You are on page 1of 24

Oxfam Discussion Papers

Low-Carbon Development For Least Developed Countries


Alex Bowen and Sam Fankhauser
GranthamResearchInstituteonClimateChangeandthe EnvironmentandCentreforClimateChangeEconomicsandPolicy, LondonSchoolofEconomicsandPoliticalScience
August 2011
This paper examines the rationale for Least Developed Countries (LDCs) to pursue lowcarbon growth paths, and identifies areas where such countries can contribute to mitigation whilst retaining a focus on poverty reduction. It argues low-carbon growth paths, appropriate to the needs of LDCs, ought to be explored now. Policies for lowcarbon development offer an opportunity to share in the benefits of green growth, address a range of existing market and government failures in LDCs, and provide lowcost options for global emissions reductions. Synergies between poverty alleviation and emissions reduction exist in the forestry and agriculture sectors, as well as rural electrification. But elsewhere there may be trade-offs, for instance in the transport and industrial sectors. Where additional costs are involved, these should not be borne by poor people, making it vital that an international framework is in place to assist LDCs, with rich countries compensating them for measures they undertake that go beyond their immediate development interests.

Oxfam Discussion Papers


Oxfam Discussion Papers are written to contribute to public debate and to invite feedback on development and humanitarian policy issues. They are work in progress documents, and do not necessarily constitute final publications or reflect Oxfam policy positions. The views and recommendations expressed are those of the author and not necessarily those of Oxfam. For more information, or to comment on this paper, email Sarah Best (sbest@oxfam.org.uk)

www.oxfam.org/grow

CONTENTS
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ............................................................................................................................. 3 1. INTRODUCTION ..................................................................................................................................... 4 2. Climate change mitigation, adaptation, and development................................................................ 6 3. Low-cost options for greenhouse gas emission reductions in LDCs ............................................. 10 4. A low-carbon development path for poor countries ......................................................................... 12 5. Conclusions............................................................................................................................................... 15 REFERENCES ............................................................................................................................................... 16 NOTES ........................................................................................................................................................... 18 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ......................................................................................................................... 23

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
The global community has to act collectively to halt climate change. But such collective action must take into account the development needs of Least Developed Countries (LDCs), which are likely to be hit earliest and hardest while having the least capacity for adaptation. The priority of such countries remains poverty alleviation and the achievement of the Millennium Development Goals, but the three challenges of limiting climate change, adapting to its consequences, and reducing poverty have to be faced together. This will require LDCs eventually to follow a development path that differs from those trodden by todays industrial countries and emerging market economies. There is no room in the long run for high-emission economies and high-carbon growth is unsustainable, given the possible consequences for fossil-fuel supplies and climate change impacts. And there are some advantages for LDCs of low-carbon growth in certain circumstances. For instance, in tackling broader market and government failures, which inhibit productivity and well-being like inadequate incentives for appropriate technology development and deployment or increasing energy security and addressing local health and environmental problems. By far the most important sources of greenhouse gas emissions in LDCs derive from land-use change, in particular deforestation. Since halting forest loss is also a major development and local environmental issue, tackling land-use change is therefore a key priority of low-carbon development. Synergies between poverty alleviation and emission reduction also exist with rural electrification, where renewable energy solutions are often least costly. And strengthening the capacity of the public sector to provide public goods such as energy infrastructure can help development in general, not just low-carbon development. But elsewhere there may be trade-offs between development and low-carbon objectives, for instance as much-needed investment in transport infrastructure leads to rising emissions. Adoption of low-carbon development paths by LDCs, as appropriate to their needs, should be conditional on the global costs of decarbonisation being shared equally. So, where reduction of emissions in LDCs introduces costs, rich people not poor people should bear these. This makes it crucial that an international framework is in place to assist LDCs and compensate them for measures they undertake that go beyond their immediate development interests.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

1. INTRODUCTION
The threat that human-induced climate change poses to the Least Developed Countries (LDCs) is profound. Greater dependence on rain-fed agriculture and forestry as sources of employment and income makes them more vulnerable to climatic changes and variability. Many LDCs are already subject to climatic stress because of their location in the Tropics and other areas subject to high incidences of weather-related shocks such as storms, drought, flooding and extremes of temperature and to high temperatures. In poor countries, but not middle-income or rich ones, higher temperatures are correlated with lower subsequent growth of GDP per capita.1 Unusually high temperatures can raise mortality in rural areas sharply by reducing agricultural incomes.2 Low incomes have made it more difficult to recover from past weatherrelated challenges and to prepare for future disasters. Many poor countries have been caught in a poverty trap due at least in part to weather-related disasters, with the high frequency of shocks eroding social and physical capital.3 Climate change is likely to exacerbate these problems, entailing rising global mean temperatures and major alterations in precipitation and increases in the incidence of storms, floods and drought.4 Recent scientific evidence suggests that many of the threats are even worse than thought three years ago.5 The risks are amplified by the fact that the precise climatic changes that will afflict particular locations, while often likely to be considerable, are uncertain. It is therefore essential for LDCs that the world puts in place effective policies to cut back drastically greenhouse gas emissions. LDCs need a global deal. And a global deal will have to involve all countries with substantial emissions, including some like India and China where large numbers of people still live in poverty. But why should a global deal mean that smaller and less-developed countries, especially those already having difficulty sustaining per capita income growth, adopt low-carbon development strategies? The contribution of LDCs to the greenhouse gas problem is, after all, very small. LDCs accounted for just over 4% of global greenhouse gas emissions in 2005 and only 0.3% of cumulative carbon dioxide emissions from energy.6 While global emissions were 6.8 tonnes of CO2 equivalent per head in 2005, the average for LDCs was only 2.4 tonnes per head; countries such as Ethiopia, Haiti and Afghanistan had average emissions of 1 tonne per head or less.7 Despite these contrasts between the world as a whole on the one hand and the LDCs on the other, we argue here that LDCs should indeed seek to follow low-carbon development paths appropriate to their development needs if certain conditions are satisfied. Why? First, tackling many of the market and government failures that stand in the way of low-carbon development would enhance productivity and well-being in LDCs themselves. Second, if a global deal is eventually achieved, technological progress around the world will be redirected towards low-carbon options. If LDCs are ultimately to share in growth from this source, their growth will have to be green too. Third, LDCs offer the world some relatively cheap options for reducing emissions, particularly from agriculture, land-use change and deforestation. The rest of the world has good reason, on efficiency grounds, to encourage LDCs to exploit these options to minimise the global costs of decarbonisation. However, there should be a quid pro quo for carrying out reductions in global greenhouse emissions where it is cheapest to do so, so that the global costs of decarbonisation are shared equitably.8 Hence one condition that should be satisfied is that, where reducing greenhouse gas emissions in LDCs entails costs, poor people should not bear these costs. Rich people should pay towards LDC mitigation burdens, on top of any assistance to help LDCs deal with the impacts of climate change. It must also be possible to switch towards low-carbon growth cheaply in the first place. That depends on whether it is in practice possible to put in place the right incentives to correct market and government failures and hence achieve the win-win outcomes that in principle could be attained. This paper considers these issues in greater detail. First, the advantages for LDCs of low-carbon growth in certain circumstances are discussed, together with the reasons why early action is desirable. The case sometimes advanced for LDCs to focus overwhelmingly on adaptation to climate change, including through

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

the promotion of conventional growth, is rebutted. Second, the advantages for the world as a whole if mitigation by LDCs is encouraged are rehearsed. Third, some possible and attractive low-carbon development paths for LDCs are suggested. These can and ought to be consistent with a continuing focus in the near term on the achievement of the Millennium Development Goals. Fourth, the paper concludes by drawing out some implications for development policies and for the appropriate shape of a Global Deal to halt human-induced climate change.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

2. Climate change mitigation, adaptation, and development


Economic growth has in the past been associated with increases in energy use and energy-related emissions per head. There has been a strong correlation over time between increases in GDP and increases in energy usage and CO2 emissions; this relationship has tended to be stronger among lower-income countries.9 The correlation can be obscured in data across countries at a point in time, given the variety of energy endowments and energy needs (related, for example, to climatic variations across countries). The energy intensity of GDP is broadly similar for LDCs and the world as a whole, although world GDP per head is about eight times the average LDC GDP per head. However, LDCs energy usage is less carbon intensive on average;10 excluding land-use change, LDCs average CO2 emissions intensity of GDP was 195 tonnes per million dollars of GDP in 2005, compared with an average of 487 tonnes for the world as a whole.11 The need for some headroom in carbon use for LDCs to grow and overcome poverty lay behind the acceptance under the Kyoto Protocol that poor countries need not adopt emission reduction targets. But rapidly industrialising countries have been much more emissions intensive than typical LDCs. The corresponding figures for India and China were 505 and 1052 tonnes per million dollars of GDP respectively. If all poorer countries were to move up towards these levels of emission intensity in power, transportation and industry as their economies grew, keeping global warming to 2C or less would be an unobtainable objective. If China and India are to play their part in global emissions control and LDCs are to follow them in achieving sustained economic growth and poverty reduction, the challenge is ultimately to decouple emissions and output growth. Given the international division of labour and the migration of more mature manufacturing industries to lower-income countries, that is also partly a challenge to decarbonise consumption of imports by rich countries. The key to decoupling is to recognise the malfunctions in economies that encourage greenhouse gas emissions. These emissions create a huge adverse externality, the likely damages flowing from climate change and the risks of even more catastrophic and irreversible climate outcomes. In the absence of carbon pricing, firms and households do not factor these damages and risks into their decisions when engaging in activities that lead to greenhouse gas emissions. But that is not the only market failure involved in the battle against human-induced climate change. Perhaps the most important ones for LDCs are: 1. Incentives that are inadequate to generate enough investment in research, development and deployment of new technologies and processes, particularly those most relevant to the comparative advantages and patterns of production in LDCs. The problem is that many new ideas give rise to benefits that do not accrue to the people who thought them up. Failure to understand and value ecosystem services properly for example, the role of forests in regulating rain-water run-off in hilly areas. The tragedy of the commons afflicting land-use in agriculture and forestry where property rights are unclear or contested.12 Imperfect information about the costs and benefits of energy efficiency, with users and producers, and landlords and tenants, having differential access to information (asymmetric information). Under-provision by the market of public infrastructure goods (e.g. transport infrastructure).

2. 3. 4. 5.

Bad governance and conflict in societies can also distort economies,13 inhibiting growth and stimulating greenhouse gas emissions and environmental degradation at the same time. Encouragement of land grabs by agroforestry businesses, conflict over fossil fuel resources and subsidies for middle-class energy consumption are three pertinent examples.14 And the provision of public goods public health, energy grids, irrigation schemes, public transport and so forth in such circumstances is much more difficult.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

All these sources of malfunctioning economies are costly and warrant tackling even without the threat of climate change. But our improved understanding of the latter increases the perceived costs of several of these malfunctions and the urgency of correcting them. That requires improved collective decision-making, which can generate other significant benefits, raising output directly and enhancing longer-run growth potential. It can also improve the composition of output in economies, better reflecting the long-run costs and benefits of different activities and thus helping to make development more environmentally sustainable, as well as enhancing the life chances of the poor. Action to reduce emissions is also likely to generate other valuable co-benefits. For example, developing renewable energy sources can produce co-benefits such as reduced air pollution, greater energy security, reduced foreign exchange needs and an improved quality of life. The World Health Organization (WHO) estimates that 1.5 million premature deaths per year are directly attributable to indoor air pollution from the use of solid fuels, implying more than 4,000 deaths per day, more than half of them children under five years of age.15 More than 85% of these deaths (about 1.3 million) are due to biomass use, the rest due to coal. Indoor air pollution associated with biomass use is directly responsible for more deaths than malaria, almost as many as tuberculosis and almost half as many as HIV/AIDS. That improves the benefits in the costbenefit calculus for carbon emission reduction measures. Aunun et al (2007) estimated that, in China reductions in CO2 emissions of 10-20% could generate reductions in air pollution and other benefits that would more than offset the costs of action. Another potential co-benefit is greater energy security. Developing renewable low-carbon energy sources is likely to provide more countries with indigenous energy supplies, reducing dependence on fossil-fuel imports and inadequate grid infrastructure, and giving them greater flexibility in energy supply. In several cases, the technologies involved are likely to be less capital-intensive and more labour-intensive (hence the advocacy of renewable technologies in proposals for green fiscal stimuli in developed countries, such as Bowen et al., 2009). Focusing on low-carbon growth will allow LDCs to benefit from the likely future bias in technological progress towards renewable energy technologies. Learning-by-doing, together with carbon pricing, is likely over time to induce significant cost reductions in renewable energy technologies compared with more mature hydrocarbon-based power. The worldwide search for better biofuels gives some LDCs scope for developing a new and valuable cash crop as well as a way of developing their own transport along lowcarbon lines. However, such a development needs to be undertaken in the context of a comprehensive lowcarbon growth strategy, so that new biofuel cultivation does not lead to accelerated deforestation and loss of peatlands.16 There are a number of reasons why it makes sense for LDCs to adopt low-carbon growth paths appropriate to their needs and capabilities immediately. First, that would avoid locking in high-carbon technologies in long-lived plant, equipment and infrastructure or, alternatively, premature scrapping later on when lowcarbon policies were finally adopted. Second, it would be export friendly in a world in which rich countries are likely to become more concerned about promoting low-carbon consumption. Third, it would allow LDCs to benefit from any subsidies for low-carbon research, development and deployment deriving from future international agreements on intellectual property rights and make it more likely that funds would be directed towards technologies relevant to the industrial structure of LDCs (in particular, agriculture and land-use). Fourth, it would enable LDCs to access the co-benefits discussed above as soon as possible. Finally, it would facilitate an eventual Global Deal on climate change, with the agreements on carbon financing and other flows of funds to LDCs that would have to be part of such a deal.17 These flows of funds should be additional to current pledges of Official Development Assistance (ODA). But additionality in this sense does not logically entail that the funds should all be earmarked for explicit climate change policies. As argued above, some of the most effective policies against climate change may be policies with the proximate target of better governance and the correction of pervasive market failures.18 The question of incremental development funding draws attention to one of the caveats about the benefits to LDCs of adopting appropriate low-carbon growth paths as soon as possible. Globally, climate change mitigation is likely to entail resource costs (discussed further below), although these costs are likely to be much less than the benefits from avoided climate change. Also, these costs will be front-loaded relative to the benefits. Developed-country support for these costs needs to be in place before they are incurred. And,

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

in some cases, effective support may be very difficult to organise, for example, because of the inadequacy of public-authority outreach in remote rural areas or of support mechanisms for the most poverty stricken.19 A second caveat is that a major share of mitigation costs will be due to the adoption of low-carbon technologies before their marginal costs have been driven below those of fossil-fuel technologies. Early adoption by developed countries is warranted by the returns to learning-by-doing and to reverse the bias towards innovation in currently cheaper technologies (Acemoglu et al, 2009). But it is not so clear how much LDCs should share in the necessary R&D and experimentation. In many industry sectors, the comparative advantage in early-stage innovation and learning-by-doing lies with developed countries, and the challenge will be to ensure rapid technology diffusion once new technologies become cost-competitive. Here, LDCs may be well advised to delay related capital investments until the relevant technologies have travelled down the learning curve (while avoiding locking in soon-to-be-obsolete carbon-intensive technologies). However, there are still likely to be activities that will benefit from innovation and experience being undertaken in LDCs (e.g. tropical forestry management, concentrated solar power). These may take longer to bring down costs, particularly if adequate technical assistance is difficult to deliver. Third, many of the benefits from early action should flow from the correction of market failures. This will depend on appropriate public policies being put in place. But greater public involvement risks the sort of rent-seeking and distortion of incentives identified by development economists such as Collier and Easterly (Collier, 2008; Easterly, 2001). The pace at which low-hanging fruit can be harvested may be slower than in OECD countries if improvements in governance and institution-building are required first. Although research in this area is at an early stage, several efforts have been made to examine the practical scope for low-carbon development, particularly among some of the larger, more rapidly growing developing economies. Chandler et al (2002), for example, investigated climate change mitigation experience and opportunities in Brazil, China, India, Mexico, South Africa and Turkey. They found that these countries had already made substantial reductions in emissions relative to business as usual, motivated primarily by economic, poverty, security and local environmental concerns. Erickson et al (2009) documented options with high mitigation potential that would also promote development, particularly in the promotion and development of renewable energy; the adoption, extension and enforcement of building and appliance energy codes; and vehicle energy efficiency standards. Ellis et al (2009) has provided a review of a number of case studies in high-, middle- and low-income countries, emphasising the advantages to developing countries if they can gain access to climate-mitigation finance from abroad, but also the benefits of technical assistance (a theme also present in Collier, 2008). Development agencies such as the World Bank and UK DFID have been promoting low-carbon growth studies and helping LDCs develop Nationally Appropriate Mitigation Action plans. Project Catalyst20 has been identifying low- and no-cost mitigation options in a variety of countries. These studies suggest that the theoretical arguments for low-carbon development are supported by empirical evidence. However, much more work tailored to the particular circumstances of LDCs is needed, recognising that there are many obstacles to correcting market and policy failures, even if the resource costs of effective and well-designed action is low. A popular counter-argument to the emphasis placed on climate change mitigation by policy-makers emphasises the need for traditional development to be encouraged. Schelling, for example, has suggested that it would be better for rich countries to transfer resources directly to LDCs to speed up their (conventional) growth and help the currently poor directly, rather than using those resources to develop mitigation and to pay for poorer countries to mitigate.21 After all, the argument goes, it is not fair to ask the currently poor to make large sacrifices on behalf of following generations that are likely to be much richer than they are. The focus needs to be on raising people out of poverty in the near term, not least to make societies more resilient in the face of climate change impacts growth (and changing industrial structure) is the best form of adaptation and, if achieved, warrants a less demanding global goal for stabilising greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere.22 The problem with this line of approach is two-fold, as Shalizi and Lecocq (2009) have pointed out.23 First, it does not take into sufficient account the benefits of accelerating mitigation actions globally, deriving from induced technical change and the option value of early global action. Second, it does not place enough weight on the risk that currently poor countries may stay poor if subjected to a higher incidence of climaterelated disasters (and even more so if any of the low-risk, high-impact global climate catastrophes discussed

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

by climate scientists take place). We cannot be sure that developing economies will all converge towards the average levels of income per head of industrial countries; the evidence for the long-run convergence of average per capita incomes outside of the OECD and major emerging-market economies is not convincing24 and a number of development economists have drawn attention to the poverty traps afflicting many LDCs despite receiving development aid.25 That has two implications. First, for a given distribution of income, there will be more people in absolute poverty for longer, so that the resilience of LDCs to climate change in the future will be exaggerated. Second, a lower discount rate for LDC investment projects, including in climate change mitigation and adaptation, will be appropriate. It is right, however, to stress that development is key to tackling poverty and making economies more climate-resilient. Richer, more diversified economies are better able to deal with weather-related shocks. Countries that have higher levels of socioeconomic development, as indicated by basic measures of factors such as literacy, health and quality of governance, are hit less hard by extreme weather-related events and are better able to recover from the damages they do suffer. Richer households can afford to take a less riskaverse approach to innovation and adaptation to climate change. And, despite the synergies between development and climate change mitigation identified above, there is a need for further research on the interactions among policies aimed at these two objectives and at promoting adaptation to climate change. Improving transport infrastructure, for example, is likely to be warranted on development grounds even though it encourages carbon emissions from vehicles. But carbon pricing and adaptation policies should influence the specific infrastructure choices made.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

3. Low-cost options for greenhouse gas emission reductions in LDCs


The costs of climate change mitigation globally are uncertain and much debated. Stern (2007) concluded that the expected annual cost of achieving emissions reductions consistent with stabilisation at around 500-550 ppm CO2e was likely to be around 1% of GDP by 2050, within a range of +/- 3%. Given the increasing emphasis among policy-makers recently on the desirability of keeping the global temperature increase since pre-industrial times to 2C or less, much subsequent analysis has focused on a more ambitious target of 450 ppm CO2e or similar.26 Several large-scale modelling exercises have suggested that such a target is both feasible and not much more expensive.27 But other studies are more sceptical.28 Estimates depend on assumptions about fossil fuel prices, the menu of technologies that will be available and the degree of substitutability in production and consumption. Similarly, detailed engineering estimates of potential energy and emission savings have pointed to policy measures with negative costs over time (but perhaps negative cash flows initially), while some economists have been sceptical about the existence of free lunches of this sort. At the moment, it seems reasonable to conclude that climate change mitigation is likely to involve costs overall, but that well-designed policies and incentives could bring these costs down substantially. Good policy entails implicit or explicit carbon pricing but also measures to tackle market and government failures, not least underinvestment in low-carbon technological development, especially in areas of greater relative importance for LDCs such as agricultural practices and forest management, where technical assistance from countries with stronger research capabilities is important. One aspect of good policy design is to ensure that there is what, where, when flexibility to keep costs down, with firms and public agencies able to choose which greenhouse gas emissions to cut, the geographical and industrial location of the cuts, and the timing of the cuts, subject to a credible and stable long-term climate change policy framework. In the jargon of economists, minimising costs requires that the marginal costs of additional emissions reductions are the same wherever they take place.29 With respect to location, the 2010 World Bank World Development Report (World Bank, 2010) pointed out that if participation by developing countries is delayed until 2050 or after, that could double the costs of hitting any given atmospheric stabilisation target. An international agreement covering only the five jurisdictions with the highest total emissions (accounting for two thirds of emissions) would triple the cost of achieving a target.30 Developing countries offer similar opportunities for zero- or negative-cost mitigation as do industrial countries, but more options at low-cost, mainly in agriculture and forestry, as Chart 1 below indicates. These estimates have to be treated with caution. They do not fully take into account the macroeconomic effects and relative price changes likely to be induced by ambitious climate change policies; they may underestimate the costs of surmounting barriers preventing the take-up of negative-cost options; and they do not reflect the difficulties of financing investments for which the pay-offs arrive much later.31 But they are consistent with the economic argument that the correction of market and policy failures can produce some very cheap mitigation. And the rank ordering of options assessed on a consistent basis is helpful for policy-makers.

10

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

Chart 1: Marginal mitigation costs in developing and high-income countries

Source: World Bank (2010), Figure 1.3(a), based on data from McKinsey & Company.

So, as far as the location of emission cuts are concerned, developing countries in general offer the world several low- or no-cost options for emissions reductions. The narrower group of LDCs offers somewhat less scope, given their low levels of energy- and industry-related emissions, but the opportunities in agriculture and forestry are substantial, especially relative to their levels of GDP. This is good news for two reasons. First, it means that some mitigation in LDCs (for example, by improving forest management, introducing local solar power and reducing the use of unmanaged traditional biomass for heating and cooking) could raise their productivity and employment while improving access to energy, providing an incentive for LDC authorities themselves to adopt low-carbon growth strategies. Second, it provides an incentive to industrial countries to pay for emissions reductions in LDCs, reducing their own mitigation costs while providing a stream of finance and technology for LDCs.32 Such payments are essential if minimising the global costs of mitigation is to go hand in hand with an equitable distribution of those costs.33 The payments can be generated through agreements and mechanisms such as the Clean Development Mechanism, Reduced Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation and the proposed Copenhagen Green Fund. Some of the burden to high-income countries will also be carried in the form of higher prices for imports from developing countries of high-carbon-content products (which should be subject to carbon pricing or taxation in the developing countries themselves, so that they benefit from the resultant revenue) and their low-carbon replacements (which are likely to be more expensive initially than high-carbon ones, in the absence of carbon pricing). Some policy-makers have argued that a uniform global carbon price would entail much larger payments than necessary to those providing cheap mitigation opportunities. They have, in effect, argued for price discrimination, paying only just enough to get the mitigation done; that way, a given amount of climatepolicy expenditure can be leveraged to have a bigger environmental effect. But the implication is that the carbon price implicit in various financing arrangements of potential benefit to LDCs would be lower than elsewhere (for example, the EU Emissions Trading System), reducing the funds available to LDCs. There are major dangers in this approach, in particular, the danger that the carbon price at the abatement margin that is implicit in separate agreements for REDD or specific industries will not be high enough to achieve enough mitigation particularly if it turns out that some supposed negative-cost options are in fact costly, because of unanticipated transactions and implementation costs.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

11

4. A low-carbon development path for poor countries


The main development objective for LDCs remains the achievement, and subsequent consolidation, of the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs), which UN member states adopted in 2001. There has been considerable progress on poverty alleviation since then, but as the 2015 deadline for the MDGs approaches, it is clear that the performance in many areas is still badly off track. This is particularly the case for subSaharan Africa (see Annex 1), and it is why the MDGs remain the top priority for low-income countries. Climate change does not alter these fundamental objectives, but it may affect the way in which the MDGs are reached. The objective is no longer just development, but development that is low-carbon and also resilient to climate change. The three challenges of poverty alleviation, emission abatement and climate change adaptation have to be considered together; there will be synergies but also trade-offs among them. The previous section showed how these three issues are intertwined. In this section we try to give a sense what low-carbon development might mean in specific sectors and for particular development issues. The conclusions are, unavoidably, generic, given the short length of this paper. Actual low-carbon development plans will have to be much more detailed and of course country-specific. They will have to take into account the particular socio-economic circumstances of countries and their approach to economic growth, employment, education, public health, social protection, energy security, trade and industrial development. Many developing countries have already embarked on such plans: Brazil, China, India and South Africa are perhaps the most prominent examples. Unlike traditional development plans, they do not necessarily have the development needs of poor people at their centre and instead focus on identifying the cheapest emission reduction options from a cost curve.34 But they tell us unequivocally that the low-carbon challenge in poor countries is fundamentally different from that in rich countries. In high-income countries, decarbonisation is about changes to power generation, the redesign of electricity grids, cuts in industrial emissions, residential energy efficiency and new approaches to transport. Capital-intensive and technologically sophisticated options are available. In LDCs, the decarbonisation challenges are in land-use change, electrification, private-sector development and access to basic services, such as the provision of heat, light and water, as these are where emissions would be most likely to rise initially in the event of high-carbon development. Labour is more plentiful relative to capital and employment-creating opportunities are generally more valuable. As low-income countries move beyond the MDGs, we will see the emergence of a middle class with middleclass aspirations and consumption patterns. This will create pressure on emissions of the kind we already see in developed countries and increasingly in middle-income countries like China. But, for the poorest countries of the world this point is still a long way off; per capita incomes are still much lower and the power, industry and transport sectors of their economies are much less important.35 When they reach it, low-carbon technologies will hopefully be more developed and widely available, allowing them to realise their development ambitions within the global carbon constraint. In the meantime, the main link between climate change and development is through adaptation. Mitigation, especially in agriculture and land-use, at least partly paid for by developed countries, and implicit or explicit carbon pricing to give the right long-term signals are desirable, but the balance between spending on mitigation and adaptation is likely to be much more skewed towards adaptation. Poor countries are more vulnerable to climate change not only because they are exposed to more severe impacts although many are but also because their institutional and socio-economic capacity to adapt is insufficient (Barr et al., 2010).36 Basic indicators of socio-economic development such as educational attainment, good health care, safe drinking water, access to credit and competent government institutions are all associated with higher resilience to and lower impacts from extreme weather events (see, for example, World Bank, 2010). Few, if any, aspects of this agenda are associated with excessive greenhouse gas emissions.

12

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

In contrast, access to energy is an obvious area of friction between development and carbon emissions. Worldwide, some 1.6 billion people still do not have access to electricity, and 2.6 billion rely on firewood for cooking (World Bank, 2010). Although there is no MDG on energy, we know that access to modern forms of energy is central to development and poverty alleviation (Modi et al, 2005). Electricity is essential to provide basic services such as education, health care and safe drinking water, and for all entrepreneurial activity. The World Bank reckons that providing modern sources of energy (predominantly from the primary use of fossil fuels) to everybody would add no more than 2% to global CO2 emissions. It seems a small price to pay, compared with the huge development benefits. Electric energy today makes up only 5% of carbon emissions in low-income countries, compared with 38% in rich countries (World Bank, 2010). Moreover, bringing electricity to LDCs need not necessarily incur excessive carbon emissions. A large part of the challenge is rural electrification, and we know that, in remote areas with dispersed demand and low levels of consumption, renewable energy sources, such as solar PV, can already compete with fossil fuelbased solutions such as diesel generators or the extension of the electricity grid. Creating solar PV markets in LDCs poses financial and institutional challenges (for example, to establish reliable dealerships and provide finance for upfront costs), but experience with the technology is growing and it shows that solar PV is cost-competitive. The World Bank is supporting projects in 30 countries that will bring electricity to 1.3 million households (IFC, 2007). Where electricity grids exist, the key challenge often is to make them more reliable, reduce outages and cut transmission and distribution losses. In other words, there is significant scope for energy efficiency improvements in low-income countries as well, by improving infrastructure investment and management usually involving public spending and regulation. However, the institutional challenges, capacity gaps and financial barriers to realise this potential are invariably large and will require effective assistance from the development community. It is also clear that not all trade-offs can be avoided, as the controversy over the approval of South Africas Medupi power station prospectively the worlds largest coal-fired power plant shows. There will be (potentially substantial) demand for increased power generation capacity in low-income countries, much of it probably from conventional hydrocarbon sources. The onus will be on rich countries to ensure that highcarbon power plants can in due course be retrofitted with carbon capture and storage technology and to pay the associated extra cost. Until energy demand picks up, the most important source of greenhouse gas emissions in low-income countries remains, by some distance, land-use change and forestry. Together it accounts for 50% of lowincome country emissions (World Bank, 2010). Reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation is often seen as one of the cheapest options to halt global warming. Inclusive, sustainable forest management is also a crucial, pro-poor development measure. Reducing forest loss is one of the indicators for MDG 7 on sustainable development (Annex 1) and a key priority of global development assistance. The importance of this goal is easy to see. Forests are critical sources of income and well-being for many poor people. An estimated 735 million people live in or near tropical forests and depend on them for their livelihood. The link between poverty and deforestation is, however, complex (Chomitz, 2007). Rich and poor people alike contribute to forest loss, and deforestation can both increase and reduce poverty levels. Even more complex than the deforestationpoverty link are the social, economic and institutional factors that underlie deforestation. They include ill-defined property rights over forest assets, government capture by vested interests, large-scale corruption and, crucially, the undervaluation of ecosystem services. Forests create financial revenues as a source of food and timber, but not for the spiritual value, climate regulation and biodiversity services they also provide. The single most important cause of forest loss, though, is agricultural expansion. High-value activities like palm oil production and cattle ranching can yield revenues in excess of $3,000 per hectare (Grieg Gran, 2008), much more than standing trees unless their carbon and ecosystem value can be factored in and monetised.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

13

This is why proposals to pay for reduced emissions from deforestation and forest degradation (REDD) under the emerging new global climate change regime are important. They might tilt the economic balance between cutting trees down and leaving them standing. The renewed willingness to tackle deforestation and to fund this effort internationally provides a unique opportunity to tackle this decades-old issue. However, the intricate nature of the problem and the deep political and economic constraints should not be underestimated, particularly if REDD creates attractive new opportunities for rent seeking. Pressure to increase agricultural output is also putting increased stress on ecosystem and forest resources. Agriculture contributes more than 20% to the gross domestic product of low-income countries and accounts for about the same amount of their greenhouse gas emissions (World Bank, 2010). For many low-income families, it is their main source of income and subsistence. Although the share of agriculture in GDP will fall as nations grow richer and diversify, increasing agricultural productivity is an important development challenge going forward. It is essential to meet development goals on malnutrition and cater for a growing world population of perhaps 9 billion by 2050. Unsurprisingly, UK DFID sees agricultural productivity as one of eight key factors that underpin economic growth in developing countries (DFID, 2009). The unprecedented increase in agricultural output and productivity needed over the coming decades may be at odds with the demands of a low-carbon economy. The green revolution of the 1960s and 1970s achieved its productivity boost largely on the back of mechanisation, irrigation and fertilisation activities that could well increase the carbon footprint of agriculture. There is ample scope for productivity improvements through better farming practices and efficient management. Nevertheless, tackling agricultural emissions is an important challenge for low-carbon development, exacerbated potentially by a growing demand for biofuels and reduced agricultural yields as a result of climate change. Transport and industry make up a much smaller share of overall greenhouse gas emissions in LDCs, 11% of the total compared with 38% in high-income countries. Private-sector-led growth is a cornerstone of virtually all poverty reduction strategies (DFID, 2009), brought about by improvements in the business environment, better access to finance, support for small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) and the promotion of foreign investment. Better transport, communications and trade infrastructure is another integral part of this general thrust. We should therefore expect (and accept) that emissions from these sectors will rise. The challenge is to ensure that economically efficient production practices and standards are adopted that are likely to promote energy and carbon efficiency too.37 There are industrial abatement opportunities in all countries, including low-income countries. Despite suspicions of a race to the bottom, foreign investment can often be associated with more efficient production practices and the transfer of technologies.38 It may be more difficult to increase the environmental performance of SMEs, which contribute most to economic activity and provide the bulk of jobs in most countries. There is evidence that SMEs are often associated with inferior environmental performance (see Blackman, 2006). For both small and large firms, targeted policy measures and financial incentives will be crucial, including appropriate energy tariffs and particularly in the case of SMEs access to finance and technical know-how. Similar policies will also be needed to ensure firms adapt to a changing climate (Agrawala and Fankhauser, 2008).

14

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

5. Conclusions
The poorest countries of the world are greatly threatened by human-induced climate change. It is vital for them that the global community collectively acts to halt it.39 The new dangers make it all the more important that collective action also takes into account the development needs of LDCs, which are likely to be hit earliest and hardest while having the least capacity for adaptation. The three major challenges of limiting climate change, adapting to its consequences and reducing poverty have to be faced together. That requires financial support from rich countries to help promote LDCs resilience and adaptive capacity. It also requires that LDCs eventually follow a development path that differs from both those trodden by todays industrial countries and those being explored by emerging-market economies at present. That too will require financial assistance from developed countries. There is no room in the long run for high-emission economies and high-carbon growth is unsustainable, given the possible consequences for fossil-fuel supplies and climate-change impacts. The most important source of greenhouse gas emissions in LDCs is land-use change, in particular deforestation. Halting forest loss is also a major development and local environmental issue and as such a key priority of low-carbon development. Synergies between poverty alleviation and emission reduction also exist in rural electrification, where renewable energy solutions such as solar PV are often cost-competitive with fossil-fuel based solutions. Elsewhere there may be trade-offs between development and low-carbon objectives, for example when it comes to transport and industrial development. Good transport links and a thriving private sector are essential for growth and development. Emissions from these sources may therefore increase, but it is important that the cleanest and most efficient technologies are deployed. Low-carbon growth paths appropriate to the needs of LDCs ought to be explored now, even though, in the near term, the emphasis must be on poverty alleviation and adaptation. Moving on to such paths is likely to entail higher resource costs initially. On grounds of equity, those extra costs should be borne largely by todays rich countries and by future generations, who if climate-change policies are successful will be better off and subject to much less risk than they would have been otherwise. That is why it is important that international negotiations focus on the financing needs of the LDCs. But lowcarbon growth for LDCs need not be solely a story about extra costs in the near term, with the promise of more sustainable development in the long term. The threat of climate change has cast more light on the importance of key failures in markets and governance and increases the urgency of tackling them in LDCs as in other countries. The poorest countries can benefit immediately from a greater focus on this task with a recognition of the need to correct underinvestment in appropriate technology development, a greater emphasis on resolving undefined or contested land rights, the provision of networks for the delivery of cleaner energy to the poor, and an appreciation of the co-benefits for health and the environment that could flow from low-carbon development strategies.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

15

REFERENCES
All websites were last accessed in August 2010. Agrawala, S. and S. Fankhauser (2008). Economic Aspects of Adaptation to Climate Change. Costs, Benefits and Policy Instruments. Paris: OECD. Aunan, K., et al. (2007). Benefits and Costs to China of a Climate Policy, Environment and Development Economics, Vol. 12, No. 3, pp. 471-497. Barr, R., S. Fankhauser and K. Hamilton (2010). The Allocation of Adaptation Funding. Policy Paper, Grantham Research Institute and Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy. London: London School of Economics. Blackman, A., ed. (2006). Small Firms and the Environment in Developing Countries: Collective Impacts, Collective Action. Washington, D.C.: RFF Press. Blanford, G.J., R.G. Richels and T.F. Rutherford (2009). Feasible Climate Targets: the Roles of Economic Growth, Coalition Development and Expectations, Energy Economics, Vol. 31 (December), Supplement 2, pp. S82-S93. Bowen, A., et al. (2009). An Outline of the Case for a Green Fiscal Stimulus. Policy Brief, Grantham Research Institute and Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy. London: London School of Economics. Bowen, A., et al. (2009). The Implications of the Economic Slowdown for Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Targets. Policy Paper, Grantham Research Institute and Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy. London: London School of Economics. Burgess, R., et al. (2009). Weather and Death in India. Mimeo, MIT. Burniaux, J.M., et al. (2009). The Economics of Climate Change Mitigation: How to Build the Necessary Global Action in a Cost-Effective Manner. Paris: OECD. Chandler, W., et al. (2002). Climate Change Mitigation in Developing Countries. Washington, D.C.: Pew Center on Global Climate Change. Chomitz, K. (2007). At Loggerheads: Agricultural Expansion, Poverty Reduction and Environment in the Tropical Forests. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. Collier, P. (2008). The Bottom Billion. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Dasgupta, P. (2008). Discounting Climate Change. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, Vol. 37, pp.141169. Dell, M., B.F. Jones and B.A. Olken (2008). Climate Shocks and Economic Growth: Evidence from the Last Half Century, NBER Working Paper No. 14132. DFID (2009). Growth: Building Jobs and Prosperity in Developing Countries. London: Department for International Development. Easterly, W. (2001). The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. EBRD (2005). Transition Report 2005: Business in Transition. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Edenhofer, O., et al. (2009). The Economics of Decarbonization. Report of the RECIPE Project. Potsdam: PotsdamInstitute for Climate Impact Research. Ellis, K., B. Baker and A. Lemma (2009). Policies for Low Carbon Growth. London: Overseas Development Institute. Erickson, P., C. Heaps and M. Lazarus (2009). Greenhouse Gas Mitigation in Developing Countries. Stockholm Environment Institute, Working Paper WP-US-03, June.

16

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

Grieg Gran, M. (2008). The Cost of Avoiding Deforestation. An Update of the Report Prepared for the Stern Review. London: International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED). Hallegatte, S., J.-C. Hourcade and P. Dumas (2007). Why Economic Dynamics Matter in Assessing Climate Change Damages: Illustration on Extreme Events. Ecological Economics, Vol. 62, pp. 330-340. Hardin, G. (1968). The Tragedy of the Commons. Science, Vol. 162, pp. 1243-1248. Hulme, M., et al. (eds) 2009. Adaptation and Mitigation Strategies: Supporting European Climate Policy. The Final Report from the ADAM Project. Norwich: Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research, University of East Anglia. Revised June 2009. IFC (2007). Selling Solar. Lessons from More than a Decade of IFCs Experience. Washington, D.C.: International Finance Corporation. IPCC (2007). Fourth Assessment Report: Climate Change, www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm#1 Jones, B.F., and B.A. Olken (2010). Climate Shocks and Exports. NBER Working Paper No. 15711, January. Lomborg, B. (ed.) (2009). Global Crises, Global Solutions, 2nd edition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mabey, N. and R. McNally (1998). Foreign Direct Investment and the Environment: From Pollution Havens to Sustainable Development. Godalming: WWF-UK. McCarthy, J., et al. (eds) (2001). Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Modi, V., et al. (2005). Energy Services for the Millennium Development Goals. Washington, D.C.: Energy Sector Management Assistance Programme. Nordhaus, W. (2008). A Question of Balance. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Project Catalyst (2009). Low Carbon Growth Plans. Advancing Good Practice. www.project-catalyst.info. Quah, D. (1996). Twin Peaks: Growth and Convergence in Models of Distribution Dynamics. CEP Discussion Paper No. 280. London: Centre for Economic Performance. Richardson, K. et al (2009). Synthesis Report: Climate Change: Global Risks, Challenges and Decisions. International Alliance of Research Universities. http://climatecongress.ku.dk/pdf/synthesisreport. Schelling, T.C. (1997). The Cost of Combating Global Warming. Foreign Affairs, November/December. Schelling, T.C. (2007). Climate Change: The Uncertainties, the Certainties, and What They Imply About Action. Economists Voice (July), pp. 1-5. Shalizi, Z., and F. Lecocq (2009). To Mitigate or to Adapt: Is that the Question? Observations on an Appropriate Response to the Climate Change Challenge to Development Strategies. World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 25, No. 2, pp. 295-321. Smarzynska, B. and S.J. Wei (2001). Pollution Haven and Foreign Direct Investment: Dirty Secret or Popular Myth. NBER Working Paper 8465, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Stern, D.I. (2004). The Rise and Fall of the Environmental Kuznets Curve. World Development, Vol. 32, No. 8, pp. 1419-1439. Stern, N. (2007). The Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wise, M.A., et al. (2009). Implications of Limiting CO2 Concentrations for Land Use and Energy. Science, Vol. 324, No. 5931, pp. 1183-1186. World Bank (2010). World Development Report 2010. Development and Climate Change. Oxford: Oxford University Press. World Resources Institute (2010). Climate Analysis Indicators Tool http://cait.wri.org Washington D.C.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

17

NOTES
1

SeeDell,JonesandOlken(2008).JonesandOlken(2010)alsofindthathightemperaturesinpoorcountrieshaveanadverse effectontheirexports,especiallyagriculturalandlightmanufacturingexports. SeeBurgessetal(2009)onIndia. Hallegatteetal(2007). Stern(2007)andIPCC(2007)describemanyofthelikelydevelopmentsandthenonnegligiblerisksofevenworseoutcomes. Richardsonetal(2009).

2 3 4 5 6

WRICAITdatabase,accessed12August2010.Internationalbunkersincluded.Cumulativedataarefortheperiod1850to2006. LDCscompriseforthispurpose:Afghanistan,Angola,Bangladesh,Benin,Bhutan,BurkinaFaso,Burundi,Cambodia,CapeVerde, CentralAfricanRepublic,Chad,Comoros,CongoDem.Republic,Djibouti,EquatorialGuinea,Eritrea,Ethiopia,Gambia,Guinea, GuineaBissau,Haiti,Kiribati,Laos,Lesotho,Liberia,Madagascar,Malawi,Maldives,Mali,Mauritania,Mozambique,Myanmar, Nepal,Niger,Rwanda,Samoa,SaoTome&Principe,Senegal,SierraLeone,SolomonIslands,Sudan,Tanzania,Togo,Uganda, Vanuatu,YemenandZambia.


7

Sourceasinfootnote6.DataonemissionsfromlandusechangeandforestryarenotavailableformanyindividualLDCs,butthe differencebetweentotalemissionsperheadforLDCsasagroupandfortheworldasawholeisestimatedtobeverysimilartothe differenceexcludinglandusechangeandforestry,eventhoughtheseactivities(togetherwithagriculture)aremoreimportantfor LDCs.

Peopledifferaboutwhatwouldbeafairdistributionofthecostsofclimatechangemitigation.Thedegreeofaversionto inequalityiscrucial.Stern(2007)offeredestimatesofthecostsofclimatechangeusinganassumptionthatimpliesthatpeople shouldpaybroadlyinproportiontotheirpercapitaconsumptionforclimatechangemitigation.Carbonpricingwithoutincome transferswouldbeunfairifcarbonintensiveproductssuchasenergyaccountedforalargershareofpoorpeoplesthanofrich peoplesconsumption.Someeconomists,suchasDasgupta(2008),havearguedthatpolicymakersshouldbemoreaverseto inequalitythanwasStern,implyingthatlargertransferstopoorpeopleareneededtopayfortheclimatemitigationcoststhey wouldotherwisebear. SeeBowenetal,2009.Therelationshipdoesnotdisappearathighlevelsofincomepercapitaifproperallowanceismadefor pasttechnicalprogressandtechnologychoice.Inotherwords,theredoesnotappeartobearobustenvironmentalKuznetsCurve phenomenonforCO2emissions(seethediscussioninStern,2004). Butcarbonintensityvarieswidelyacrosscountries;in2006,thecarbonintensityofelectricityproductionvariedfrom1842.6 gCO2eperkWhinBotswanato1.4gCO2eperkWhinMozambique. WRICAITdatabaseaccessed4May2010. SeeHardin(1968).

10

11 12 13

Asdocumented,forexample,bytheresearchdiscussedinCollier(2008).Collierstresseshowsuchfactorsinhibitgrowthinmany LDCs,hometothebottombillion,partlybypreventinggoodgovernance,institutionbuildingandprovisionofpublicgoods.

14

TheOECDandIEAhavedetailedthehighcostsofenergysubsidies(seethediscussioninBurniauxetal,2009).Thesemaybe motivatedtosomeextentbyconcernsabouttheaccesstoenergybythelesswelloff(theissueofenergypoverty)butitisfar fromclearthatthepoorarethemainbeneficiaries.Inanycase,directfinancialtransfersandmicroloanstothepoormaybemore effectiveintacklingpovertyaswellasmoreefficientfromthepointofviewofthestructureoftheeconomy. QuotedinWorldBank(2009).

15 16

Blanfordetal(2009)andWiseetal(2009)illustrateinaglobalframeworkthedangersofbiofuelproductiondisplacingforests andfoodproductionindevelopingcountries,severelydistortinggloballanduse,intheabsenceofappropriateclimatechange mitigationpoliciesinthosecountries.

17

Theseadditionalfundsarewarrantedtomaketheincidenceofmitigationandadaptationcostsfairer;theresponsibilityof developedcountriesforthelionsshareofpastgreenhousegasemissionsstrengthensthecase.

18

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

18

Similarly,thereisnoreasonwhytheusesoffundslabelledODAshouldbeentirelyunaffectedbytherealisationthatclimate changeisamoreseriousthreatthanpreviouslythought.Inpractice,earmarkingseemstobeacrudewayoffacilitatingmonitoring bydonorcountries,inparticulartoensurethatrecipientsdonotfreerideonemissionscutbacksbydevelopednations.

19

But,justasenergysubsidiessupportingfossilfuelusedonotnecessarilyhelpthepoorest,particularlyifadequateenergysupply isnotforthcomingatsubsidisedprices,pricingcarbonneednotharmthepoorestifcombinedwithastrategytopromotelocally generatedrenewableenergyandenergyefficiency. AnNGOprovidingpolicyanalysisandadvicetopartiesinvolvedintheUNFCCCnegotiations(www.projectcatalyst.info) See,forexample,Schelling(1997,2007).

20 21 22

ArelatedcritiqueofclimatechangemitigationpolicyhasemergedfromLomborgandthesocalledCopenhagenConsensus (Lomborg(ed.),2009).Thisdrawsattentiontothehigherbenefitcostratiosfromseveralalternativedevelopmentpolicies. However,theapproachtoclimatechangepolicytakentheremakesinsufficientallowanceforriskandinequalityaversionorthe uncertaintiesaboutthedangersofclimatecatastrophes.Also,Lomborgisremarkablysanguineinassumingahighlikelihoodofa zerocarbonenergytechnologysoondisplacinghydrocarbonswithoutaggressivecarbonpricing. Schellinghimselfarguesfortheneedtoactimmediatelytomitigate,eventhoughheislesskeenontheideaofaglobal greenhousegasatmosphericconcentrationtargetunchangingovertime. Quah(1996).

23

24 25

SeeCollier,op.cit.Flowsofdevelopmentassistanceseemlowerthanwarrantedbythedegreeofinequalityaversionassumedby Stern(andevenmoreDasgupta)incalculatingtheexpectedcostsofclimatechange,Equityconsiderationswouldseemtopointto theneedformoreredistributionfromtherichtothepoorwithingenerations,butlessredistributionfromcurrenttofuture generationsoncetheclimatechangeexternalityhasbeenaddressedthatis,lesssavingtobequeathcapitaltofuturegenerations. Theimplicationforcapitalaccumulationincurrentlypoorcountriesisambiguous.

26

Therehasstillbeenremarkablylittleeconomicanalysisofwhethertheadvantagesofhavingatargetof450ppmCO2einsteadof, say,550ppm,outweightheadditionalcosts.Someeconomistswhohavestudiedthisquestionremainsceptical,whileagreeingthat appropriateactionismuchbetterthannoaction(e.g.Nordhaus,2008). See,forexample,thereportsoftheADAMandRECIPEprojects,Hulmeetal(ed.s),2009,availableatwww.adamproject.eu/,and Edenhoferetal,2009,availableatwww.pikpotsdam.de/,respectively.

27

Someofthepapersforthe22ndStanfordEnergyModelingForumsuggestthatitmaybeimpossibletostabiliseat450ppmCO2e. SeethespecialissueofEnergyEconomics,Vol.31,Supplement2,December2009,availableviaemf.stanford.edu/
29 30 31

28

Themarginalcostsshouldriseovertime,inlinewitharisingcommonglobalcarbonprice. WorldBank(2009),pp.5556.

Fightinghumaninducedclimatechangeentailssignificantinvestmentflows.Globally,thatmeansthateitherotherinvestment hastobedisplacedorprivateand/orpublicconsumptionhastobereduced,throughfiscalormonetarymeasures.Thatislikelyto addtothecostsofmitigationpolicycalculatedfrommarginalabatementcostcurves.

32

Carbonoffsetmarketsallowthistobedoneinadecentralisedway,buttheyarenottheonlyoption.Developedcountry governmentshaveanincentivetogivefinancialsupporttofundsthatwillprovidehelpfordecarbonisationindevelopingcountries. Buttargetsforemissionreductionsfinancedbydevelopedcountriesmustbestringentenough(togetherwithnationally appropriateactionsamongdevelopingcountries)togeneratetheglobalreductionsnecessary.Forsomedevelopedcountries,that mightentailfinancinglongrunreductionsgreaterthanthecurrentlevelofemissionsphysicallylocatedinthosecountries.

33

Seethediscussioninfootnote(8).Economistsoftenassumethatefficiencyandequitycanbetreatedseparately,butthisrestson anassumptionthatsidepaymentscanalwaysbemadetocorrectanyadversedistributionalconsequencesofimprovementsin efficiency.Thatassumptionisverystrong,particularlywhenpaymentsacrossbordersandacrosstimemaybenecessary.And paymentscansometimesinducenewinefficienciesbychangingincentivesandencouragingrentseeking. SeeProjectCatalyst(2009)forasummary.

34 35

AccordingtotheWorldBank(2009),power,transportationandindustryaccountedfor5%,4%and7%respectivelyoflow incomecountryGHGemissions,comparedwith26%,7%and16%inmiddleincomecountries.Incontrast,landusechangeand forestryaccountedfor50%,comparedwith23%.

36

Thedistinctionbetweenmitigationandadaptationisnotalwaysclearcut.Manyactivitiesdesignedtopromotedevelopment couldandshouldpromoteboth.Inthiscontext,itisunhelpfultoinsistonrigidearmarkingoffinancialassistanceforoneorother ortraditionaldevelopmentobjectives.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

19

37

Byeconomicallyefficient,wemeanthatproductioniscarriedoutatleastcostwhencostsarevaluedattheappropriateprices, whichmaydifferfromactualpricesiftherearemarketandregulatoryfailuresofwhichthefailuretopricecarbonemissionsis oneofthemostimportant.Thetermsenergyandcarbonefficiencyareusedintheloosersenseofloweruseofenergyandcarbon forgivenoutput. SeeEBRD(2005)andSmarzynskaandWei(2001).TheracetothebottomconcernwasexpressedeloquentlybyMabeyand McNally(1998). TheunfairdistributionofclimatechangeimpactswasanimportantreasonforconcernidentifiedbytheIPCCbackin2001 (McCarthyetal.,2001).

38

39

20

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

Annex 1: Progress with the Millennium Development Goals

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

21

22

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
We are grateful to Oxfam GB for initiating this paper and to Robert Bailey, Kirsty Hughes, Kate Raworth and their colleagues for their thoughtful and detailed comments. We would also like to acknowledge support by the Grantham Foundation for the Protection of the Environment, as well as the Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy, which is funded by the ESRC and Munich Re.

For Least Developed Countries, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

23

Oxfam International August 2011 This paper was written by Alex Bowen and Sam Fankhauser. Oxfam acknowledges the assistance of Sarah Best, Robert Bailey, Kirsty Hughes, Kate Raworth and their colleagues in its production. This publication is under copyright but text may be used free of charge for the purposes of advocacy, campaigning, education, and research, provided that the source is acknowledged in full. The copyright holder requests that all such use be registered with them for impact assessment purposes. For copying in any other circumstances, or for re-use in other publications, or for translation or adaptation, permission must be secured and a fee may be charged. E-mail publish@oxfam.org.uk. For further information on the issues raised in this paper please e-mail advocacy@oxfaminternational.org. The information in this publication is correct at the time of going to press. Published by Oxfam GB for Oxfam International under ISBN 978-1-84814-812-3 in August 2011. Oxfam GB, Oxfam House, John Smith Drive, Cowley, Oxford, OX4 2JY, UK. Oxfam is a registered charity in England and Wales (no 202918) and Scotland (SC039042). www.oxfam.org

Oxfam is an international confederation of fifteen organizations working together in 98 countries to find lasting solutions to poverty and injustice: Oxfam America (www.oxfamamerica.org), Oxfam Australia (www.oxfam.org.au), Oxfam-in-Belgium (www.oxfamsol.be), Oxfam Canada (www.oxfam.ca), Oxfam France - Agir ici (www.oxfamfrance.org), Oxfam Germany (www.oxfam.de), Oxfam GB (www.oxfam.org.uk), Oxfam Hong Kong (www.oxfam.org.hk), Oxfam India (www.oxfamindia.org), Intermn Oxfam (www.intermonoxfam.org), Oxfam Ireland (www.oxfamireland.org), Oxfam Mexico (www.oxfammexico.org), Oxfam New Zealand (www.oxfam.org.nz), Oxfam Novib (www.oxfamnovib.nl), Oxfam Quebec (www.oxfam.qc.ca)

The following organizations are currently observer members of Oxfam International, working towards full affiliation: Oxfam Japan (www.oxfam.jp) Oxfam Italy (www.oxfamitalia.org) Please write to any of the agencies for further information, or visit www.oxfam.org. Email: advocacy@oxfaminternational.org

www.oxfam.org/grow
24 www.oxfam.org/grow, Oxfam Discussion paper, Month Year

You might also like