to
consumers through changing the main fuel used for generating electricity, as well as a range
of other sector reform options.

0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
0.35
0.40
0.45
U
S
$
/
k
W
h
Residentialtariff Commercialtariff Industrialtariff
Confidential
4
3 Option 1: Changing the Main Fuel
In this section we examine the option of changing the main fuel used for generating
electricity to a cheaper fuel. Diesel oil and heavy fuel oil (HFO) are the main fuels currently
being used in Jamaica. Liquefied Natural Gas (LNG) and coal both constitute cheaper fuels.
In this section we examine the effect of using LNG as a main fuel source, as the OUR
recently tendered for a 480MW new plant (including a first block of capacity of 360MW),
and a natural gas-fired option was the only bid submitted. We also consider that if LNG was
made available in Jamaica and this plant was commissioned, JPS would also convert its
existing combined cycle plant at Bogue (Bogue plant), near Montego Bay to use LNG as
fuel.
We find that using LNG as a fuel for electricity generation in Jamaica could lead to a
reduction in electricity tariffs of around US$0.10 per kWh.
Alternatively, there are other fuel options which, although not examined in detail in this
report, may enable cost savings in Jamaica. For example, commissioning a large coal plant of
360MW could lead to a reduction in electricity prices at least as great as with an LNG plant.
Plants running on petcoke may also enable similar cost savings. Should these options reveal
to be viable options that can reduce electricity costs in Jamaica, they should be considered
for electricity generation.
Below we describe the option of changing the main fuel for electricity generation to a
cheaper fuel (3.1). We then estimate the cost of electricity generation from using a cheaper
fuel (3.2), and determine the impact on electricity prices to customers (3.3).
3.1 Using a Cheaper Fuel
Natural gas is a major source of electricity generation worldwide, through the use of gas
turbines and steam turbines. Power plants combining gas turbines with a steam turbine in
combined cycle mode (Natural Gas Combined Cycle, NGCC) can achieve very high
efficiency.
At current prices, LNG is substantially less expensive than diesel fuel: in 2010, the OUR
estimated that the price of LNG delivered at plant site would be US$8.50 per MMBtu,
3

compared to a current price of about US$24 per MMBtu for Automotive Diesel Oil (ADO),
and US$17 per MMBtu for Heavy Fuel Oil (HFO).
4
Furthermore, natural gas burns more
cleanly than other hydrocarbon fuels such as oil and coal, and produces less carbon dioxide
per unit of energy released. Combined cycle power generation using natural gas is thus the
cleanest source of power available using hydrocarbon fuels, and this technology is widely
used wherever gas can be obtained at a reasonable price.
The Government is well advanced in its plans to make natural gas available in Jamaica.
Under current plans, the gas will be purchased in liquefied form (LNG) on world markets,
and will enter the country through a floating or seaside re-gasification terminal (FSRU). The
gas will then be distributed through a pipeline network. Recently, the industry trend has been
to ship LNG in larger vessels to effect economies of scalethis has led to an oversupply of
smaller LNG tankers which are serviceable, but economically obsolete as LNG tankers.

3
Office of Utilities Regulation (2010). Generation Expansion Plan 2010. p.40.
4
Prices for March 2011, including cost of delivery to power plants
Confidential
5
These vessels are therefore available as FSRUs. The Government concluded that the FSRU
approach to landing LNG in Jamaica is technically sound, and there are several projects
around the world which demonstrate this.
Another option that could be considered to generate electricity at a lower cost would consist
of commissioning coal plants and using imported coal. Coal-fired power plants can generate
baseload power at a very low cost relative to other fuel cycles. In addition, coal could be
imported easily and at a relatively low cost in Jamaica, given that it is already abundant in
Caribbean trade, with supplies readily available from the United States and Colombia.
3.2 Change in Cost of Electricity Generation Resulting from Using a
Cheaper Fuel
In this section we estimate the cost of electricity generation when using a cheaper fuel in
Jamaica. In particular, we examine the option of using LNG as a fuel, on the basis this is the
option currently being pursued. We base our assumptions on the OURs Generation Expansion
Plan 2010, which recommends the commissioning of three NGCC units of 120MW each in
2014, and another 120MW unit in 2016, and also recommends that JPSs existing oil-fired
units are no longer dispatched regularly, but kept in reserve in case of emergency. In
addition, we assume that JPS would convert its existing combined cycle plant located at
Bogue (Bogue plant) to use LNG as fuel, using cost estimates from JPS.
5

3.2.1 Unit cost of generation from NGCC plant
Table 3.1 below demonstrates how we calculate the Long-Run Marginal Cost (LRMC) and
Short-Run Marginal Cost (SRMC) of new NGCC capacity, and Table 3.2 demonstrates how
we calculate the LRMC and SRMC of the Bogue plant converted to LNG. The SRMC
includes the fuel (LNG) cost, plus any other variable costs that result from operating a plant.
The LRMC includes fuel cost and variable O&M cost, as well as the capital cost recovery
factor per kWh, and fixed O&M costs.
A key component of the LRMC is the capital-related charge which depends on the required
rate of return in electricity generation projects. We use a discount rate of 11.95 percent,
based on the OURs estimation of the Weighted Average Cost of Capital for the electricity
sector in 2009.
The figures for the NGCC plant are based on figures provided in the OURs 2010 Generation
Expansion Plan. The estimates for capital cost and fixed operation and maintenance cost do
not appear to be market-specific for Jamaica (given local duties, taxes and construction
costs), and therefore are likely to be lower than the actual cost of commissioning and
operating a NGCC plant in Jamaica. However, these figures should provide a sense of the
order of magnitude for the LRMC and SRMC of a NGCC plant in Jamaica.
In this section and throughout the rest of this report, we follow the OURs approach of
using constant real prices.

5
There is a possibility that JEP may also convert its medium speed diesel plant to use LNG as a fuel, if and
when LNG becomes available. This could result in an even greater reduction in electricity generation costs
and electricity tariffs than the reductions we estimate in this section. The estimates of reduction in electricity
costs provided in this section are therefore based on conservative assumptions.

Confidential
6
We assume that once commissioned, the NGCC plant and Bogue plant converted to LNG
will be available 90 percent of the time.
Table 3.1: Estimation of Unit Cost of Electricity Generation for the New NGCC Plant
(constant 2010 US$, no escalation)
Average price of natural gas for the period 2010-2029* (a) US$/MMBtu 8.96
Plant heat rate** (b) MMbtu/kWh 0.007255
Installed capacity (c) kW 120,000
Unit capital cost*** (d) US$/kW 1,317
Fixed O&M costs (e) US$/kW/month 1.07
Variable O&M cost (f) US$/kWh 0.00253
Lifetime (g) Years 25
Availability**** (h) % 90
Typical output per year (j = c*h) kWh/kW/year 7,873.2
Total capacity cost (k = c*d) US$ 158,040,000
Annualized capital cost (l ) US$/year 20,080,225
Annual fixed O&M cost (m = e*c*12) US$/year 1,540,800
Typical annual output (n = c*j) kWh/year 944,784,000
Capital cost recovery factor (o = l/n) US$/kWh 0.021
O&M cost per kWh (p) US$/kWh 0.002
LNG cost per kWh (q) US$/kWh 0.065
LRMC (=o+p+q+f) US$/kWh 0.09
SRMC (f+q) US$/kWh 0.07
*Derived from projected LNG prices over the period 2010-2029 (from the Generation Expansion Plan), and
adding US$2.5/MMBtu for freight and transport charges to the plant
**Converted from a heat rate of 7,654kJ/kWh using a conversion factor of 1,055 MJ per MMBtu
***Includes interest during construction, but is unlikely to include local duties, taxes and construction costs
****Assuming a forced outage rate of 3 percent and 26 planned outage days
Source: Office of Utilities Regulation (2010). Generation Expansion Plan 2010.

Confidential
7
Table 3.2: Estimation of Unit Cost of Electricity Generation using the Converted
Combined Cycle Plant at Bogue
Average price of natural gas for the period 2010-2029* (a) US$/MMBtu 8.96
Plant heat rate** (b) MMbtu/kWh 0.008859
Installed capacity*** (c) kW 112,110
Total cost of conversion and pipeline**** (d) US$/kW 97,400,000
Fixed O&M costs (e) US$/kW/month 0.99
Variable O&M cost (f) US$/kWh 0.006
Lifetime (g) Years 25
Availability (h) % 90
Typical output per year (j = c*h) kWh/kW/year 7,884
Annualized capital cost (k) US$/year 12,375,436
Annual fixed O&M cost (l = e*c*12) US$/year 1,331,867
Typical annual output (m = c*j) kWh/year 883,875,240
Capital cost recovery factor (o = k/m) US$/kWh 0.014
Fixed O&M cost per kWh (p) US$/kWh 0.002
LNG cost per kWh (q) US$/kWh 0.079
LRMC (=o+p+q+f) US$/kWh 0.101
SRMC (=f+q) US$/kWh 0.085
*Derived from projected LNG prices over the period 2010-2029 (from the Generation Expansion Plan), and
adding US$2.5/MMBtu for freight and transport charges to the plant. We assume that the cost of LNG would
be the same as for the new NGCC plant.
**Assuming that the conversion would lead to a 0.5 percent improvement compared to the current heat rate of
the plant; ***Assuming that the conversion would lead to a 1 percent increase in the capacity of the plant;
****Cost estimate provided by JPS
Source: JPS; OUR (2010). Generation Expansion Plan 2010.

In the following section we estimate the impact of commissioning three NGCC units of
120MW each on the cost of electricity generation in 2014, and converting the Bogue plant to
LNG.
3.2.2 Reduction in total cost of electricity generation when using NGCC plant and
converted combined cycle plant
To calculate the reduction in the cost of electricity generation, we:
1. Calculate how much the NGCC plant and Bogue plant would save by avoiding
the need to run expensive HFO and diesel plants. In other words, we calculate
how much less these expensive plants would be used, and hence what the savings
in fuel cost would be

Box
B
T
c
G
F
2
e
e
e
g
d


S

2. Calcu
Bogu
new p
3. Subtr
from
3.1 below s
Box 3.1: Ass
To calculate
converted Bo
Generation Exp
For electricity
2009 provided
electricity dem
electricity gen
easily, as we
generation as
different gene
Source: Offic
Week
Perfo
Dema
ulate the co
ue plant. Thi
plant
ract 1 from 2
using the N
ummarizes t
sumptions f
the cost of
ogue plant, w
pansion Plan 2
y demand, we
d in the OU
mand in 2014
neration with
can examine
ssets being u
eration pattern
e of Utilities R
kday Load Prof
ormance Chara
and/Capacity R
ost of electr
is includes b
2 to give us
NGCC plant
the assumpt
for Calcula
f electricity g
we use data on
010.
e use the typic
UR Generation
is the same a
and without
e changes in
used (rather t
ns).
Regulation (201
file for Jamaica
cteristics of th
Requirements
Confidentia
8
ricity genera
both the cos
the net savi
and convert
tions we mad
ating the Co
generation w
n current and
cal weekday l
Expansion Pl
as that in 200
the NGCC p
n prices resul
than also ha
10). Generation E
as Power Syste
he Existing The
for 2010 to 20
al
ation when
st of the fue
ings to the c
ted Bogue p
de for these
ost of Electr
with and with
d planned ca
load profile fo
lan 2010 (sho
09. This enabl
plant and con
lting strictly
aving change
Expansion Plan
em. p.32. Tabl
ermal Generati
019 (Natural G
using the N
el, and the c
country that
plant.
calculations
ricity Gener
hout the NG
apacity provid
for Jamaicas p
own below). W
les us to com
nverted plant
from chang
s in demand
2010. Figure 3
e 6.7-1Capab
ing Units, p.54
Gas Strategy), p
NGCC plan
capital cost
could be ex
s.
ration
GCC plant a
ded in the O
power system
We assume t
mpare the cost
t at Bogue m
ging the type
d, and theref
3.5-2Typical
bilities and
4. Table 9.4.1-1
/70.
nt and
of the
xpected
and
UR
m in
that
t of
more
e of
fore
1
Confidential
9
Below we demonstrate how we calculate the cost of electricity generation with the current
generation capacity, and the cost of generation once the NGCC plant comes in and the
existing Bogue plant is converted to LNG.
Cost of electricity generation given existing generation capacity
In this section we estimate the cost of generating power using the existing capacity, in order
to see how much that cost would be reduced when the NGCC plant comes in and the
existing Bogue plant is converted to LNG. We find that once these new plants are
commissioned, the slow speed diesel, oil-fired steam, and combustion turbine plants would
not be run. So the cost saving is the savings in fuel cost from not running those plants.
In order to work this out, we need to know the cost of each plant. We also assume that
when LNG plant becomes available, the most expensive plants will be the ones that stop
running. We also assume that the oil-fired steam plants will be decommissioned once the
NGCC plant comes in, as outlined in the Generation Expansion Plan 2010.
As an input to calculate the cost of each plant, Table 3.3 below lists the plants currently
installed and being operated by JPS and IPPs in Jamaica (ordered in terms of short-run
marginal cost per kWh generated, from the cheapest to the most expensivethe short-run
marginal cost includes fuel cost, and variable operation and maintenance costs). The table
shows two additional plants:
A new medium speed diesel plant with a total installed capacity of 65MW, which
West Kingston Power (a subsidiary of JEP) expects to commission by 2012. We
assume that the plant (which we call West Kingston Power throughout this
report) will be available 90 percent of the time, and use a similar heat rate, fuel
cost and variable operation and maintenance cost as for JEPs existing medium-
speed diesel plant
JPSs new hydropower plant at Maggotty, which JPS expects to commission in
2013. The installed capacity of this plant will be 6.3MW, and we assume a 45
percent capacity factor for the plant on average
6

We calculate the average cost of electricity generation using all existing plants as
well as these two plants, in order to subsequently strictly isolate the effect of
introducing LNG as a fuel for electricity generation (from introducing the new
NGCC plant and converting the Bogue plant to LNG).
For each plant, the table indicates effective capacity, type and current price of fuel used, and
heat rate. The table also shows the fuel cost per kWh (which is calculated, for each plant, as
the heat rate in MMBtu per kWh times the fuel price in US$ per MMBtu) and variable
operation and maintenance (O&M) cost of each plantadding these together gives the
short-run marginal cost of each plant, in US$ per kWh.

6
Capacity factor estimate provided by JPS to the OUR for the Renewable Energy Generation BOO Tender in 2008, and
confirmed by JPS.
Confidential
10
Table 3.3: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants Currently on the System (March 2011
Fuel Prices)

Note: For the JPPC plant, we assume same HFO prices as those for Hunts Bay (given location proximity).
For JEP and West Kingston Power, we assume same HFO prices as for Old Harbour.
We assume an availability of 90 percent for the JEP plant, and 89 percent for the JPPC plant.
Source: OUR (2010), Generation Expansion Plan 2010; JPS

Using the typical weekday load profile for 2009 (provided by the OUR in the Generation
Expansion Plan 2010), and assuming dispatching based on merit order of short-run marginal
costs, we determine the dispatching profile of the system on a typical daythis is illustrated
in Figure 3.1 below.
Effective
capacity
Average
heat rate
Current
fuel
price**
Variable
O&M
cost
Fuel cost
Short-run
marginal
cost
MW MMBtu/kWh US$/MMBtu US$/kWh US$/kWh US$/kWh
Wigton Wind farm n/a 10.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
Munro Wind farm n/a 0.9 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
JPS Hydropower Hydropower n/a 13.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
JPS Maggotty Hydropower n/a 2.8 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
JPPC Slow Speed Diesel HFO 54.6 0.0077 16.90 0.010 0.13 0.14
JEP Medium Speed Diesel HFO 111.9 0.0078 17.53 0.020 0.14 0.16
West Kingston Power Medium Speed Diesel HFO 58.5 0.0078 17.53 0.020 0.14 0.16
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.0093 16.90 0.008 0.16 0.16
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.0095 16.90 0.008 0.16 0.17
Old Harbour Oil Fired Steam HFO 61.8 0.0122 16.70 0.007 0.20 0.21
Old Harbour Oil Fired Steam HFO 65.1 0.0123 16.70 0.007 0.21 0.21
Hunts Bay Oil Fired Steam HFO 65.1 0.0124 16.79 0.007 0.21 0.21
Old Harbour Oil Fired Steam HFO 57 0.0126 16.70 0.007 0.21 0.22
Bogue Combined Cycle ADO 111 0.0089 23.88 0.006 0.21 0.22
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.0129 23.75 0.005 0.31 0.31
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.0165 23.75 0.005 0.39 0.40
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.0169 23.75 0.005 0.40 0.41
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.0170 23.75 0.005 0.40 0.41
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 32.1 0.0179 23.75 0.005 0.43 0.43
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0180 23.75 0.005 0.43 0.43
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0180 23.75 0.005 0.43 0.43
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0212 23.75 0.005 0.50 0.51
Location/IPP name Type of plant
Type of
fossil fuel
used*
* HFO = Heavy Fuel Oil, ADO = Automotive Diesel Oil
** Based on March 2011 prices of fuel delivered at each plant.
Confidential
11
Figure 3.1: Merit Order Dispatch for Typical Week Day (Based on 2009 Load Profile)

Note: For simplicity, we consider the average short-run marginal cost of all oil-fired steam plants together in
this figure. Some of the oil-fired steam units are more expensive than the combined cycle plant
therefore, in reality these particular units should be dispatched after the combined cycle plant.

The above figure shows how different plants would be chosen to generate sufficient
electricity to meet demand throughout a typical week day in Jamaica, given the current
system plus the additional medium speed diesel plant (included as West Kingston Power
on the figure), and the hydropower plant at Maggotty (included as Hydro on the figure).
The entire colored area shows total electricity demand in MW, and the dispatching of each
plant used to meet this demand (given the effective capacity of each plant). For example, the
figure shows that hydropower and wind plants are dispatched first, as they incur a SRMC of
zero. Then the JPPC, JEP, West Kingston Power and slow speed diesel plants are used, as
they represent the next cheapest options (with a SRMC of US$0.14, $0.16, and $0.17 per
kWh, respectively). The oil-fired steam plant is then used, and when demand grows beyond
the capacity of all these plants at about 11:00 am, the more expensive combined cycle plant
is added. The combustion turbines are kept in reserve.
Using this order of dispatch, we calculate the average variable cost of the system throughout
the day. We do this by adding the SRMC of all plants operating on the system at half-hour
intervals throughout the day, weighted by their contribution to total generation,
7
and taking
the average of this total weighted-average cost over the entire day.
We find that the average variable cost of generation is US$0.17 per kWh.
Cost of generation when using LNG as the main fuel for electricity generation
In this section we estimate the variable cost of electricity generation after LNG is made
available in Jamaica. To estimate this cost, we need to make assumptions about what plants
would be added to the system. We assume that JPS would:

7
For example, if at 6:00 am demand is 420MW, and JPPC is operating 60MW of its plant capacity, the weighted average
cost of JPPCs plant is US$0.14 times 14 percent ([60/420]*100), or US$0.0198.
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
M
W
Timeoftheday
CombinedCycle
OilFiredSteam
SlowSpeedDiesel
JEP
WestKingstonPower
JPPC
Wind
Hydro
US$0.14/kWh
US$0.16/kWh
US$0.17/kWh
US$0.22/kWh
US$0.21/kWh(average)
US$0.16/kWh
Confidential
12
Add a 360MW NGCC plant to the system in 2014 (as specified in the OUR 2010
Generation Expansion Plan)
Convert its existing combined cycle plant located at Bogue in order to use LNG
as a fuel in 2014.
In addition, we assume that from 2014 JPS would hold its oil-fired steam plants units (OB2,
OB3, OB4 and B6, all running on HFO) in reserve, rather than dispatching them regularly,
as prescribed in the OURs Generation Expansion Plan 2010. This means that the estimated
variable cost of electricity generation may not pick up the pure effect of using LNG to
generate electricity in Jamaica. Indeed, the oil-fired steam plants are cheaper to run than the
combustion turbines (which are the next alternative available), therefore our estimation may
understate the likely savings from using LNG for electricity generation because under the
LNG scenario the combustion turbines would need to be used instead of the oil-fired
plants. However, this issue turns out to be irrelevant because the NGCC plant and converted
combustion turbine available under the LNG scenario would be sufficiently large to avoid
the use of combustion turbines, and even slow speed diesel units.
The resulting capacity would therefore be a mix of hydropower (including the hydropower
plant at Maggotty), wind power, slow speed diesel, medium speed diesel, and combustion
turbines, as well as the combined cycle plant at Bogue (converted to use natural gas as fuel),
and the new NGCC plant. We assume that JPS would only use the combustion turbines
occasionally as peaking units, as these represent the most expensive plants on the system.
Table 3.4 below provides information on the capacity, efficiency and marginal cost for each
of these plants.
To calculate the fuel cost of each plant we use the following fuel prices:
US$8.96 per MMBtu for LNG: this includes the OURs estimated average fuel
price over the period 2010-2029, plus a delivery cost of US$2.50 per MMBtu
US$18.32 per MMBtu for HFO: this includes the OURs estimated average fuel
price over the period 2010-2029 (US$16.67 per MMBtu), adjusted using
Petrojams pricing formulae for fuel delivery to the various power plants
US$21.33 per MMBtu for ADO: including an estimated average fuel price of
US$19.29 per MMBtu over the period 2010-2029, adjusted using Petrojams
pricing formulae for fuel delivery to the various power plants.
Confidential
13
Table 3.4: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Generation Plants Planned for 2014 (with LNG)

*Based on data provided by JPSassuming that the conversion of the plant would increase capacity by 1
percent of initial capacity, and improve the heat rate of the plant by 0.5 percent.
Note: LNG = Liquefied Natural Gas, HFO = Heavy Fuel Oil, ADO = Automotive Diesel Oil
Fuel prices based on average projected prices between 2010 and 2019, as projected by the OUR
We assume the same price of natural gas for the Bogue plant and the NGCC plant (although in
reality, the price of gas at Bogue plant is likely to be slightly more expensive).
For the Combined Cycle plant, we assume that the heat rate remains the same as the current heat rate.
However, Combined Cycle units tend to become less efficient when used as peaking plants, as they
are designed for base or intermediate load.
8
Therefore the marginal cost of this plant may increase if it
was used as a peaking plant.
There is a possibility that JEP may also convert its medium speed diesel plant to use LNG as a fuel, if and
when LNG becomes available. This could result in an even greater reduction in electricity generation
costs and electricity tariffs than the reductions we estimate in this section.
Source: OUR (2010), Generation Expansion Plan 2010; JPS

Figure 3.2 below shows the typical daily dispatching of the systemagain, using the typical
weekday load profile for 2009 provided in the OUR Generation Expansion Plan, and based
on merit order of short-run marginal costs.

8
Chase, D.L. (2000). Combined Cycle Development Evolution and Future. GE Power Systems GER-4206.
Effective
capacity
Average
heat rate
Fuel price
Variable
O&M
cost
Fuel cost
Short-run
marginal
cost
MW MMBtu/kWh US$/MMBtu US$/kWh US$/kWh US$/kWh
Wigton Wind farm n/a 10.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
Munro Wind farm n/a 0.9 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
JPS Hydropower Hydropower n/a 13.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
Maggotty Hydropower n/a 2.8 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
LNG Natural Gas Combined Cycle LNG 323.6 0.0073 8.96 0.003 0.07 0.07
Bogue (converted)* Combined Cycle LNG 100.9 0.0089 8.96 0.006 0.08 0.09
JPPC Slow Speed Diesel HFO 54.6 0.0077 18.32 0.010 0.14 0.15
JEP Medium Speed Diesel HFO 111.9 0.0078 18.32 0.020 0.14 0.16
West Kingston Power Medium Speed Diesel HFO 58.5 0.0078 18.32 0.020 0.14 0.16
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.0093 18.32 0.008 0.17 0.18
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.0095 18.32 0.008 0.17 0.18
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.0129 21.33 0.005 0.28 0.28
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.0165 21.33 0.005 0.35 0.36
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.0169 21.33 0.005 0.36 0.37
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.0170 21.33 0.005 0.36 0.37
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 32.1 0.0179 21.33 0.005 0.38 0.39
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0180 21.33 0.005 0.38 0.39
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0180 21.33 0.005 0.38 0.39
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0212 21.33 0.005 0.45 0.46
LNG = Liquefied Natural Gas, HFO = Heavy Fuel Oil, ADO = Automotive Diesel Oil
Fuel prices based on average projected fuel prices between 2010 and 2019, as projected by the OUR
Location/IPP name Type of plant
Type of
fossil fuel
used
Confidential
14
Figure 3.2: Merit Order Dispatch for Typical Week Day (Based on 2009 Load
Profile)Capacity Planned for 2014


Using the order of dispatch shown in Figure 3.2, we calculate the average variable cost of the
system throughout the day. We do this by adding the SRMC of all plants operating on the
system half-hour intervals throughout the day, weighted by their contribution to total
generation, then taking the average of this total weighted-average cost over the entire day.
We find that the average variable cost of electricity generation for the system would be
US$0.08 per kWh.
To generate electricity using LNG as a main fuel and achieve this system average variable
cost of US$0.08 per kWh, JPS will first need to invest in the new capacity. As the owner of a
new plant (and like any other IPPs), JPS will therefore need to recover this capital cost. To
account for the capital costs of the new plants, we account for the Long-Run Marginal Cost
(LRMC) of the NGCC plant, and of the conversion of the combined cycle plant at Bogue.
For the NGCC plant, we use the LRMC derived in Table 3.1. For the conversion of the
plant at Bogue, we use a LRMC of US$0.10 per kWh, based on estimates for conversion and
pipeline costs provided by JPS.
9

When accounting for the capital costs of the NGCC plant and the conversion of the plant at
Bogue, we find that the total cost of the system (including variable costs and capital costs per
kWh generated for the plants running on LNG) would be US$0.10 per kWh.
3.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity
We estimate the impact on the cost of electricity to JPSs customers as follows:
RcJuction in priccs =
Rcducton n gcncuton costs
LIcctcty soId


9
Assuming a capital cost of US$97.4 million, fixed O&M costs of US$0.99 per kW per month, heat rate of 0.008859
MMBtu/kWh, a discount rate of 11.95 percent and availability of 90 percent.
0.0
100.0
200.0
300.0
400.0
500.0
600.0
700.0
M
W
Timeoftheday
JEP
WestKingstonPower
JPPC
ConvertedcombinedcycleatBogue
Naturalgascombinedcycle
Wind
Newhydro
Hydro
US$0.07/kWh
US$0.09/kWh
US$0.15/kWh
US$0.16/kWh
Confidential
15
Where reduction in generation costs is the annual reduction in the cost of generating
electricity resulting from operating the NGCC plant and Bogue plant converted to LNG
(and retiring the oil-fired plant) in US$.
To calculate this, we:
1. Multiply the average variable cost of generation of the system (including variable
costs and capital costs per kWh generated for the plants that are running on
LNG) with the planned NGCC plant and Bogue plant converted to LNG
(US$0.10 per kWh) by the total amount of electricity generated in 2010 (about
4,137 GWh)
10

2. Multiply the variable cost of generation with the system capacity before using
LNG as a main fuel by electricity generated in 2010
3. Take the difference between 1 and 2 above.
We find that the annual reduction in electricity generation costs would be about US$313
million.
We then divide this figure by total electricity sold in 2010 (about 3,235 GWh).
11

We find that the average reduction in electricity prices is US$0.10 per kWh.
All customers (whether residential, commercial or industrial) could benefit from this
reduction equally.


10
Although we used the 2009 load profile to estimate the system average short-run marginal cost, 2010 figures for total
electricity generation and sales are very close to those of 2009, therefore using the more recent figures should not create a
significant discrepancy.
11
2010 electricity generation and sales figures provided by JPS (2011).
Confidential
16
4 Option 2: Increasing the Use of Renewable Energy
In this section we examine the potential for reducing electricity prices by implementing
additional economically viable utility-scale renewable energy projects, and increasing the use
of commercially viable distributed-scale renewable energy technologies in Jamaica.
We find that bagasse cogeneration, wind power, and landfill gas to energy are cheaper than
the current plant on the system. Adding these to the system now could reduce electricity
costs by about US$0.02 per kWh.
12

We find that distributed scale renewable energy technologies such as small solar photovoltaic
system and small wind turbines are unlikely to be generally commercially viable in Jamaica,
and therefore expect a limited uptake over the short-term. Nevertheless, setting up a net
billing framework in Jamaica would be an effective and appropriate way of enabling
customers who want to generate their own power, and the use of such framework may
increase over the medium term as the cost of distributed generation technologies comes
down. The OUR is currently working on a net billing framework, but there is scope to
improve over current plans.
Bagasse cogeneration, wind power and landfill gas-to-energy have a higher Long-Run
Marginal Cost than the NGCC plant and Bogue plant converted to LNG. However, the
renewable energy technologies could still reduce electricity costs after the natural gas plants
are commissioned. The reason is that the plants running on natural gas would not be the
only plants on the system (some of the high cost plant will be kept, such as the medium
speed diesel and slow speed diesel). Because the renewable energy technologies are cheaper
than these plants, adding these technologies to the system could therefore reduce electricity
generation costs. Nevertheless, because of the limited capacity of bagasse cogeneration, wind
power and landfill gas to energy available in Jamaica, the reduction in electricity generation
costs would probably not be significantabout US$0.001 per kWh. Below we provide a
description of the reform (4.1), examine the costs and benefits of implementing
economically viable renewable energy projects (4.2), and examine the costs and benefits of
increasing the use of distributed generation technologies (4.3).
4.1 Description of the Reform
There are already a few renewable energy technologies being used in Jamaica, including:
A 34.7MW wind farm in Manchester (owned and operated by an Independent
Power Producer, Wigton Windfarm Ltd.)Wigton Windfarm Ltd. is also
planning another 4MW extension to this farm
A 3MW farm in Munro, owned and operated by JPS
Eight small hydropower plants with a combined capacity of 23MW, owned and
operated by JPS.
13
We understand that JPS is also at an advanced stage of planning

12
This estimate accounts for the addition of 60MW of bagasse cogeneration, 70MW of wind power, and 1.3MW of landfill
gas-to-energy. Given current costs, waste-to-energy technology would also be viable, however we do not account for this
technology as it would become non-viable with the addition of a NGCC plant on the system (and conversion of the
Bogue plant to LNG)by non-viable, we mean that the waste-to-energy plant would generate electricity at a cost higher
than the avoided cost of the system. Hydropower is not considered for utility-scale renewable energy generation, because
most resources for utility-scale hydropower projects in Jamaica are already used.
13
Ministry of Energy (August 2010). National Renewable Energy Policy.
Confidential
17
a new hydropower plant with a capacity of 6.4MW at Maggotty in St. Elizabeth,
and aiming to commission this plant in 2013.
The Government of Jamaica and various stakeholders in the sector recognize that there is
potential for expanding renewable energy generation further through the use of viable utility-
scale technologies, as well as small-scale, distributed generation technologies (generation that
is located in close proximity to the load being served).
We look at two reforms. The first involves building large renewable power plants feeding the
grid (utility-scale technologies). The second involves distributed renewable generation
serving the customers own needs and selling any excess power into the grid.
In the following section we examine each of these reforms in further detail, and estimate
their impact on electricity costs in Jamaica.
4.2 Evidence of Benefits and CostsUtility-Scale Technologies
In this sub-section we examine the economic viability of utility-scale technologies given the
generation capacity planned for the near future. This includes all plants that are currently on
the system, in addition to the new medium-speed diesel plant to be commissioned by West
Kingston Power, and a new hydropower plant at Maggotty (to be commissioned by JPS in
2013). We then examine the viability of these technologies in the context of using LNG as a
main fuel source. For this, we consider the viability of renewable energy technologies
compared to the generation capacity mix that the OUR has planned for 2014, which
includes the addition of a 360MW natural gas combined cycle plant, the conversion of the
combined cycle plant at Bogue to use natural gas as fuel. Furthermore, we assume that JPS
would stop dispatching its oil-fired steam plants regularly, and simply hold them in reserve
for generating only in case of emergency. Finally, we estimate the impact of adding
economically viable technologies to the system on electricity costs in Jamaica.
We examine the viability of the following utility-scale technologies: bagasse cogeneration,
wind power, landfill gas to energy, waste to energy, concentrated solar power, and
commercial-scale solar photovoltaic. We do not consider hydropower because, although it is
a mature technology, recent evidence suggests that resources for utility-scale hydropower
projects are already used.
14
While there may be some potential for mini hydropower, we do
not examine this potential here, as the contribution of a mini hydropower plant to total
generation would be insignificant.
Table 4.1 below summarizes key information on each of these technologies. The table
provides a brief description of these technologies, and information on their potential
capacity in Jamaica, potential capacity factor, capital costs and Long-Run Marginal Cost
(LRMCwhich includes capital, and operating and maintenance costs). Wherever possible,
we use estimates of the Long-Run Marginal Cost (which includes capital costs, fixed and
variable operating costs) from feasibility studies specific to projects in Jamaica.
For solar photovoltaic, wind power and concentrated solar power, we use our existing
knowledge of the various projects implemented or considered in other countries in the

14
In response to the OURs competitive tender for renewable energy BOO in 2008, JPS submitted bids for two
hydropower plants: the Maggotty Project, with an installed capacity of 6.37MW, and the Great River Project, with an
installed capacity of 8MW. The bid for the Maggotty Project was accepted, and the project is scheduled for completion in
2013.
14
However, the Great River Project was rejected, on the grounds that the proposed tariff was too high.
Confidential
18
region, such as Barbados and the Turks and Caicos Islands. We use a discount rate of 11.95
percent for utility-scale renewable energy projects, as recommended in the OURs Generation
Expansion Plan 2010 and Declaration of Indicative Generation Avoided Costs.
Confidential
19
Table 4.1: Renewable Energy TechnologiesDescription, Costs and Potential in Jamaica
Technology Description
Potential
capacity,
MW
Potential
capacity
factor, %
Capital cost,
US$/kW
LRMC,
US$/kWh
Bagasse
cogeneration
Uses fuel to generate both heat and electricity with combined heat
and power plants
60MW 85% $3,000 $0.12 *
Wind power (2
MW turbines)
Captures the kinetic energy in surface winds with blades, and uses
the mechanical power generated by the rotation of the blades to
turn a generator, converting kinetic power into electrical energy
70MW 30% $2,640 $0.15**
Landfill gas to
energy
Uses the gas produced from landfills to generate electricity. The
technology for extracting landfill gas is mature and widely available
1.3 MW 80% $3,800 $0.15 ***
Waste to energy Converts waste matter into heat or various forms of fuel that can
be used to generate electricity. A proven, commercial technology
used in more than 25 countries
65MW 85% $8,250
(incineration
technology)
$0.24 ****
Concentrated
solar power
Converts the suns energy into high temperature heat using various
mirror or lens configurations. This heat is then transformed into
mechanical energy through a boiler that powers a steam turbine,
and then into electricity (or directly into electricity using micro-
turbines)
n/a 45% (solar
tower)
65%
(parabolic
trough)
$8,000 (solar
tower)
$12,000
(parabolic trough)
$0.32 (solar tower)
US$0.30 (parabolic
trough)
Commercial-scale
solar
photovoltaic
Transforms solar radiation into electricity. The basic component is
the PV cell, a semiconductor device that converts solar radiation
into direct-current electricity
n/a 20% $5,000 (high
efficiency)
$4,000 (thin film)
US$0.48 (high
efficiency)
US$0.48 (thin film)
*As disclosed by the Sugar Industry Authority on the basis of recent feasibility studies for bagasse cogeneration projects. This estimate is consistent with prices of
electricity purchased by the utility in Mauritius from independent power producers operating bagasse cogeneration plants; **Based on capital cost of the 14MW
extension of the Wigton wind farm (US$47.5 million for 14MW); *** OUR estimate of levelized cost of a 1.3MW plant proposed as part of the OURs tender for
renewable energy generation in 2008; **** discussion with Petroleum Corporation of Jamaica
Source: Government of Jamaica (2010) National Renewable Energy Policy; Castalia; Wigton Windfarm Ltd; http://www.pcj.com/wigton/about/factsheet.html;
Petroleum Corporation of Jamaica; Sugar Industry Authority; JPS

Confidential
20
We define a technology as economically viable if its LRMC is equal to, or lower than, the
relevant avoided cost. The relevant avoided cost for a particular technology depends on the
type of conventional generation that the technology is displacing:
Bagasse cogeneration and waste-to-energy technologies are firm
technologies; they can be depended on to generate electricity at any time, just like
a conventional generation unit. Therefore, the relevant avoided cost should be the
SRMC of electricity generation of the marginal plants on the existing system, plus
the capital cost of deferred capacity
Wind energy is considered non-firm. This means that there needs to be a
conventional generator on standby that is used as firming supply when the wind
is not blowing. Every unit of energy (kWh) generated by wind technologies will
save fuel and variable O&M costs, but it will not save the fixed costs of capacity
(because the firming technology capacity would also be needed). For wind power,
we therefore use the weighted average SRMC of the marginal plants on the
electricity system as the avoided cost
Solar photovoltaic and Concentrated Solar Power are also non-firm, but
generate power in daylight hours only. Therefore, we use the SRMC of the
specific plant that constitutes the marginal plant on the system during this
timeframe (daylight hours) as the relevant avoided cost
Overall, we find that bagasse cogeneration, wind power, landfill gas-to-energy and
waste-to-energy would be economically viable given the current avoided costs.
Once the NGCC plant is commissioned and the existing CC plant converted to
LNG, the relevant avoided costs would decrease, nevertheless each of these
technologies except for waste-to-energy would remain viable (the avoided cost
relevant to waste-to-energy would decrease to a level below the LRMC of that
technology)
Figure 4.1 below shows the reduction in the avoided costs relevant to wind, solar
and firm renewable energy technologies resulting from the commissioning of the
NGCC plant and converting the CC plant to LNG in 2014.
Confidential
21
Figure 4.1: Avoided Cost for Firm Renewable Energy Technologies, Wind Power and
Solar Photovoltaic (2011-2014)


4.2.1 Economic viability of adding utility-scale renewables to the current system
In this section we compare the costs of renewable energy technologies to the relevant
avoided costs, given existing capacity and fuel costs. To determine avoided costs we use the
2009 load profile and merit-order dispatching profile for a typical week day in Jamaicaas
presented in section 3.2.2, and illustrated again in Figure 4.2 below.
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
Bagasse,LandfillGastoEnergy Wind Solar
Commissioning ofnewNGCC
plantandconversionofplant
Confidential
22
Figure 4.2: Dispatching of Generation Capacity on a Typical Week Day in Jamaica
and Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants

Note: Figure based on 2009 load profile and March 2011 fuel prices
Marginal cost figures based on prices of fuel delivered to power plants in March 2011 of about
US$0.17 per MMBtu for HFO, and US$0.24 per MMBtu for ADO (prices provided by JPS).
For simplicity, this figure shows the average short-run marginal cost of all oil-fired steam plants
together. Some of the oil-fired steam units are in fact more expensive than the combined cycle
planttherefore, in reality these particular units should be dispatched after the combined cycle plant.
Source: Developed using data from: OUR (2010). Generation Expansion Plan 2010, and JPS

0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
M
W
Timeoftheday
CombinedCycle
OilFiredSteam
SlowSpeedDiesel
JEP
WestKingstonPower
JPPC
Wind
Hydro
US$0.14/kWh
US$0.16/kWh
US$0.17/kWh
US$0.22/kWh
US$0.21/kWh(average)
Confidential
23
We estimate avoided costs as follows:
For bagasse cogeneration, Concentrated Solar Power (CSP)
15
and waste-to-
energy technologies the relevant avoided cost should be the average marginal
cost of electricity generation of the existing system plus the capital cost of
deferred capacity. As illustrated in Figure 4.2, the marginal plant on the system is
always either the oil-fired steam plant, or the combined cycle plant (that is running
on ADO). We calculate the weighted average SRMC as shown in Table 4.2. The
OUR Generation Expansion Plan 2010 shows that the next capacity addition to the
system will be a natural gas combined cycle plant in 2014 (with a further unit in
2016), then a gas turbine unit in 2017. Since the OUR has already started engaging
in the procurement of the NGCC plant for 2014, we assume that firm renewables
would only displace the gas turbine unit. We estimate the capital cost of this plant
to be around US$0.02 per kWh (assuming a capital cost of US$1,279 per kW,
plant lifetime of 25 years, and a discount rate of 11.95 percent).
16
The total
avoided cost for firm renewables is therefore US$0.24 per kWh
For wind power, we use the weighted average marginal cost of the electricity
system throughout the day (US$0.22 per kWh, as shown in Table 4.2) as the
avoided cost
For solar photovoltaic we use the weighted average of the marginal cost of the
system between 6:00 am and 6:00 pm as the relevant avoided cost (this is also
US$0.22 per kWh, as shown in Table 4.2).

15
For the purpose of this analysis, we consider CSP as a firm technology in spite of being a solar technology because we
consider energy storage solutions associated with these plants
16
Estimate of capital cost provided by JPS
Confidential
24
Table 4.2: System Weighted Average Marginal Cost of Generation
Type of plant
Short-run marginal cost
(fuel and variable O&M),
US$/kWh*
% of time that the
plant is on the
margin**
Weighted average
marginal cost,
US$/kWh
Weighted Average Marginal Cost for the Day
Oil-Fired Steam 0.21 60% 0.13
Combined Cycle 0.22 40% 0.09
Total 0.22
Weighted Average Marginal Cost between 6:00 am and 6:00pm
Oil-Fired Steam 0.21 54% 0.12
Combined Cycle 0.22 46% 0.10
Total 0.22
*Given a price of US$0.24 per MMBtu for ADO and US$0.17 per MMBtu delivered to the plants (March 2011
price provided by JPS)
**Calculated as the number of hours that each plant is running, divided by the total number of hours in a day
(24) and multiplied by 100
Source: OUR (2010). Generation Expansion Plan 2010.

Figure 4.3 below shows our assessment of the economic and commercial viability of
potential technologies for renewable generation in Jamaica. The figure shows the Long Run
Marginal Cost (LRMC, or all-in cost) of generation (US$ per kWh) for the renewable energy
technologies, and compares these against the relevant avoided costs.
Confidential
25
Figure 4.3: Economic Viability of Utility-Scale Renewable Energy Technologies in
Jamaica


Figure 4.3 shows the LRMC of each technology in US$ per kWh, compared to the relevant
avoided costs. For example, technologies with costs highlighted in grey represent the firm
technologies, and should be compared with the avoided cost highlighted in grey. The figure
shows that bagasse cogeneration, wind power, and landfill gas to energy are currently
economically viable in Jamaica, and waste-to-energy may be viable. Solar PV and CSP have a
LRMC well above the relevant avoided cost, and therefore not considered economically
viable.
In section 4.2.3 we analyze how implementing these projects would affect the cost of
electricity in Jamaica.
4.2.2 Economic viability of renewables once LNG is used as the main fuel
In this section we examine the viability of utility-scale renewable energy technologies given
the commissioning of a 360MW NGCC plant, the conversion of the CC plant at Bogue to
use LNG as a fuel, and assuming that JPS stops dispatching its oil-fired steam plants
regularly (as planned by the OUR in the Generation Expansion Plan 2010).
We use the dispatching profile that we estimated in section 3.2.2as shown in Figure 4.4
below. The figure shows that given this new mix of capacity on the system, the marginal
plants are the JPPC plant, the converted combined cycle plant at Bogue, and the West
Kingston Power plantsthis is because the oil-fired steam plant would no longer be used
for dispatching, and the natural gas plants would also displace the slow speed diesel plant
and high-cost combustion turbines (these plants would therefore not be needed for meeting
demand).
0.52
0.38
0.32
0.30
0.24
0.15
0.15
0.12
0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60
SolarPV(HighEfficiency,fixed,commercial)
SolarPV(thinfilm,fixed,commercial)
CSP(SolarTower,w/storage)
CSP(ParabolicTrough,w/storage)
WastetoEnergy(incineration)
Wind(2MWturbines)
Landfillgastoenergy(internalcombustion)
Bagassecogeneration
US$/kWh
Avoidedcost(firm):US$0.24/kWh
Avoidedcost(wind):US$0.22/kWh
Avoidedcost(solar):US$0.22/kWh
Confidential
26
Figure 4.4: Merit Order Dispatch on a Typical Week Day in Jamaica

Note: Figures based on 2009 load profile, and projected fuel prices for the period 2010-2019

To determine the economic viability of renewable energy technologies given the new
generation mix, we use the same LRMC estimates for renewable energy technologies as in
the previous subsection. However, given the addition of a large natural gas plant to the
system, the avoided costs are expected to decreasewe estimate the relevant avoided costs
as follows:
For firm technologies, we use an avoided cost of US$0.17 per kWh, calculated by
adding the weighted average marginal cost of the combined cycle, JPPC and West
Kingston Power and JEP plants (shown in Table 4.3 below) to the capacity cost
of the natural gas combustion turbine that would be displaced (US$0.02 per kWh)
For wind power, we use the weighted average marginal cost of slow speed diesel,
JEP and combined cycle plants throughout the day (US$0.15 per kWh)
For solar power we use the weighted average marginal cost of the JPPC, JEP and
converted Bogue plants during daylight hours (US$0.16 per kWh, as shown in
Table 4.3 below).
0.0
100.0
200.0
300.0
400.0
500.0
600.0
700.0
M
W
Timeoftheday
JEP
WestKingstonPower
JPPC
ConvertedcombinedcycleatBogue
Naturalgascombinedcycle
Wind
Newhydro
Hydro
US$0.07/kWh
US$0.09/kWh
US$0.15/kWh
US$0.16/kWh
Confidential
27
Table 4.3: Weighted Average Marginal Cost of Combined Cycle and Slow Speed
Diesel Plants
Type of plant
Short-run marginal cost
(fuel and variable O&M),
US$/kWh*
% of time that the
plant is on the
margin
Weighted average
marginal cost,
US$/kWh
Weighted Average Marginal Cost throughout the Day
Converted Combined
Cycle
0.09 19%
0.02
JPPC 0.15 19% 0.03
West Kingston Power
and JEP
0.16 63% 0.010
Total 0.15
Weighted Average Marginal Cost during Daylight Hours (between 6:00 am and 6:00 pm)
Converted Combined
Cycle
0.09 4%
0.004
JPPC 0.15 29% 0.04
West Kingston Power
and JEP
0.16 67% 0.11
Total 0.16
Note: We assume that the JEP plant and West Kingston Power plant have the same characteristics and costs
Source: Data from OUR (2010). Generation Expansion Plan 2010

Figure 4.5 below shows our assessment of the economic viability of potential technologies
for utility-scale renewable energy generation in Jamaica. The figure shows that bagasse
cogeneration and landfill gas to energy technologies would remain economically viable, and
wind power may be viable. However, waste-to-energy would become non-viable, as the
avoided cost would decrease well below the LRMC of the plant (avoided cost of US$0.17
per kWh, compared to LRMC of US$0.24 per kWh).
Confidential
28
Figure 4.5: Economic Viability of Utility-Scale Renewables Given Capacity Planned
for 2014


4.2.3 Reduction in electricity costs from implementing utility-scale renewable
energy technologies
In the previous subsection we found that three types of renewable energy technologies
would be viable given the current fuel prices and generation capacity: bagasse cogeneration,
wind power and landfill gas to energy. We also found that these technologies would likely
remain viable once LNG is used as a main fuel for electricity generation. Waste-to-energy
may currently be viable, but would not remain viable once LNG is used for electricity
generation.
In this section we estimate the potential reduction in electricity costs from implementing
these viable technologies. We consider the addition of the full potential capacity estimated
for bagasse cogeneration, wind power and landfill gas-to-energy technologies in Jamaica as
indicated in Table 4.1that is: 60MW of bagasse cogeneration, 70MW of wind power, and a
1.3MW landfill gas-to-energy plant. We do not consider the addition of the waste-to-energy
plant, as the plant would not be able to recover its LRMC from 2014 onwards.
We calculate the reduction in the cost of electricity generation as follows:
1. We estimate the average variable cost of electricity generation throughout the day
given the baseline generation capacity mix (which we already did in section 3.2.2)
2. We calculate the average variable cost of electricity generation throughout the day
if the renewable energy plants were added to the system. This cost should be
lower than the cost calculated in step 1, because the renewable energy plants
would avoid the need to run expensive plants running on diesel and HFO,
thereby enabling savings in fuel costs
0.52
0.38
0.32
0.30
0.24
0.15
0.15
0.12
0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60
SolarPV(HighEfficiency,fixed,commercial)
SolarPV(thinfilm,fixed,commercial)
CSP(SolarTower,w/storage)
CSP(ParabolicTrough,w/storage)
WastetoEnergy(incineration)
Wind(2MWturbines)
Landfillgastoenergy(internalcombustion)
Bagassecogeneration
US$/kWh
Avoidedcost(wind):US$0.15/kWh
Avoidedcost(firm):US$0.17/kWh
Avoidedcost(solar):US$0.16/kWh
Confidential
29
3. We subtract the costs calculated in step 1 and 2, to give us the reduction in
electricity generation costs resulting from the use of renewable energy
technologies
4. We estimate the impact on the cost of electricity to JPSs customers using the
same method as in section 3.2.2; that is:
RcJuction in priccs =
Rcducton n gcncuton costs
LIcctcty soId

5. We then repeat this process to compare the cost of electricity generation when the
NGCC plant comes in, and the CC plant converted to LNG, and the oil-fired
steam plants are no longer dispatched regularly, with and without the renewable
energy plants.
Reduction in prices from adding renewable energy technologies to the current
system
In section 3.2.2 we demonstrated how we calculate the average variable cost of electricity
generation using the current capacitywe estimate this cost to be US$0.17 per kWh.
To calculate how this cost would change as a result of adding more renewables to the
system, we use the data provided in Table 4.4 below, which shows the short-run marginal
cost of all existing plants, and of the new renewable energy plants added to the system.
Confidential
30
Table 4.4: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants (March 2011 Fuel Prices)

Note: Landfill gas-to-energy and bagasse cogeneration would involve some variable O&M costs. Nevertheless,
such costs are typically insignificant compared to the fixed O&M costs, and because there was no specific data
available on variable O&M costs for such plants in Jamaica, we approximated these costs to zero. This should
not change the results, however, as these costs are typically very small.


Figure 4.6 below shows the typical daily dispatching of the systemagain, using the typical
weekday load profile for 2009 provided in the OUR Generation Expansion Plan, and based
on merit order of short-run marginal costs. The figure shows that the new renewable energy
plants would be used at all times, given that they are less costly than the existing fossil fuel
plants. The figure also shows that with the addition of these renewable energy plants, the
expensive combustion turbine plants would not be required as much to satisfy electricity
demand on a daily basis.
Effective
capacity
Average
heat rate
Current
fuel
price**
Variable
O&M
cost
Fuel cost
Short-run
marginal
cost
MW MMBtu/kWh US$/MMBtu US$/kWh US$/kWh US$/kWh
Wigton Wind farm n/a 10.4 n/a 0.0 0.000 - -
Munro Wind farm n/a 0.9 n/a 0.0 0.000 - -
JPS Hydropower Hydropower n/a 13.4 n/a 0.0 0.000 - -
JPS Maggotty Hydropower n/a 2.8 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
New wind Wind farm n/a 21.0 n/a 0.0 0.000 - -
Bagasse Bagasse cogeneration Bagasse 51.0 n/a 0.0 0.000 - -
Landfill gas Lanfill gas-to-energy Landfill gas 1.0 n/a 0.0 0.000 - -
JPPC Slow Speed Diesel HFO 54.6 0.008 16.9 0.010 0.13 0.14
JEP Medium Speed Diesel HFO 111.9 0.008 17.5 0.020 0.14 0.16
West Kingston Power Medium Speed Diesel HFO 58.5 0.008 17.5 0.020 0.14 0.16
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.009 16.9 0.008 0.16 0.16
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.009 16.9 0.008 0.16 0.17
Old Harbour Oil Fired Steam HFO 61.8 0.012 16.7 0.007 0.20 0.21
Old Harbour Oil Fired Steam HFO 65.1 0.012 16.7 0.007 0.21 0.21
Hunts Bay Oil Fired Steam HFO 65.1 0.012 16.8 0.007 0.21 0.21
Old Harbour Oil Fired Steam HFO 57.0 0.013 16.7 0.007 0.21 0.22
Bogue Combined Cycle ADO 111.0 0.009 23.9 0.006 0.21 0.22
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.013 23.8 0.005 0.31 0.31
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.016 23.8 0.005 0.39 0.40
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.017 23.8 0.005 0.40 0.41
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.017 23.8 0.005 0.40 0.41
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 32.1 0.018 23.8 0.005 0.43 0.43
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.018 23.8 0.005 0.43 0.43
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.018 23.8 0.005 0.43 0.43
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.021 23.8 0.005 0.50 0.51
Location/IPP name Type of plant
Type of
fossil fuel
used*
* HFO = Heavy Fuel Oil, ADO = Automotive Diesel Oil
** Based on March 2011 prices of fuel delivered at each plant.
Note: for the JPPC plant, we assume same HFO prices as those for Hunts Bay (given location proximity). For JEP and West Kingston Power,
we assume same HFO prices as for Old Harbour
Confidential
31
Figure 4.6: Merit-Order Dispatch with Viable Utility-Scale Renewables

Note: Figures based on 2009 load profile provided in the OUR Generation Expansion Plan 2010, and March
2011 fuel prices provided by JPS
For simplicity, this figure shows the average short-run marginal cost of all oil-fired steam plants
together. Some of the oil-fired steam units are in fact more expensive than the combined cycle
planttherefore, in reality these particular units should be dispatched after the combined cycle plant.

Using the order of dispatch shown above, we calculate the average variable cost of the
system throughout the day. We do this by:
1. Multiplying the short-run marginal cost of all plants operating on the system by
their contribution to total generation at half-hour intervals throughout the day
2. Taking the average of the weighted-average cost of all plants over the entire day.
We find that the average variable cost of electricity generation would decrease to US$0.14
per kWh.
To achieve this reduction in variable costs, investment in renewable energy capacity would
be required, and the owners of the renewable energy plants will need to recover their capital
cost. To account for the capital costs of the new plants, we account for the Long-Run
Marginal Cost (LRMC) of the renewable energy plants (shown in Table 4.1).
When accounting for the capital costs of the renewable energy plants, we find that the total
cost of the system (including variable costs and capital costs per kWh generated of the new
renewable energy plants) would be US$0.16 per kWh.
We then estimate the impact on the cost of electricity to JPSs customers as follows:
RcJuction in priccs =
Rcducton n gcncuton costs
LIcctcty soId

0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
M
W
Timeoftheday
CombinedCycle
OilFiredSteam
SlowSpeedDiesel
JEP
NewJEP
JPPC
Landfillgastoenergy
Bagasse
NewWind
ExistingWind
Hydro
US$0.14/kWh
US$0.17/kWh
US$0.16/kWh
US$0.21/kWh
US$0.16/kWh
US$0.22/kWh
Confidential
32
Where reduction in generation costs is the annual reduction in the cost of generating
electricity resulting from implementing the viable renewable energy projects, in US$. To
calculate this, we:
1. Multiply the average variable cost of generation of the system with the viable
renewable energy capacity (including the capital cost of renewable energy plants
that is US$0.16 per kWh) by the electricity generated in 2010 (about 4,137 GWh)
2. Multiply the system average variable cost of generation without the renewables by
electricity generated in 2010
3. Take the difference between 1 and 2 above.
We find that the annual reduction in electricity generation costs would be about US$51
million.
We then divide this figure by total electricity sold in 2010 (about 3,235 GWh).
17

We find that the average reduction in electricity prices is US$0.02 per kWh.
Reduction in prices from adding renewable energy technologies to the system
planned for 2014
In this section we compare the estimated cost of electricity generation once LNG is used as
a main fuel for electricity generation (that is, once the NGCC plant is commissioned, the CC
plant at Bogue has been converted to use LNG, and the oil-fired steam plants no longer
dispatched regularly), with the cost of electricity generation if the viable renewable energy
plants were added to that system.
In section 3.2.2 we demonstrated how we calculate the average variable cost of electricity
generation using the capacity planned for 2014we estimate this cost to be US$0.08 per
kWh.
To calculate how this cost would change as a result of adding more renewables to the
system, we use the data provided in Table 4.5 below, which shows the effective capacity and
short-run-marginal cost of all plants that would be on the system, including the NGCC
plant, converted CC plant, and the new bagasse cogeneration, wind power and landfill gas to
energy plants.

17
2010 generation and sales figures provided by JPS.
Confidential
33
Table 4.5: Marginal Cost of Plants on the System (with Renewables and LNG plants)
Note: Landfill gas-to-energy and bagasse cogeneration would involve some variable O&M costs.
Nevertheless, such costs are typically insignificant compared to the fixed O&M costs, and because there was no
specific data available on variable O&M costs for such plants in Jamaica, we approximated these costs to zero.
This should not change the results, however, as these costs are typically very small.

Figure 4.7 below shows the typical daily dispatching of the systemagain, using the typical
weekday load profile for 2009 provided in the OUR Generation Expansion Plan 2010, and
based on merit order of the marginal cost of each plant.
The figure shows that the new renewable energy plants would be dispatched before the
NGCC plant (as they incur a short-run marginal cost of zero). The figure also shows that
with the addition of these renewable energy plants, JEPs medium-speed diesel plant would
not be used as much on a daily basis to satisfy electricity demand. The renewable energy
plants would also enable fuel cost savings, as the JPPC, JEP and West Kingston Power
plants would not be needed as much (see Figure 3.2 in comparison).

Effective
capacity
Average
heat rate
Current
fuel
price**
Variable
O&M
cost
Fuel cost
Short-run
marginal
cost
MW MMBtu/kWh US$/MMBtu US$/kWh US$/kWh US$/kWh
Wigton Wind farm n/a 10.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 0.00 -
Munro Wind farm n/a 0.9 n/a 0.00 0.000 0.00 -
JPS Hydropower Hydropower n/a 13.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 0.00 -
JPS Maggotty Hydropower n/a 2.8 n/a 0.00 0.000 0.00 -
New wind Wind farm n/a 21.0 n/a 0.00 0.000 0.00 -
Bagasse Bagasse cogeneration Bagasse 51.0 n/a 0.00 0.000 0.00 -
Landfill gas Lanfill gas-to-energy Landfill gas 1.0 n/a 0.00 0.000 0.00 -
NGCC Natural Gas Combined Cycle LNG 323.6 0.01 8.96 0.003 0.07 0.07
Bogue (converted) Combined Cycle LNG 100.9 0.009 9.0 0.006 0.08 0.09
JPPC Slow Speed Diesel HFO 54.6 0.008 18.32 0.01 0.14 0.15
JEP Medium Speed Diesel HFO 111.9 0.008 18.32 0.020 0.14 0.16
West Kingston Power Medium Speed Diesel HFO 58.5 0.008 18.32 0.020 0.14 0.16
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.009 18.32 0.008 0.17 0.18
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.009 18.32 0.008 0.17 0.18
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.01 21.33 0.01 0.28 0.28
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.02 21.33 0.01 0.35 0.36
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.02 21.33 0.01 0.36 0.37
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.02 21.33 0.01 0.36 0.37
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 32.1 0.02 21.33 0.01 0.38 0.39
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.02 21.33 0.01 0.38 0.39
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.02 21.33 0.01 0.38 0.39
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.02 21.33 0.01 0.45 0.46
Location/IPP name Type of plant
Type of
fossil fuel
used*
* HFO = Heavy Fuel Oil, ADO = Automotive Diesel Oil
** Based on projected fuel prices for the period 2010-2029
Note: for the JPPC plant, we assume same HFO prices as those for Hunts Bay (given location proximity). For JEP and West Kingston Power,
we assume same HFO prices as for Old Harbour. For the Combined Cycle plant, we assume that the heat rate remains the same as the current
heat rate.
Confidential
34
Figure 4.7: Merit-Order Dispatch with Viable Utility-Scale Renewables

Note: Figure based on 2009 load profile and projected fuel prices for the period 2010-2029 provided in the
OUR Generation Expansion Plan 2010

Using the order of dispatch shown above, we calculate the average variable cost of the
system throughout the day. We do this by multiplying the short-run marginal cost of all
plants operating on the system by their contribution to total generation at half-hour intervals
throughout the day. We then take the average of the weighted-average cost of all plants over
the entire day. We find that the cost of electricity generation would decrease to US$0.06 per
kWh.
When accounting for the capital costs per kWh generated of the renewable energy plants and
of the NGCC and CC plants, the average cost of electricity generation (including variable
costs of all plants, and capital costs per kWh generated of the new plants) would increase to
about US$0.09 per kWh.
We then estimate the impact on the cost of electricity to JPSs customers as follows:
RcJuction in priccs =
Rcducton n gcncuton costs
LIcctcty soId

Where reduction in generation costs is the annual reduction in the cost of generating
electricity resulting from implementing the viable renewable energy projects, in US$. To
calculate this, we:
1. Multiply the average cost of generation of the system with the viable renewable
energy capacity (taking into account the capital and fixed O&M costs of the new
plantsUS$0.09 per kWh) by the electricity generated in 2010
2. Multiply the cost of generation with projected capacity (with NGCC plant,
converted combined cycle plant and no oil-based steam plantincluding capital
and fixed O&M costs) by electricity generated in 2010
3. Take the difference between 1 and 2 above.

0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
M
W
Timeoftheday
WestKingstonPower
JPPC
ConvertedCombinedCycle
NaturalGasCombinedCycle
Landfillgastoenergy
Bagasse
NewWind
ExistingWind
Hydro
US$0.07/kWh
US$0.09/kWh
US$0.16/kWh
US$0.14/kWh
Confidential
35
We find that the annual reduction in electricity generation costs would be about US$1.9
million.
We then divide this figure by total electricity sold in 2010this results in an average
reduction in electricity prices of US$0.001 per kWh.
4.3 Evidence of Benefits and CostsDistributed Scale Technologies
In this section we examine the commercial viability of three distributed renewable energy
technologies in Jamaica: small wind turbines, small thin film solar photovoltaic panels
(fixed), and high-efficiency solar photovoltaic panels (fixed). We use cost estimates for these
technologies from other countries of the Caribbean, which should be a reasonable
approximation given the similar geographical and climate conditions. Table 4.6 below shows
the typical size, capacity factor and capital cost and LRMC for each of these technologies.
We use a 15 percent discount rate (compared to 11.95 percent for utility-scale technologies),
because distributed renewable energy technologies are typically implemented by hotels,
businesses and householdswho have a higher cost of capital than utilities.
Table 4.6: Key Information on Distributed Renewable Energy Technologies
Technology
Typical
size,
kW
Potential
capacity
factor
Capital cost,
US$/kW
Long-Run
Marginal Cost,
US$/kWh
Thin film solar photovoltaic, fixed
(small)
2 21% 5,000 0.48
Thin film solar photovoltaic, fixed
(commercial)
50 21% 4,000 0.38
Small wind turbine 10 30% 6,000 0.41
High-efficiency solar photovoltaic,
fixed (small)
3 19% 6,000 0.63
High-efficiency solar photovoltaic,
fixed (commercial)
50 19% 5,000 0.52

Figure 4.8 below compares the LRMC of each of these technologies to current tariffs for
residential and small commercial customers in Jamaica. The figure also displays the projected
tariffs in 2014to calculate these tariffs we use our estimation of tariff reductions as a result
of using LNG as a main fuel source for generating electricity (US$0.09 per kWh), as
calculated in section 3.2.2 of this report.
The figure shows that of all these technologies, the commercial-sized thin film fixed solar
photovoltaic is the only technology that can be considered commercially viable given the
March 2011 electricity tariffs in Jamaicain other words, this technology is the only one that
can generate electricity at a cost that is lower than the relevant electricity tariff. However, this
technology would be unlikely to remain commercially viable once LNG is used as a main
fuel for electricity generation, as the addition of this plant to the system is likely to reduce
electricity tariffs significantly (down to US$0.30 per kWh for small commercial customers
with a consumption of 1000 kWh per month), as shown in the figure below and
demonstrated in section 3.2.2.
Confidential
36
Implementing such technologies would not generate any savings to customers and therefore
it is unlikely that many people will invest in these technologies over the next few years.
Given the small size of these technologies and the limited expected uptake, the potential for
generating electricity from these technologies in Jamaica is very limited.
Figure 4.8: Commercial Viability of Distributed Renewable Energy Technologies


Nevertheless, some people may wish to use these technologies to generate their own power,
even if at a high cost. In addition, possible further reductions in the cost of such
technologies mean that more consumers may start to find it attractive to install these
technologies on their own premises. Distributed-scale renewable generation can also be
advantageous not only to individual customers, but on a nation-wide levelprovided that
there are adequate frameworks in place to avoid compromising on electricity cost, safety,
quality and reliability. Potential benefits of distributed-scale renewable generation include
minimizing transmission and distribution losses, reducing network congestion, deferring
investments in utility-scale generation capacity or network upgrading, reducing greenhouse
gas emissions, and improving system security.
For these reasons, we think that it would be beneficial in the long run to set up a framework
governing the installation and operation of such technologies, and the sale of excess
distributed generation to the grid. We understand that the OUR is currently preparing a
framework and standard contract for enabling net billing in Jamaica. We think that the
general principle of the net billing approach is sound and appropriate for Jamaica (as
explained in Box 4.1 below) and, if implemented effectively, should not result in any increase
in the price of electricity to customers. However, there is scope to improve the design of the
net billing system currently being proposed by the OUR. Below we provide some
recommendations on designing an effective net billing contract in Jamaica.

0.63
0.52
0.48
0.41
0.38
0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70
SolarPV(HighEfficiency,fixed,small)
SolarPV(HighEfficiency,fixed,
commercial)
SolarPV(thinfilm,fixed,small)
Wind(10kWdistributedscaleturbines)
SolarPV(thinfilm,fixed,commercial)
US$/kWh
Current residentialtariff
(300kWh/month):US$0.39/kWh
Current tariffforsmallcommercial customers
(1000kWh/month):US$0.39/kWh
Projected tariffforsmallcommercial
customers(1000kWh/month,2014):
US$0.29/kWh
Projected tariffforresidential
customers(300kWh/month,2014):
US$0.29/kWh
Confidential
37
Box 4.1: Net Billing vs. Net Metering
When customers of electric utilities invest in distributed generation, their consumption of
the power that utilities generate will decrease. At the same time, because distributed
renewable power is intermittent, it will often not fully meet the customers demands.
Therefore the customers will continue to demand that utilities maintain their connection to
the power grid, and will expect utilities to supply them with power when generation from
the customers own unit is not enough. Customers will also at times generate power in
excess of their own needs. This power can be made available to the grid, and customers
will expect to be paid for it.
To enable distributed generation it is therefore necessary to meter the power that the
customers buy from utilities, and the power that utilities buy from customers. This would
require an investment in metering, and new rules for the types of meters to be used, who is
to pay for them, and how they are to be read.
Some countries use a net-metering approach to avoid the need for investment in
additional meters. Under this approach, the electricity supplied back into the grid by the
customer simply runs the meter backward, effectively subtracting kilowatt hours from the
customers recorded consumption. This approach is economically questionable, because it
is equivalent to letting customers sell their power to utilities at the retail ratewhich
includes the cost of electricity generation, transmission and distributioneven though the
customers only generate electricity and the utilities still incur the cost of electricity
transmission and distribution. The result is that the utility pays considerably more than
avoided cost for power, and so the total cost of the electricity supply goes up. The ultimate
effect of net metering, then, is that those customers who do not have distributed
generation end up subsidizing those who do. In the long-term, net-metering therefore
tends to increase the total cost of electricity supply by promoting inefficient distributed
generation.
Under net billing, electricity consumed and produced is measured separately, thereby
enabling utilities to buy distributed power from customers at a tariff that is lower than the
retail tariff. This approach is particularly suitable for countries that wish to enable
distributed renewable generation with an objective of reducing electricity costs (such as
Jamaica), rather than simply developing renewable generation (such as in European
countries). The key is then to set a tariff that promotes efficient investment in distributed
scale renewable generation, and design appropriate contracts for distributed renewable
energy.

The OUR recently drafted a Standard Offer Contract for Net Billing in Jamaica.
18
The
Standard Offer Contract is a 5 year renewable contract offering qualifying facilities with a
capacity under 100kW a payment equivalent to the long-run avoided cost (estimated over a
20 year period), plus a 15 percent premium. The Declaration of Indicative Generation Avoided
Costs (December 2010) provides the OURs latest estimate for the long-run avoided cost for
qualifying facilities without guaranteed capacityUS$0.0933 per kWh, which is equivalent to
about US$0.107 per kWh when accounting for the 15 percent premium.
We think that the OUR could improve the design of this contract by:
Extending the contract duration to 20 yearsthis would provide further
certainty to customers (given that most distributed renewable energy technologies

18
JPS (15 March 2011). JPSCo Ltd Standard Offer Contract for the Purchase of As-Available Energy from Intermittent Renewable Energy
Facilities up to 100kW between Qualifying Entity and JPS.
Confidential
38
have an average lifetime of 20 years) and minimize transaction and processing
costs (JPS and customers would only need to sign one contract over a 20 year
period, rather than having to renew the contract every five yearsthis could also
minimize the risk and potential for disputes over contract renewals)
Offering two options to qualifying facilities:
1. Providing the long-run avoided cost and 15 percent premium, fixed for a period of 20
yearsunder this contract, customers would sell their excess generation to
JPS at a price fixed at the long-run avoided cost for a period of 20 years.
The OUR has estimated the long-run avoided cost as US$0.0933; adding a
15 percent premium gives a total of US$0.1073 per kWh. This cost is slightly
lower than (but close to) the average cost of electricity generation that we
estimated for the whole system with a NGCC plant and converted
combined cycle plant (US$0.10 per kWh as shown in section 3.2.2).
However, this long-run avoided cost does not compare with the avoided
cost that we estimated for non-firm renewable energy with the NGCC and
converted combined cycle plant (we estimated this cost as US$0.16 per
kWh, as shown in section 4.2.3with a 15 percent premium, this would
amount to about US$0.18 per kWh), as shown in Figure 4.9 below. We
recommend that the OUR provides further information regarding the
calculation and determination of the avoided cost. Either way, under this
contract, the price at which customers would sell their excess power to JPS
would be fixed for a period of 20 years
2. Providing the current short-run avoided cost for a period of 3 years,
19
with the OUR
resetting the avoided cost to actual short-run avoided cost on an annual basisUnder
this contract, for the first three years customers would be able to sell their
excess power to JPS at the current avoided costwhich we estimate at
around US$0.22 per kWh. If a 15 percent premium were added (as is
suggested in the current Standard Offer Contract), this would amount to
about US$0.25 per kWh. This is higher than the long-run avoided cost set in
the other contract, because the electricity generation is more costly now
compared to when the NGCC plant comes in and the CC plant converted
to LNG. Once LNG is used as the main fuel for electricity generation, the
OUR would then reset the avoided cost to actual avoided cost on an annual
basisthe avoided cost would therefore decrease. However, the avoided
cost may increase or decrease in subsequent years, depending on the
evolution of gas, ADO and HFO prices (as illustrated in Figure 4.9 below).
Therefore, under this contract, customers would always sell their power to
JPS at the short-run avoided costthis would be higher than the long-run
avoided cost over the next three years, and may be similar to, higher or
lower than the long-run avoided cost in the long-term.

19
We choose a period of three years because the cost of electricity generation is unlikely to change significantly until 2014,
given the OURs current Generation Expansion Plan
Confidential
39
Figure 4.9: Comparison of Avoided Costs Provided under Different Contracts

0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
U
S
$
/
k
W
h
Year
Longrunavoidedcost+15%premium(OUR)
Shortrun avoidedcostestimate+15%premium(Castalia)
Avoidedcostestimate+15%
premiumwhenLNGusedas
mainfuel(Castalia)
Avoidedcostmayincreaseordecreasein
thefuture,dependingongasandoilprices
Option1
Option2
Confidential
40
5 Option 3: Reducing System Losses
In this section we examine the option of reducing electricity losses from the transmission
and distribution system to reduce electricity supply costs. We find that, all else being equal, a
reduction of electricity losses by one percentage point would enable an average reduction in
electricity tariffs of 0.8 percent. A reduction in losses by 5 percentage points would lead to a
reduction in tariffs of US$0.01 per kWh compared to current tariffs, for all customer
categories. We also estimate that reducing losses by 5 percentage points on projected tariffs
(after the commissioning of a large NGCC plant and conversion of the existing combined
cycle plant to natural gas) would lead to a reduction of US$0.006 per kWh for all customers.
Below we briefly describe what the reform of reducing losses would entail, and summarize
the current status of losses in Jamaica (5.1). We then estimate the potential for reducing
losses, taking into account what JPS is already doing, as well as further actions that the
Government and JPS could take (5.2). We then examine the impact of reducing electricity
losses on electricity prices to customers (5.3).
5.1 Description of the Reform
In this section we provide some general information about system losses. We then
summarize the current status of electricity losses in Jamaica.
5.1.1 Definition of system losses
Transmission and distribution losses are the difference between electricity produced (as
recorded of the power plants) and electricity sold to end customers (as recorded by the
customers energy meters, and billed by the utility). In other words, the total amount of
kilowatt-hours sent out from the generating stations is greater than the corresponding values
consumed, because of losses in the system. Transmission and distribution network losses
occur in the lines, substations, and transformers. These losses are referred to as technical
losses.
Electricity losses also include non-technical losses, which result from theft and unmetered
consumption. Non-technical losses are caused by deficiencies in billing and meter reading, as
well as by consumption not captured by meters such as theft, meter errors, non-billing and-
under billing of legal accounts. Non-technical losses represent the difference between
electricity supplied to customers and electricity billed. High levels of non-technical losses at
the distribution level mean that honest consumers have to bear the burden caused by
dishonest consumers who steal electricity.
The difference between units sent out of the power stations and units sold (as appearing in
the billing statement) are the net system losses consisting of the sum of the two components,
technical and non-technical losses.
The reduction of these net system losses will result in a reduction of the utilitys overall cost
of operations. These cost savings will translate into lower tariffs to the consumer through
the performance-based rate setting mechanism (PBRM) contained in the JPS licence.
20


20
The PBRM places a cap on the costs resulting from losses that the company can be compensated for through the tariff.
It also requires that, to the extent that JPSs costs are reduced by a lowering of non-technical losses, these reductions are
shared between JPS and the consumer because the tariff is reset annually to take account of the actual losses performance
in the previous period.

5.2
In th
the c
strat
then
losse
5.2.1
JPS
have
repr
Loss
repr
in A
Figu
Sourc

Figu
that
trans
total
Potent
his section w
current statu
tegy for redu
n suggest ot
es even furth
1 Net elec
s transmissi
e been decr
esented 22.4
ses increased
esented 982
April 2011.
ure 5.1: Syst
ce: JPS
ure 5.2 below
non-techni
smission an
l losses, resp
tial for Ele
we evaluate
us of electric
ucing losses
ther actions
her.
ctricity loss
ion and distr
reasing since
4 percent o
d to 24.1 pe
2.5 GWh of
em Losses
w shows the
cal losses re
d secondary
pectively.
ectricity L
the potenti
city losses in
, and what t
that JPS an
ses in Jama
ribution los
e 2009, as
of net electr
ercent in 20
electricity ge
in Jamaica
e compositi
epresent mo
y distribution
Confidentia
41
Loss Redu
ial for reduc
Jamaica, an
targets it ha
nd the Gov
aica
ses have bee
shown in F
ricity genera
08, and redu
enerated. JP
a (Rolling A
on of electr
ore than hal
n lines cons
al
uction in J
cing electrici
nd then exam
s set over th
vernment co
en somewha
Figure 5.1 b
ation, down
uced again t
PS reported t
Average for
ricity losses
lf of total e
stitute the 3
Jamaica
ity losses. W
mine JPSs cu
he short-to-m
ould take to
at volatile in
below. In 20
n from 23.5
to 23.3 perc
that losses w
2005-2010)
in Jamaica.
electricity lo
.7 percent a
We first sum
urrent and pl
medium term
o reduce elec
n recent yea
007 system
percent in
cent in 2009
were 21.74 p
The figure
osses. Losses
and 3.8 perc
marize
lanned
m. We
ctricity
ars, but
losses
n 2006.
9this
percent

shows
s from
cent of

Figu
Sourc

JPS
JPS
to pr
In 2
emp
deve
losse
cons
Infra
deriv
mete
calcu
JPS
assis
JPS
locat
insta

21
R
ure 5.2: Com
ce: JPS
s loss redu
has recently
roduce good
2009 JPS est
ployees who
eloped a pol
es, including
struction (t
astructure
ve from imp
er reading a
ulations, and
also expect
st it in reduc
and IPP ne
tions; instal
allation of a

ed Zones are in
mposition o
uction progr
y taken sever
d results. Bel
tablished a s
o are solely
licy framew
g account au
through the
see Box 5.
plementing t
and billing a
d the ability t
ts to improv
cing system l
et generation
llation of m
additional P

nner city locatio
of JPSs Elec
ramme
ral steps to r
low we discu
special divis
dedicated t
work and a s
udits, meteri
e implemen
1 below), a
the above st
and tamper
to determine
ve its capab
losses, includ
n metering;
metering wit
Parish bound

ns where extrem
Confidentia
42
ctricity Los
reduce non-t
uss these ste
ionthe lo
to loss redu
set of strateg
ing monitori
ntation of
and data an
trategies and
detection, a
e losses in ea
bility to mak
ding through
replacement
thin the 13
dary meteri
me poverty and h
al
sses, Decem
technical los
eps in furthe
ss control d
uction activ
gies to guid
ing, tamper
the Resid
nalysis. The
d actions inc
automatic ne
ach feeder.
ke measurem
h: scheduled
t of old met
34 Red Zo
ng where in
higher than usua
mber 2010
sses, which h
er detail.
divisionwi
vities. The c
e its efforts
resistant ne
dential Auto
benefits tha
clude autom
et generation
ments on th
d checks and
ters at subst
ones
21
iden
ndicated; in
al criminal activit
have already
ith more tha
company ha
to reduce s
twork design
omated Me
at JPS expe
mated process
n and system
he system th
d re-certificat
tation transf
ntified island
nstallation o
ty is said to exist

begun
an 200
as also
system
ns and
etering
ects to
ses for
m loss
hat will
tion of
former
d-wide;
of total
t.
Confidential
43
metering on approximately 80 secondary circuits; and installation of new current
transformers and potential transformers at approximately 85 metering points island-wide.

Box 5.1: Residential Automated Metering Infrastructure
The Residential Automated Metering Infrastructure (RAMI) is a recent innovation by JPS
which installs a metering unit in a cabinet attached to the low voltage bushings of the
distribution transformer. The metering takes place within the cabinet and is remotely
displayed in the customers premises by way of a signal communicated from the electronic
meter to the display unit via a 110Volt plug outlet. Up to 24 customer meters are contained
within each cabinet. The customer, or other persons who would steal electricity, therefore
has no access to the low voltage circuit as all of the connections to customer locations are
within the cabinet which will disconnect if it is tampered with in any way. The facility can
offer the possibility of pre-payment arrangements similar to that used by cellular
telephones, help to conserve energy by allowing consumers to monitor their own energy
usage, and a way for JPS to provide information to customers on monthly bills,
disconnection dates, and advice and notification of outages.
Source: JPS

Thanks to the implementation of RAMI and other strategies, JPS has already achieved
reductions in system losses since the beginning of 2010, as shown in Figure 5.3 below.
Figure 5.3: Recent Trends in System Losses at JPS

Source: JPS

The Loss Control Division has set an overall target to reduce system losses by 5.2 percentage
points over the next five years. The Division expects that this can be achieved by a
combination of reduction in non-technical losses, increased sales, and reduction in outages.

23. 32%
23 .25%
23 .43%
23. 47%
2 3.63 %
23. 58%
2 3.46 %
22.9 4%
22. 75%
22.5 8%
22. 27%
22. 24%
21 .81%
20.50%
21.00%
21.50%
22.00%
22.50%
23.00%
23.50%
24.00%
Confidential
44
The Division expects to achieve this through energy recovery resulting from audits and a
reduction in net generation by anti-theft network construction. Further reduction will also be
achieved through increased energy sales resulting from a reduction of the SAIDI and SAIFI
indices, which will translate to more energy being sold to legitimate customers. Energy sales
may also increase through the addition of new large customers as the economy returns to a
growth path.
Achieving further loss reduction
So far, JPS has concentrated the major part of its efforts to reduce system losses on the
reduction of non-technical lossesthis makes sense, since non-technical losses represent
more than half of total losses. However, there is also scope for reducing technical losses in
Jamaica.
For example, JPS could reduce technical losses by adding voltage regulators for feeders,
upgrading high voltage distribution lines from 12kV to 24kV, and possibly by
interconnecting different feeders. The Government could also do the following in order to
reduce non-technical losses (and therefore related electricity costs to consumers) in Jamaica:
Increase the legislative penalties for theft of electricity
Allow JPS to charge penalties for meter tampering and breaking meter seals
Implement a name and shame programme to publicize the names of individuals
and companies found to be stealing electricity, such as the programme implemented
for helping to reduce tax evasion
Formalize procedures allowing JPS to back-bill for stolen electricity, and to charge
interest to customers for late or non-payments
Work further on the Community Renewal Programme (CRP),
22
to guide the design
and implementation of violence reduction and community development projects in
100 of the most vulnerable areas across the country.
Government could also assist in reducing technical losses in Jamaica by educating the public
at all levels about the need for, and the national economic benefits to be derived from,
energy conservation and efficiency.
5.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity
In this section we estimate how a reduction in net electricity losses would impact the cost of
electricity to customers. We first examine the relationship between electricity losses and
tariffs, and then estimate by how much electricity tariffs could decrease as a result of a
reduction in system losses of 5 percentage points (from 17.5 percent to 12.5 percent). We
first examine the effect of reducing system losses on current tariffs, then on projected tariffs
once LNG is used as a main fuel for generating electricity (that is, assuming a reduction in
tariffs of US$0.10 per kWh, as estimated in section 3.2.2).
The sensitivity of system fuel costs to net electricity losses can be described as:

22
The CRP will seek to promote interventions aimed at building capacity for self-empowerment at the individual and
community levels in the targeted areas. Implementation of the programme, arose from the results of a study undertaken
by the PIOJs Growth Secretariat, established to bring focus to the recovery, growth, modernization and global
competitiveness of the Jamaican economy.
Confidential
45
Fucl cost poss troug = Fucl cost Ecot rotc (1 + Systcm Iosscs) (1)
Where the fuel cost is the actual fuel cost in US$ per MMBtu, the heat rate is the target heat
rate in kJ per kWh, and the system losses are the target system losses determined by the
OUR annually, expressed in percentage of net generationgiven that the OUR determines
target system losses annually based on actual performance and system losses.
The OUR sets fixed targets for heat rates and system losses when reviewing electricity tariffs
annually. The current target for system losses as of June 1, 2011 is 17.5 percentmeaning
that JPS is using a figure of 17.5 percent for system losses to calculate the fuel cost pass
through. We therefore use this figure as the baseline for calculating changes in the fuel cost
pass through. We also use the current heat rate target (set for June 2011) of 10,470 kJ per
kWh.
We calculate the sensitivity of electricity tariffs (including the non-fuel rate and the fuel cost
pass through) to system losses given the relationship described above, and where:
Iori =
Non ucl rotc I1 + u.76
Lx.Rutc
Currcnt
-Lx.Rutc
Bcsc
Lx.Rutc
Bcsc
] +Fucl cost poss troug(2)

Where Ex. Rate Current represents the current exchange rate (we use an exchange rate of
US$1:J$85.7), and Ex. Rate Base represent the base exchange rate provided in the latest
tariff determination of 2011 (US$1:J$86.5).
We use the non-fuel rates (in US$/kWh) provided in the latest tariff determination.
23
We
calculate the fuel cost pass-through as demonstrated in equation (1).
Impact on electricity costs given current tariffs
Figure 5.4 below shows the sensitivity of current residential, commercial and industrial
electricity tariffs (including the non-fuel rate and the fuel cost pass through) to electricity
losses, when considering the effect of system losses on the fuel cost pass-through only.
The figure shows that even with no electricity losses, the residential, commercial and
industrial tariffs would remain at about US$0.31, $0.35 and $0.28 per kWh respectivelythis
is because electricity generation still incurs a fuel cost, even if there are no system losses.
Given the current target for system losses (17.5 percent of net generation), the fuel cost pass
through is about US$0.24 per kWh. The figure shows that given this current target, the
electricity tariff for a residential customer with a monthly consumption of 100 kWh is
US$0.35 per kWh. The tariff for a commercial customer with a monthly consumption of
1,000 kWh per month is US$0.39 per kWh, and the tariff for an industrial customer with a
consumption of 500MWh per month and demand of 1,500 kVA per month is US$0.32 per
kWh.
Based on the sensitivity of the fuel cost pass-through to system losses shown in Figure 5.4,
we find that each percentage point reduction in system losses could reduce electricity tariffs
by 0.8 percent on average.
Reducing system losses by 5 percentage points could reduce the fuel cost pass through to
US$0.23 per kWh.

23
Office of Utilities Regulation (2011). Jamaica Public Service Company Limited Annual Tariff Adjustment 2011.
Confidential
46
This could lower the residential, commercial and industrial tariffs to US$0.34, $0.38 and
$0.31 per kWhthat is, a reduction of US$0.01 per kWh.
24

Figure 5.4: Impact of Net Electricity Losses on the Fuel Cost Pass Through
Component of Electricity Tariffs in Jamaica

Note: Calculation based on a heat rate target fixed at 10,470 kJ/kWh, base exchange rate of US$1:J$86.5, and
actual exchange rate of US$1:J$85.7.
Source: Office of Utilities Regulation (2011). Jamaica Public Service Company Limited Annual Tariff Adjustment
2011; JPS

Impact on electricity costs given projected tariffs
In section 3.2.2 we estimated that electricity generation costs would decrease from US$0.17
per kWh to US$0.10 per kWh as a result of commissioning the NGCC plant and converting
the existing combined cycle plant to LNG. This represents a reduction in average electricity
generation costs of 43 percent.
To calculate the reduction in tariffs resulting from a reduction of 5 percentage point in
system losses once this new capacity is commissioned, we multiply the average reduction in
tariffs from reducing system losses given current capacity (US$0.01 per kWh) by the average
reduction in generation costs from introducing the new natural gas plants on the system (43
percent). The result is US$0.006 per kWh.

24
This is estimated using the OUR formula examining the sensitivity of the fuel cost component of the tariffs to system
losses. This estimate does not account for other effects of decreasing system losses on tariffs. For example, a reduction in
system losses and particularly non-technical losses would result in an increase in electricity sales, as some people who
used to steal electricity would become customers and start paying for their own consumption. The increase in electricity
sales would mean that fuel costs for electricity generation would be spread across more customers. Over time, these
savings should translate into lower tariffs to consumers through the performance-based rate setting mechanism
contained in the JPS licence. Therefore, our estimate is conservative and likely underestimates the true potential
reduction in tariffs from reducing system losses.

0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
0.35
0.40
0.45
0% 5% 10% 15% 20% 25%
T
a
r
i
f
f
,

U
S
$
/
k
W
h
SystemLosses,%
Residentialtariff(R10,100kWh/month)
Commercialtariff(R20,1000kWh/month)
Industrialtariff(R50,500MWh/month;1,500kVA/month)
Currentsystem
losstarget:17.5%
Confidential
47
Summary
When examining the sensitivity of the fuel-cost pass through component of electricity tariffs
only, we find that each percentage point reduction in system losses can reduce electricity
tariffs by 0.8 percent on average. Reducing electricity losses by 5 percentage points
compared to the current target for system losses could reduce electricity tariffs by US$0.01
per kWh, given the current mix of electricity generation capacity on the system, and by
US$0.006 per kWh, given the mix of generation capacity planned for 2014.
The reduction in tariffs from reduced system losses should be proportionate across all
categories of customers.
Confidential
48
6 Option 4: Increasing the Use of Energy Efficient
Technologies
In this section we examine the potential for electricity customers to reduce their electricity
bills through an increased use of energy efficient technologies. We find that there are several
energy efficient technologies which would enable all types of customers to save electricity at
a lower cost than the current electricity tariffs, and that there is substantial scope for
customers to reduce their electricity bills by using these technologies.
Below we provide a brief description of this reform (6.1) and evidence of the benefits and
costs of implementing this reform (6.2). We then examine the impact of implementing this
reform on electricity prices in Jamaica (6.3).
6.1 Description of the Reform
Under this reform, electricity customers would increase their use of commercially viable
energy efficient technologies in order to reduce their electricity bills. By commercially viable
we mean technologies that could save electricity at a lower cost than the current applicable
electricity tariff.
6.2 Evidence of Benefits and Costs
Castalia recently conducted a detailed study of energy efficiency technologies and potential
uptake in Barbados, which the Government of Barbados is now implementing with
assistance from the Inter-American Development Bank. The study showed that several
energy efficient technologies were commercially viable in Barbados.
Table 6.1 below provides information from that study on commercially viable technologies
and estimated levelized cost of power savedthat is, how much it costs for each
technology to reduce one kWh of electricity consumption. We use a 15 percent discount
rate, to reflect the higher cost of capital for hotels, businesses and households compared to
utilities.
Using data on the cost of the technologies listed in Table 6.1, and comparing these costs
with current electricity tariffs in Jamaica, we can estimate the potential savings in electricity
bills for different electricity customer categories in Jamaica.


Confidential
49
Table 6.1: Energy Efficient Technologies and Estimated Costs


Below we estimate the potential savings for different customers given current electricity
tariffs, and then examine how these results would change when the NGCC plant is
commissioned and existing CC plant converted to LNG (using our estimate of reduction in
tariffs calculated in section 3.3). Box 6.1 provides some information regarding the
assumptions we make to estimate the potential net savings.

EE Technology Description
Levelized
Cost of
Power
Saved,
US$/kWh
Compact
Fluorescent
Lamps (CFLs)
Efficient light bulbs that replace conventional incandescent ones. More
efficient (more power converted to light, less to heat), more luminous for
any given installed capacity, and up to 10-20 times more long-lasting.
0.02
Power Monitors
Handheld devices that provide real-time information on energy consumption
and expenditure. Their use increases awareness on energy efficiency, and
achieves behavioral changes for a more efficient consumption of energy.
0.07
Magnetic Induction
Street Lighting
High-efficiency street lights that replace conventional ones and provide
higher efficiency, better luminosity, longer lifetime, and lower costs
0.31
Premium Efficiency
Motors
Efficient motors that replace conventional motors. Higher actual power for
the same electrical motor load and rated power.
0.11
Efficient Window
Air Conditioning
Systems
A/C systems for window installation that are more efficient than
conventional ones. Same or better performance, lower electrical load. 0.12
Variable Frequency
Drives
Add-on device that adjusts motor speed to make motor output meet actual
demand (no unnecessary extra output).
0.12
Efficient Split Air
Conditioning
Systems
A/C systems with indoor unit for air emission separate from outdoor
condensing unit, more efficient than conventional systems. One system
can cool multiple rooms. Same or better performance, lower electrical load.
0.31
T8 Fluorescent
Lamps with
Occupancy
Sensor
Efficient fluorescent lights for offices that replace older fluorescent lights,
achieving better lighting with lower energy consumption. Occupancy
sensors turn lights on or off based on detecting people in a room, reducing
on time.
0.25
Efficient Chillers
Industrial cooling devices with efficient compressors incorporating VFD
technology. They replace conventional chillers with traditional
compressors operating at constant speed.
0.15
T5 High Output
Fluorescent
Lamps
Lighting fixtures for indoor applications, mostly in the industrial sector. They
replace conventional metal halide bulbs. Brighter and higher quality light
with lower energy consumption.
0.32
LCD Computer
Monitors
Liquid Crystal Display monitors that replace conventional Cathode Ray Tube
(CRT) monitors for computers.
0.32
Efficient Residential
Refrigerators
Efficient fridges for homes that replace conventional ones. Lower power
draw, and better insulation.
0.34
Efficient Retail
Refrigerators
(Condensing
Unit)
Condensing units with more efficient cooling performance for commercial
refrigerators used in stores, supermarkets, and restaurants. Replacement is
limited to the condensing unit to contain costs.
0.53
Solar Water Heaters
Use solar radiation to heat water, and are composed of a storage tank, and a
solar collector (flat plate panels and evacuated glass tube collectors are the
two main types of solar collectors)
0.15-0.17
Confidential
50
Box 6.1: Assumptions for calculating potential net savings from using more
energy efficient technologies in Jamaica
The assumptions we make regarding electricity consumption in each customer category
are:
Residential customers: about 45 percent of a residential customers consumption is for
refrigeration, 21 percent for lighting, 10 percent for other appliances such as televisions,
and 24 percent for heating water
Commercial customers (small): about 30 percent of average consumption is for lighting,
12 percent for refrigeration, 50 percent for air conditioning, and 8 percent for other
appliances (we assume that half of this consumption for other appliances is for heating
water)
Industrial and large commercial customers: about 28 percent of consumption is for
motors, 10 percent for lighting, 19 percent for refrigeration, 15 percent for air
conditioning and 28 percent for other appliances (we assume that half of this
consumption for other appliances is for heating water, for large commercial customers
only)

Using these consumption breakdowns, we estimate how much electricity could be saved
by using relevant energy efficient technologies. Although energy efficient technologies
could be used in any sector, we did not consider application in a sector when it would be
negligible. For example, commercial companies could in some cases benefit from premium
efficiency motors, but these would only represent a small portion of overall energy use in
the sector, compared to the industrial sector where energy from motors is a significant
portion of energy use. We find that electricity consumption could be reduced by 26
percent in the residential sector, 23 percent in the commercial sector, and 12 percent for
large commercial customers and 12 percent for industrial customers over a 20 year period.
Next, we calculate the weighted average cost of saving each kWh using energy efficient
technologies. We do this by multiplying the savings cost of each technology by its share in
total potential consumption reduction. We derive two different estimates:
For residential and small commercial customers, we calculate the weighted average
savings cost given the use of a small (2kW) solar water heater. The resulting average
savings cost is US$0.21 per kWh
For large commercial and industrial customers, we calculate the weighted average
savings cost given the installation of a 70kW solar water heater. The resulting weighted
average savings cost is US$0.18 per kWh.
Source: Castalia; A. Binger (August 2010). Energy Efficiency Potential in Jamaica: Challenges,
Opportunities and Strategies for ImplementationReport to the Economic Commission for
Latin America and the Caribbean, and Deutsche Gesellschaft fr Internationale
Zusammenarbeit (GIZ); Demand Side Energy Consultants Inc. (1998). JPSCo. Large
Commercial retrofit ProgrammeFinal Summary Report

Table 6.2 shows the potential net savings that an average customer in each type of category
could make on electricity bills each year, as a result of using more energy efficient
technologies (based on the assumptions listed in Box 6.1). By net savings we mean the
savings resulting from spending less money on electricity bills as a result of a lower
consumption in electricity, minus the average cost of saving each kWh.
Confidential
51
Table 6.2: Potential Net Financial Savings for Different Customer Classes from
Energy Efficient TechnologiesCurrent Tariff Levels

*2008 figures from OUR (2010). Electricity Peak and Energy Demand Forecast 2010-2030; **Based on non-
fuel rates provided in OUR (2011). JPSCo Ltd Annual Tariff Adjustment 2011, adjusted using April 2011 fuel
prices and exchange rate adjustment, and calculated for each customer category using 2008 average annual
consumption figures; ***Based on Castalia's assumptions for end-use consumption in each sector shown in
Box 6.1, and Castalias estimates for potential reduction in electricity consumption from increased use of energy
efficiency technologies; ****Based on an weighted average cost of energy efficient technologies of US$0.24 per
kWh saved
Note: Electricity tariffs are calculated using the non-fuel charges indicated in the latest tariff review for JPS, as
well as data on fuel and IPP charges, and exchange rate adjustment from JPS for March 2011.
These estimations include the potential for installing small solar water heaters in the residential sector
and small commercial sector, and 50kW heaters in the large commercial sector.

The table above shows that by increasing their use of energy efficient technologies,
residential customers could reduce their annual consumption of electricity by about 26
percent, and save about US$86 per year on electricity bills. Small commercial customers
could reduce their consumption by 23 percent and save US$446 per year on electricity bills.
Large commercial customers could on average save more than US$8,000 on their electricity
bills each year, and industrial customers could save more than US$100,000 each year on
average.
Table 6.3 below shows how much customers could potentially save by using energy efficient
technologies once the new medium speed diesel, hydropower and NGCC plants are
commissioned, and the combined cycle plant is converted to natural gas.
25



25
To estimate the reduction in current electricity tariffs, we estimate the average reduction in electricity generation costs
from introducing the West Kingston Power plant, hydropower and NGCC plants on the system, and converting the
combined cycle plant to natural gas, compared to the average cost of electricity generation using the current system
(which does not yet include the medium speed diesel plant and Maggotty plant). We find that the average reduction in
electricity tariffs would be about US$0.10 per kWh, assuming a LRMC of US$0.12 per kWh for the new hydropower
plant at Maggotty, and a LRMC of US$0.22 per kWh for the new medium speed diesel plant.
Category of
customer
Average annual
consumption*
Current tariff**
Typical annual
electricity bill
Potential
reduction in
electricity
consumption***
Potential net
savings****
kWh/year US$/kWh US$/year % per year US$/year
Residential 1,971 0.37 739 26% 86
Commercial (small) 10,746 0.39 4,235 23% 446
Commercial (large) 489,000 0.32 156,639 12% 8,255
Industrial 6,301,770 0.32 2,008,220 12% 105,131
Confidential
52
Table 6.3: Potential Net Financial Savings for Different Customer ClassesProjected
Tariff Levels

*2008 figures from OUR (2010). Electricity Peak and Energy Demand Forecast 2010-2030; **Based on non-
fuel rates provided in OUR (2011). JPSCo Ltd Annual Tariff Adjustment 2011, adjusted using April 2011 fuel
prices and exchange rate adjustment, and calculated for each customer category using 2008 average annual
consumption figures; ***Based on Castalia's assumptions for end-use consumption in each sector shown in
Box 6.1, and Castalias estimates for potential reduction in electricity consumption from increased use of energy
efficiency technologies; ****Based on an weighted average cost of energy efficient technologies of US$0.24 per
kWh saved

6.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity to Consumers
Increasing the use of energy efficient technologies amongst end-users in Jamaica would not
have a direct impact on electricity tariffs. However, by using these technologies consumers
can reduce the quantity of electricity they use, thereby reducing their electricity bills.
Consumption curtailment provides an effective way for consumers to hedge against volatility
in electricity prices.
We find that by using energy efficient technologies, typical residential, commercial and large
customers could achieve net savings equivalent to 16 percent, 14 percent and 8 percent of
their current electricity bills respectively, on average. As shown in Table 6.4 below,
customers would still benefit from savings equivalent to between 2 and 6 percent of their
current electricity bills even if electricity tariffs decreased by US$0.10 per kWh (as a result of
using a cheaper fuel for generating electricity).
Category of
customer
Average annual
consumption*
Projected tariff**
Typical annual
electricity bill
Potential
reduction in
electricity
consumption***
Potential net
savings
kWh/year US$/kWh US$/year % per year US$/year
Residential 1,971 0.27 541 26% 33
Commercial (small) 10,746 0.29 3,156 23% 203
Commercial (large) 489,000 0.22 107,533 12% 2,347
Industrial 6,301,770 0.22 1,375,383 12% 29,000
Confidential
53
Table 6.4: Potential Net Saving in Electricity Bills from Increased Use of Energy
Efficient Technologies



Category of
customer
Typical annual
electricity bill
Potential net
savings
Potential net
savings compared
to current
electricity bill
US$/year US$/year %
With current tariff
Residential 541 86 16%
Commercial (small) 3,156 446 14%
Commercial (large) 107,533 8,255 8%
Industrial 1,375,383 105,131 8%
With projected tariff (when NGCC plant comes in)
Residential 541 33 6%
Commercial (small) 3,156 203 6%
Commercial (large) 107,533 2,347 2%
Industrial 1,375,383 29,000 2%
Confidential
54
Box 6.2: How can the Government help achieve these savings?
The Government of Jamaica is already working on promoting energy efficiency in Jamaica:
the Ministry of Energy and Mining recently issued a National Energy Conservation and
Efficiency Policy for Jamaica for 2010-2030, which outlines the strategy that the
Government intends to focus on. In addition, the Government is investing in the
implementation of programmes throughout the country, including through loans from the
Inter-American Development Bank and the World Bank. Given the analysis shown in this
section, there are several energy efficient technologies in Jamaica that can help reduce
electricity costs to consumers in Jamaica. Specific things that the Government could do to
save energy, in addition to what is already being done, are the following:
Increase uptake of efficient technologies other than lighting. The Government is
already promoting the use of efficient lighting. However, as shown in Table 6.1, there
are many other technologies that would enable customers in the residential,
commercial, and industrial sectors to reduce their electricity bills. The government
could increase uptake of these technologies by: (i) informing the public about the costs
and benefits of key energy-saving technologies; (ii) increasing the availability of these
technologies in Jamaica, including through import of equipment that meets adequate
performance standards; (iii) helping to finance their implementation
Procure an ESCO for retrofitting public buildings, and for marketing to large
consumers. ESCOs are companies that (i) develop, finance, and implement energy
efficiency projects on a turnkey basis; (ii) guarantee a contracted amount of savings to
clients, assuming the risk for these savings actual realization; and (iii) earn returns over
time from the financial savings the projects create. This type of model may be helpful
to overcome any lack of finance or incentives for implementing energy efficient
programme within the public sector. The Government could increase the attractiveness
of an ESCO deal for retrofitting public buildings by letting the selected ESCO do a
trade show to market its services to large energy consumers in the industrial and
commercial sectors
Negotiate an arrangement for retrofitting street lights. The Government could
structure a deal for using efficient technologies for street lighting, such as magnetic
induction lights, or (if cost-effective) LED lights
Implement a standard and labeling programme for appliances. This could be an
effective way of informing consumers about the quality and performance of appliances.
The Government has already started working on a labeling programme, but recognized
the need to expand it, to ensure that it is effective. Developing standards for key
appliances could serve to prepare better labeling, and determine eligibility for other
fiscal or customs incentives
Restrict import of non-efficient equipment, or provide a preferential customs
regime for energy efficient equipment. This would have a direct impact on the type
of technologies used in Jamaica. Standards could be used to ensure that sub-standard
energy efficient equipment is not eligible for preferential customs treatment, or is
banned from imports
Review the building code to mandate energy efficiency measures, solar water
heaters, and efficient design in new buildings. This mandate would affect builders
much the same way that any other building rule does. Energy standards for buildings
provide a degree of control over building design, and encourage energy conscious
design in building. Inefficiencies could be reduced over time if the building code
required energy efficient design and materials in new buildings and major renovations.
Many industrialized countries have included such requirements in their buildings codes.
Solar water heaters could be mandated in new buildings so that when a water heater is
installed it could be a solar water heater, and one compliant with a Caribbean
certification such as one used in Jamaica, Barbados, or Saint Lucia.
Confidential
55
7 Option 5: Forcing Vertical and Horizontal
Disaggregation of the Electricity Sector
Some stakeholders in Jamaica have suggested that the Jamaican electricity sector should be
unbundled so as to increase competition in electricity generation and retailing. The rationale
behind this suggestion is that increased competition creates an incentive for firms to reduce
their costs and prices, thereby leading to an overall reduction in electricity prices. These
effects have been demonstrated in wholesale competition and retail markets following
successful reforms in many countries, such as the United Kingdom, United States and
Australia.
In this section we examine the option of restructuring the electricity sector by forcing a
vertical and horizontal disaggregation of the utility so as to introduce competition in
electricity generation and retailing.
We find that such reform would be unlikely to result in any decrease of electricity prices, but
would rather lead to a significant increase in electricity prices (increase of US$0.11 per kWh
if competition was introduced amongst existing generation capacity, and of US$0.12 per
kWh if competition was introduced after the NGCC plant is commissioned and the CC
plant is converted to LNG). This increase arises mostly as a result of the lack of potential for
competition in electricity generation for a system of the size of Jamaicas. In addition, a
sector disaggregation would likely involve additional costs in electricity distribution and
retail, due to the duplication of overhead costs, in addition to transaction and restructuring
costs.
In this section we describe what Jamaicas electricity sector would look like if it was vertically
and horizontally disaggregated (7.1). We then evaluate the potential benefits and costs arising
from implementing this reform, and estimate the impact of this reform on electricity prices
in Jamaica (7.2).
7.1 Description of the Reform
This reform would involve restructuring the sector from a single buyer model (under which
JPS ensures the generation, transmission and distribution of electricity, and enters into
power purchase agreements with independent power producers), to a retail competition
model. Under a retail competition model, the generation, transmission and distribution of
electricity are unbundled, and firms trade electricity in a wholesale power market through
bilateral contracts and a spot market, and various firms can compete in the supply and sale
of power to consumers.
Below we describe what the Jamaican electricity sector would look like under a retail
competition model. We assume that electricity would be traded in an energy only market
(such as the markets developed in New Zealand, the Philippines, and Singapore). Under an
energy only market, generators submit price and quantity (supply) offers at regular intervals
to meet instantaneous demand. Energy only markets are driven by the spot price of
electricity.
Given the current size of the system and the system expansion planned by the OUR, we
anticipate that if the Jamaican electricity sector was to be disaggregated, it would likely
comprise:
Confidential
56
At most five or six competitors in generation: These may include the three
existing Independent Power Producers (Wigton Windfarm Ltd., JEP including
West Kingston Power, and JPPC), and one firm operating the new LNG plant
(JPS). JPSs current generation assets could be separated to create two generation
companies
One transmission company: Electricity transmission is a natural monopoly
meaning that one firm can supply the entire market at a lower cost than multiple
firms serving the marketand therefore would remain as a single company
One system operator: The transmission grid through which electricity flows
would also need to be physically managed to ensure that operating constraints are
satisfied, therefore the market would also need a system operator, who would be
responsible for the physical operation of the grid, and its quality and security of
supply. The system operator would coordinate the actions of grid-connected
parties by contracting with generators to supply capacity, or purchasers to allow
short-notice interruption of supply, to ensure that an adequate voltage and
frequency of electricity is maintained
One market operator: Under a disaggregated model, generators and purchasers
would trade electricity in a spot wholesale market, which could comprise real-time
electricity trading, and bilateral trading. The market operator would be responsible
for administrating the market, aggregating the information from suppliers and
purchasers of electricity to determine the price at which proposed supply meets
demand at least cost, while satisfying technical constraints relating to grid
availability and security
Three distribution companies: the network could be separated to allow three
companies to operate in different areasfor example, Distribution Company A
could operate the distribution network located in the Western side of the country,
Distribution Company B in the North and North-East, Distribution Company C
in the South and South-East. We assume that each of these companies would be
responsible for distributing electricity in their respective areas, as well as retailing
electricity, although some companies may also be able to provide retailing services
to customers in other distributed areas through competing carriage competition.
Electricity retailing would involve entering contracts with the transmission and
distribution companies, buying power on the wholesale market, to sell electricity
to individual consumers through contracts. Because wholesale electricity markets
can be volatile, retailers may also wish to enter into long-term contracts with
generators, in order to hedge their energy purchases and mitigate the effect of
price spikes (as discussed in Box 7.1 below).
Figure 7.1 below illustrates the possible location and separation of generation, transmission
and distribution assets under a sector disaggregation.

Figu
Disa


ure 7.1: Poss
aggregation
sible Struct
n
ture of the E
Confidentia
57
Electricity S
al
Sector undeer Vertical aand Horizoontal

Confidential
58
Box 7.1: Price Spikes in Wholesale Electricity Markets
Electricity prices in wholesale markets can vary extensively from day to day and hour to hour,
depending on electricity demand, and the short-term availability of supply. Experience in
existing wholesale electricity markets suggests that large spikes in the price of electricity can
occur frequently. To protect themselves and their customers from such variations in
wholesale price of electricity, electricity retailers often enter into long-term, fixed-price
contracts with electricity generators. Regulators may also decide to cap wholesale electricity
prices or offers, to limit the extent to which prices can rise.
The figure below shows price spikes that occurred in Hayward, New Zealand between
January and May 2003, in NZ$ per MWh. The figure shows that electricity prices rose to
more than NZ$1,000 per MWhabout US$0.78 per kWhthree times during that period.
The second figure below shows the volatility of nation-wide wholesale electricity prices in
New Zealand over the past seven years.
Spot Electricity Prices in Hayward, New Zealand, January-May 2003

New Zealand Electricity Price Index, 2003-2011 (7-day Demand-Weighted Rolling
Average, NZ$/MWh)
Source: Norske Skog Tasman Limited (October 2007). Comments on the Review of Reserve Energy Policy
Consultation Paper; New Zealand Electricity Authority (January 2011). Wholesale Electricity Prices: December
2010.

Confidential
59

7.2 Evidence of Benefits and Costs
Below we examine whether the introduction of competition in the electricity sector in
Jamaica would likely result in positive effects on electricity costs. We do this by reviewing
experience with wholesale electricity market reforms in island countries, and by analyzing
how restructuring the Jamaican electricity sector would affect prices. We then examine the
costs that would likely arise as a result of implementing this reform. We conclude that
introducing competition in the electricity sector would be likely to result in an increase in
electricity prices in Jamaica, due to the limited size of the market.
7.2.1 Experience with Wholesale and Retail Competition in Island Countries
Economic theory suggests that competition encourages efficiency and leads to lower prices
compared to markets with no competition. Under competition, commercial firms strive to
capture a greater share of a market by lowering their costs and prices and/or developing new
products, services and technologies. In practice, this theory has proven correct across many
countries and sectors, including the electricity sector. Indeed, since the 1980s several
countries have reformed their electricity sector to enable wholesale and retail competition,
and have benefited from improvements in efficiency and lower pricesexamples include the
United Kingdom, the United States (despite problems in California), and Australia.
However, most of these countries have large power systems which can accommodate
numerous competitive generators and retailers, while retaining sufficient economies of scale.
In this section we review experience with electricity wholesale and retail competition in
smaller countries, including New Zealand, the Philippines, and Dominican Republic, in order
to identify potential issues that may arise if such reform was implemented in Jamaica.
Experience with wholesale and retail competition in small and island countries has shown
mixed results. Attempts to introduce competition have often resulted in oligopolies, where a
few participants dominate a large share of the market and are able to set prices higher than in
perfectly competitive markets. As a result, allegations of anti-competitive conduct and abuse
of market power are seen as a recurrent problem in small-sized, unbundled electricity
markets. For example:
In New Zealandsince the creation of a wholesale electricity market (New
Zealand Electricity Market), electricity generation in New Zealand has been
dominated by five companies, who supply more than 90 percent of total
electricity.
26
These five companies also serve more than 90 percent of the retailing
market.
27
Problems with perceived anti-competitive behavior in the generation
and retailing market are raised regularly in New Zealand. For example Genesis
Energy, one of the largest generators and retailers in New Zealand, is currently
being investigated by the Electricity Authority (the entity responsible for the
efficient operation of the market), with regards to a spike in wholesale electricity
prices (from about US$80 per MWh to more than US$15,700 per MWh) which
occurred on April 26, 2011. The Authority has led numerous other anti-
competitive investigations over the past few yearsand some studies have shown

26
New Zealand Ministry of Economic Development (2006). http://www.med.govt.nz/templates/Page____13481.aspx
27
New Zealand Electricity Commission (2010). About the New Zealand Electricity Sector.
Confidential
60
that electricity prices in New Zealand are on average higher than they would be in
a perfectly competitive market.
28

In the Philippinesupon the establishment of the Wholesale Electricity Spot
Market in 2006, two companies (National Power Corporation and PSALM) held
nearly 90 percent of the countrys supply of electricity, and one company
accounted for 70 percent of demand in one area (Luzon). Since the establishment
of the market, frequent spikes in the price of electricity have been a recurring
problem, and the Energy Regulatory Commission has had to investigate several
allegations of market abuse and anti-competitive behavior by generators
(including, for example, an alleged price manipulation in February 2010 that
caused spikes in the price of electricity
29
)
30

In Dominican Republicthe vertically integrated electricity utility was
unbundled in 1997, and in 2000 the Government established an open generation
market under which distributors and generators could trade electricity. By 2008
there were more than a dozen generators, a transmission company and three
regional distribution companies operating in the sector (although the Government
of Dominican Republic has purchased two of these distribution companies
back)however, the lack of competition in electricity generation was identified as
a problem in the sector, contributing to high electricity tariffs.
31

Overall, experience with wholesale electricity markets in these countries suggests that sector
disaggregation can only lead to price reductions if the power system is large enough to attract
a sufficient level of competition. Given that Jamaicas power system is significantly smaller
than the systems in these countries, with an installed capacity ten times smaller than that in
New Zealand, and about twenty times smaller than that in the Philippines, as shown in Table
7.1 below, there is good reason to believe that unbundling the Jamaican electricity sector
would not result in sufficient competition to reduce electricity prices. In the following sub-
section we examine whether this would really be the case, by estimating average wholesale
electricity costs in Jamaica under a disaggregated sector structure with unregulated wholesale
market pricing.

28
Murray, K. (August 2004). Analysis of the State of Competition and Investment and Entry Barriers to New Zealands Wholesale and
Retail Electricity Markets. Report prepared for the Electricity Commission.
29
Corsino, N. (August 2010). Energy Regulatory Commission Still to Probe alleged WESM Price Spikes. GMA News, 06 August
2010. http://www.gmanews.tv/story/192918/erc-still-to-probe-alleged-wesm-price-spikes
30
Pascual, M. D. (February 2011). Why Competition in WESM Causes Costly Kuryente. http://www.manilatimes.net/sunday-
times/special-report/why-competition-in-wesm-causes-costly-%E2%80%98kuryente%E2%80%99/
31
The World Bank (April 2008). Project Appraisal Document on a Proposed Loan to the Dominican Republic for an Electricity
Distribution Rehabilitation Project.
Confidential
61
Table 7.1: Size of Electricity Markets
Country
Population,
million
Total installed
capacity, MW
Peak Demand,
MW
Ratio to Peak
Demand in
Jamaica
New Zealand (2009) 4.3 9,100 6,500 10.5
Philippines (2010) 91.9 15,881 10,231 16.5
Dominican Republic (2009) 10.1 3,000 1,800 2.9
Jamaica* (2010) 2.7 830 620 -

Sources: World Bank Development Indicators; JPS; New Zealand Electricity Commission (2009). About the
New Zealand Electricity Sector; Office of Utilities Regulation (2010). Generation Expansion Plan.; Asirit, J.
P. M. (March 2011). Investment Opportunities in the Philippines Energy Sector. Presentation at the PPP
Conference in Makati Shangri-La Hotel, March 2, 2011; ADIE (June 2010). The Electricity Sector in the
Dominican Republic.

7.2.2 Estimation of Wholesale Electricity Prices in Jamaica with a Disaggregated
Sector Structure
In this section we examine the impact of disaggregating the Jamaican electricity sector on
wholesale electricity prices. Electricity generation accounts for about 77 percent of current
electricity rates.
32
The remaining 20 percent of the costs is determined by transmission and
distribution (about 18 percent), and customer service and administration costs (about 5
percent). Disaggregating the electricity sector could not affect transmission and distribution
costs, because the transmission and distribution of electricity is a natural monopolyand
therefore competition could not be introduced in the sector. Therefore, about 18 percent of
the cost of electricity cannot be affected by the sector disaggregation.
We therefore examine the potential for reducing electricity generation costs by
disaggregating the electricity sector in Jamaica. We estimate and compare the average variable
cost of electricity generation under the current market structure (a single buyer model), and
under a wholesale competition structure.
For both structures, we assume that the market operates under a marginal cost structure
where generators with units available for dispatch are put in order of merit based on their
variable cost (the variable cost includes fuel cost, and variable operating and maintenance
cost). This enables us to extract the difference in electricity costs to consumers simply as a
result of changing the structure of the market.
We estimate variable generation costs for both types of market structures under two
scenarios:
1. With current generation assetsthat is, we estimate average variable costs
under the current framework, as well as under a wholesale competitive model,
given current demand and existing generation assets (assuming that the Maggotty
hydropower plant and West Kingston Power plant are already commissioned)

32
JPS (2011)
Confidential
62
2. With generation assets planned for 2014given the OUR and JPSs planned
changes in generation capacity (that is, the addition of a 360MW LNG plant to
the system, the conversion of the Bogue plant to LNG, and assuming that JPS no
longer uses oil-fired steam plants for regular dispatch).
For both scenarios we use the typical weekday load profile for Jamaicas power system in
2009, provided in the OUR Generation Expansion Plan 2010.
33
In other words, we assume that
there is no growth in demand, so that electricity demand today and in 2014 are the same as
that in 2009. This enables us to compare both scenarios more easily, as we can examine
changes in prices resulting strictly from changing the type of generation assets being used.
For both scenarios and market structures we use data on current and planned capacity
provided in the OUR Generation Expansion Plan 2010.
34

Our estimates confirm that Jamaicas electricity system is too small to accommodate a
sufficient number of generators on the market to reduce electricity prices. Wholesale
electricity prices would be much higher under a wholesale competition structure, because
generators would be able to price their electricity at a cost higher than their actual marginal
cost. We find that wholesale electricity prices would increase by an average of US$0.08 per
kWh if competition was introduced among the various plants existing on the system, as well
as the Maggotty hydropower plant and the new medium speed diesel plant. Wholesale prices
would increase by US$0.06 per kWh under a competition structure compared to a single
buyer structure, if the 360MW natural gas plant was commissioned and the oil-fired steam
plant was decommissioned. Below we outline how we estimated these prices under each
scenario.
Scenario 1Electricity generation costs given the current mix of generation assets
Table 7.2 below lists the plants currently installed and being operated by JPS and IPPs in
Jamaica (ordered in terms of variable cost per unit of generation, from the cheapest to the
most expensive). For each plant, the table indicates effective capacity, type and current price
of fuel used, and heat rate. The table also shows the fuel cost per kWh (which is calculated,
for each plant, as the heat rate in MMBtu per kWh times the fuel price in US$ per MMBtu)
and variable O&M cost of each plantadding these together gives total short-run marginal
costs, in US$ per kWh.

33
Office of Utilities Regulation (2010). Generation Expansion Plan 2010. Figure 3.5-2 Typical Weekday Load Profile for
Jamaicas Power System. p.32.
34
Office of Utilities Regulation (2010). Generation Expansion Plan 2010. Table 6.7-1Capabilities and Performance
Characteristics of the Existing Thermal Generating Units, p.54. Table 9.4.1-1Demand/Capacity Requirements for
2010 to 2019 (Natural Gas Strategy), p/70.
Confidential
63
Table 7.2: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants on the System (March 2011 Fuel Prices)

Note: For the JPPC plant, we assume same HFO prices as those for Hunts Bay (given location proximity).
For JEP and West Kingston Power, we assume same HFO prices as for Old Harbour
Source: OUR (2010), Generation Expansion Plan 2010; JPS

Using the typical weekday load profile provided by the OUR, and assuming dispatching
based on merit order of variable costs, we determine the typical daily dispatching profile of
the systemthis is shown in Figure 7.2 below.

Effective
capacity
Average
heat rate
Current
fuel
price**
Variable
O&M
cost
Fuel cost
Short-run
marginal
cost
MW MMBtu/kWh US$/MMBtu US$/kWh US$/kWh US$/kWh
Wigton Wind farm n/a 10.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
Munro Wind farm n/a 0.9 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
JPS Hydropower Hydropower n/a 13.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
JPS Maggotty Hydropower n/a 2.8 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
JPPC Slow Speed Diesel HFO 54.6 0.0077 16.90 0.010 0.13 0.14
JEP Medium Speed Diesel HFO 111.9 0.0078 17.53 0.020 0.14 0.16
West Kingston Power Medium Speed Diesel HFO 58.5 0.0078 17.53 0.020 0.14 0.16
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.0093 16.90 0.008 0.16 0.16
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.0095 16.90 0.008 0.16 0.17
Old Harbour Oil Fired Steam HFO 61.8 0.0122 16.70 0.007 0.20 0.21
Old Harbour Oil Fired Steam HFO 65.1 0.0123 16.70 0.007 0.21 0.21
Hunts Bay Oil Fired Steam HFO 65.1 0.0124 16.79 0.007 0.21 0.21
Old Harbour Oil Fired Steam HFO 57 0.0126 16.70 0.007 0.21 0.22
Bogue Combined Cycle ADO 111 0.0089 23.88 0.006 0.21 0.22
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.0129 23.75 0.005 0.31 0.31
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.0165 23.75 0.005 0.39 0.40
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.0169 23.75 0.005 0.40 0.41
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.0170 23.75 0.005 0.40 0.41
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 32.1 0.0179 23.75 0.005 0.43 0.43
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0180 23.75 0.005 0.43 0.43
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0180 23.75 0.005 0.43 0.43
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0212 23.75 0.005 0.50 0.51
Location/IPP name Type of plant
Type of
fossil fuel
used*
* HFO = Heavy Fuel Oil, ADO = Automotive Diesel Oil
** Based on March 2011 prices of fuel delivered at each plant.
Confidential
64
Figure 7.2: Dispatching Profile for Typical Week Day

Note: Figures based on 2009 load profile provided in the OUR Generation Expansion Plan 2010, and March
2011 fuel prices provided by JPS
For simplicity, this figure shows the average short-run marginal cost of all oil-fired steam plants
together . Some of the oil-fired steam units are in fact more expensive than the combined cycle
planttherefore, in reality these particular units should be dispatched after the combined cycle plant.

The above figure shows that the wind, hydropower, JPPC, JEP, West Kingston Power, slow
speed diesel and oil-fired steam plants are always operating to meet electricity demand. The
combined cycle is also operating between 11am and 6:30pm, and between 7.30pm and
11:30pm to meet peak demand.
Using this information, we calculate the variable cost of the system throughout the day
under the two different market structures. For the single buyer model (which is the current
market structure), we use the same methodology and figures as shown in section 3.2.2.
With a wholesale competition market structure, generators send out bids or offers on the
market at regular intervals (say every 30 minutes). Each bid defines the minimum price that
the generator would accept to run the plant in the given half hour, and these bids serve as
the guide for the dispatch. In a system where there are enough competitors so that each
generator assumes that it will not be determining the marginal plant, then the optimal bid for
each generator is the true marginal cost.
35
However, with only eight different types of plants
on the system, generators are able to maximize profit by bidding just below the cost of the
plant on the margin. Every half hour, generators will receive the short-run marginal cost
price for the total quantity of energy supplied in that half hour. In other words, all generators
receive the same price for the electricity they supply.
For example, at 10:00 p.m. the plant on the margin is the combined cycle plant, which
generates at a SRMC of US$0.22 per kWh. Therefore the generator operating the oil-fired
steam plant can bid at, say US$0.21 per kWh, in order to undercut the combined cycle plant,

35
Hogan, W. (1998). Competitive Electricity Market Design: A Wholesale Primer. Center for Business and Government, John F.
Kennedy School of Government. Harvard University. p. 5.

0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
M
W
Timeoftheday
CombinedCycle
OilFiredSteam
SlowSpeedDiesel
JEP
WestKingstonPower
JPPC
Wind
Hydro
US$0.14/kWh
US$0.16/kWh
US$0.17/kWh
US$0.22/kWh
US$0.21/kWh(average)
US$0.16/kWh
Confidential
65
while extracting as much profit as possible. During peak hours, the combined cycle plant
must be used. The next cheapest plant available is a combustion turbine with a SRMC of
US$0.31 per kWh (as shown in Table 7.2), so the operator of the combined cycle plant is
able to bid at US$0.30 per kWh.
On this basis, we assume that:
When the combined cycle plant is on the margin, the oil-fired steam generator
bids at US$0.01 per kWh lower than the cost of the combined cycle plantthat
is, US$0.21 per kWh, and all generators (except the combined cycle and
combustion turbine generators, who do not generate electricity) are paid that price
for each unit of electricity they generate
During times of peak demand, the combined cycle generator bids for US$0.30 per
kWh, and all generators are paid US$0.30 for each kWh they generate.
The price of wholesale electricity under each structure is shown in Figure 7.3 below, for 30
minute intervals in a typical weekday. The figure shows that the wholesale price of electricity
would be on average about twice as high under a competitive market than under a single
buyer market structure (with an average price of US$0.26 per kWh compared to US$0.17 per
kWh).
Figure 7.3: Wholesale Electricity Prices under Single Buyer (Current System) and
Wholesale Competitive Power Markets, US$/kWh


To estimate the changes in electricity prices to consumers arising from introducing
competition in the electricity market, we use the same methodology as in section 3.2.2that
is:
RcJuction in priccs =
RcJuction in gcncrotion costs
Elcctricity solJ

0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
0.35
1
2
.
3
0

a
m
1
.
0
0

a
m
1
.
3
0

a
m
2
.
0
0

a
m
2
.
3
0

a
m
3
.
0
0

a
m
3
.
3
0

a
m
4
.
0
0

a
m
4
.
3
0

a
m
5
.
0
0

a
m
5
.
3
0

a
m
6
.
0
0

a
m
6
.
3
0

a
m
7
.
0
0

a
m
7
.
3
0

a
m
8
.
0
0

a
m
8
.
3
0

a
m
9
.
0
0

a
m
9
.
3
0

a
m
1
0
.
0
0

a
m
1
0
.
3
0

a
m
1
1
.
0
0

a
m
1
1
.
3
0

a
m
1
2
.
0
0

p
m
1
2
.
3
0

p
m
1
.
0
0

p
m
1
.
3
0

p
m
2
.
0
0

p
m
2
.
3
0

p
m
3
.
0
0

p
m
3
.
3
0

p
m
4
.
0
0

p
m
4
.
3
0

p
m
5
.
0
0

p
m
5
.
3
0

a
m
6
.
0
0

p
m
6
.
3
0

p
m
7
.
0
0

p
m
7
.
3
0

p
m
8
.
0
0

p
m
8
.
3
0

p
m
9
.
0
0

p
m
9
.
3
0

p
m
1
0
.
0
0

p
m
1
0
.
3
0

p
m
1
1
.
0
0

p
m
1
1
.
3
0

p
m
1
2
.
0
0

a
m
U
S
$
/
k
W
h
Timeoftheday
Wholesalepricewithsinglebuyerstructure Average,US$/kWh Wholesalepricewithwholesalecompetitionstructure
Confidential
66
where reduction in generation costs is the annual reduction in the cost of generating
electricity resulting from changing the market structure to a competitive market, in US$. To
calculate the reduction in generation costs, we:
1. Multiply the average cost of generation of the system with the competitive market
structure (US$0.26 per kWh) by the electricity generated in 2010
2. Multiply the cost of generation with the current (single buyer) market structure
(US$0.17 per kWh) by electricity generated in 2010
3. Take the difference between 1 and 2 above.
Assuming that total electricity generation is 4,137 GWh and electricity sold is 3,235 GWh,
we find that electricity tariffs would increase by about US$0.11 per kWh under a wholesale
competition structure.
Scenario 2Electricity generation costs with new generation mix
In this section we examine the wholesale price of electricity under the single-buyer market
structure and wholesale competition market structure, given the generation capacity planned
for the year 2014.
Table 7.3 below provides information on the capacity, efficiency and variable cost for each
unit of capacity planned for 2014. The table shows the SMRC of the NGCC plant and
converted combined cycle planthowever, we use the Long-Run Marginal Cost of
generation for these plants when examining generation costs instead, as the owner of this
plant will need to recoup the capital cost.
Confidential
67
Table 7.3: Short-Run Marginal Cost of Plants on the System in 2014 (Based on
Average Projected Fuel Prices for the Period 2010-2029)

Source: OUR (2010), Generation Expansion Plan 2010; JPS

Figure 7.4 shows the typical daily dispatching of the system, again using the typical weekday
load profile for 2009 provided in the OUR Generation Expansion Plan. The figure shows
that the JPPC, West Kingston Power, and JEP plants would become the marginal plants on
the system. This is because the oil-fired plants would be decommissioned, and the NGCC
plant and converted combined cycle plant would have sufficient capacity to displace (at least
temporarily) the slow speed diesel plants, and expensive combustion turbines.

Effective
capacity
Average
heat rate
Fuel price
Variable
O&M
cost
Fuel cost
Short-run
marginal
cost
MW MMBtu/kWh US$/MMBtu US$/kWh US$/kWh US$/kWh
Wigton Wind farm n/a 10.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
Munro Wind farm n/a 0.9 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
JPS Hydropower Hydropower n/a 13.4 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
Maggotty Hydropower n/a 2.8 n/a 0.00 0.000 - -
LNG Natural Gas Combined Cycle LNG 323.6 0.0073 8.96 0.003 0.07 0.07
Bogue (converted)* Combined Cycle LNG 100.9 0.0089 8.96 0.006 0.08 0.09
JPPC Slow Speed Diesel HFO 54.6 0.0077 18.32 0.010 0.14 0.15
JEP Medium Speed Diesel HFO 111.9 0.0078 18.32 0.020 0.14 0.16
West Kingston Power Medium Speed Diesel HFO 58.5 0.0078 18.32 0.020 0.14 0.16
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.0093 18.32 0.008 0.17 0.18
Rockfort Slow Speed Diesel HFO 19.2 0.0095 18.32 0.008 0.17 0.18
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.0129 21.33 0.005 0.28 0.28
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.0165 21.33 0.005 0.35 0.36
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 19.9 0.0169 21.33 0.005 0.36 0.37
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 21.4 0.0170 21.33 0.005 0.36 0.37
Hunts Bay Combustion Turbine ADO 32.1 0.0179 21.33 0.005 0.38 0.39
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0180 21.33 0.005 0.38 0.39
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0180 21.33 0.005 0.38 0.39
Bogue Combustion Turbine ADO 17.9 0.0212 21.33 0.005 0.45 0.46
LNG = Liquefied Natural Gas, HFO = Heavy Fuel Oil, ADO = Automotive Diesel Oil
Fuel prices based on average projected fuel prices between 2010 and 2019, as projected by the OUR
Location/IPP name Type of plant
Type of
fossil fuel
used
Confidential
68
Figure 7.4: Dispatching Profile for Typical Week Day

Note: Figures based on 2009 load profile and fuel prices projected for the period 2010-2029, as provided in
the OURs 2010 Generation Expansion Plan.

To calculate the wholesale electricity price, we use the same assumptions for pricing under
each structure as in the previous scenario. That is, under the single buyer structure, the
wholesale electricity price at a given time is the weighted average SRMC of all plants running
on the system at that time.
Under a competitive market structure, the wholesale electricity price is the price of the
marginal plant on the system at the time. When the JPPC is on the margin (between 01:30
am and 08:30am), we assume that the wholesale electricity price is US$0.14 per kWh
(US$0.005 per kWh lower than the SRMC of the JPPC plant). When the West Kingston
Power and JEP plant are the marginal plants, we assume that the wholesale electricity price is
US$0.155 per kWh (slightly lower than the SRMC of the marginal plant). When the JEP or
West Kingston Power plants are running, we assume that the wholesale electricity price is
US$0.175 per kWh (US$0.005 per kWh lower than the cost of the slow speed diesel plants).
Figure 7.5 below shows the wholesale prices under each market structure on a typical week
day. The figure shows that, with the commissioning of the natural gas plant, the average
price of wholesale electricity would be about US$0.11 per kWh (compared to US$0.17 per
kWh under a single buyer market structure with the current capacity). Under a competition
market structure, the wholesale electricity price would be around US$0.18 per kWhthat is
an increase in the wholesale electricity price of about US$0.7 per kWh compared to the
current market structure. Below we estimate how this increase in wholesale electricity prices
would affect electricity prices to consumers.

0.0
100.0
200.0
300.0
400.0
500.0
600.0
700.0
M
W
Timeoftheday
JEP
WestKingstonPower
JPPC
ConvertedcombinedcycleatBogue
Naturalgascombinedcycle
Wind
Newhydro
Hydro
US$0.07/kWh
US$0.09/kWh
US$0.15/kWh
US$0.16/kWh
Confidential
69
Figure 7.5: Wholesale Electricity Prices under Single Buyer (Current Market
Structure) and Wholesale Competitive Power Markets, US$/kWh


To estimate the changes in electricity prices to consumers arising from introducing
competition in the electricity market, we use the same methodology as in section 7.2.2that
is:
RcJuction in priccs =
Rcducton n gcncuton costs
LIcctcty soId

Assuming that total electricity generation is 4,137 GWh and electricity sold is 3,235 GWh,
we find that electricity tariffs would increase by about US$0.12 per kWh if competition was
introduced after the NGCC is commissioned and combined cycle plant converted to natural
gas.
In section 3.2.2 we found that if LNG was used as the main fuel for electricity generation,
the cost of electricity generation would decrease, leading to a decrease in electricity tariffs of
US$0.10 per kWh. This means that if LNG was used as a main fuel for generating electricity
and the market structure was changed to a competitive structure, electricity generators would
take in all of the benefits from the reduction in electricity generation costsinstead of
decreasing by US$0.10 per kWh, electricity prices to consumers would increase by US$0.12
per kWh.
Summary
Experience with introducing wholesale and retail competition in island countries has shown
that in such countries, the limited scope for attracting sufficient competition levels has led to
issues of market power abuse, and higher electricity prices. In the above section, we have
demonstrated that this would indeed be a relevant issue in Jamaica, and that disaggregating
the sector would lead to a significant increase in electricity costs to customers.
One way of addressing this problem would be to regulate electricity pricesbut in that case,
the electricity market would not be a free market. Furthermore, it is difficult to envisage any

0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0.10
0.12
0.14
0.16
0.18
0.20
U
S
$
/
k
W
h
Timeoftheday
Wholesalepricewithsinglebuyerstructure Averagepricewithsinglebuyerstructure,US$/kWh
Wholesalepricewithwholesalecompetitionstructure
Confidential
70
benefit from breaking up the electricity system and then regulating each company separately,
when the OUR already regulates all the activities in generation, transmission and distribution
anyway.
7.2.3 Other Costs and Possible Problems Arising from Restructuring the Jamaican
Electricity Sector
In the previous section we showed that electricity prices would increase substantially under a
wholesale competition market structure, compared to a single buyer market. In addition to
this increase in wholesale prices, changing the market structure to a wholesale competition
model would involve various costs.
We estimate that a disaggregation of the sector could:
Increase prices by US$0.11 per kWh given the current generation capacity on the
system, or US$0.12 per kWh given planned generation capacity (with a NGCC
plant)
Involve high transaction and restructuring costs
Increase administration and overhead costs
Prevent financing of the large new plant needed to allow a change of fuel, and
therefore forfeit the corresponding saving in electricity cost of US$0.10 per kWh
from using LNG as a main fuel for electricity generation
Risk undermining the investment climate in the sector, potentially resulting in
rolling blackouts such as the many blackouts that have plagued the Dominican
Republic since the sector was restructured in 2000
Risk reducing incentive and ability to maintain the transmission and distribution
networks, thereby affecting electricity tariffs for residential and commercial
customers (an increase in losses to 25 percent would lead to an increase of
electricity costs by US$0.02 per kWh to these customers)
Risk eliminating the ability to cross-subsidize tariffs from richer areas to poor and
rural areas.
Below we examine each of these points in further detail.
Transactions and restructuring costs
Until its licence expires in 2027, JPS has:
the exclusive right to provide service within the framework of an All-Island Electric
Licence and the All-Island Electrical System. [] The Licensee shall have the exclusive
right to transmit, distribute and supply electricity throughout Jamaica for a period of 20
years.
36

Therefore, unbundling the generation, transmission, distribution and retail of electricity in
Jamaica would involve transaction costs related to terminating this licence, setting a new
framework for providing licences, and attracting new companies in the sector. The
Government would need to create a competitive market mechanism, as well as a new
framework and protocols (such as protocols for open access) under which the various

36
Jamaica Public Service Limited - All-Island Electricity Licence, 2001. P.8
Confidential
71
electricity sector companies could operate. This would also involve restructuring costs for
JPS. All these transaction costs will need to be recovered from customers.
Furthermore, JPS has entered into various long-term loan agreements (with a total current
debt of about US$350 million) with different multilateral financial institutions. Any material
change in JPSs licence would result in a default on all of JPSs loans. Restructuring the
sector would therefore require obtaining consent from the various lenders, which could be
difficult and costly.
Increased administration and overhead costs
Under the current structure, administration and overhead costs are minimized because there
is only a need for one CEO, and one group of key management and administrative staff.
Ideally, if unbundled the electricity sector would comprise at least five or six generator
companies and three distribution and retail companies. Each company would need to recruit
management staff, specialized and qualified staff, and administrative staff.
In 2009, JPS provided about US$1.4 million in remuneration and compensation to its
directors and key management staff.
37
With six new generators and three distribution
companies, customers in each distribution area would need to be paying for the cost of
hiring and remunerating directors, key management and administrative staff in seven
companies. Assuming that each distribution company would hire five people to fill director
and top management positions, and that each generation company would hire four directors
and top managers, and assuming an average salary of US$75,000 for directors and top
management positions, electricity prices would need to be sufficiently high to cover a total
annual remuneration of about US$2.9 million for directors and key management staff. In
addition to that, each company would need to set up a billing and accounting system, and
hire administrative staffthese costs would also need to be paid for by customers.
Potential issues with financing generation
The limited ability to finance new generation assets could become an important problem in
the electricity sector. To finance new generation assets, companies need an off-taker (that is,
someone who can commit to purchase the electricity generated for a defined period), in
order to show that there is a secure market for the future output of the facility.
Under a competitive system there would be no single off-takerpotential buyers would
include the three distribution companies and large users, so that each of the distribution
companies would only be able to commit to buy less than a third of current capacity.
Therefore, to finance a large plant, companies would need to sign off-take agreements with
two or more distribution companies, as well as a number of large customers for a period of
20 years.
Experience in other markets has shown that this is very difficult in practice. For example, as
mentioned in section 7.2.1 the New Zealand electricity market has had difficulty in attracting
market-driven investment in generation
38
, and as a result the Government had to invest in a
155MW oil-fired power plant in 2003, at a cost of more than US$100 million.
39
The
Philippines has also experienced difficulties with financing generation, resulting in

37
JPS (2010). Growth in the Midst of Adversity-2009 Annual Report. p.82.
38
New Zealand Ministry of Economic Development (June 2003). Discussion Paper: Reserve Generation.
39
TVNZ (June 2004). Whirinaki Power Station Opened.
Confidential
72
insufficient generating capacity to cover peak demand, and consequent risk of power
shortages.
40
The Dominican Republic has also experienced major difficulties due to
distribution companies failing to pay generators for contracted capacity, resulting in frequent
and extended rolling blackouts.
Therefore, risks related to off-take agreements would need to be examined very carefully
before implementing any sector disaggregation in Jamaica. Securing off-take agreements may
be even more difficult if distribution companies have a poor credit rating. In Jamaica, the
distribution of electricity is currently characterized by high losses, lack of insurance, and
collection problems, therefore unbundling the generation, transmission and distribution
would enhance this risk.
In light of the above, financing the new NGCC plant would be very difficult if the system
was disaggregated. Therefore, disaggregating the sector would mean foregoing the US$0.10
per kWh benefit that adding this plant would bring to customers.
Risk of increased system losses
A competitive market structure with separate distribution and retailing companies can
undermine the incentive to reduce electricity losses and maintain the system. This is because
the companies that have the ability to maintain the system and reduce system losses are the
distribution companies; however under this type of market structure, the distribution
companies would not benefit from any increase revenue as a result of improving the
systemthe retailing companies would. Therefore, under this type of market structure, the
distribution companies have the ability to maintain the system performance to an adequate
or desired level but do not have a direct incentive to do so, while the retailing companies
have an incentive to maintain the system to increase their revenue, but are not able to do so,
as the transmission and distribution assets do not belong to them.
The electricity sector in the Dominican Republic provides a real example of how system
losses can increase under a competitive market structure, and contribute to a power crisis
that affects all stakeholders in the country, as outlined in Box 7.2 below.


40
Rubrico J. G. (April 2010). Philippines Power at Crisis Point.
http://www.atimes.com/atimes/Southeast_Asia/LD10Ae01.html
Confidential
73
Box 7.2: Electricity Sector Disaggregation in Dominican Republic
In the Dominican Republic, the disaggregation of the sector has resulted in a long sector
crisis involving a combination of high prices, poor sector performance and costly
subsidies. The vertically integrated electricity utility was unbundled in 1997, and in 2000 the
Government established an open generation market under which distributors and
generators could trade electricity. By 2008 there were more than a dozen generators, a
transmission company and three regional distribution companies operating in the sector.
A range of national and international market shocks starting in 2001 led to an economic
crisis throughout the country, as well as increases in energy prices. In 2003 the
Government introduced a new tariff regime under which distribution companies were not
allowed to recover increases in energy prices. The three distribution companies have been
suffering from financial instability since (also due to high levels of non-technical losses),
and have been unable to recover sufficient cash from their customers. In 2003, the
Government renationalized two of the three distribution companies by repurchasing 50
percent of the shares held in them. In 2008 the distribution companies had a cash recovery
index of about 60 percent (whereas a CRI of 70-75 percent was estimated for ensuring
operational breakeven), and were expected to require a cash infusion of over US$800
million just to meet their 2008 deficit. System losses were around 32 percent in 2008.
Despite the reasonable availability of generation capacity, distribution companies have
been unable to purchase sufficient electricity to meet demand. This has resulted in frequent
and extended rolling blackouts, and temporary shutdown of power generation units. In
September 2010, the System Average Interruption Duration Index for the distribution
company in the North was still as high as 23.63 hoursmeaning that during that month,
the average outage duration for each customer served was almost 24 hours.
The electricity crisis in Dominican Republic has had significant and extensive social
consequences. The unreliability of the service has affected the poorest areas more than
other areas. In September 2002, as blackouts of up to 20 hours a day were affecting many
neighborhoods and particularly the poorest areas, the population expressed dissatisfaction
through riots that turned violent and led to the loss of 15 lives.
Due to a shortage of funds, the distribution companies have been unable to invest in
maintaining and improving their assetsthis resulted in deteriorating networks. Between
2005 and 2006, the Government provided more than US$100 million to the companies for
investment. However, much of this went into working capital that was essential for
continuing operations. The Government provided another US$53 million for investments
in 2007, US$75 million in 2008, and agreed to US$80-100 million in both 2009 and 2010.
The Government has had to provide large subsidies to the distribution companies (for
example, the Government provided more than US$1.3 billion subsidies to these companies
between 2005 and 2007 alone), and implement a long Blackout Reduction programme to
provide about 20 hours of electricity per day in the poorest neighborhoods. This
programme was extended from 2001 until 2009.
Sources: DeNorte (30 September 2010). Operatividad Tcnica-Distribucin; The World Bank (August
2008). Project Appraisal Document on a Proposed Loan to the Dominican Republic for an Electricity
Distribution Rehabilitation Project; BCP Securities, LLC (September 2010). The Dominican
Republics Electricity Industry: A Sector that Generates Attractive Yields.

Using the current pricing formula for electricity tariffs in Jamaica, we can estimate the impact
of increased system losses on electricity costs to customers, as shown in section 5.3:
Fucl cost poss troug = Fucl cost Ecot rotc (1 + Systcm Iosscs) (1)
Confidential
74
Where the fuel cost is the actual fuel cost in US$ per MMBtu, the heat rate is the average
heat rate of all plants operating on the system in MMBtu per kWh, and system losses are
expressed in percentage of net generation, and where:
Iori=nonucl rotc+ucl cost poss troug (2)
Assuming an increase in electricity losses to 26 percent (that is about half way between the
current level of system losses in Jamaica and Dominican Republic), and that the target for
system losses was accordingly adjusted to 26 percent, we estimate that the electricity prices to
customers would increase by US$0.02 per kWh for residential and commercial customers.
Risk eliminating ability to cross-subsidize tariffs between different areas
Unbundling the distribution of electricity into three different companies serving three main
regions would likely require the OUR to determine separate tariffs for different regions. This
could impede on the ability for firms to cross-subsidize tariffs from richer areas to poor and
rural areasparticularly if one of the distribution companies serves most of the richer
customers, while the other companies serve mostly poorer and rural areas. In addition,
service quality and standards may differ from one distribution company to another, thereby
affecting customers differently, depending on their geographical location.
7.3 Summary
In this section we have shown that disaggregating the electricity sector in Jamaica would not
lead to any reduction in the cost of electricity transmission and distribution (as this is a
natural monopoly). We have also demonstrated that disaggregating the sector would lead to
an increase in electricity generation costs, with an increase in electricity costs to customers of
US$0.11 per kWh if competition was introduced given the current generation capacity, and
increase by US$0.12 per kWh if competition was introduced after the NGCC is
commissioned and the CC plant is converted to LNG. In other words, if LNG was used as
the main fuel for electricity generation and the market structure was changed to a
competitive structure, electricity generators would absorb all of the benefits from the
reduction in electricity generation costs.
We anticipate that the cost of electricity would likely increase disproportionately for different
types of customers, with a disadvantage for small customer classes such as residential and
commercial customers.
These estimates represent the minimum possible increase in retail electricity prices. We
expect that retail electricity prices would increase further as a result of the transaction and
restructuring costs listed in section 7.2.3. Furthermore, disaggregating the sector may lead to
difficulties in financing generation assets, thereby potentially preventing the financing of the
NGCC plant and conversion of the CC plant to LNG, and forfeiting the potential saving of
US$0.10 per kWh. In addition, we have seen that disaggregating the sector may increase the
risk of blackouts throughout the country.
Confidential
75
8 Option 6: Enabling Competition in Generation and
Supply to Large Users
In this section we examine the option of enabling competition in electricity generation and
retailing for large customersthis is known as retail wheeling.
Below we provide a description of the reform and explain how it would change the sector
(8.1), examine the potential costs and benefits of this reform (8.2), and the potential impact
on electricity costs to customers (8.3). We find that enabling retail wheeling in Jamaica would
unlikely be economically viable, and therefore would be unlikely to bring any benefits to
large customers. If large customers were able to buy power from generators other than JPS
at a lower cost, however, the result would be an increase in electricity tariffs to smaller
customers.
8.1 Description of the Reform
Some stakeholders in Jamaica have suggested that the electricity sector be reformed so as to
enable competition in electricity generation and supply to large users (retail wheeling).
Possible benefits of retail wheeling include lower prices, more consumer choice, and greater
efficiencies in the generation of electricity. These benefits could, in turn, lower electricity-
related costs for industrial producers and other businesses, thereby potentially affecting their
national and international competitiveness.
Retail wheeling would enable large commercial and industrial electricity customers to buy
electricity from suppliers other than JPS, and pay JPS a wheeling charge for the power
transmitted and distributed. Implementing this reform would therefore require modifying
the current regulatory arrangements so as to:
Enable third party generators to generate and sell electricity to customers in
JamaicaJPS currently has the exclusive right to provide service within the framework of an
All-Island Electric Licence and the All-Island Electrical System [] the exclusive right to
transmit, distribute and supply electricity throughout Jamaica for a period of 20 years
41
; therefore
the licence would need to be renegotiated
Enable third party generators to wheel their electricity over the transmission and
distribution lines owned by JPSthis would require the OUR to set a wheeling tariff
which JPS would charge to third party generators.
8.2 Evidence of Benefits and Costs
The potential benefit of enabling retail wheeling in Jamaica would be a reduction in the cost
of generation through an increase in competition. However, in theory this option would be
unlikely to result in a reduction in electricity costs, because the OUR already commissions all
new capacity under competitive tenderstherefore all capacity recently commissioned
should represent low cost solutions.
In addition, under the current market structure and legislation, all customers have the right
to self-generate. Therefore, if JPS charged tariffs that were higher than self-generation costs,
the company could lose its largest customers.

41
Jamaica Public Service Limited - All-Island Electricity Licence, 2001. P.8
Confidential
76
Furthermore, as seen in section 1, the implementation of a NGCC plant such as that planned
for 2014 and conversion of existing CC plant to LNG could achieve a significant reduction
in electricity coststhereby providing little scope for other, smaller plants to generate
electricity at a cost lower than the resulting tariffs.
Below we examine the cost of generating electricity for two large users in Jamaica, to
determine whether retail wheeling would be beneficial to such customers.
To determine whether retail wheeling would be beneficial to large electricity users, we
estimate the cost of electricity generation using a generator that would be large enough to
supply two of the biggest industrial customers in Jamaica. We assume that the combined
peak demand of these two users is 2.5MW. Table 8.1 below shows the Long-Run Marginal
Cost of a 2.7MW diesel generator, using cost figures from a small generator used in Nevis.
Table 8.1: Estimation of Unit Cost of Electricity Generation using a Small Diesel
Generator
Average price of diesel for the period 2010-2029* (a) US$/MMBtu 21.33
Plant heat rate (b) MMbtu/kWh 0.012994
Installed capacity (c) kW 2,700
Unit capital cost** (d) US$/kW 1,500
Fixed O&M costs (e) US$/kW/month 2.3
Variable O&M cost (f) US$/kWh 0.00021
Lifetime (g) Years 25
Capacity factor (h) % 97
Availability (i) % 99
Typical output per year*** (j = c*h*i) kWh/kW/year 8,403.6
Total system cost (k = c*d) US$ 4,050,000
Annualized capital cost (l ) US$/year 514,584
Annual fixed O&M cost (m = e*c*12) US$/year 74,520
Typical annual output (n = c*j) kWh/year 22,689,600
Capital cost recovery factor (o = l/n) US$/kWh 0.023
O&M cost per kWh (p) US$/kWh 0.003
Fuel cost (q) US$/kWh 0.277
LRMC (=o+p+q+f) US$/kWh 0.303
*Calculated from projected ADO prices over the period 2010-2029 (from the Generation Expansion Plan), and
adding freight and transport charges (derived from Petrojams pricing formulas); **Includes interest during
construction
Note: Costs derived using a discount rate of 11.95%
Source: Capital cost, efficiency and availability figures from NEVLEC (2003). O&M Cost figures from: The
World Bank (1985) Diesel Plant Performance Study. Energy Department Paper No. 21

Confidential
77
The table above shows that the LRMC of a small diesel generator (the type of plant that
would be used to supply electricity to a couple of large users in Jamaica), is around US$0.30
per kWh. This is very close to the current tariff charged to industrial customers (US$0.31 for
R50 customers, and US$0.33 for R40 customers).
The independent generator running this system would therefore charge a minimum of
US$0.30 per kWh to the customers. In addition to that, all retail wheeling customers would
be required to pay a wheeling charge to JPS for transmitting the electricity to their premises.
If the wheeling charge was below US$0.02 per kWh, it would cost the same for the large
customers to buy power exclusively from JPS, or from the small generator. However, if the
wheeling charge was more than US$0.02 per kWh, it would not be economically viable for
large users to buy power from generators other than JPS. Importantly, customers may still
want to have a separate contract with JPS for standby power, to ensure continuity of supply
even when the independent generator is unable to supply power. Adding this cost to the
generation cost and wheeling charge would make retail wheeling non-viable.
In section 3.2.2 we found that with the commissioning of the NGCC plant on the system
and conversion of existing CC plant to LNG, electricity tariffs would decrease by US$0.10
per kWh. In this context, it would therefore not make sense for the large customers to buy
their power from the small generator, as they would be able to buy power from JPS at a
much lower rate.
Bagasse cogeneration, wind power and landfill gas to energy would also generate power at a
lower cost than a small diesel plant (as shown in section 4.2.3). The best solution would be
for all customers to benefit from cheaper power from these sources, as demonstrated in
section 4.2.
If an independent generator was able to sell power to large users at a cheaper cost than JPS,
it is likely that the generator would in fact be taking advantage of a distortion in electricity
prices (such as a cross-subsidy from large customers to smaller customers). Furthermore, if
several of JPSs large customers were to buy their power directly from other generators, JPS
would be forced to increase its tariffs to the residential and commercial customers, in order
to recover its actual cost of operations. The burden of maintaining the system capacity
would therefore be shifted to smaller users.
Jamaica has already seen some adverse effects of introducing competition in the market for
water and cherry picking. By cherry picking, we mean when operators target specific
market segments within a given service area, and exclude less desirable customers. For
example, in Ocho Rios, there is a water company is supplying to large hotels, but not to
residential and small users (as doing so is not considered profitable). This cherry picking
removes NWCs ability to cross-subsidize small users with profits from the hotels, and may
ultimately push up charges for small users.
8.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity
As shown in section 8.2, enabling retail wheeling in the sector would be unlikely to bring a
reduction in the cost of electricity to large customers. At best, it would cost the same amount
for large customers to buy power from JPS or a small independent generator. Therefore,
even if it was available, the retail wheeling option would unlikely be sought after, as large
customers would not benefit from buying power from small generators.
Confidential
78
Nevertheless, even if large customers benefited from this option if this reform was
implemented, there would likely be tariff rebalancing and social consequences. Electricity
tariffs would increase for residential and small commercial usersin other words, any
benefits that may be brought by retail wheeling (if any) would not be shared across
customers, the costs would simply be shifted from large users to small customers.
Therefore, we would not recommend implementing retail wheeling, because despite
involving transaction and regulatory costs, it would be unlikely to benefit large customers,
and could harm small customers. The best option would be for people to propose projects
or technologies that could really reduce system costs (if these options are not already being
used or considered), and for the OUR to ensure that power is purchased from least-cost
suppliers for the benefit of all customers.
Confidential
79
9 Option 7: Creating an Independent System
Operator
Economic dispatch is the method of determining the most efficient, low-cost and reliable
operation of a power system by dispatching the available electricity generation resources to
supply the load on the system. The primary objective of economic dispatch is to minimize
the total cost of generation while honoring the operational constraints of the available
generation resources and the transmission system.
In this section we examine the option of setting up independent dispatching, amid claims
that JPS is manipulating the dispatching in order to increase profits. In this section we
provide a description of the reform and explain how it would change the market structure
(9.1), examine the potential costs and benefits of this reform (9.2), and evaluate the potential
impact on electricity costs to customers (9.3). We find that setting up an independent system
operator would have no impact on the cost of electricity to customers, or increase the cost
slightly across all customers.
9.1 Description of the Reform
As a vertically-integrated utility responsible for electricity generation, transmission and
distribution on the island, JPS is currently responsible for dispatching the generation
required to meet the load. Figure 9.1 below illustrates the current arrangement for
dispatching electricity.
Figure 9.1: Current Arrangement for System Dispatch in Jamaica


JPS Generation
JEP Old Harbour
IPP
JPPC Rockfort
IPP
Wigton Wind
Farm
Residential
Consumers
Large Commercial
Consumers
Large Industrial
Consumers
Other IPPs
Street Lights
Small Commercial
Consumers
Small Industrial
Consumers
Generators Consumers System Dispatch and Transmission and Distribution
JPS System Dispatcher and
Transmission & Distribution System
Confidential
80
The current requirements and rules for system dispatch in Jamaica are established under
JPSs electricity licence, as follows:
1. The Licensee shall establish and operate as part of the Generation Code a merit order
system, for generation sets that are subject to central dispatch.
2. The Licensee shall schedule and issue direct instructions for the dispatch in accordance
with a merit order system of all available generation sets of each authorised electricity
operator which are required or are agreed to be subject to such scheduling and instructions.
3. Subject to the factors in paragraph 4, the Licensee shall schedule and issue direct
instructions for the dispatch of such generation sets as are at such times available to generate
or transfer electricity:
(a) in ascending order of the marginal cost in respect of any hour for the generation
and delivery or transfer of electricity into the System, to the extent allowed by
Transmission System operating constraints based on "Equal Incremental Cost-
System" principles; and
(b) as will in aggregate and after taking into account electricity delivered into or
out of the System from or to other sources be sufficient to match at all times (so far
as possible in view of the availability of generation sets) demand forecast taking
account of information provided by authorised electricity operators, together with an
appropriate margin of reserve for security operation.
4. The factors referred to in paragraph 3 above include:
(a) forecast demand (including transmission losses and distribution losses);
(b) economic and technical constraints from time to time imposed on the System or
any part or parts thereof;
(c) the dynamic operating characteristics of available generation sets; and
(d) other matters provided for in the Generation Code.
5. The Licensee shall provide to the Office such information as the Office shall request
concerning the merit order system or any aspect of its operation.
42

To ensure that the system dispatcher uses up-to-date information on plant costs and
efficiencies for determining dispatch, the OUR requires that JPS tests the efficiency of all
plants regularly.
Recently, some stakeholders in Jamaica have suggested that JPS has not been operating
faithfully in accordance with the principles established in its licence (as explained in Box 8.1
below), and that an effective way of addressing this problem would be to create an
independent entity that would be responsible for the dispatch of the various generators on
the system.


42
Jamaica Public Service Company Limited All-Island Electricity Licence, 2001. Condition 23, page 33.
Confidential
81
Box 9.1: Is JPS manipulating dispatch out of merit-order?
Some stakeholders in the sector have suggested that JPS has not been operating faithfully
in accordance with the principles established in its licence, and that the company has been
using the excuse of transmission system constraints to dispatch its own plant at the
expense of the IPPs.
Others believe that JPS has been dispatching plant to achieve reductions in heat rate
figures, in order to achieve heat rates that are less than the target maximum rates specified
in the fuel recovery clause of the tariffwhereas according to JPSs licence, the dispatch
should be arranged to minimize costs rather than overall heat rates.
However, to date there is no firm evidence that this is the case, and the above claims are
impossible to verify one way or another in this study. JPS states that, to the extent allowed
by transmission system operating constraints, its dispatch is in accordance with the cost
minimization function specified in the licence, and that it reports on its dispatch to the
OUR on a monthly basis (in addition to sending two Gross Plant Capacity Reports to the
OUR every day). JPS further states that because of the transparency involved in this
reporting, it should be easy for the OUR to verify that the dispatch is undertaken in
accordance with the requirements set out in the licence. The OUR has recently audited the
dispatch function, but the results have not yet been published.
Source: JPS

The proposed reform would involve setting up an independent system operator who would
be responsible for dispatching the power produced by both the IPPs and JPS unto the JPS-
owned transmission and distribution system for distribution to customers. It is not intended
that the independent system operator would be a wholesaler of power or take any title to the
power sold to the JPS transmission system. Figure 9.2 below illustrates how the system
would be dispatched with an independent system operator.
Figure 9.2: Dispatch of Electricity with a New, Independent System Operator

Independent
System
Dispatcher
JPS Generation
JEP Old Harbour
IPP
JPPC Rockfort
IPP
Wigton Wind
Farm
Residential
Consumers
Large Commercial
Consumers
Large Industrial
Consumers
Other IPPs
Street Lights
Small Commercial
Consumers
Small Industrial
Consumers
Generators Consumers System Dispatch and Transmission and Distribution
JPS
Transmission
and Distribution
System
Confidential
82
9.2 Benefits and Costs of the Proposed Reform
Creating an independent system operator would ensure that the dispatching of plant is
always undertaken according to the principles established under JPSs current licence, and
therefore improve perceptions about the fairness of dispatch. These outcomes should be
achieved at all times. However, we think that setting up an independent system operator
would not be the most efficient way of achieving these outcomes because:
Setting up an independent system operator would involve transaction
costs, which would be borne by customers: these transaction costs will be
related to renegotiating JPSs licence, setting up the new operator, and a new
regulatory framework for dispatching
Setting up an independent system operator would entail increased
overhead costs which would be borne by customers: even though it may be
argued that the size of the new system operating team may be the same size as the
current team at JPS, the team will require executive and management support
staff, and administrative and clerical staff, therefore leading to an increase in the
operating costs of the dispatching. These increased costs will have to be passed
on to customers in the form of higher rates, and such increases will have to be
offset by any gains in the efficiency of dispatch which would result in lower unit
costs
The OUR is already monitoring the dispatching on a monthly basis: if the
OUR is monitoring the dispatch effectively and not reporting any problems, then
this means that the system dispatch is already undertaken in an efficient manner,
and following the principles established in JPSs licence. On this basis,
establishing an independent system operator would entail additional costs to
customers, with no benefits compared to the current system.
In light of the above, the most cost-effective solution would be to improve the monitoring
of dispatching. One way to ensure effective monitoring would be to require that JPS
provides, in addition to the data already being provided:
An ex-ante monthly maintenance plan: JPS would file a report outlining its
maintenance plan for each month ahead, describing which lines and/or units it is
planning to take out of service, and at what time. The OUR would be able to vet
this report before approving the maintenance plan, or suggest an alternative plan.
JPS would then be required to follow the maintenance plan approved by the OUR
Evidence of emergency: in cases where the actual maintenance plan followed by
JPS was different to the maintenance plan approved by the OUR, JPS would be
required to provide compelling evidence that this was due to an emergency. JPS
would be required to report on how it dispatched all plant, explaining and
justifying any dispatching out of merit order. In such cases, the OUR would have
the right to audit JPS. In the event that the OUR does not find an allowable
reason for JPS to diverge from the approved maintenance plan, JPS would be
liable for a penalty.
Confidential
83
9.3 Impact on the Cost of Electricity
At best, setting up an independent system operator would not affect the cost of electricity to
customers. The cost of electricity might slightly increase (for all customer categories) if a
system operator fee was imposed on customers.
Confidential
84
10 Conclusion and Recommendations
If the priority for all stakeholders in the electricity sector in Jamaica is to reduce prices, any
efforts to reform the sector should not focus on options that will increase prices or have no
discernable effects. Accordingly, the analysis shown in this report demonstrates that the
options of disaggregating the electricity sector, setting up an independent system operator,
and enabling retail wheeling should not be a focus.
Fortunately, our analysis also shows that there are four options which would bring down
electricity prices in Jamaicathese are:
Changing the main fuel used for generating electricity to LNG or coal,
Reducing losses in the electricity system,
Implementing viable renewable energy technologies, and
Increasing the use of energy efficient technologies amongst end-users.
These options should be prioritized.
The Government and JPS are already working on these options. Nevertheless, there may be
scope for more rapid and effective progress. This report has identified a number of specific
actions that JPS and the Government could take to ensure that the reform options listed
above are implemented rapidly and effectivelywe summarize these in Table 10.1 below.

Confidential
85
Table 10.1: Reducing Electricity Costs in JamaicaCurrent Efforts and Recommendations
Reform
option
Current efforts to implement reform Recommendations
Changing the
main fuel
The OUR recently completed a tender for a large new
plant, with preference for the use of LNG as a fuel. JPS
submitted a bid to build a NGCC plant
Secure an off-take agreement for the NGCC plant and non-
generation gas customers, so that an LNG terminal can be
financed
Secure supply of natural gas
Reducing
losses in the
electricity
system
JPS is working on installing new systems, aiming to reduce
system losses to 15 percent
JPS to keep working on reducing non-technical losses, but also
focus on reducing technical losses (for example by adding
voltage regulators for feeders, upgrading high voltage
distribution lines from 12kV to 24kV, and possibly by
interconnecting different feeders)
Government could also reduce non-technical losses by:
Increasing legislative penalties for theft of electricity
Formalizing procedures allowing JPS to back-bill for stolen
electricity
Implementing a name and shame programme to
publicize the names of individuals and companies found to
be stealing electricity (similar to that proposed for tax
evasion)
Educating the public about electricity theft and its
consequences.
Confidential
86
Reform
option
Current efforts to implement reform Recommendations
Implementing
viable
renewable
energy
technologies
Government has released its first National Energy Policy to
facilitate the deployment of renewable energy technologies
The OUR has released indicative generation avoided costs,
to be used as a basis for pricing distributed renewable
energy generation
JPS and the OUR have drafted a standard contract for
distributed generation technologies
Integrate viable renewable energy options (bagasse
cogeneration, wind power and landfill gas-to-energy) into the
system expansion plan
Extend the duration of the standard offer contract to 20
yearsto provide more certainty, and minimize transaction
and processing costs
Offer two options for pricing distributed renewable energy
generation:
Providing the long-run avoided cost and 15 percent
premium, fixed for a period of 20 years
Providing the current short-run avoided cost for a period
of 3 years, with the OUR resetting the avoided cost to
actual short-run avoided cost on an annual basis
Increasing
the use of
energy
efficient
technologies
amongst end-
users
Government issued a National Energy Conservation and
Efficiency Policy for 2010-2030, and proposed a flagship
project for supporting increased energy efficiency in
Jamaica
Government invested in a Testing, Labeling and Energy
Efficiency Information Programme
Government could:
Increase uptake of efficient technologies other than lighting
Procure an ESCO for retrofitting public buildings, and for
marketing to large consumers
Negotiate an arrangement for retrofitting street lights.
Implement a standard and labeling programme for appliances
Restrict the import of non-efficient equipment, or provide a
preferential customs regime for energy efficient equipment
Review the building code to mandate energy efficiency
measures and solar water heaters, and efficient design in new
buildings.















T: +1 (
F: +1 (
1700 K
WASH
United

T: +61
F: +61
36 38
SYDN
Austral

T: +64
F: +64
Level 2
PO Bo
WELL
New Z

T: +33
F: +33
7 Rue C
PARIS
France

----------


(202) 466-67
(202) 466-67
K Street NW
HINGTON D
States of Am
(2) 9231 68
(2) 9231 38
8 Young Stre
EY NSW 20
lia
4 (4) 913 280
(4) 913 280
2, 88 The Te
ox 10-225
LINGTON 6
Zealand
(1) 45 27 24
(1) 45 20 17
Claude Chah
75116
---- www.cast
790
797
W Suite 410
DC 20006
merica
862
847
eet
000
00
08
errace
6143
4 55
7 69
hu
talia-advisors..com

You might also like