You are on page 1of 169

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES

EXAM MLC ACTUARIAL MODELS

EXAM MLC SAMPLE SOLUTIONS

Copyright 2008 by the Society of Actuaries

Some of the questions in this study note are taken from past SOA examinations.

MLC-09-08 PRINTED IN U.S.A.


Question #1
Key: E

2 q30:34 = 2 p30:34 − 3 p30:34

2 p30 = ( 0.9 )( 0.8 ) = 0.72


2 p34 = ( 0.5 )( 0.4 ) = 0.20
2 p30:34 = ( 0.72 )( 0.20 ) = 0.144
2 p30:34 = 0.72 + 0.20 − 0.144 = 0.776
3 p30 = ( 0.72 )( 0.7 ) = 0.504
3 p34 = ( 0.20 )( 0.3) = 0.06
3 p30:34 = ( 0.504 )( 0.06 ) = 0.03024
3 p30:34 = 0.504 + 0.06 − 0.03024
= 0.53376

2 q30:34 = 0.776 − 0.53376


= 0.24224

Alternatively,

2 q30:34 = 2 q30 + 2 q34 − 2 q30:34

b
= 2 p30q32 + 2 p34q36 − 2 p30:34 1 − p32:36 g
= (0.9)(0.8)(0.3) + (0.5)(0.4)(0.7) – (0.9)(0.8)(0.5)(0.4) [1-(0.7)(0.3)]
= 0.216 + 0.140 – 0.144(0.79)
= 0.24224

Alternatively,

2 q30:34 = 3 q30 × 3 q34 − 2 q30 × 2 q34


= (1 − 3 p30 )(1 − 3 p34 ) − (1 − 2 p30 )(1 − 2 p34 )
= (1 − 0.504 )(1 − 0.06 ) − (1 − 0.72 )(1 − 0.20 )
= 0.24224

(see first solution for 2 p30 , 2 p34 , 3 p30 , 3 p34 )

MLC-09-08 -1-
Question #2
Key: E

1000 Ax = 1000 ⎡ Ax1:10 + 10 Ax ⎤


⎣ ⎦
= 1000 ⎡ ∫ e −0.04t e −0.06t (0.06)dt + e−0.4e−0.6 ∫ e−0.05t e−0.07t (0.07)dt ⎤
10 ∞
⎢⎣ 0 0 ⎥⎦

= 1000 ⎡ 0.06∫ e −0.1t dt + e −1 (0.07) ∫ e−0.12t dt ⎤


10 ∞

⎣⎢ 0 0 ⎦⎥
⎡ −0.10 t 10 −0.12 t ∞ ⎤
= 1000 ⎢ 0.06 ⎡ − e0.10 ⎤ + e −1 (0.07) ⎡ − e0.12 ⎤ ⎥
⎣ ⎣ ⎦0 ⎣ ⎦0 ⎦

= 1000 ⎡ 0.06 ⎡1 − e −1 ⎤ + 0.07 −1 ⎡ −1.2 ⎤ ⎤


⎦ 0.12 e ⎣1 − e ⎦ ⎦
⎣ 0.10 ⎣
= 1000 ( 0.37927 + 0.21460 ) = 593.87

Because this is a timed exam, many candidates will know common results for constant
force
and constant interest without integration.

μ
For example Ax1:10 = (1 − 10 Ex )
μ +δ
−10 ( μ +δ )
10 E x =e
μ
Ax =
μ +δ

With those relationships, the solution becomes


1000 Ax = 1000 ⎡⎣ Ax1:10 + 10 Ex Ax +10 ⎤⎦
⎡⎛
= 1000 ⎢⎜
0.06 ⎞
⎟ 1− e
⎣⎝ 0.06 + 0.04 ⎠
(
−( 0.06+ 0.04 )10
+e ( )
− 0.06+ 0.04 )10 ⎛

0.07 ⎞ ⎤
⎟⎥
⎝ 0.07 + 0.05 ⎠ ⎦

( )
= 1000 ⎡( 0.60 ) 1 − e −1 + 0.5833 e −1 ⎤⎥
⎣ ⎦
= 593.86

Question #3
Key: D

∞ ∞ 1
E [ Z ] = ∫ bt v t t p x μ ( x + t ) dt = ∫ e0.06 t e −0.08 t e−0.05 t dt
0 0 20
1 ⎛ 100 ⎞ −0.07 t ⎤ ∞ 5
= ⎜ ⎟⎣⎡ − e =
20 ⎝ 7 ⎠ ⎦ 0 7

MLC-09-08 -2-
(b v )
∞ ∞ 1 1 ∞
px μ ( x + t ) dt = ∫ e0.12t e−0.16t e−0.05t
2
E ⎡⎣ Z 2 ⎤⎦ = ∫ t
t
t dt = ∫ e−0.09t dt
0 0 20 20 0
1 ⎛ 100 ⎞ −0.09t ∞ 5
= ⎜ ⎟ ⎡e ⎤
⎦0 = 9
20 ⎝ 9 ⎠ ⎣
2
5 ⎛5⎞
Var [ Z ] = − ⎜ ⎟ = 0.04535
9 ⎝7⎠

Question #4
Key: C

Let ns = nonsmoker and s = smoker

q xb + kg pxb + kg q xb +gk px( +)k


ns ns s s
k=
0 .05 0.95 0.10 0.90
1 .10 0.90 0.20 0.80
2 .15 0.85 0.30 0.70

A x:2( ) = v q x( ) + px( ) qx( +1)


1 ns ns ns ns
v2
1 1
( 0.05) 0.95 × 0.10 = 0.1403
1.02 1.022

A x:2( ) qx( ) + v2 px( ) q x( +)1


1 s s s s
v
1 1
( 0.10 ) + 0.90 × 0.20 = 0.2710
1.02 (1.02 )2

A1x:2 = weighted average = (0.75)(0.1403) + (0.25)(0.2710)


= 0.1730

Question #5
Key: B

μ x(τ ) = μ x(1) + μ x( 2 ) + μ x( 3) = 0.0001045


px( ) = e −0.0001045t
τ
t

MLC-09-08 -3-

APV Benefits = ∫ e −δ t 1,000,000 t px ( ) μ x( ) dt
τ 1
0
∞ −δ t
500,000 t px ( ) μ x( ) dt
τ
+∫ e
2
0

+ ∫ e −δτ 200,000 t px ( ) μ x( ) dt
τ 3
0
1,000,000 ∞ −0.0601045t 500,000 ∞ −0.0601045t 250,000 ∞ −0.0601045t
= ∫
2,000,000 0
e dt + ∫
250,000 0
e dt +
10,000 ∫0
e dt

= 27.5 (16.6377 ) = 457.54

Question #6
Key: B


APV Benefits = 1000 A40:20
1
+ ∑ k E401000vq40+k
k = 20

APV Premiums = π a&&40:20 + ∑ k E401000vq40+k
k = 20
Benefit premiums ⇒ Equivalence principle ⇒
∞ ∞
1
1000 A40:20 + ∑ k E401000vq40+k = π a&&40:20 + ∑ k E401000vq40+k
k = 20 20

π = 1000 A40:
1
20
/ a&&40:20
161.32 − ( 0.27414 )( 369.13)
=
14.8166 − ( 0.27414 )(11.1454 )
= 5.11

While this solution above recognized that π = 1000 P40:20


1
and was structured to take
advantage of that, it wasn’t necessary, nor would it save much time. Instead, you could
do:

APV Benefits = 1000 A40 = 161.32



APV Premiums =π a&&40:20 + 20 E40 ∑ k E60 1000vq60+ k
k =0
= π a&&40:20 + 20 E40 1000 A60
= π ⎡⎣14.8166 − ( 0.27414 )(11.1454 ) ⎤⎦ + ( 0.27414 )( 369.13)
= 11.7612π + 101.19
11.7612π + 101.19 = 161.32
161.32 − 101.19
π= = 5.11
11.7612

MLC-09-08 -4-
Question #7
Key: C

ln (1.06 )
A70 = δ A70 = ( 0.53) = 0.5147
i 0.06
1 − A70 1 − 0.5147
a&&70 = = = 8.5736
d 0.06 /1.06
⎛ 0.97 ⎞
a&&69 = 1 + vp69a&&70 = 1 + ⎜ ⎟ ( 8.5736 ) = 8.8457
⎝ 1.06 ⎠
( 2)
a&&69 = α ( 2 ) a&&69 − β ( 2 ) = (1.00021)( 8.8457 ) − 0.25739
= 8.5902

Note that the approximation a&&x( ) ≅ a&&x −


m ( m − 1) works well (is closest to the exact answer,
2m
1
only off by less than 0.01). Since m = 2, this estimate becomes 8.8457 − = 8.5957
4

Question #8
Key: C

The following steps would do in this multiple-choice context:

1. From the answer choices, this is a recursion for an insurance or pure


endowment.
2. Only C and E would satisfy u(70) = 1.0.
1+ i
3. It is not E. The recursion for a pure endowment is simpler: u ( k ) = u ( k − 1)
pk −1
4. Thus, it must be C.

More rigorously, transform the recursion to its backward equivalent,


u ( k − 1) in terms of u ( k ) :

⎛ q ⎞ ⎛ 1+ i ⎞
u ( k ) = − ⎜ k −1 ⎟ + ⎜ ⎟ u ( k − 1)
⎝ pk −1 ⎠ ⎝ pk −1 ⎠
pk −1u ( k ) = − qk −1 + (1 + i ) u ( k − 1)
u ( k − 1) = vqk −1 + vpk −1 u ( k )

This is the form of (a), (b) and (c) on page 119 of Bowers with x = k − 1 . Thus, the
recursion could be:

MLC-09-08 -5-
Ax = vqx + vpx Ax +1
or A1x: y − x = vq x + vp x Ax1+1: y − x −1
or Ax: y − x = vqx + vpx Ax +1: y − x −1

Condition (iii) forces it to be answer choice C

u ( k − 1) = Ax fails at x = 69 since it is not true that


(
A69 = vq69 + vp69 (1) )
u ( k − 1) = A1x: y − x fails at x = 69 since it is not true that
1
A69:1 (
= vq69 + vp69 (1) )
u ( k − 1) = Ax: y − x is OK at x = 69 since

(
A69:1 = vq69 + vp69 (1) )
Note: While writing recursion in backward form gave us something exactly like page
119 of Bowers, in its original forward form it is comparable to problem 8.7 on page 251.
Reasoning from that formula, with π h = 0 and bh +1 = 1 , should also lead to the correct
answer.

MLC-09-08 -6-
Question #9
Key: A

You arrive first if both (A) the first train to arrive is a local and (B) no express arrives in
the 12 minutes after the local arrives.
P ( A) = 0.75
Expresses arrive at Poisson rate of ( 0.25 )( 20 ) = 5 per hour, hence 1 per 12 minutes.

e −110
f ( 0) = = 0.368
0!
A and B are independent, so
P ( A and B ) = ( 0.75 )( 0.368 ) = 0.276

Question #10
Key: E

d = 0.05 → v = 0.095

At issue

( ) ( )
49
A40 = ∑ v k +1 k q40 = 0.02 v1 + ... + v50 = 0.02v 1 − v50 / d = 0.35076
k =0

and a&&40 = (1 − A40 ) / d = (1 − 0.35076 ) / 0.05 = 12.9848


1000 A40 350.76
so P40 = = = 27.013
a&&40 12.9848

( )
K ( 40 ) ≥ 10 = 1000 A50 = 549.18 − ( 27.013)( 9.0164 ) = 305.62
Revised Revised
E 10 L − P40a&&50

where

( ) ( )
24
= ∑ v k +1 k q50
Revised Revised
A50 = 0.04 v1 + ... + v 25 = 0.04v 1 − v 25 / d = 0.54918
k =0

and
Revised
a&&50 = (1 − A
Revised
50 ) / d = (1 − 0.54918) / 0.05 = 9.0164

MLC-09-08 -7-
Question #11
Key: E

Let NS denote non-smokers and S denote smokers.

The shortest solution is based on the conditional variance formula

(
Var ( X ) = E Var ( X Y ) + Var E ( X Y ) ) ( )
Let Y = 1 if smoker; Y = 0 if non-smoker
1 − AxS
(
E aT Y = 1 = ax =
S
) δ
1 − 0.444
=
= 5.56
0.1
1 − 0.286
(
Similarly E aT Y = 0 =
0.1
= 7.14)
( (
E E aT Y ) ) = E ( E ( aT 0 ) ) × Prob ( Y=0 ) + E ( E ( aT 1) ) × Prob ( Y=1)
= ( 7.14 )( 0.70 ) + ( 5.56 )( 0.30 )
= 6.67

( (
E ⎡⎢ E aT Y )) ( ) ( )
2⎤
⎥⎦ = 7.14 ( 0.70 ) + 5.56 ( 0.30 )
2 2

= 44.96
( (
Var E aT Y ) ) = 44.96 − 6.672 = 0.47
E ( Var ( aT Y ) ) = ( 8.503)( 0.70 ) + ( 8.818 )( 0.30 )
= 8.60
( )
Var aT = 8.60 + 0.47 = 9.07

Alternatively, here is a solution based on


( )
Var(Y ) = E Y 2 − ⎡⎣ E (Y ) ⎤⎦ , a formula for the variance of any random variable. This
2

can be
( )
transformed into E Y 2 = Var (Y ) + ⎡⎣ E (Y ) ⎤⎦ which we will use in its conditional form
2

(( )
E aT
2
) (
NS = Var aT NS + ⎡ E aT NS ⎤
⎣ ⎦ ) ( )
2

Var ⎡⎣ aT ⎤⎦ = E ⎡ aT ( ) ( )
2⎤ 2
− E ⎡⎣ aT ⎤⎦
⎢⎣ ⎥⎦
E ⎡⎣ aT ⎤⎦ = E ⎡⎣ aT S⎤⎦ × Prob [S] + E ⎡⎣ aT NS⎤⎦ × Prob [ NS]

MLC-09-08 -8-
= 0.30axS + 0.70axNS

=
(
0.30 1 − AxS ) + 0.70 (1 − A ) NS
x

0.1 0.1
0.30 (1 − 0.444 ) + 0.70 (1 − 0.286 )
= = ( 0.30 )( 5.56 ) + ( 0.70 )( 7.14 )
0.1
= 1.67 + 5.00 = 6.67

( )
E ⎡ aT
2⎤
= E ⎡⎣ aT 2 S⎤⎦ × Prob [S] + E ⎡⎣ aT 2 NS⎤⎦ × Prob [ NS]
⎢⎣ ⎥⎦

( ( ) (
= 0.30 Var aT S + E ⎡⎣ aT S⎤⎦ ⎞⎟ )
2

( (
+0.70 Var aT NS + E aT NS ) ( )
2
)
= 0.30 ⎡8.818 + ( 5.56 ) ⎤ + 0.70 ⎡8.503 + ( 7.14 ) ⎤
2 2
⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦
11.919 + 41.638 = 53.557

Var ⎡⎣ aT ⎤⎦ = 53.557 − ( 6.67 ) = 9.1


2

1 − vT
Alternatively, here is a solution based on aT =
δ
⎛1 v ⎞ T
( )
Var aT = Var ⎜ − ⎟
⎝δ δ ⎠
⎛ − vT ⎞
= Var ⎜ ⎟ since Var ( X + constant ) = Var ( X )
⎝ δ ⎠

=
Var vT ( ) since Var ( constant × X ) = constant 2
× Var ( X )
δ2
Ax − ( Ax )
2 2

= which is Bowers formula 5.2.9


δ2

( )
This could be transformed into 2Ax = δ 2 Var aT + Ax2 , which we will use to get
2
Ax NS and 2AxS .

MLC-09-08 -9-
2
Ax = E ⎡⎣ v 2T ⎤⎦

= E ⎡⎣ v 2T NS⎤⎦ × Prob ( NS) + E ⎡⎣ v 2T S⎤⎦ × Prob ( S )

( ) ( )
= ⎡⎢δ 2 Var aT NS + Ax NS ⎤⎥ × Prob ( NS)
2

⎣ ⎦

( ) ( )
+ ⎢⎡δ 2Var aT S + AxS ⎥⎤ × Prob ( S)
2

⎣ ⎦
= ⎡⎣( 0.01)( 8.503) + 0.2862 ⎤⎦ × 0.70

+ ⎣⎡( 0.01)( 8.818 ) + 0.4442 ⎦⎤ × 0.30


= ( 0.16683)( 0.70 ) + ( 0.28532 )( 0.30 )
= 0.20238

Ax = E ⎡⎣ vT ⎤⎦

= E ⎡⎣ vT NS⎤⎦ × Prob ( NS) + E ⎡⎣ vT S⎤⎦ × Prob ( S)


= ( 0.286 )( 0.70 ) + ( 0.444 )( 0.30 )
= 0.3334
Ax − ( Ax )
2 2

( )
Var aT =
δ2
0.20238 − 0.33342
= = 9.12
0.01

Question #12
Key: A

To be a density function, the integral of f must be 1 (i.e., everyone dies eventually). The
solution is written for the general case, with upper limit ∞ . Given the distribution of
f 2 ( t ) , we could have used upper limit 100 here.

Preliminary calculations from the Illustrative Life Table:

l50
= 0.8951
l0
l40
= 0.9313
l0

MLC-09-08 - 10 -
∞ ∞
1 = ∫ fT ( t ) dt = ∫ k f1 ( t ) dt + ∫ 1.2 f 2 ( t )dt
50
0 0 50

f1 ( t ) dt + 1.2∫ f 2 ( t )dt
50
= k∫
0 50

= k F1 ( 50 ) + 1.2 ( F2 ( ∞ ) − F2 ( 50 ) )
= k (1 − 50 p0 ) + 1.2 (1 − 0.5 )
= k (1 − 0.8951) + 0.6
1 − 0.6
k= = 3.813
1 − 0.8951

For x ≤ 50, FT ( x ) = ∫ 3.813 f1 ( t ) dt = 3.813F1 ( x )


x
0

⎛ l ⎞
FT ( 40 ) = 3.813 ⎜ 1 − 40 ⎟ = 3.813 (1 − 0.9313) = 0.262
⎝ l0 ⎠
⎛ l ⎞
FT ( 50 ) = 3.813 ⎜ 1 − 50 ⎟ = 3.813 (1 − 0.8951) = 0.400
⎝ l0 ⎠
1 − FT ( 50 ) 1 − 0.400
p40 = = = 0.813
1 − FT ( 40 ) 1 − 0.262
10

Question #13
Key: D

Let NS denote non-smokers, S denote smokers.

Prob (T < t ) = Prob (T < t NS) × Prob ( NS ) + P rob (T < t S) × P rob ( S )

( ) (
= 1 − e −0.1t × 0.7 + 1 − e −0.2t × 0.3 )
= 1 − 0.7e −0.1t − 0.3 e −0.2t

S ( t ) = 0.3e−0.2 t + 0.7e−0.1t
Want tˆ such that 0.75 = 1 − S ( tˆ ) or 0.25 = S ( tˆ )

0.25 = 0.3e−2t + 0.7e −0.1t = 0.3 e−0.1t


ˆ ˆ
( ˆ 2
) + 0.7e−0.1t
ˆ

Substitute: let x = e −0.1t


ˆ

0.3 x 2 + 0.7 x − 0.25 = 0

MLC-09-08 - 11 -
−0.7 ± 0.49 + ( 0.3)( 0.25 ) 4
This is quadratic, so x =
2 ( 0.3)

x = 0.3147

e −0.1t = 0.3147
ˆ
so tˆ = 11.56

Question #14
Key: A

P ( Ax ) = μ = 0.03
μ 0.03
2
Ax = 0.20 = =
2δ + μ 2δ + 0.03
⇒ δ = 0.06
Ax − ( Ax ) 0.20 − ( 13 )
2 2 2

Var ( 0 L ) = = = 0.20
(δ a )2 ( 0.06
0.09 )
2

μ 0.03 1 1 1
where A = = = a= =
μ +δ 0.09 3 μ + δ 0.09

Question #15
Key: C

Let N = number of sales on that day


S = aggregate prospective loss at issue on those sales
K = curtate future lifetime

N~Poisson (0.2∗50) ⇒ E [ N ] = Var [ N ] = 10

0L = 10,000v K +1
− 500a&&K +1 ⇒ E [ 0 L ] = 10,000 A65 − 500a&&65
2
⎛ 500 ⎞ K +1 500 ⎛ 500 ⎞ ⎡ 2
⇒ Var [ 0 L ] = ⎜ 10,000 + ⎟ ⎣ A65 − ( A65 ) ⎦
2⎤
0 L = ⎜ 10,000 + ⎟v −
⎝ d ⎠ d ⎝ d ⎠

S = 0 L1 + 0 L2 + ... + 0 LN
E [ S ] = E [ N ] ⋅ E [ 0 L]

Var [ S ] = Var [ 0 L ] ⋅ E [ N ] + ( E [ 0 L ]) ⋅ Var [ N ]


2

MLC-09-08 - 12 -
⎛ 0 − E [S ] ⎞
Pr ( S < 0 ) = Pr ⎜ Z < ⎟

⎝ Var [ S ] ⎟

Substituting d = 0.06/(1+0.06), 2 A65 = 0.23603, A65 = 0.43980 and a&&65 = 9.8969 yields
E [ 0 L ] = −550.45
Var [ 0 L ] = 15,112,000
E [ S ] = −5504.5
Var [ S ] = 154,150,000

Std Dev (S) = 12,416


⎛ S + 5504.5 5504.5 ⎞
Pr ( S < 0 ) = Pr ⎜ <
⎝ 12,416 12, 416 ⎟⎠
= Pr ( Z < 0.443)
= 0.67

With the answer choices, it was sufficient to recognize that:


0.6554 = Φ ( 0.4 ) < Φ ( 0.443) < Φ ( 0.5 ) = 0.6915
By interpolation, Φ ( 0.443) ≈ ( 0.43) Φ ( 0.5 ) + ( 0.57 ) Φ ( 0.4 )
= ( 0.43)( 0.6915 ) + ( 0.57 )( 0.6554 )
= 0.6709

MLC-09-08 - 13 -
Question #16
Key: A

A40 161.32
1000 P40 = = = 10.89
a&&40 14.8166
⎛ a&& ⎞ ⎛ 11.1454 ⎞
1000 20V40 = 1000 ⎜ 1 − 60 ⎟ = 1000 ⎜ 1 − ⎟ = 247.78
⎝ a&&40 ⎠ ⎝ 14.8166 ⎠
( 20V + 5000 P40 ) (1 + i) − 5000q60
21V =
P60

=
( 247.78 + (5)(10.89) ) × 1.06 − 5000 ( 0.01376 ) = 255
1 − 0.01376

[Note: For this insurance, 20V = 1000 20V40 because retrospectively, this is identical to
whole life]

Though it would have taken much longer, you can do this as a prospective reserve.
The prospective solution is included for educational purposes, not to suggest it
would be suitable under exam time constraints.

1000 P40 = 10.89 as above


1000 A40 + 4000 20 E40 A60:5
1
= 1000 P40 + 5000 P40 × 20 E40 a&&60:5 + π 20 E40 × 5 E60 a&&65
1
where A60:5 = A60 − 5 E60 A65 = 0.06674
a&&40:20 = a&&40 − 20 E40 a&&60 = 11.7612
a&&60:5 = a&&60 − 5 E60 a&&65 = 4.3407
1000 ( 0.16132 ) + ( 4000 )( 0.27414 )( 0.06674 ) =
= (10.89 )(11.7612 ) + ( 5 )(10.89 )( 0.27414 )( 4.3407 ) + π ( 0.27414 )( 0.68756 )( 9.8969 )

161.32 + 73.18 − 128.08 − 64.79


π=
1.86544
= 22.32

Having struggled to solve for π , you could calculate 20 V prospectively then (as
above)
calculate 21V recursively.

20V = 4000 A60:5


1
+ 1000 A60 − 5000 P40 a&&60:5 − π 5 E60 a&&65
= ( 4000 )( 0.06674 ) + 369.13 − ( 5000 )( 0.01089 )( 4.3407 ) − ( 22.32 )( 0.68756 )( 9.8969 )
= 247.86 (minor rounding difference from 1000 20V40 )

MLC-09-08 - 14 -
Or we can continue to 21V prospectively

21V = 1
5000 A61:4 + 1000 4 E61 A65 − 5000 P40 a&&61:4 − π 4 E61 a&&65
l65 4 ⎛ 7,533,964 ⎞
where 4 E61 = v =⎜ ⎟ ( 0.79209 ) = 0.73898
l61 ⎝ 8,075, 403 ⎠

1
A61:4 = A61 − 4 E61 A65 = 0.38279 − 0.73898 × 0.43980
= 0.05779
a&&61:4 = a&&61 − 4 E61 a&&65 = 10.9041 − 0.73898 × 9.8969
= 3.5905

21V = ( 5000 )( 0.05779 ) + (1000 )( 0.73898 )( 0.43980 )


− ( 5 )(10.89 )( 3.5905 ) − 22.32 ( 0.73898 )( 9.8969 )
= 255

Finally. A moral victory. Under exam conditions since prospective benefit reserves
must equal retrospective benefit reserves, calculate whichever is simpler.

Question #17
Key: C

Var ( Z ) = 2 A41 − ( A41 )


2

A41 − A40 = 0.00822 = A41 − (vq40 + vp40 A41 )


= A41 − (0.0028 /1.05 + ( 0.9972 /1.05 ) A41 )
⇒ A41 = 0.21650

2
(
A41 − 2 A40 = 0.00433 = 2 A41 − v 2 q40 + v 2 p40 2 A41 )
( )
2
= 2 A41 − (0.0028 /1.052 + 0.9972 /1.052 A41 )
2
A41 = 0.07193

Var ( Z ) = 0.07193 − 0.216502


= 0.02544

MLC-09-08 - 15 -
Question #18
Key: D

This solution looks imposing because there is no standard notation. Try to focus on the
big picture ideas rather than starting with the details of the formulas.

Big picture ideas:


1. We can express the present values of the perpetuity recursively.
2. Because the interest rates follow a Markov process, the present value (at time t )
of the future payments at time t depends only on the state you are in at time t ,
not how you got there.
3. Because the interest rates follow a Markov process, the present value of the
future payments at times t1 and t2 are equal if you are in the same state at times
t1 and t2 .

Method 1: Attack without considering the special characteristics of this transition matrix.

Let sk = state you are in at time k ( thus sk = 0, 1 or 2 )

Let Yk = present value, at time k , of the future payments.


Yk is a random variable because its value depends on the pattern of discount factors,
which are random. The expected value of Yk is not constant; it depends on what state
we are in at time k.

Recursively we can write

Yk = v × (1 + Yk +1 ) , where it would be better to have notation that indicates the v’s are not
constant, but are realizations of a random variable, where the random variable itself has
different distributions depending on what state we’re in. However, that would make the
notation so complex as to mask the simplicity of the relationship.

Every time we are in state 0 we have


(
E ⎡⎣Yk sk = 0 ⎤⎦ = 0.95 × 1 + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk = 0 ⎤⎦ )
( {( )) (
= 0.95 × 1 + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk +1 = 0 ⎤⎦ × Pr ob s k+1 = 0 sk = 0] )
(
+ E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk +1 = 1⎤⎦ ) × Pr ob ( s k +1 = 1 s = 0])
k

= ( E ⎡⎣Y k +1 sk +1 = 2 ⎤⎦ ) × Pr ob ( s k +1 = 2 s = 0])}
k

(
= 0.95 × 1 + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk +1 = 1⎤⎦ )

MLC-09-08 - 16 -
That last step follows because from the transition matrix if we are in state 0, we always
move to state 1 one period later.

Similarly, every time we are in state 2 we have


(
E ⎡⎣Yk sk = 2 ⎤⎦ = 0.93 × 1 + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk = 2 ⎤⎦ )
(
= 0.93 × 1 + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk +1 = 1⎤⎦ )
That last step follows because from the transition matrix if we are in state 2, we always
move to state 1 one period later.

Finally, every time we are in state 1 we have


(
E ⎡⎣Yk sk = 1⎤⎦ = 0.94 × 1 + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk = 1⎤⎦ )
( { })
= 0.94 × 1 + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk +1 = 0 ⎤⎦ × Pr ⎡⎣ sk +1 = 0 sk = 1⎤⎦ + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk +1 = 2 ⎤⎦ × Pr ⎡⎣ sk +1 = 2 sk = 1⎤⎦

( { })
= 0.94 × 1 + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk +1 = 0 ⎤⎦ × 0.9 + E ⎡⎣Yk +1 sk +1 = 2 ⎤⎦ × 0.1 . Those last two steps follow
from the fact that from state 1 we always go to either state 0 (with probability 0.9) or
state 2 (with probability 0.1).

Now let’s write those last three paragraphs using this shorter notation:
xn = E ⎡⎣Yk sk = n ⎤⎦ . We can do this because (big picture idea #3), the conditional
expected value is only a function of the state we are in, not when we are in it or how we
got there.

x0 = 0.95 (1 + x1 )
x1 = 0.94 (1 + 0.9 x0 + 0.1x2 )
x2 = 0.93 (1 + x1 )

That’s three equations in three unknowns. Solve (by substituting the first and third into
the second) to get x1 = 16.82 .

That’s the answer to the question, the expected present value of the future payments
given in state 1.

The solution above is almost exactly what we would have to do with any 3 × 3 transition
matrix. As we worked through, we put only the non-zero entries into our formulas. But
if for example the top row of the transition matrix had been ( 0.4 0.5 0.1) , then the first
of our three equations would have become x0 = 0.95 (1 + 0.4 x0 + 0.5 x1 + 0.1x2 ) , similar in
structure to our actual equation for x1 . We would still have ended up with three linear
equations in three unknowns, just more tedious ones to solve.

Method 2: Recognize the patterns of changes for this particular transition matrix.

MLC-09-08 - 17 -
This particular transition matrix has a recurring pattern that leads to a much quicker
solution. We are starting in state 1 and are guaranteed to be back in state 1 two steps
later, with the same prospective value then as we have now.
Thus,
E [Y ] = E ⎡⎣Y first move is to 0 ⎤⎦ × Pr [ first move is to 0] + E ⎡⎣Y first move is to 2 ⎤⎦ × Pr [first move is to 2 ]

⎣ ( ⎦ ) ⎣ ⎣(
= 0.94 × ⎡ 1 + 0.95 × (1 + E [Y ] ⎤ × 0.9 + ⎡ 0.94 × ⎡ 1 + 0.93 × (1 + E [Y ]) × 0.1⎤

(Note that the equation above is exactly what you get when you substitute x0 and x2
into the formula for x1 in Method 1.)

= 1.6497 + 0.8037 E [Y ] + 0.1814 + 0.0874 E [Y ]


1.6497 + 0.1814
E [Y ] =
(1 − 0.8037 − 0.0874 )
= 16.82

Question #19
Key: E

The number of problems solved in 10 minutes is Poisson with mean 2.


If she solves exactly one, there is 1/3 probability that it is #3.
If she solves exactly two, there is a 2/3 probability that she solved #3.
If she solves #3 or more, she got #3.

f(0) = 0.1353
f(1) = 0.2707
f(2) = 0.2707

⎛1⎞ ⎛ 2⎞
P = ⎜ ⎟ ( 0.2707 ) + ⎜ ⎟ ( 0.2707 ) + (1 − 0.1353 − 0.2707 − 0.2707 ) = 0.594
⎝ 3⎠ ⎝ 3⎠

MLC-09-08 - 18 -
Question #20
Key: D

μ x(τ ) = μ x(1) ( t ) + μ x( 2 ) ( t )

= 0.2 μ x( ) ( t ) + μ x( ) ( t )
τ 2

⇒ μ x( ) ( t ) = 0.8μ x( ) ( t )
2 τ

1 k
− ∫ 0.2 k t 2
−0.2
qx( ) = 1 − px( ) = 1 − e 0
dt
= 1− e = 0.04
'1 '1 3

k
3 ⇒ ln (1 − 0.04 ) / ( −0.2 ) = 0.2041
k = 0.6123

( 2)
px( ) μ x( ) dt = 0.8∫ px( ) μ x( ) ( t ) dt
2 τ 2 τ τ
=∫
2
2 qx 0 t 0 t

= 0.8 2 qx( ) = 0.8 1 − 2 px( )


τ τ
( )
− ∫ μ x (t ) d t
2
(τ )
2 px = e
0

= e ∫0
− kt 2
dt

−8 k
= e 3
−( 8 ) ( 0.6123)
= e 3

= 0.19538

( 2)
2 qx = 0.8 (1 − 0.19538 ) = 0.644

Question #21
Key: A

k min(k ,3) f(k) f ( k ) × ( min(k ,3) ) f ( k ) × ⎡⎣ min ( k ,3) ⎤⎦


2

0 0 0.1 0 0
1 1 (0.9)(0.2) = 0.18 0.18 0.18
2 2 (0.72)(0.3) = 0.216 0.432 0.864
3+ 3 1-0.1-0.18-0.216 = 0.504 1.512 4.536
2.124 5.580

MLC-09-08 - 19 -
E [ min( K ,3) ] = 2.124

{
E ⎡⎣ min ( K ,3) ⎤⎦
2
} = 5.580
Var [ min( K ,3) ] = 5.580 − 2.1242 = 1.07

Note that E [ min( K ,3) ] is the temporary curtate life expectancy, ex:3 if the life is age x.
Problem 3.17 in Bowers, pages 86 and 87, gives an alternative formula for the variance,
basing the calculation on k px rather than k q x .

Question #22
Key: B

e ( )( ) + e ( )( )
− 0.1 60 − 0.08 60
s ( 60 ) =
2
= 0.005354
e ( )( ) + e ( )( )
− 0.1 61 − 0.08 61
s ( 61) =
2
= 0.00492
0.00492
q60 = 1 − = 0.081
0.005354

Question #23
Key: D

Let q64 for Michel equal the standard q64 plus c. We need to solve for c.
Recursion formula for a standard insurance:

20V45 = ( 19V45 + P45 ) (1.03) − q64 (1 − 20V45 )

Recursion formula for Michel’s insurance

20V45 = ( 19V45 + P45 + 0.01) (1.03) − ( q64 + c ) (1 − 20V45 )

The values of 19 V45 and 20V45 are the same in the two equations because we are told
Michel’s benefit reserves are the same as for a standard insurance.

Subtract the second equation from the first to get:

MLC-09-08 - 20 -
0 = − (1.03) (0.01) + c(1 − 20V45 )
(1.03) ( 0.01)
c=
(1 − 20V45 )
0.0103
=
1 − 0.427
= 0.018

Question #24
Key: B

K is the curtate future lifetime for one insured.


L is the loss random variable for one insurance.
LAGG is the aggregate loss random variables for the individual insurances.
σ AGG is the standard deviation of LAGG .
M is the number of policies.

⎛ ⎞ π
L = v K +1 − π a&&K +1 = ⎜ 1 + ⎟ v K +1 − π
⎝ d⎠ d

E [ L ] = ( Ax − π a&&x ) = Ax − π
(1 − Ax )
d
⎛ 0.75095 ⎞
= 0.24905 − 0.025 ⎜ ⎟ = −0.082618
⎝ 0.056604 ⎠
⎛ π⎞
( )
2 2
Var [ L ] = ⎜ 1 + ⎟
⎝ d⎠
( 2
Ax − Ax2 ) ⎛
= ⎜1 +
0.025 ⎞
⎟ 0.09476 − ( 0.24905 ) = 0.068034
⎝ 0.056604 ⎠
2

E [ LAGG ] = M E [ L ] = −0.082618M
Var [ LAGG ] = M Var [ L ] = M (0.068034) ⇒ σ AGG = 0.260833 M
⎡L − E [ LAGG ] − E ( LAGG ) ⎤
Pr [ LAGG > 0] = ⎢ AGG > ⎥
⎣ σ AGG σ AGG ⎦
⎛ 0.082618M ⎞
≈ Pr ⎜ N (0,1) > ⎟
⎜ M ( 0.260833) ⎟⎠

0.082618 M
⇒ 1.645 =
0.260833
⇒ M = 26.97

⇒ minimum number needed = 27

MLC-09-08 - 21 -
Question #25
Key: D

1 − v K +1
Annuity benefit: Z1 = 12,000 for K = 0,1, 2,...
d
Death benefit: Z 2 = Bv K +1 for K = 0,1, 2,...
1 − v K +1
New benefit: Z = Z1 + Z 2 = 12,000 + Bv K +1
d
12,000 ⎛ 12,000 ⎞ K +1
= +⎜B− ⎟v
d ⎝ d ⎠

2

Var( Z ) = ⎜ B −

12,000 ⎞
d ⎠
⎟ Var v
K +1
( )
12,000
Var ( Z ) = 0 if B = = 150,000 .
0.08

In the first formula for Var ( Z ) , we used the formula, valid for any constants a and b and
random variable X,

Var ( a + bX ) = b 2Var ( X )

Question #26
Key: A

μ xy ( t ) = μ x ( t ) + μ y ( t ) = 0.08 + 0.04 = 0.12


Ax = μ x ( t ) / ( μ x ( t ) + δ ) = 0.5714
( )
Ay = μ y ( t ) / μ y ( t ) + δ = 0.4
( )
Axy = μ xy ( t ) / μ xy ( t ) + δ = 0.6667
( )
axy = 1/ μ xy ( t ) + δ = 5.556

Axy = Ax + Ay − Axy = 0.5714 + 0.4 − 0.6667 = 0.3047


Premium = 0.304762/5.556 = 0.0549

MLC-09-08 - 22 -
Question #27
Key: B

P40 = A40 / a&&40 = 0.16132 /14.8166 = 0.0108878

P42 = A42 / a&&42 = 0.17636 /14.5510 = 0.0121201

a45 = a&&45 − 1 = 13.1121

E ⎡⎣ 3 L K ( 42 ) ≥ 3⎤⎦ = 1000 A45 − 1000 P40 − 1000 P42 a45


= 201.20 − 10.89 − (12.12 )(13.1121)
= 31.39

Many similar formulas would work equally well. One possibility would be
1000 3V42 + (1000 P42 − 1000 P40 ) , because prospectively after duration 3, this differs from
the normal benefit reserve in that in the next year you collect 1000 P40 instead of
1000 P42 .

MLC-09-08 - 23 -
Question #28
Key: E

E ⎡⎣ min (T ,40 ) ⎤⎦ = 40 − 0.005 ( 40 ) = 32


2

32 = ∫ t f ( t ) dt + ∫ 40 f ( t ) dt
40 w

0 40

= ∫ t f ( t ) dt − ∫ t f ( t ) dt + 40 (.6 )
w w

0 40

= 86 − ∫ tf ( t ) dt
w

40

∫ tf ( t )dt = 54
w

40

∫ ( t − 40 ) f ( t ) dt = 54 − 40 (.6 ) = 50
w

e° 40 = 40

s ( 40 ) .6

Question #29
Key: B

d = 0.05 ⇒ v = 0.95

Step 1 Determine px from Kevin’s work:


608 + 350vpx = 1000vqx + 1000v 2 px ( px +1 + qx +1 )
608 + 350 ( 0.95 ) px = 1000 ( 0.95 ) (1 − px ) + 1000 ( 0.9025 ) px (1)
608 + 332.5 px = 950 (1 − px ) + 902.5 px
px = 342 / 380 = 0.9

Step 2 Calculate 1000 Px:2 , as Kira did:


608 + 350 ( 0.95 )( 0.9 ) = 1000 Px:2 ⎡⎣1 + ( 0.95 )( 0.9 ) ⎤⎦

1000 Px:2 =
[ 299.25 + 608] = 489.08
1.855

The first line of Kira’s solution is that the actuarial present value of Kevin’s benefit
premiums is equal to the actuarial present value of Kira’s, since each must equal the
actuarial present value of benefits. The actuarial present value of benefits would also
have been easy to calculate as
( )
(1000 )( 0.95)( 0.1) + (1000 ) 0.952 ( 0.9 ) = 907.25

MLC-09-08 - 24 -
Question #30
Key: E

Because no premiums are paid after year 10 for (x), 11Vx = Ax +11

Rearranging 8.3.10 from Bowers, we get =


( hV + π h ) (1 + i ) − bh+1qx+ h
h +1V
px + h

=
( 32,535 + 2,078) × (1.05) − 100,000 × 0.011 = 35,635.642
10V
0.989
( 35,635.642 + 0 ) × (1.05) − 100,000 × 0.012 = 36,657.31 = A
11V = x +11
0.988

Question #31
Key: B

⎛ x⎞
For De Moivre’s law where s ( x ) = ⎜ 1 − ⎟ :
⎝ ω⎠

° ω−x ⎛ t ⎞
ex = and t px = ⎜ 1 − ⎟
2 ⎝ ω −x⎠
° 105 − 45
e45 = = 30
2
105 − 65
e°65 = = 20
2

° 40 40 60 − t 40 − t
e 45:65 = ∫ t p45:65dt = ∫ × dt
0 0 60 40

1 FG 60 + 40 2 1 3 IJ 40
=
60 × 40 H
60 × 40 × t −
2
t + t
3 K 0

= 1556
.

o o o o
e 45:65 = e 45 + e 65 − e 45:65
= 30 + 20 − 1556 . = 34

o
In the integral for e45:65 , the upper limit is 40 since 65 (and thus the joint status also)
can survive a maximum of 40 years.

MLC-09-08 - 25 -
Question #32
Answer: E

bg bg bg
μ 4 = − s' 4 / s 4

− d − e / 100i
4
=
1 − e4 / 100

e4 / 100
=
1 − e4 / 100

e4
=
100 − e4

= 1202553
.

Question # 33
Answer: A

τ g L ln px′ O bτ g LM ln e− μ OP
bi g bi g
b ig b
qx = qx M P =
M ln p bτ g P M ln e-μb g P
N x Q
q x
N
τ
Q
b τg μb g i
= q x × bτ g
μ

μ x bτ g = μ x b1g + μ x b 2 g + μ x b 3g = 15
.

q xbτ g = 1 − e − μ bτ g = 1 − e −1.5

=0.7769

q xb 2 g =
b0.7769gμ b2g
=
b0.5gb0.7769g
μ bτ g 15
.

= 0.2590

MLC-09-08 - 26 -
Question # 34
Answer: D

22 A 60 = v 3 × 2 p 60 × q 60 + 2 +
B B B
pay at end live then die
of year 3 2 years in year 3

+ v4 × 3p 60 × q60+ 3
pay at end live then die
of year 4 3 years in year 4

=
1
b103
. g
b1 − 0.09gb1 − 011
3
. gb013
. g+
1
b103
. g
b1 − 0.09gb1 − 011
4
. gb1 − 013
. gb015
. g

= 019
.

Question # 35
Answer: B

a x = a x:5 +5 E x a x +5

1 − e −0.07b5g
a x:5 = = 4.219 , where 0.07 = μ + δ for t < 5
0.07

5 Ex = e −0.07b5g = 0.705

1
a x +5 = = 12.5 , where 0.08 = μ + δ for t ≥ 5
0.08

b gb g
∴ a x = 4.219 + 0.705 12.5 = 13.03

MLC-09-08 - 27 -
Question #36
Key: D

px( ) = p ' x( ) p ' x( ) = 0.8 ( 0.7 ) = 0.56


τ 1 2

1 ( )
⎡ ln p ' (1) ⎤
qx( ) = ⎢
x
⎥ q(τ ) since UDD in double decrement table
⎢⎣ ( )
⎢ ln p(τ ) ⎥ x
x
⎦⎥
⎡ ln ( 0.8 ) ⎤
=⎢ ⎥ 0.44
⎣ ln ( 0.56 ) ⎦
= 0.1693
0.3qx( )
1
(1)
0.3 q x + 0.1 = = 0.053
1 − 0.1qx( )
τ

To elaborate on the last step:

⎛ Number dying from cause ⎞


⎜ ⎟
(1) ⎝ 1 between x + 0.1 and x + 0.4 ⎠
0.3 q x + 0.1 =
Number alive at x + 0.1

Since UDD in double decrement,


l x( ) ( 0.3) qx( )
τ 1
=
(
lx( ) 1 − 0.1qx( )
τ τ
)

MLC-09-08 - 28 -
Question #37
Key: E

P ( Ax ) =
1 1
− δ = − 0.04 = 0.04333
ax 12
o Le = o L + E

= v T − P ( Ax ) aT + co + ( g − e ) aT
⎛ 1− vT ⎞ ⎛ 1− vT ⎞
= v − P ( Ax ) ⎜
T
⎟ + co + ( g − e ) ⎜ ⎟
⎝ δ ⎠ ⎝ δ ⎠
⎛ P ( Ax ) ( g − e ) ⎞ P ( Ax ) ( g − e)
= v T ⎜1 + − ⎟− + co +
⎜ δ δ ⎟⎠ δ δ

⎛ P ( Ax ) ( g − e ) ⎞
2

Var ( o Le ) = Var v( )T
⎜1 +
⎜ δ

δ


⎝ ⎠

Above step is because for any random variable X and constants a and b,
Var ( a X + b ) = a 2 Var ( X ) .
Apply that formula with X = v T .

Plugging in,
⎛ 0.04333 ( 0.0030 − 0.0066 ) ⎞
2

Var ( o Le ) = ( 0.10 ) ⎜1 + − ⎟
⎝ 0.04 0.04 ⎠
= ( 0.10 )( 2.17325 )
2

= 0.472

Question #38
Key: D

⎛ 0.7 0.1 0.2 ⎞ ⎛ 0.52 0.13 0.35 ⎞


⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟
T = ⎜ 0.3 0.6 0.1 ⎟ T = ⎜ 0.39 0.39 0.22 ⎟
2

⎜ 0 1 ⎟⎠ ⎜ 0 1 ⎟⎠
⎝ 0 ⎝ 0

MLC-09-08 - 29 -
Actuarial present value (A.P.V.) prem = 800(1 + (0.7 + 0.1) + (0.52 + 0.13)) = 1,960
A.P.V. claim = 500(1 + 0.7 + 0.52) + 3000(0 + 0.1 + 0.13) = 1800
Difference = 160

MLC-09-08 - 30 -
Question # 39
Answer: D

Per 10 minutes, find coins worth exactly 10 at Poisson rate 0.5 0.2 10 = 1 b gb gb g
Per 10 minutes, f b0g = 0.3679 bg
F 0 = 0.3679
f b1g = 0.3679 bg
F 1 = 0.7358
f b2g = 01839
. bg
F 2 = 0.9197
f b3g = 0.0613 bg
F 3 = 0.9810

Let Period 1 = first 10 minutes; period 2 = next 10.

Method 1, succeed with 3 or more in period 1; or exactly 2, then one or more in period 2
c b gh b gc b gh b
P = 1 − F 2 + f 2 1 − F 0 = 1 − 0.9197 + 01839
. g b
1 − 0.3679 gb g
= 01965
.

Method 2: fail in period 1 if < 2; bg


Pr ob = F 1 = 0.7358
fail in period 2 if exactly 2 in period 1, then 0; bg bg
Pr ob = f 2 f 0
b gb
= 01839
. g
0.3679 = 0.0677
Succeed if fail neither period; Pr ob = 1 − 0.7358 − 0.0677
= 01965
.

(Method 1 is attacking the problem as a stochastic process model; method 2 attacks it


as a ruin model.)

Question # 40
Answer: D

Use Mod to designate values unique to this insured.

b g b g b gb g
a&&60 = 1 − A60 / d = 1 − 0.36933 / 0.06 / 106
. = 111418
.

1000 P60 = 1000 A60 / a&&60 = 1000b0.36933 / 111418


. g = 3315
.

d
A60Mod = v q60
Mod
+ p60
Mod
A61 = i .
1
106
.
01376 b gb g
+ 0.8624 0.383 = 0.44141

MLC-09-08 - 31 -
d i b
a&& Mod = 1 − A60Mod / d = 1 − 0.44141 / 0.06 / 106
. = 9.8684 g
d
E 0 LMod = 1000 A60Mod − P60a&&60
Mod
i
= 1000 0.44141 − 0.03315 9.8684 b g
= 114.27

Question # 41
Answer: D

The prospective reserve at age 60 per 1 of insurance is A60 , since there will be no
future premiums. Equating that to the retrospective reserve per 1 of coverage, we have:
&&s40:10
A60 = P40 + P50Mod &&s50:10 − 20 k40
10 E50

1
A a&&40:10 a&&50:10 A40:20
A60 = 40 × + P50Mod −
a&&40 10 E40 10 E50 10 E50 20 E40

016132
. 7.70 7.57 0.06
0.36913 = × + P50Mod −
b
14.8166 0.53667 0.51081 gb
0.51081 0.27414 g
0.36913 = 0.30582 + 14.8196 P50Mod − 0.21887

1000 P50Mod = 19.04

Alternatively, you could equate the retrospective and prospective reserves at age 50.
Your equation would be:

1
A40 a&&40:10 A40:10
A50 − P50Mod a&&50:10 = × −
a&&40 10 E40 10 E40

1
where A40:10
= A40 −10 E40 A50
= 016132
. b
− 0.53667 0.24905 gb g
= 0.02766

MLC-09-08 - 32 -
d
0.24905 − P50Mod 7.57 = ib g 14016132
.
×
7.70

0.02766
.8166 0.53667 0.53667
1000 P50Mod =
b gb
1000 014437
. g = 19.07
7.57

Alternatively, you could set the actuarial present value of benefits at age 40 to the
actuarial present value of benefit premiums. The change at age 50 did not change the
benefits, only the pattern of paying for them.

A40 = P40 a&&40:10 + P50Mod 10 E40 a&&50:10

FG 016132
. IJ b7.70g + d P ib0.53667gb7.57g
=
H 14.8166K
Mod
016132
. 50

1000 P50Mod =
b1000gb0.07748g = 19.07
4.0626

Question # 42
Answer: A

d xb 2 g = q xb 2 g × lxbτ g = 400

b g
d xb1g = 0.45 400 = 180

d xb 2 g
q x′ b 2 g =
400
= = 0.488
lxbτ g − d xb1g 1000 − 180

px′b 2 g = 1 − 0.488 = 0.512

Note: The UDD assumption was not critical except to have all deaths during the year so
that 1000 - 180 lives are subject to decrement 2.

MLC-09-08 - 33 -
Question #43
Answer: D

Use “age” subscripts for years completed in program. E.g., p0 applies to a person newly
hired (“age” 0).

Let decrement 1 = fail, 2 = resign, 3 = other.


Then q0′b1g = 1 4 , q1′ b1g = 15 , q2′b1g = 1 3
q0′b 2 g = 1
5, q1′b 2 g = 1
3, q2′b 2 g = 1
8

q ′b 3g = 1
0 10 , q ′b3g = 1
1 9, q ′b 3g = 1
2 4

b gb
This gives p0bτ g = 1 − 1 / 4 1 − 1 / 5 1 − 1 / 10 = 0.54 gb g
b gb gb g
p1bτ g = 1 − 1 / 5 1 − 1 / 3 1 − 1 / 9 = 0.474
pb g = b1 − 1 / 3gb1 − 1 / 8gb1 − 1 / 4g = 0.438
2
τ

So 1b g = 200, 1b g = 200 b0.54g = 108 , and 1b g = 108 b0.474g = 512


0
τ
1
τ
. 2
τ

q2b1g = log p2′b1g / log p2bτ g q2bτ g

q2b1g = log c h / logb0.438g 1 − 0.438


2
3

= b0.405 / 0.826gb0.562g

= 0.276

d2b1g = l2bτ g q2b1g


= 512 b gb
. 0.276 = 14 g
Question #44
Answer: C

Let: N = number
X = profit
S = aggregate profit
subscripts G = “good”, B = “bad”, AB = “accepted bad”

λG = c hb60g = 40
2
3

MLC-09-08 - 34 -
λ AB = c hc hb60g = 10
1
2
1
3 (If you have trouble accepting this, think instead of a heads-tails
rule, that the application is accepted if the applicant’s government-issued identification
number, e.g. U.S. Social Security Number, is odd. It is not the same as saying he
automatically alternates accepting and rejecting.)

b g b g b g b g b g
Var SG = E N G × Var X G + Var N G × E X G
2

= b40gb10,000g + b40gd300 i = 4,000,000


2

Var b S g = E b N g × Var b X g + Var b N g × E b X g


2
AB AB AB AB AB

= b10gb90,000g + b10gb−100g = 1,000,000


2

S and S are independent, so


G AB
Var b S g = Var b S g + Var b S g = 4,000,000 + 1,000,000
G AB
= 5,000,000

If you don’t treat it as three streams (“goods”, “accepted bads”, “rejected bads”), you
can compute the mean and variance of the profit per “bad” received.
c hb g
λ B = 13 60 = 20
d i
If all “bads” were accepted, we would have E X 2 B = Var X B + E X B b g b g 2

= 90,000 + b−100g = 100,000


2

Since the probability a “bad” will be accepted is only 50%,


b g b g c h b
E X B = Prob accepted × E X B accepted + Prob not accepted × E X B not accepted g c h
= b0.5gb −100g + b0.5gb0g = −50
E d X i = b0.5gb100,000g + b0.5gb0g = 50,000
2
B

Likewise,
b g b g b g b g b g
Now Var S B = E N B × Var X B + Var N B × E X B
2

= b20gb47,500g + b20gd50 i = 1,000,000


2

SG and S B are independent, so


bg b g b g
Var S = Var SG + Var S B = 4,000,000 + 1,000,000
= 5,000,000

Question #45
Key: E

MLC-09-08 - 35 -
o ω−x
For De Moivre’s Law: ex =
2
1
qx =
k
ω−x
ω − x −1
1 ω − x −1 k +1
Ax = ∑ v k +1
k qx = ∑v
ω − x k =b
k =b
aω − x
Ax =
ω−x
1 − Ax
a&&x =
d

o
e50 = 25 ⇒ ω = 100 for typical annuitants
o
e y = 15 ⇒ y = Assumed age = 70

a30
A70 = = 0.45883
30
a&&70 = 9.5607
500000 = b a&&20 ⇒ b = 52, 297

Question #46
Answer: B

10 E30:40 = 10 p30 10 p40 v10 =d p v id p v ib1 + i g


10 30
10
10 40
10 10

= b E gb E gb1 + i g
10
10 30 10 40

= b0.54733gb0.53667 gb179085
. g
= 0.52604

The above is only one of many possible ways to evaluate 10 p30 10 p40 v10 , all of which
should give 0.52604

a30:40:10 = a30:40 −10 E30:40 a30+10:40+10

b g b gb g
= a&&30:40 − 1 − 0.52604 a&&40:50 − 1
= b13.2068g − b0.52604gb114784
. g
= 7.1687

MLC-09-08 - 36 -
Question #47
Answer: A

Equivalence Principle, where π is annual benefit premium, gives

d
1000 A35 + IA b g 35 i
× π = a&&xπ

1000 A35 1000 × 0.42898


π= =
d b gi
a&&35 − IA 35 (1199143
. − 616761
. )
428.98
=
.
582382
= 73.66

We obtained a&&35 from

1 − A35 1 − 0.42898
a&&35 = = = 1199143
.
d 0.047619

MLC-09-08 - 37 -
Question #48
Answer: C

Time until arrival = waiting time plus travel time.

Waiting time is exponentially distributed with mean 1 λ . The time you may already have
been waiting is irrelevant: exponential is memoryless.

You: E (wait) = 201 hour = 3 minutes


b gb g b gb g
E (travel) = 0.25 16 + 0.75 28 = 25 minutes
E (total) = 28 minutes

Co-worker: E (wait) = 15 hour = 12 minutes


E (travel) = 16 minutes
E (total) = 28 minutes

Question #49
Answer: C

μ xy = μ x + μ y = 014
.
μ 0.07
Ax = Ay = = = 0.5833
μ + δ 0.07 + 0.05
μ xy 014
. 014
. 1 1
Axy = = = = 0.7368 and a xy = = = 5.2632
μ xy + δ 014 . + 0.05 019 . μ xy + δ 014
. + 0.05

P=
Axy
=
Ax + Ay − Axy
=
b g
2 0.5833 − 0.7368
= 0.0817
a xy a xy 5.2632

MLC-09-08 - 38 -
Question #50
Answer: E

b V + P gb1 + ig − q b1− V g= V
20 20 20 40 21 20 21 20

b0.49 + 0.01gb1 + ig − 0.022b1 − 0.545g = 0.545


b1 + ig = b0.545gb1 − 0.022g + 0.022
0.50

= 111
.

b V + P gb1 + ig − q b1− V g= V
21 20 20 41 22 20 22 20

b0.545+.01gb111
. g − q b1 − 0.605g = 0.605
41

0.61605 − 0.605
q41 =
0.395

= 0.028

Question #51
Answer: E

1000 P60 = 1000 A60 / a&&60

b gb g
= 1000 v q60 + p60 A61 / 1 + p60 v a&&61

= 1000bq + p A g / b106
60 60 . + p a&& g
61 60 61

= c15 + b0.985gb382.79gh / c106


. + b0.985gb10.9041gh = 33.22

MLC-09-08 - 39 -
Question #52
Key: D

Since the rate of depletion is constant there are only 2 ways the reservoir can be empty
sometime within the next 10 days.

Way #1:
There is no rainfall within the next 5 days

Way #2
There is one rainfall in the next 5 days
And it is a normal rainfall
And there are no further rainfalls for the next five days

Prob (Way #1) = Prob(0 in 5 days) = exp(-0.2*5) = 0.3679


Prob (Way #2) = Prob(1 in 5 days) × 0.8 × Prob(0 in 5 days)
= 5*0.2 exp(-0.2* 5)* 0.8 * exp(-0.2* 5)
= 1 exp(-1) * 0.8 * exp(-1) = 0.1083

Hence Prob empty at some time = 0.3679 + 0.1083 = 0.476

Question #53
Key: E

0.96 = e ( 1 )
− μ +λ

μ1 + λ = − ln ( 0.96 ) = 0.04082
μ1 = 0.04082 − λ = 0.04082 − 0.01 = 0.03082

Similarly

μ 2 = − ln ( 0.97 ) − λ = 0.03046 − 0.01 = 0.02046


μ xy = μ1 + μ 2 + λ = 0.03082 + 0.02046 + 0.01 = 0.06128
pxy = e ( ) (
− 5 0.06128 )
5 = e −0.3064 = 0.736

Question #54
Answer: B

Transform these scenarios into a four-state Markov chain, where the final disposition of
rates in any scenario is that they decrease, rather than if rates increase, as what is
given.

MLC-09-08 - 40 -
from year t – 3 from year t – 2 Probability that year t will
State
to year t – 2 to year t – 1 decrease from year t - 1
0 Decrease Decrease 0.8
1 Increase Decrease 0.6
2 Decrease Increase 0.75
3 Increase Increase 0.9

LM0.80 0.00 0.20 OP


0.00

Transition matrix is M PP
0.60 0.00 0.40 0.00
MM0.00 0.75 0.00 0.25
PQ
N0.00 0.90 0.00 .
010

P002 + P012 = 0.8 * 0.8 + 0.2 * 0.75 = 0.79

For this problem, you don’t need the full transition matrix. There are two cases to
consider. Case 1: decrease in 2003, then decrease in 2004; Case 2: increase in 2003,
then decrease in 2004.

For Case 1: decrease in 2003 (following 2 decreases) is 0.8; decrease in 2004


(following 2 decreases is 0.8. Prob(both) = 0.8 × 0.8 = 0.64
For Case 2: increase in 2003 (following 2 decreases) is 0.2; decrease in 2004 (following
a decrease, then increase) is 0.75. Prob(both) = 0.2 × 0.75 = 0.15
Combined probability of Case 1 and Case 2 is 0.64 + 0.15 = 0.79

MLC-09-08 - 41 -
Question #55
Answer: B

lx = ω − x = 105 − x
⇒t P45 = l45+ t / l45 = 60 − t / 60

Let K be the curtate future lifetime of (45). Then the sum of the payments is 0 if K ≤ 19
and is K – 19 if K ≥ 20 .

F 60 − K IJ × 1
∑ 1 × GH
60

20 a45 =
60 K
&&
K = 20

=
b40 + 39+...+1g = b40gb41g = 13.66
60 2b60g

Hence,

c h c
Prob K − 19 > 13.66 = Prob K > 32.66 h
b g
= Prob K ≥ 33 since K is an integer

= ProbbT ≥ 33g

l78 27
= 33p45 = =
l45 60

= 0.450

MLC-09-08 - 42 -
Question #56
Answer: C

μ
2
Ax = = 0.25 → μ = 0.04
μ + 2δ

μ
Ax = = 0.4
μ +δ

d IAi x
= z ∞
0 s
Ax ds

z ∞
E
0s x
Ax ds

= zd ∞
0
ib g
e −0.1s 0.4 ds

F −e I
= b0.4 gG
−0.1s

H 01. JK
0.4
= =4
01
.
0

Alternatively, using a more fundamental formula but requiring more difficult integration.

c IA h x
= z ∞

0
bg
t t px μ x t e − δ t dt

= z ∞
0
t e −0.04 t b0.04g e −0.06 t
dt

= 0.04 z
(integration by parts, not shown)

0
t e −0.1t dt

−t 1 FG
e −0.1 t
∞ IJ
= 0.04
01

. 0.01 H0 K
0.04
= =4
0.01

MLC-09-08 - 43 -
Question #57
Answer: E

Subscripts A and B here just distinguish between the tools and do not represent ages.
ο
We have to find e AB

ο
z 10 FG 1 − t IJ dt = t − t 2 10
eA =
0 H 10K 20 0
= 10 − 5 = 5

ο
eB = z FGH
7

0
1−
t
7
IJ
K
dt = t −
t2
14
7

0
= 49 −
49
14
= 35
.

ο
z FGH7 t IJ FG 1 − t IJ dt = z FG 1 − t − t + t IJ dt
7 2
e AB =
ο
1−
7 K H 10K 0H 10 7 70K
7
t2 t2 t3
=t− − +
20 14 210 0

49 49 343
= 7− − + = 2.683
20 14 210

ο ο ο ο
e AB = e A + e B − e AB

= 5 + 35
. − 2.683 = 5817
.

MLC-09-08 - 44 -
Question #58
Answer: A

bg
μ bxτ g t = 0100
. + 0.004 = 0104
.

t pxbτ g = e −0.104 t

Actuarial present value (APV) = APV for cause 1 + APV for cause 2.

z 0
5
2000 e −0.04 t e −0.104 t 0100
. b g z 5
dt + 500,000 e −0.04 t e −0.104 t 0.400 dt
0
b g
c b g
= 2000 010
. + 500,000 0.004 b ghz e
5 −0.144 t
0
dt

1 − e −0.144b5g = 7841
e j
2200
=
.
0144

Question #59
Answer: A

R = 1 − px = q x

e z =e z z
d 1
bg i 1
bg 1

× eb − k g since
− μ x t + k dt − μ x t dt − k dt
S = 1 − px 0 0 0

=e z e z
1
bg
− μ x t dt − k dt
0
1
0

So S = 0.75R ⇒ 1 − px × e − k = 0.75q x

1 − 0.75q x
e− k =
px
px 1 − qx
ek = =
1 − 0.75q x 1 − 0.75q x

k = ln
LM 1 − q OPx

N1 − 0.75q Q x

MLC-09-08 - 45 -
Question #60
Key: C

A60 = 0.36913 d = 0.05660


2
A60 = 0.17741
and 2
A60 − A60
2
= 0.202862
⎛ π⎞ π
Expected Loss on one policy is E ⎣⎡ L (π ) ⎦⎤ = ⎜100,000 + ⎟ A60 −
⎝ d⎠ d
π⎞
2

Variance on one policy is Var ⎣⎡ L (π ) ⎦⎤ = ⎜100,000 + ⎟ 2 A60 − A60
⎝ d ⎠
( 2
)
On the 10000 lives,
E [ S ] = 10,000 E ⎡⎣ L (π ) ⎤⎦ and Var [ S ] = 10,000 Var ⎡⎣ L (π ) ⎤⎦
The π is such that 0 − E [ S ] / Var [ S ] = 2.326 since Φ ( 2.326 ) = 0.99
⎛π ⎛ π⎞ ⎞
10,000 ⎜ − ⎜100,000 + ⎟ A60 ⎟
⎝d ⎝ d⎠ ⎠ = 2.326
⎛ π⎞
100 ⎜100,000 + ⎟ 2 A60 − A60
2
⎝ d⎠

⎛π ⎛ π ⎞⎞
100 ⎜ − ⎜100,000 + ⎟ ⎟ ( 0.36913)
⎝d ⎝ d ⎠⎠
= 2.326
⎛ π⎞
⎜100,000 + ⎟ ( 0.202862 )
⎝ d⎠
π
0.63087 − 36913
d = 0.004719
π
100,000 +
d
π π
0.63087 − 36913 = 471.9 = 0.004719
d d
π 36913 + 471.9
=
d 0.63087 − 0.004719
= 59706
π = 59706 × d = 3379

MLC-09-08 - 46 -
Question #61
Key: C

1V = ( 0V + π ) (1 + i ) − (1000 + 1V − 1V ) × q75
= 1.05π − 1000q75

Similarly,
2 V = ( 1V + π ) × 1.05 − 1000q76

3V = ( 2V + π ) × 1.05 − 1000q77

( )
1000 =3V = 1.053π + 1.052 ⋅ π + 1.05π − 1000 × q75 × 1.052 − 1000 × 1.05 × q76 − 1000 × q77 *

π=
(
1000 + 1000 1.052 q75 + 1.05q76 + q77 )
(1.05) + (1.05)
3 2
+ 1.05

=
(
1000 x 1 + 1.052 × 0.05169 + 1.05 × 0.05647 + 0.06168 )
3.310125
1000 × 1.17796
= = 355.87
3.310125

* This equation is algebraic manipulation of the three equations in three unknowns


( 1V , 2V , π ) . One method – usually effective in problems where benefit = stated amount
plus reserve, is to multiply the 1V equation by 1.052 , the 2V equation by 1.05, and add
those two to the 3V equation: in the result, you can cancel out the 1V , and 2V terms.
Or you can substitute the 1V equation into the 2V equation, giving 2V in terms of π ,
and then substitute that into the 3V equation.

Question #62
Answer: D

A281:2 = z2 −δ t

0
e 1 72 dt

=
1
72δ
d i
1 − e −2δ = 0.02622 since δ = ln 106
. = 0.05827b g
FG IJ
71
a&&28:2 = 1+ v
72H K = 19303
.

3V = 500,000 A281:2 − 6643 a&&28:2


= 287

MLC-09-08 - 47 -
Question #63
Answer: D

Let Ax and a x be calculated with μ x t and δ = 0.06 bg


Let Ax* and a x * be the corresponding values with μ x t bg
increased by 0.03 and δ decreased by 0.03

1 − Ax 0.4
ax = = = 6.667
δ 0.06
ax = ax
*

LM Proof: a e z
z d bg i
t
∞ − μ x s + 0.03 ds −0.03t
*
= 0 e dt
N x 0

z e z

t
bg
− μ x s ds −0.03t −0.03t
= 0 e e dt
0

= z zt
∞ − 0 μ x s ds −0.06 t
e
bg
e dt
0

= ax

Ax* = 1 − 0.03 a x * = 1 − 0.03 a x


b gb
= 1 − 0.03 6.667 g
= 0.8

Question #64
Answer: A

bulb ages
#
Year 0 1 2 3
replaced
0 10000 0 0 0 -
1 1000 9000 0 0 1000
2 100+2700 900 6300 0 2800
3 280+270+3150 3700

The diagonals represent bulbs that don’t burn out.


E.g., of the initial 10,000, (10,000) (1-0.1) = 9000 reach year 1.
(9000) (1-0.3) = 6300 of those reach year 2.

MLC-09-08 - 48 -
Replacement bulbs are new, so they start at age 0.
At the end of year 1, that’s (10,000) (0.1) = 1000
At the end of 2, it’s (9000) (0.3) + (1000) (0.1) = 2700 + 100
At the end of 3, it’s (2800) (0.1) + (900) (0.3) + (6300) (0.5) = 3700

1000 2800 3700


Actuarial present value = + +
.
105 . 2 105
105 . 3
= 6688

Question #65
Key: E

o
e25:25 = z15
0 t
p25dt +15 p25 z10
0t
p40 dt

F IJ e
z dt + G e z
Kz
15
15 −.04 t − .04 ds 10 −.05t
= e
H dt
0
0 0

=
1
d −.60 L1
1 − e i + e M d1 − e − .60 −.50
iOPQ
.04 N.05
= 112797
. + 4.3187
= 15.60

Question #66
Key: C

5 p 60 +1 =

e1 − q je1 − q jb1 − q gb1 − q gb1 − q g


60 +1 60 + 2 63 64 65

= b0.89gb0.87gb0.85gb0.84gb0.83g
= 0.4589

MLC-09-08 - 49 -
Question # 67
Key: E

1
12.50 = a x = ⇒ μ + δ = 0.08 ⇒ μ = δ = 0.04
μ +δ

μ
Ax = = 0.5
μ +δ
μ 1
2
Ax = =
μ + 2δ 3

2
Ax − Ax2
e j
Var aT =
δ2
1 1

= 3 4 = 52.083
0.0016

S.D. = 52.083 = 7.217

Question # 68
Key: D

v = 0.90 ⇒ d = 010 .
Ax = 1 − da&&x = 1 − 010 b gb g
. 5 = 0.5

5000 Ax − 5000vqx
Benefit premium π =
a&&x

=
b5000gb0.5g − 5000b0.90gb0.05g = 455
5

a&&x +10
10Vx = 1−
a&&x
a&&
0.2 = 1 − x +10 ⇒ a&&x +10 = 4
5

Ax +10 = 1 − da&&x +10 = 1 − 010


. b gb g
4 = 0.6
10V = 5000 Ax +10 − π a&& = b5000gb0.6g − b455gb4g = 1180
x +10

MLC-09-08 - 50 -
Question #69
Key: D

v is the lowest premium to ensure a zero % chance of loss in year 1 (The present value
of the payment upon death is v, so you must collect at least v to avoid a loss should
death occur).
Thus v = 0.95.
bg b g
2
E Z = vqx + v 2 px qx +1 = 0.95 × 0.25 + 0.95 × 0.75 × 0.2
= 0.3729
d i b g 2
b g 4
E Z2 = v 2qx + v 4 px qx +1 = 0.95 × 0.25 + 0.95 × 0.75 × 0.2
= 0.3478

b g d i c b gh
Var Z = E Z2 − E Z
2
b g
= 0.3478 − 0.3729 = 0.21
2

Question #70
Key: D

Actuarial present value (APV) of future benefits =


= ( 0.005 × 2000 + 0.04 × 1000 ) /1.06 + (1 − 0.005 − 0.04 )( 0.008 × 2000 + 0.06 × 1000 ) /1.062
= 47.17 + 64.60
= 111.77

APV of future premiums = ⎡⎣1 + (1 − 0.005 − 0.04 ) /1.06 ⎤⎦ 50


= (1.9009 )( 50 )
= 95.05
E ⎡⎣ 1 L K ( 55 ) ≥ 1⎤⎦ = 111.77 − 95.05 = 16.72

Question #71
Key: A

This is a nonhomogeneous Poisson process with intensity function

λ (t) = 3+3t, 0 ≤ t ≤ 2 , where t is time after noon

MLC-09-08 - 51 -
∫1 λ ( t ) dt =
2

∫1 ( 3 + 3t )dt
2
Average λ =
1
2
⎡ 3t 2 ⎤
= ⎢3t + ⎥
⎣ 2 ⎦
1
= 7.5
e −7.5 7.52
f ( 2) = = 0.0156
2!

Question #72
Key: A

Let Z be the present value random variable for one life.


Let S be the present value random variable for the 100 lives.
bg
E Z = 10 z
5
∞ δt μ t

μ
e e μ dt

= 10 e − bδ + μ g 5
δ +μ
= 2.426

d i
E Z 2 = 102
FG μ IJ e b g − 2δ + μ 5
H 2δ + μ K
= 10 G
F 0.04IJ de i = 11233−0.8
H 0.16K
2
.

Var b Z g = E d Z i − c E b Z gh
2 2

= 11233
. − 2.4262
= 5.348

bg bg
E S = 100 E Z = 242.6
VarbSg = 100 Varb Zg = 534.8
F − 242.6
= 1645
. → F = 281
534.8

MLC-09-08 - 52 -
Question #73
Key: D

Prob{only 1 survives} = 1-Prob{both survive}-Prob{neither survives}


b ge
= 1− 3p50 × 3p 50 − 1− 3p50 1− 3p 50 j
b gb gb gb gb gb
= 1 − 0.9713 0.9698 0.9682 0.9849 0.9819 0.9682 − 1 − 0.912012 1 − 0.93632
14444244443 14444244443
g b gb g
= 0.912012 0.936320
= 0.140461

Question # 74
Key: C

The tyrannosaur dies at the end of the first day if it eats no scientists that day. It dies at
the end of the second day if it eats exactly one the first day and none the second day. If
it does not die by the end of the second day, it will have at least 10,000 calories then,
and will survive beyond 2.5.

b g bg b g
Prob (dies) = f 0 + f 1 f 0
b gb g
= 0.368 + 0.368 0.368
= 0.503
−1 0
b g e 01! = 0.368
since f 0 =
−1 1
f b1g =
e 1
= 0.368
1!

Question #75
Key: B

Let X = expected scientists eaten.


b
For each period, E X = E X dead × Prob already dead + E X alive × Prob alive g b g
b g
= 0 × Prob dead + E X alive × Prob alive b g
Day 1, E X1 = 1
−1 1
b g b g e 0!0 = 0.368
Prob dead at end of day 1 = f 0 =

Day 2, E X 2 = 0 × 0.368 + 1 × b1 − 0.368g = 0.632


Prob (dead at end of day 2) = 0.503
[per problem 10]

b
Day 2.5, E X 2.5 = 0 × 0.503 + 0.5 × 1 − 0.503 = 0.249 g
MLC-09-08 - 53 -
where E X 2.5 alive = 0.5 since only 1
2 day in period.

E X = E X1 + E X 2 + E X 2.5 = 1 + 0.632 + 0.249 = 1881


.
E 10,000 X = 18,810

Question # 76
Key: C

This solution applies the equivalence principle to each life. Applying the equivalence
principle to the 100 life group just multiplies both sides of the first equation by 100,
producing the same result for P.

b g b g
APV Prems = P = APV Benefits = 10q70 v + 10 p70q71v 2 + Pp70 p71v 2

P=
b10gb0.03318g + b10gb1 − 0.03318gb0.03626g + Pb1 − 0.03318gb1 − 0.03626g
108
. . 2
108 . 2
108
= 0.3072 + 0.3006 + 0.7988 P
0.6078
P= = 3.02
0.2012

(APV above means Actuarial Present Value).

Question #77
Key: E

Level benefit premiums can be split into two pieces: one piece to provide term
insurance
for n years; one to fund the reserve for those who survive.

Then,
Px = Px1:n + Px:n1 nVx

And plug in to get

b gb
0.090 = Px1:n + 0.00864 0.563 g
Px1:n = 0.0851

MLC-09-08 - 54 -
Another approach is to think in terms of retrospective reserves. Here is one such
solution:

nVx e j
= Px − Px1:n &&sx:n
a&&
= eP − P j
x
1
x:n
x:n
E n x
a&&x:n
e
= Px − Px1:n jP 1
a&&x:n
x:n

=
eP − P j
x
1
x:n

eP j x:n
1

e
0.563 = 0.090 − Px1:n / 0.00864 j
Px1:n = 0.090 − 0.00864 0.563 b gb g
= 0.0851

Question #78
Key: A

b g
δ = ln 1.05 = 0.04879

Ax = zω −x
0 t bg
px μ x t e −δt dt

= z0
ω −x 1
ω−x
e −δt dt for DeMoivre

1
= a
ω − x ω −x

From here, many formulas for 10 V c A h could be used.


40 One approach is:

Since

MLC-09-08 - 55 -
A50 =
a50
=
18.71
= 0.3742 so a50 =
FG
1 − A50 IJ
= 12.83
50 50 Hδ K
A40 =
a60
=
19.40
= 0.3233 so a40 =G
F1− A IJ = 1387
H δ K .
40
60 60

so P A40 =c h 01387
.3233
.
= 0.02331

10 V c A h = A − P c A ha = 0.3742 − b0.02331gb12.83g = 0.0751.


40 50 40 50

Question #79
Key: D

b g bg
Ax = E v T b x g = E v T b x g NS × Prob NS + E v T b x g S × Prob S

F 0.03 IJ × 0.70 + FG 0.6 IJ × 0.30


=G
H 0.03 + 0.08 K H 0.06 + 0.08 K
= 0.3195

FG 0.03 IJ × 0.70 + FG 0.06 IJ × 0.30 = 01923


Similarly, 2 Ax =
H 0.03 + 0.16K H 0.06 + 0.16K . .

F I= 2
Ax − Ax2 01923
. − 0.31952
H b gK
Var a T x δ2
=
0.082
= 141
..

Question #80
Key: B

2 q80:84 = 2 q80 + 2 q84 − 2 q80:84

= 0.5 × 0.4 × (1 − 0.6 ) + 0.2 × 0.15 × (1 − 0.1)


= 0.10136

Using new p82 value of 0.3

0.5 × 0.4 × (1 − 0.3) + 0.2 × 0.15 × (1 − 0.1)

MLC-09-08 - 56 -
= 0.16118

Change = 0.16118 – 0.10136 = 0.06

Alternatively,
2 p80 = 0.5 × 0.4 = 0.20

3 p80 = 2 p80 × 0.6 = 0.12

2 p84 = 0.20 × 0.15 = 0.03

3 p84 = 2 p84 × 0.10 = 0.003

2 p80:84 = 2 p80 + 2 p84 − 2 p80 2 p84 since independent

= 0.20 + 0.03 − ( 0.20 )( 0.03) = 0.224


3 p80:84 = 3 p80 + 3 p84 − 3 p80 3 p84
= 0.12 + 0.003 − ( 0.12 )( 0.003) = 0.12264
2 q 80:84 = 2 p80:84 − 3 p80:84

= 0.224 − 0.12264 = 0.10136

Revised
3 p80 = 0.20 × 0.30 = 0.06

3 p 80:84 = 0.06 + 0.003 − ( 0.06 )( 0.003)


= 0.06282
2 q 80:84 = 0.224 − 0.06282 = 0.16118

change = 0.16118 − 0.10136 = 0.06

Question #81
Key: D

Poisson processes are separable. The aggregate claims process is therefore


equivalent to two independent processes, one for Type I claims with expected
FG 1IJ b3000g = 1000 and
frequency
H 3K
one for Type II claims.

Let S I = aggregate Type I claims.


N I = number of Type I claims.
X I = severity of a Type I claim (here = 10).

MLC-09-08 - 57 -
b g
Since X I = 10, a constant , E X I = 10; Var X I = 0. b g
b g b g b g b g b g
Var S I = E N I Var X I + Var N I E X I
2

= b1000gb0g + b1000gb10g
2

= 100,000

bg b g
b g
Var S = Var S I + Var S II since independent
2,100,000 = 100,000 + Var b S g II
Var b S g = 2 ,000,000
II

Question #82
Key: A

bτ g = p′b1g p′b2g
p50
5 5 50 5 50

FG 100 − 55IJ e b gb g − 0.05 5


=
H 100 − 50K
= b0.9gb0.7788g = 0.7009

Similarly
bτ g = FG 100 − 60IJ e b g b g − 0.05 10
10 p50
H 100 − 50 K
= b0.8gb0.6065g = 0.4852

bτ g = pbτ g − pbτ g = 0.7009 − 0.4852


5 5 q50 5 50 10 50

= 0.2157

Question #83
Key: C

Only decrement 1 operates before t = 0.7

′1b g = b0.7g q′b1g = b0.7gb010


. g = 0.07 since UDD
0.7 q40 40

Probability of reaching t = 0.7 is 1-0.07 = 0.93

Decrement 2 operates only at t = 0.7, eliminating 0.125 of those who reached 0.7

q40 b gb
b2g = 0.93 0125
. = 011625
. g
MLC-09-08 - 58 -
Question #84
Key: C

πvq80 πv 3 2 p80q82
e j
π 1+ 2 p80v 2 = 1000 A80 +
2
+
2

FG 0.83910 IJ = 665.75 + πFG 0.08030 + 0.83910 × 0.09561IJ


H
π 1+
1.062 K H 2b106
. g 2b1.06g K 3

b
π 174680
. g b
= 665.75 + π 0.07156 g
πb167524
. g = 665.75
π = 397.41

3,284 ,542
Where 2 p80 = = 0.83910
3,914 ,365

b gb
Or 2 p80 = 1 − 0.08030 1 − 0.08764 = 0.83910 g
Question #85
Key: E

At issue, actuarial present value (APV) of benefits


= z ∞
0
bt v t t p65 μ
65
bt gdt
z ∞
d id
= 1000 e0.04 t e −0.04 t t p65 μ 65 t dt
0
i bg
= 1000 z ∞
p
0 t 65
bg
μ 65 t dt = 1000 ∞ q65 = 1000

APV of premiums = π a65 = π


FG 1 IJ = 16.667π
H 0.04 + 0.02K
Benefit premium π = 1000 / 16.667 = 60
2V = z
0

b g
b2+u v u u p67 μ 65 2 + u du − π a67

= z∞
1000 e0.04b 2+uge −0.04u u p67 μ 65 2 + u du − 60 16.667b g b gb g
z
0

= 1000e0.08
0 u

b g
p67 μ 65 2 + u du − 1000
= 1083.29 ∞ q67 − 1000 = 1083.29 − 1000 = 83.29

MLC-09-08 - 59 -
Question #86
Key: B

(1) a x:20 = a&&x:20 − 1+ 20 Ex


1 − Ax:20
(2) a&&x:20 =
d
(3) Ax:20 = A1x:20 + Ax:201
(4) Ax = A1x:20 + 20 Ex Ax + 20

b gb g
0.28 = A1x:20 + 0.25 0.40

A1x:20 = 018
.

Now plug into (3): Ax:20 = 018


. + 0.25 = 0.43

1 − 0.43
a&&x:20 = = 1197
Now plug into (2):
b g
0.05 / 105
.
.

Now plug into (1): a x:20 = 1197


. − 1 + 0.25 = 1122
.

Question #87
Key: A

−( λ 2 )
e− λ λ1 ( λ / 2 ) e
p1 = ∫ p (1 λ ) f ( λ ) d λ = ∫
∞ ∞

0 0 1! λΓ (1)
1 ∞ − 32λ
= ∫ λe d λ
2 0

[Integrate by parts; not shown]

1 ⎛ 2 − 32 λ 4 − 23 λ ⎞ ∞
= ⎜ − λe − e ⎟
2⎝ 3 9 ⎠ 0

2
= = 0.22
9

MLC-09-08 - 60 -
Question #88
Key: B

ex 8.83
ex = px + pxex +1 ⇒ px = = = 0.95048
1 + ex +1 9.29
a&&x = 1 + vpx + v 2 2 px + ....
a&& = 1 + v + v 2 2 p x + ...
x:2
a&&x:2 − a&&x = vqx = 5.6459 − 5.60 = 0.0459

v (1 − 0.95048 ) = 0.0459
v = 0.9269
1
i = − 1 = 0.0789
v

Question #89
Key: E

M = Initial state matrix = 1 0 0 0


LM0.20 0.80 0 0 OP
T = One year transition matrix = M
0.50 0 0.50 0 P
MM0.75 0 0 0.25P
P
N1.00 0 0 0 Q

M × T = 0.20 0.80 0 0
b M × T g × T = 0.44 016
. 0.40 0
cb M × T g × T h × T = 0.468 0.352 0.08 010
.

Probability of being in state F after three years = 0.468.

d
Actuarial present value = 0.468v 3 500 = 171 ib g
Note:
Only the first entry of the last matrix need be calculated (verifying that the four sum
to 1 is useful “quality control.”)

MLC-09-08 - 61 -
Question #90
Key: B

Let Yi be the number of claims in the ith envelope.

b g
Let X 13 be the aggregate number of claims received in 13 weeks.

g bb g b g b g
E Yi = 1 × 0.2 + 2 × 0.25 + 3 × 0.4 + 4 × 015
. = 2.5
E Y = b1 × 0.2g + b4 × 0.25g + b9 × 0.4g + b16 × 015
i
2
. g = 7.2
E X b13g = 50 × 13 × 2.5 = 1625
Var X b13g = 50 × 13 × 7.2 = 4680
ProbmXb13g ≤ Zr = 0.90 = Φb1282
. g

⇒ Prob S
R X b13g − 1625 ≤ 1282
. V
U
T 4680 W
X b13g ≤ 1712.7

b g
Note: The formula for Var X 13 took advantage of the frequency’s being
Poisson.
The more general formula for the variance of a compound distribution,
bg b g b g b gb g
2
Var S = E N Var X + Var N E X , would give the same result.

Question #91
Key: E

μ M 60 = b g ω −1 60 = 75 −1 60 = 151
μF b60g = ω ′ −1 60 = 151 × 53 = 251 ⇒ ω ′ = 85
t
t
M
p65 = 1−
10
t
t
F
p60 = 1−
25

Let x denote the male and y denote the female.

MLC-09-08 - 62 -
eo x =5 cmean for uniform distribution over b0,10gh
eo y = 12 .5 c mean for uniform distribution over b0,25gh

eo xy = z 0
FG1 − t IJ FG1 − t IJ ⋅ dt
10

H 10K H 25K
F1 − 7 t + t I ⋅ dt
= z GH 50 250JK
10

0
2

F 7 t + t I = 10 − 7 × 100 + 1000
= Gt −
3 10

H 100 750JK
2
100 0 750
4 13
= 10 − 7 + =
3 3

o o o o 25 13 30 + 75 − 26
exy = ex + e y − exy = 5 + − = = 1317
.
2 3 6

Question #92
Key: B

μ 1
Ax = =
μ+δ 3
μ 1
2
Ax = =
μ + 2δ 5

c h
P Ax = μ = 0.04

F Pc A hI A − A
Var b Lg = G 1 +
2

H δ JK e j
x 2 2
x x

F 0.04 IJ FG 1 − FG 1IJ IJ
= G1 +
2 2

H 0.08 K H 5 H 3K K
F 3I F 4 I
=G J G J
2

H 2 K H 45K
1
=
5

Question #93
Key: A

MLC-09-08 - 63 -
Let π be the benefit premium
Let kV denote the benefit reserve a the end of year k.
For any n, ( nV + π ) (1 + i ) = ( q25+ n × n +1V + p25+ n × n +1V )
= n +1V
Thus 1V = ( 0 V + π ) (1 + i )

2V = ( 1V + π )(1 + i ) = (π (1 + i ) + π ) (1 + i ) = π &&
s2

3V (
= ( 2V + π )(1 + i ) = π && )
s2 + π (1 + i ) = π &&
s3

By induction (proof omitted)


n V = π &&
sn
For n = 35, n V = a&&60 (actuarial present value of future benefits; there are no future
premiums)
a&&60 = π &&
s35
a&&
π = 60
&&
s35
For n = 20, 20 V = π &&
s20
⎛ a&& ⎞
= ⎜ 60 ⎟ &&
s
⎜ &&
s ⎟ 20
⎝ 35 ⎠

Alternatively, as above
( nV + π ) (1 + i ) = n+1V
Write those equations, for n = 0 to n = 34
0 : ( 0V + π ) (1 + i ) = 1V
1: ( 1V + π )(1 + i ) = 2V
2 : ( 2V + π )(1 + i ) = 3V
M
34 : ( 34V + π ) (1 + i ) = 35V
34 − k
Multiply equation k by (1 + i ) and sum the results:
( 0V + π ) (1 + i )35 + ( 1V + π )(1 + i )34 + ( 2V + π )(1 + i )33 + L + ( 34V + π ) (1 + i ) =
1V (1 + i ) + 2V (1 + i ) + 3V (1 + i ) + L + 34 V (1 + i ) + 35V
34 33 32

MLC-09-08 - 64 -
35− k
For k = 1, 2,L , 34, the k V (1 + i ) terms in both sides cancel, leaving

0V (1 + i )35 + π ⎡⎣(1 + i )35 + (1 + i )34 + L + (1 + i ) ⎤⎦ = 35V


Since 0V = 0
π &&s35 = 35V
= a&&60
(see above for remainder of solution)

Question #94
Key: B

t qy t px μ ( x + t ) + t qx t p y μ ( y + t )
μ xy ( t ) =
t qx × t p y + t px × t q y + t px × t p y

For (x) = (y) = (50)

μ50:50 (10.5 ) =
( 10.5 q50 )( 10 p50 ) q60 ⋅ 2 =
( 0.09152 )( 0.91478)( 0.01376 )( 2 ) = 0.0023
( 10.5 q50 )( 10.5 p50 ) ⋅ 2 + ( 10.5 p50 ) ( 0.09152 )( 0.90848)( 2 ) + ( 0.90848)2
2

where
p50 =
1
2 ( l60 + l61 ) = 12 (8,188,074 + 8,075, 403) = 0.90848
10.5
l50 8,950,901
10.5 q50 = 1 − 10.5 p50 = 0.09152
8,188,074
10 p50 = = 0.91478
8,950,901

10.5 p50 μ ( 50 + 10.5 ) = ( 10 p50 ) q60 since UDD


Alternatively, (10+t ) p50 = 10 p50 t p60

(10+t ) p50:50 = ( 10 p50 ) ( t p60 )


2 2

(10+t ) p 50:50 = 2 10 p50 t p60 − ( 10 p50 ) ( t p60 )


2 2

= 2 10 p50 (1 − tq60 ) − ( 10 p50 ) (1 − tq60 ) since UDD


2 2

Derivative = −2 10 p50 q60 + 2 ( 10 p50 ) (1 − tq60 ) q60


2

Derivative at 10 + t = 10.5 is
−2 ( 0.91478 )( 0.01376 ) + ( 0.91478 ) (1 − ( 0.5 )( 0.01376 ) ) ( 0.01376 ) = −0.0023
2

MLC-09-08 - 65 -
p 50:50 = 2 10.5 p50 − ( 10.5 p50 )
2
10.5

= 2 ( 0.90848 ) − ( 0.90848 )
2

= 0.99162
dp

μ (for any sort of lifetime) = dt = − ( −0.0023) = 0.0023
p 0.99162

Question #95
Key: D

μ x(τ ) ( t ) = μ x(1) ( t ) + μ x( 2) ( t ) = 0.01 + 2.29 = 2.30



P = P ∫ vt t px( ) μ x( ) ( t ) dt + 50, 000 ∫ vt t px( ) μ x( ) ( t ) dt + 50, 000∫ vt t px( ) μ x( ) ( t ) dt
2 τ 2 2 τ 1 τ τ
0 0 2
2 −0.1t −2.3t 2 −0.1t −2.3t ∞
P = P∫ e e × 2.29dt + 50, 000∫ e e × 0.01dt + 50, 000 ∫ e−0.1t e−2.3t × 2.3dt
0 0 2
⎡ −2( 2.4 ) ⎤ ⎡ −2( 2.4 ) −2( 2.4 )

1− e 1− e e
P ⎢1 − 2.29 × ⎥ = 50000 ⎢ 0.01× + 2.3 × ⎥
⎣⎢ 2.4 ⎦⎥ ⎣⎢ 2.4 2.4 ⎦⎥
P = 11,194

Question #96
Key: B

ex = px + 2 px + 3 px + ... = 1105
.

Annuity = v 3 3 p x 1000 + v 4 4 p x × 1000 × 104


. + ... b g

∑1000b104
. g
k −3 k
= v k px
k =3

= 1000v 3 ∑ k px
k =3

b g FG 1 IJ 3
= 1000v 3 ex − 0.99 − 0.98 = 1000
H 104
. K
× 9.08 = 8072

Let π = benefit premium.

MLC-09-08 - 66 -
e
π 1 + 0.99v + 0.98v 2 = 8072 j
2.8580π = 8072
π = 2824

Question #97
Key B

π a&&30:10 = 1000 A30 + P IA 30


1
:10
+ 10π b g b ge 10 A30 j
1000 A30
π=
b g
a&&30:10 − IA 1
30:10
− 1010 A30

=
1000 0102
. b g
7.747 − 0.078 − 10 0.088 b g
102
=
6.789
= 15.024

Test Question: 98 Key: E

For de Moivre’s law,


o
z FG1 − t IJ dt
ω − 30
e 30 =
0 H ω − 30K
L t OP
= Mt −
2 ω − 30

N 2bω − 30g Q 0
ω − 30
=
2
100 − 30
Prior to medical breakthrough ω = 100 ⇒ eo 30 = = 35
2

o o
After medical breakthrough e ′ 30 = e 30 + 4 = 39

o ω ′ − 30
so ′ = 39 =
e30 ⇒ ω ′ = 108
2

MLC-09-08 - 67 -
Test Question: 99 Key: A

0L = 100,000v 2.5 − 4000a&&3 @5%


= 77,079

Question #100
Key: D

μ ( accid ) = 0.001
μ ( total ) = 0.01
μ ( other ) = 0.01 − 0.001 = 0.009


Actuarial present value = ∫ 500,000 e −0.05t e−0.01t ( 0.009 ) dt
0


+10 ∫ 50,000 e0.04t e−0.05t e −0.01t ( 0.001) dt
0

⎡ 0.009 0.001 ⎤
= 500, 000 ⎢ + = 100, 000
⎣ 0.06 0.02 ⎥⎦

MLC-09-08 - 68 -
Test Question: 101 Key: E

b gb g
E N = Var N = 60 0.5 = 30
b gb g b gb g b gb g
E X = 0.6 1 + 0.2 5 + 0.2 10 = 3.6
E X2 = b0.6gb1g + b0.2gb25g + b0.2gb100g = 25.6
Var X = 25.6 − 3.62 = 12.64

For any compound distribution


Var S = E N Var X + Var N E X c h 2

= (30) (12.64) + (30) 3.62 d i


= 768

For specifically Compound Poisson


Var S = λt E X 2 = (60) (0.5) (25.6) = 768

Alternatively, consider this as 3 Compound Poisson processes (coins worth 1; worth 5;


b g bg b g
2
worth 10), where for each Var X = 0 , thus for each Var S = Var N E X .
Processes are independent, so total Var is
Var = b60gb0.5gb0.6g1 + b60gb0.5gb0.2g5 + b60gb0.5gb0.2gb10g
2 2 2

= 768

Test Question: 102 Key: D

1000 20
20Vx = 1000 Ax +20 =
1000 d 19Vx + 20 Px
20
ib106
. g − q b1000g
x +19

px +19

=
b342.03 + 13.72gb106
. g − 0.01254b1000g
= 36918
.
0.98746
1 − 0.36918
a&&x +20 = = 111445
b0.06 / 106
. g
.

Ax +20 36918.
so 1000 Px +20 = 1000 = = 331
.
a&&x +20 111445
.

MLC-09-08 - 69 -
Test Question: 103 Key: B

k pxbτ g = e
− z
0
k
μ bxτ g t dt
bg =e z b gb g

k
0
2 μ x1 t dt

F b g b g IJ
= Ge z

k
μ x1 t dt
2

H K
0

= b p g where is from Illustrative Life Table, since μ b1g follows I.L.T.


2
k x k px
6,616,155
10 p60 = = 0.80802
8,188,074
6,396,609
11 p60 = = 0.78121
8,188,074
b τ g = p b τ g − p bτ g
q60
10 10 60 11 60

= b 10 p60 g −b
2
11 p60 g 2
from I.L.T.
= 0.80802 2 − 0.781212 = 0.0426

Test Question: 104 Key: C

1
Ps = − d , where s can stand for any of the statuses under consideration.
a&& s

1
a&&s =
Ps + d
1
a&&x = a&&y = = 6.25
01. + 0.06
1
a&&xy = = 8.333
0.06 + 0.06

a&&xy + a&&xy = a&&x + a&&y

a&&xy = 6.25 + 6.25 − 8.333 = 4.167


1
Pxy = − 0.06 = 018
.
4.167

MLC-09-08 - 70 -
Test Question: 105 Key: A

z b
d 0bτ g = 1000 e − b μ + 0.04 gt μ + 0.04 dt
0
1
g
= 1000 1 − e − b μ + 0.04
e g j = 48

e − b μ + 0.04 g = 0.952
μ + 0.04 = − ln 0.952 b g
= 0.049
μ = 0.009

z
d 3b1g = 1000 e −0.049 t 0.009 dt
4

3
b g
0.009 − b 0.049 gb 3g − b 0.049 gb 4 g
= 1000
0.049
e e −e = 7.6 j
Question #106
Key: B

This is a graph of lx μ x . bg
bg
μ x would be increasing in the interval 80,100 . b g
The graphs of lx px , lx and lx2 would be decreasing everywhere.

Question #107
Key: B

Variance = v30 15 px 15 qx Expected value = v15 15 px


v30 15 px 15 qx = 0.065 v15 15 px
v15 15qx = 0.065 ⇒ 15 qx = 0.3157

Since μ is constant

15 q x (
= 1 − ( px )
15
)
( px )
15
= 0.6843
px = 0.975
qx = 0.025

MLC-09-08 - 71 -
Question #108
Key: E

) (p
1+ i)
(1) 11V
A
= ( 10V
A
+0 −
qx +10
px +10
× 1000
x +10

) (p
1+ i)
( 2) 11V
B
= ( 10V
B
+π B −
qx +10
px +10
× 1000
x +10

) (p
1+ i)
(1) − ( 2 ) 11V
A
− 11V B = ( 10V
A
− 10V B − π B
x +10

= (101.35 − 8.36 )
(1.06 )
1 − 0.004

= 98.97

Test Question: 109 Key: A

2
A P V (x’s benefits) = ∑ v k +1bk +1 k px q x + k
k =0

b g b gb g
= 1000 300v 0.02 + 350v 2 0.98 0.04 + 400v 3 0.98 0.96 0.06b gb gb g
= 36,829

MLC-09-08 - 72 -
Test Question: 110 Key: E

π denotes benefit premium


19V = APV future benefits - APV future premiums
1
0.6 = − π ⇒ π = 0.326
108
.

11V =
b gb g b gb g
10V + π 108
. − q65 10
p65

=
b gb g b gb g
5.0 + 0.326 108
. − 010
. 10
1 − 010
.
=5.28

Question #111
Key: A

Actuarial present value Benefits =


( 0.8)( 0.1)(10,000 ) + ( 0.8)( 0.9 )( 0.097 )( 9,000 )
1.062 1.063
= 1, 239.75

⎛ ( 0.8 ) ( 0.8 )( 0.9 ) ⎞


1, 239.75 = P ⎜ 1 + + ⎟
⎝ 1.06 1.062 ⎠
= P ( 2.3955 )
P = 517.53 ⇒ 518

Test Question: 112 Key: A

1180 = 70a30 + 50a40 − 20a30:40


b gb g b gb g
1180 = 70 12 + 50 10 − 20a30:40
a30:40 = 8
a30:40 = a30 + a40 − a30:40 = 12 + 10 − 8 = 14
100a30:40 = 1400

Test Question: 113 Key: B

MLC-09-08 - 73 -
z ∞
a = a¬ f t dt =
o t
bg zo
∞ 1 − e −0.05t

0.05
1
Γ2
te − t dt
bg
=
1
0.05 zb

o
te
−t
i
− te −1.05t dt

1 LM b g FG
− t + 1 e−t +
t 1 IJ
e −1.05t
OP ∞

=
0.05 N .H
105
+
. 2
105 K Q 0

1 L F 1 I O
2

= M1 − G . JK PP = 185941
0.05 NM H 105
.
Q
20,000 × 185941
. = 37,188

Question #114
Key: C

Event Prob Present Value


x=0 ( 0.05) 15
x =1 ( 0.95)( 0.10 ) = 0.095 15 + 20 /1.06 = 33.87
x≥2 ( 0.95)( 0.90 ) = 0.855 15 + 20 /1.06 + 25 /1.062 = 56.12

E [ X ] = ( 0.05 )(15 ) + ( 0.095 )( 33.87 ) + ( 0.855 )( 56.12 ) = 51.95

E ⎡⎣ X 2 ⎤⎦ = ( 0.05 )(15 ) + ( 0.095 )( 33.87 ) + ( 0.855 )( 56.12 ) = 2813.01


2 2 2

( )
Var [ X ] = E X 2 − E ( X ) = 2813.01 − ( 51.95 ) = 114.2
2 2

Question #115
Key: B

Let K be the curtate future lifetime of (x + k)

kL = 1000v K +1 − 1000 Px:3 × a&&K +1


When (as given in the problem), (x) dies in the second year from issue, the curtate
future lifetime of ( x + 1) is 0, so

MLC-09-08 - 74 -
1L = 1000v − 1000 Px:3 a&&1
1000
= − 279.21
1.1
= 629.88 ≈ 630

The premium came from


A
Px:3 = x:3
a&&x:3
Ax:3 = 1 − d a&&x:3
1 − d a&&x:3 1
Px:3 = 279.21 = = −d
a&&x:3 a&&x:3

Test Question: 116 Key: D

Let M = the force of mortality of an individual drawn at random; and T = future lifetime
of the individual.

Pr T ≤ 1 n
= E Pr T ≤ 1 M s
= z

0
Pr T ≤ 1 M = μ f M μ dμ bg
= zz
2 1

0 0
1
μe − μ t dt dμ
2
= zd
2

0
1 − e−μ i 21 du = 21 d2 + e −2
i 21 d1 + e i
−1 = −2

= 0.56767

Question #117
Key: E

Note that above 40, decrement 1 is DeMoivre with omega = 100; decrement 2 is
DeMoivre with omega = 80.
(1)
That means μ 40 ( 20 ) = 1/ 40 = 0.025; μ 40( 2) ( 20 ) = 1/ 20 = 0.05
(τ )
μ 40 ( 20 ) = 0.025 + 0.05 = 0.075
Or from basic definition of μ ,
60 − t 40 − t 2400 − 100t + t 2
(τ )
t p40 = × =
60 40 2400
MLC-09-08 - 75 -
d ( t
( )
p40
τ
)
/ dt = ( −100 + 2t ) / 2400
at t = 20 gives −60 / 2400 = 0.025
( )
= ( 2 / 3) * (1/ 2 ) = 1/ 3
τ
20 p40
(τ )
μ 40 ( 20 ) = ⎡⎢ −d ⎣ ( t p40 )
(τ ) (τ )
/ dt ⎤⎥ / 20 p40

= 0.025 / (1/ 3) = 0.075

Test Question: 118 Key: D

Let π = benefit premium

Actuarial present value of benefits =


b gb g b gb gb
= 0.03 200,000 v + 0.97 0.06 150,000 v 2 + 0.97 0.94 0.09 100,000 v 3 g b gb gb gb g
= 5660.38 + 7769.67 + 6890.08
= 20,32013
.

Actuarial present value of benefit premiums


= a&&x:3 π

b gb g
= 1 + 0.97v + 0.97 0.94 v 2 π
= 2.7266 π
20,32013
.
π = = 7452.55
2.7266

1V =
b7452.55gb106
. g − b200,000gb0.03g
1 − 0.03
= 1958.46

Initial reserve, year 2 = 1V + π


= 1958.56 + 7452.55
= 9411.01

Test Question: 119 Key: A

Let π denote the premium.

L = bT v T − π aT = 1+ i b g T
× v T − π aT
= 1 − π aT
E L = 1 − π ax = 0 ⇒π = 1
ax

MLC-09-08 - 76 -
⇒ L = 1 − π aT = 1 −
aT
=
d
δ ax − 1 − v T i
ax δ ax

=
b
v T − 1 − δ ax
=
g
v T − Ax
δ ax 1 − Ax

Test Question: 120 Key: D

(0, 1) (1, 0.9)

(1.5, 0.8775)

(2, 0.885)

tp1

1 2
t

1 p1 = (1 − 01
. ) = 0.9
2 b gb g
p1 = 0.9 1 − 0.05 = 0.855

b
since uniform, 1.5 p1 = 0.9 + 0.855 / 2 g
= 0.8775

o
e1:1.5 = Area between t = 0 and t = 15
.
FG 1 + 0.9 IJ b1g + FG 0.9 + 0.8775IJ b0.5g
=
H 2 K H 2 K
= 0.95 + 0.444
= 1394
.

Alternatively,

MLC-09-08 - 77 -
o
e11: .5 = z
1.5

0 t
p1dt

= z
1
0 t
0.5
p1dt +1p1 x
0 z p2 dx

= zb
1

0
1 − 01 g
. t dt + 0.9
1
z0
0.5
b1 − 0.05xgdx
0.5
= t − 0.12t + 0.9 x − 0.052 x
2 2

0 0
= 0.95 + 0.444 = 1394
.

Test Question: 121 Key: A

b g
. = 5233
10,000 A63 112
A63 = 0.4672

Ax +1 =
b g
Ax 1 + i − qx
px

A64 =
b0.4672gb105
. g − 0.01788
1 − 0.01788
= 0.4813

A65 =
b0.4813gb105
. g − 0.01952
1 − 0.01952
= 0.4955
Single contract premium at 65 = (1.12) (10,000) (0.4955)
= 5550

b1 + ig 2
=
5550
5233
i=
5550
5233
− 1 = 0.02984

MLC-09-08 - 78 -
Test Question: 122 Key: B

Original Calculation (assuming independence):

μ x = 0.06
μ y = 0.06
μ xy = 0.06 + 0.06 = 012
.
μx 0.06
Ax = = = 0.54545
μ x + δ 0.06 + 0.05
μy 0.06
Ay = = = 0.54545
μ y + δ 0.06 + 0.05
μ xy 012
.
Axy = = = 0.70588
μ xy + δ 012. + 0.05
Axy = Ax + Ay − Axy = 0.54545 + 0.54545 − 0.70588 = 0.38502

Revised Calculation (common shock model):

μ x = 0.06, μ Tx *b x g = 0.04
μ y = 0.06, μ Ty*b y g = 0.04
μ xy = μ Tx *b x g + μ Ty*b y g + μ Z + 0.04 + 0.04 + 0.02 = 010
.
μx 0.06
Ax = = = 0.54545
μ x + δ 0.06 + 0.05
μy 0.06
Ay = = = 0.54545
μ y +δ 0.06 + 0.05
μ xy 010
.
Axy = = = 0.66667
μ xy + δ 010 . + 0.05
Axy = Ax + Ay − Axy = 0.54545 + 0.54545 − 0.66667 = 0.42423

Difference = 0.42423 − 0.38502 = 0.03921

MLC-09-08 - 79 -
Question #123
Key: B

5
q35:45 = 5 q35 + 5 q45 − 5 q35:45
= 5 p35q40 + 5 p45q50 − 5 p35:45q40:50
b g
= 5 p35q40 + 5 p45q50 − 5 p35 × 5 p45 1 − p40:50
= p q + p q − p × p b1 − p p g
5 35 40 5 45 50 5 35 5 45 40 50

= b0.9gb.03g + b0.8gb0.05g − b0.9gb0.8g 1 − b0.97gb0.95g


= 0.01048

Alternatively,

6 p35 = 5 p35 × p40 = ( 0.90 )(1 − 0.03) = 0.873


6 p45 = 5 p45 × p50 = ( 0.80 )(1 − 0.05 ) = 0.76

5 q35:45 = 5 p35:45 − 6 p35:45


= ( 5 p35 + 5 p45 − 5 p35:45 ) − ( 6 p35 + 6 p45 − 6 p35:45 )
= ( 5 p35 + 5 p45 + 5 p35 × 5 p45 ) − ( 6 p35 + 6 p45 − 6 p35 × 6 p45 )
= ( 0.90 + 0.80 − 0.90 × 0.80 ) − ( 0.873 + 0.76 − 0.873 × 0.76 )
= 0.98 − 0.96952
= 0.01048

Test Question: 124 Key: C

z 3

0
bg bg
λ t dt = 6 so N 3 is Poisson with λ = 6.

P is Poisson with mean 3 (with mean 3 since Prob yi < 500 = 0.5 b g g
P and Q are independent, so the mean of P is 3, no matter what the value of Q is.

MLC-09-08 - 80 -
Test Question: 125 Key: A

At age x:
FG 1 A IJ 1000
Actuarial Present value (APV) of future benefits =
H5 Kx

FG 4 a&& IJ π
APV of future premiums =
H5 K x

1000 4
A25 = π a&&25 by equivalence principle
5 5
1000 A25 1 8165
.
=π ⇒π = × = 1258
.
4 a&&25 4 16.2242

10V = APV (Future benefits) – APV (Future benefit premiums)


1000 4
= A35 − π a&&35
5 5
1
b g b gb
= 128.72 − 1258
5
4
5
. 15.3926 g
= 10.25

Test Question: 126 Key: E

Let Y = present value random variable for payments on one life


S = ∑ Y = present value random variable for all payments
E Y = 10a&&40 = 148166
.

Var Y = 10 2 d 2
A40 − A40
2
i
2
d
d
= 100 0.04863 − 016132
. 2
106 ib
. / 0.06 g 2

= 70555
.
E S = 100 E Y = 14,816.6
Var S = 100 Var Y = 70,555
Standard deviation S = 70,555 = 265.62

By normal approximation, need


E [S] + 1.645 Standard deviations = 14,816.6 + (1.645) (265.62)
= 15,254

MLC-09-08 - 81 -
Test Question: 127 Key: B

Initial Benefit Prem =


e
5 A30 − 4 A301 :20 j
5a&&30:35 − 4a&&30:20

=
b
5 010248
. g b
− 4 0.02933 g
b g b
5 14.835 − 4 11959
. g
0.5124 − 011732
. 0.39508
= = = 0.015
74.175 − 47.836 26.339

Where
1
A30:20 e j
= A30:20 − A30:201 = 0.32307 − 0.29374 = 0.02933
and
1 − A30:20 1 − 0.32307
a&&30:20 = = = 11959
d FG IJ
0.06
.
H K
106
.

Comment: the numerator could equally well have been calculated as A30 + 4 20 E30 A50
= 0.10248 + (4) (0.29374) (0.24905)
= 0.39510

Test Question: 128 Key: B

0.75 b gb g
px = 1 − 0.75 0.05
= 0.9625
0.75 b gb g
p y = 1 − 0.75 .10
= 0.925
0.75 qxy = 1− 0.75 pxy

= 1− b p gd p i since independent
0.75 x 0.75 y

= 1- b0.9625gb0.925g
= 01097
.

Question #129
Key: D

Let G be the expense-loaded premium.


Actuarial present value (APV) of benefits = 100,000A35
APV of premiums = Ga&&35
APV of expenses = ⎡⎣ 0.1G + 25 + ( 2.50 )(100 ) ⎤⎦ a&&35
Equivalence principle:

MCL-09-08 - 82 -
Ga&&35 = 100,000 A35 + ( 0.1G + 25 + 250 ) a&&35
A35
G = 100,000 + 0.1G + 275
a&&35
0.9G = 100,000 P35 + 275

G=
(100 )(8.36 ) + 275
0.9
= 1234

Test Question: 130 Key: A

The person receives K per year guaranteed for 10 years ⇒ Ka&&10 = 8.4353K
The person receives K per years alive starting 10 years from now ⇒10 a&&40 K

*Hence we have 10000 = 8.4353+10 E40a&&50 K b g


Derive 10 E40:
A40 = A4010
1
:
+ b 10 E40 gA 50

A40 − A40
1
:10 0.30 − 0.09
10 E40 = = = 0.60
A50 0.35

1 − A50 1 − 0.35
Derive a&&50 = = = 16.90
d .04
104
.

Plug in values:
c
10,000 = 8.4353 + 0.60 16.90 K b gb gh
= 18.5753K
K = 538.35

Test Question: 131 Key: D

STANDARD: eo 25:11 = z11 FG1 − t IJ dt = t − t 2 11

0 H 75K 2 × 75 0
= 101933
.

=e z
1
− 0.1ds
MODIFIED: p25 0
= e −.1 = 0.90484

o
: =
e2511 z1
p dt
0 t 25
+ p25 z FGH
10

0
1−
t
74
IJ
dt
K
MCL-09-08 - 83 -
= z
0
1 −0.1t
e
IJ
dt + e−0.1
K z FGH
10

0
1−
t
74
dt

1− e F t I
−0.1
+ e Gt −
2 10

H 2 × 74 JK
−0.1
=
01
. 0

= 0.95163 + 0.90484b9.32432g = 9.3886

Difference =0.8047

Test Question: 132 Key: B

Comparing B & D: Prospectively at time 2, they have the same future benefits. At issue,
B has the lower benefit premium. Thus, by formula 7.2.2, B has the higher reserve.

Comparing A to B: use formula 7.3.5. At issue, B has the higher benefit premium. Until
time 2, they have had the same benefits, so B has the higher reserve.

Comparing B to C: Visualize a graph C* that matches graph B on one side of t=2 and
matches graph C on the other side. By using the logic of the two preceding paragraphs,
C’s reserve is lower than C*’s which is lower than B’s.

Comparing B to E: Reserves on E are constant at 0.

Test Question: 133 Key: C

Since only decrements (1) and (2) occur during the year, probability of reaching the end
of the year is
′b1g × p60
p60 b gb
′b 2g = 1 − 0.01 1 − 0.05 = 0.9405 g
Probability of remaining through the year is
p60′b1g × p60
′b 2g × p60 b gb
′b3g = 1 − 0.01 1 − 0.05 1 − 010 gb
. = 0.84645 g
Probability of exiting at the end of the year is
b3g = 0.9405 − 0.84645 = 0.09405
q60

MCL-09-08 - 84 -
Question #134
Key: D

Poisoned wine glasses are drunk at a Poisson rate of 2 × 0.01 = 0.02 per day.
Number of glasses in 30 days is Poisson with λ = 0.02 × 30 = 0.60
f ( 0 ) = e −0.60 = 0.55

Test Question: 135 Key: D

APV of regular death benefit = zb ∞


gd ib gd i
100000 e-δ t 0.008 e- μ t dt

zb
0

=

0
gd ib gd
100000 e-0.06t 0.008 e-0.008t dt i
b
= 100000 0.008 / 0.06 + 0.008 = 11,764.71 g
APV of accidental death benefit = zb
30
gd ib gd i
100000 e-δ t 0.001 e- μ t dt

zb
0

=
30
0
gd ib gd
100000 e-0.06t 0.001 e-0.008t dt i
= 100 1 − e-2.04 / 0.068 = 1,279.37
Total APV = 11765 + 1279 = 13044

Test Question: 136 Key: B

b gb g b gb
l 60 +.6 = .6 79,954 + .4 80,625 g
= 80,222.4
b gb g b gb
l 60 +1.5 = .5 79,954 + .5 78,839 g
= 79,396.5

80222.4 − 79,396.5
0.9 q 60 +.6 =
80,222.4
= 0.0103

P0 = 111 = 9.0909%

MCL-09-08 - 85 -
Question #137
Key: E

View the compound Poisson process as two compound Poisson processes, one for
smokers and one for non-smokers. These processes are independent, so the total
variance is the sum of their variances.

For smokers, λ = ( 0.2 )(1000 ) = 200

Var(losses) = λ ⎡⎢ Var ( X ) + ( E ( X ) ) ⎤⎥
2
⎣ ⎦
= 200 ⎡5000 + ( −100 ) ⎤
2
⎣ ⎦
= 3,000,000

For non-smokers, λ = ( 0.8 )(1000 ) = 800

Var(losses) = λ ⎡⎢ Var ( X ) + ( E ( X ) ) ⎤⎥
2
⎣ ⎦
= 800 ⎡8000 + ( −100 ) ⎤
2
⎣ ⎦
= 14, 400,000

Total variance = 3,000,000 + 14,400,000


= 17,400,000

Test Question: 138 Key: A

bτ g = qb1g + qb2g = 0.34


q40 40 40

′b g p40
= 1 − p40 ′b g
1 2

′ b 2g
0.34 = 1 − 0.75 p40

′ b 2g = 0.88
p40
′ b 2g = 012
q40 . =y

′ b 2g = 2 y = 0.24
q41
b gb g
bτ g = 1 − 0.8 1 − 0.24 = 0.392
q41
l b g = 2000b1 − 0.34gb1 − 0.392g = 803
τ
42

MCL-09-08 - 86 -
Test Question: 139 Key: C

b g
Pr L π ' > 0 < 0.5

Pr 10,000v K +1 − π ' a&&K +1 > 0 < 0.5


From Illustrative Life Table, 47 p30 = 0.50816 and 48 p30 =.47681

Since L is a decreasing function of K, to have


b g
Pr L π ′ > 0 < 0.5 means we must have L π ′ ≤ 0 for K ≥ 47. b g
b g
Highest value of L π ′ for K ≥ 47 is at K = 47.
b g
L π ′ at K = 47 = 10,000 v 47+1 − π ′ a&&47+1
= 609.98 − 16.589π ′
b g b
L π ′ ≤ 0 ⇒ 609.98 − 16.589 π ′ ≤ 0 g
609.98
⇒ π′ > = 36.77
16.589

Test Question: 140 Key: B

b g
Pr K = 0 = 1 − px = 01
.
Prb K = 1g = p − p = 0.9 − 0.81 = 0.09
1 x 2 x

Prb K > 1g = p = 0.81


2 x

E bY g = .1 × 1+.09 × 187
. +.81 × 2.72 = 2.4715
E dY i = .1 × 1 +.09 × 187
2 2
. +.81 × 2.72 = 6.407
2 2

VARbY g = 6.407 − 2.4715 = 0.299 2

Question #141
Key: E

E [ Z ] = b Ax
since constant force Ax = μ / μ + δ
bμ b ( 0.02 )
E(Z) = = = b/3
μ +δ ( 0.06 )

MCL-09-08 - 87 -
Var [ Z ] = Var ⎡⎣b v T ⎤⎦ = b 2 Var ⎡⎣ vΤ ⎤⎦ = b 2 ( 2
Ax − Ax2 )
⎛ μ ⎛ μ ⎞ ⎞
2
=b ⎜
2
− ⎟
⎜ μ + 2δ ⎜⎝ μ + δ ⎟⎠ ⎟
⎝ ⎠
⎡ 2 1⎤ ⎛ 4⎞
= b2 ⎢ − ⎥ = b2 ⎜ ⎟
⎣10 9 ⎦ ⎝ 45 ⎠

Var ( Z ) = E ( Z )

⎡4⎤ b
b2 ⎢ ⎥ =
⎣ 45 ⎦ 3
⎡4⎤ 1
b ⎢ ⎥ = ⇒ b = 3.75
⎣ 45 ⎦ 3

Test Question: 142 Key: B

b g b g c A−A h
In general Var L = 1 + δP
2 2
x
2
x

c h
Here P Ax =
1
ax
1
− δ = −.08 =.12
5
F .12 I
So Var b Lg = G 1 + J c A − A h =.5625
2

H .08K
2 2
x x

F b.12gIJ c A − A h
and Var b L *g = G 1 +
5
2

H .08 K
4 2 2
x x

So Var b L *g =
b1 + g b0.5625g =.744
15 2
8

b1 + g 12 2
8

E L * = A −.15a = 1 − a bδ +.15g = 1 − 5b.23g = −.15


x x x

E L * + Var b L *g =.7125

Test Question: 143 Key: C

Serious claims are reported according to a Poisson process at an average rate of 2 per
month. The chance of seeing at least 3 claims is (1 – the chance of seeing 0, 1, or 2
claims).

b g
P 3 + ≥ 0.9 is the same as P 0,1,2 ≤ 01 b g
. is the same as P 0 + P 1 + P 2 ≤ 01
. b g bg b g
MCL-09-08 - 88 -
d
. ≥ e − λ + λe− λ + λ2 / 2 e− λ
01 i
The expected value is 2 per month, so we would expect it to be at least 2 months
bλ=4 . g
Plug in and try
d i
e−4 + 4e−4 + 42 / 2 e−4 =.238, too high, so try 3 months λ = 6 b g
e−6 + 6e−6 + d6 / 2ie
2 −6
=.062, okay. The answer is 3 months.

[While 2 is a reasonable first guess, it was not critical to the solution. Wherever you
start, you should conclude 2 is too few, and 3 is enough].

Test Question: 144 Key: B

Let l0bτ g = number of students entering year 1


superscript (f) denote academic failure
superscript (w) denote withdrawal
subscript is “age” at start of year; equals year - 1

p0bτ g = 1 − 0.40 − 0.20 = 0.40

l2bτ g = 10 l2bτ g q2b f g ⇒ q2b f g = 01


.

q2b wg = q2bτ g − q2b f g = 10


. − 0.6 − 01 b
. = 0.3 g
l1bτ gq1b f g = 0.4 l1bτ g 1 − q1b f g − q1b wg
e j
q1b f g = 0.4 1 − q1b f g − 0.3
e j
q1b f g =
0.28
= 0.2
14
.

p1bτ g = 1 − q1b f g − q1b wg = 1 − 0.2 − 0.3 = 0.5

b g = q b w g + p b τ g q b w g + p b τ g p bτ g q b w g
w
3 q0 0 0 1 0 1 2

b gb g b gb gb g
= 0.2 + 0.4 0.3 + 0.4 0.5 0.3

= 0.38
MCL-09-08 - 89 -
Test Question: 145 Key: D

e25 = p25 1 + e26b g


N
e26 = e26
M
since same μ

N
p25 =e z−
1
0
μ 25
M
bg c h
t + 0.1 1− t dt

=e z z
− μ 25
M 1
bg
t dt − 0.1 1− t dt
0
1
0
c h

=e z e z
− μ 25
M 1
bg
t dt − 0.1 1− t dt
0
1
0
c h

L F I OP1
M MN H
2
− 0.1 t − t2
= p25 e
K Q0

= e−0.05 p25
M

N
e25 = p25
N
b
1 + e26 g
= e−0.05 p25
M
1 + e26 b g
= 0.951 e25
M
= 0.951 10.0 = 9.5 b gb g

MCL-09-08 - 90 -
Test Question: 146 Key: D

E YAGG = 100E Y = 100 10,000 a x b g


F c1 − A hI = 10,000,000
= 100b10,000gG
H δ JK
x

σ Y = Var Y = b10,000g δ1 c A − A h2
2
2
x
2
x

=
b10,000g b0.25g − b016
. g = 50,000
δ

b
σ AGG = 100σ Y = 10 50,000 = 500,000 g
0.90 = Pr
LM F − E Y AGG
>0
OP
N σ AGG Q
F − E YAGG
⇒ 1282
. =
σ AGG
. σ AGG + E YAGG
F = 1282
F = 1282
. b g
500,000 + 10,000,000 = 10,641,000

Question #147
Key: A

1
A30:3 = 1000vq30 + 500v 2 1 q30 + 250v3 2 q30
2 3
⎛ 1 ⎞⎛ 1.53 ⎞ ⎛ 1 ⎞ ⎛ 1.61 ⎞ ⎛ 1 ⎞ ⎛ 1.70 ⎞
= 1000 ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ + 500 ⎜ ⎟ ( 0.99847 ) ⎜ ⎟ + 250 ⎜ ⎟ ( 0.99847 )( 0.99839 ) ⎜ ⎟
⎝ 1.06 ⎠⎝ 1000 ⎠ ⎝ 1.06 ⎠ ⎝ 1000 ⎠ ⎝ 1.06 ⎠ ⎝ 1000 ⎠
= 1.4434 + 0.71535 + 0.35572 = 2.51447
1
⎛ 1 ⎞2 ⎛ 0.00153 ⎞
&&( 2 )
1 1
a30:1 = 1 2 + 1 2 ⎜ ⎟ (1 − 2 q30 ) = + ( 0.97129 ) ⎜1 − ⎟
1
⎝ 1.06 ⎠ 2 2 ⎝ 2 ⎠
1 1
= + ( 0.97129 )( 0.999235 )
2 2
= 0.985273
2.51447
Annualized premium =
0.985273
= 2.552

2.552
Each semiannual premium =
2
= 1.28

MCL-09-08 - 91 -
Test Question: 148 Key: E

b DAg 1
80:20 eb g j
= 20vq80 + vp80 DA 1
8119
:

q80 =.2 13 =
20 .2
+
bg.8
b gDA 81
1
:19
106
. 106
.

b g
∴ DA 8119 1 =
b g. −4
13 106
= 12.225
:
.8
q80 =.1 b g b gb g
DA801 :20 = 20 v .1 + v .9 12.225
2+.9b12.225g
= = 12.267
106
.

Test Question: 149 Key: B

Let T denote the random variable of time until the college graduate finds a job
m bg r
Let N t , t ≥ 0 denote the job offer process

Each offer can be classified as either


R|
Type I - - accept with probability p ⇒ N1 t m b gr
S|Type II - - reject with probability b1 − pg ⇒ mN bt gr
T 2

mN bt gr is Poisson process with λ = λ ⋅ p


1 1
p = Prb w > 28,000g = Prbln w > ln 28,000g
F ln w − 1012
= Prbln w > 10.24g = Pr G
. . I
10.24 − 1012
JK = 1 − Φb1g
H 012 .
>
012
.
= 01587
.
λ1 = 01587
. × 2 = 0.3174
1
T has an exponential distribution with θ = = 315
.
.3174
b g
Pr T > 3 = 1 − F 3 bg
−3
= e 3.15 = 0.386

MCL-09-08 - 92 -
Test Question: 150 Key: A

px = exp −
LM z t ds OP
= exp ln 100 − x − s b g t
=
100 − x − t
t
N 0 100 − x − s Q 0
100 − x

o o o o
e50:60 = e50 + e60 − e50:60
o
e50 =z
50 50 − t
dt =
1 LM
50t −
t2 OP = 25 50

0 50 50 N 2 Q 0

1 L t O
=z
2 40
40 − t
M 40t − P = 20
o 40
e60 dt =
0 40 40 N 2Q 0
o
=z G
F 50 − t IJ FG 40 − t IJ dt = z 1 d2000 − 90t + t idt
40 40

H 50 K H 40 K
2
e50:60
0 20000

1 F I = 14.67
3

2000 GH 3 JK
t
= 2000 t − 45 t + 2 40
0

o
e50:60 = 25 + 20 − 14.67 = 30.33

Question #151
Key: C

Ways to go 0 → 2 in 2 years
0 − 0 − 2; p = ( 0.7 )( 0.1) = 0.07
0 − 1 − 2; p = ( 0.2 )( 0.25 ) = 0.05
0 − 2 − 2; p = ( 0.1)(1) = 0.1

Total = 0.22
Binomial m = 100 q = 0.22
Var = (100) (0.22) (0.78) = 17

Question #152
Key: A

For death occurring in year 2


0.3 × 1000
APV = = 285.71
1.05
For death occurring in year 3, two cases:

MCL-09-08 - 93 -
(1) State 2 → State 1 → State 4: (0.2 × 0.1) = 0.02
(2) State 2 → State 2 → State 4: (0.5 × 0.3) = 0.15
Total 0.17

0.17 ×1000
APV = = 154.20
1.052

Total. APV = 285.71 + 154.20 = 439.91

Test Question: 153 Key: E

b g
Var 0 L b g b g since VarbΛ g = 0
= Var Λ 0 + v 2 Var Λ 1 2

Var b Λ g = v bb − V g p q
2
0 1 1 50 50

=
b10,000 − 3,209g b0.00832gb0.99168g
2

. 2
103
= 358664.09

b g
Var Λ 1 b
= v b2 − 2V g 2
p50q51 p51

=
b10,000 − 6,539g b0.99168gb0.00911gb0.99089g
2

. 2
103
= 101075.09

b g
Var 0 L = 358664.09 +
101075.09
. 2
103
= 453937.06

Alternative solution:

π = 10,000 v − 2V50:3 = 9708.74 − 6539 = 3169.74

MCL-09-08 - 94 -
R|10,000 v − π a&& = 6539 for K = 0
|
1

L = S10,000 v − π a&& = 3178.80 for K = 1


2
0
||10,000 v − π a&& = −83.52 for K > 1
2

T
3
3

Prb K = 0g = q = 0.0083250

Prb K = 1g = p q = b0.99168gb0.00911g = 0.0090342


50 51

Prb K > 1g = 1 − Prb K = 0g − Prb K = 1g = 0.98265


Varb Lg = E L − E L = E L since π is benefit premium
2 2 2
0 0 0 0

= 0.00832 × 6539 + 0.00903 × 3178.80 + 0.98265 × b−83.52g


2 2 2

= 453,895 [difference from the other solution is due to rounding]

Test Question: 154 Key: C

Let π denote the single benefit premium.


π = 30 a&&35 + π A351 :30

π= 30 a&&35
=
eA 35:30
− A35
1
:30 j
a&&65
=
1 − A35
1
:30
1− 1
A35:30

=
b.21−.07g9.9
b1−.07g
1.386
=
.93
= 1.49

Test Question: 155 Key: E

=.5 = e z

0. 4
e F +e2 x jdx
0.4 p0
0

LM e22x OP.4
−.4 F −
=e N Q0
−.4 F −F e 2 −1 I
0.8

=e H K
.5 = e−.4 F −.6128

MCL-09-08 - 95 -
bg
⇒ ln .5 = −.4 F −.6128
⇒ −.6931 = −.4F −.6128
⇒ F = 0.20

Question #156
Key: C

( 9V + P ) (1.03) = qx+9b + (1 − qx+9 ) 10V


= qx +9 ( b − 10V ) + 10V
( 343)(1.03) = 0.02904 ( 872 ) + 10V
⇒ 10V = 327.97
b = ( b − 10V ) + 10V = 872 + 327.97 = 1199.97
⎛ 1 ⎞ ⎛ 1 0.03 ⎞
P = b ⎜ − d ⎟ = 1200 ⎜ − ⎟
⎝ a&&x ⎠ ⎝ 14.65976 1.03 ⎠
= 46.92
9V = initial reserve – P = 343 – 46.92 = 296.08

Question #157
Key: B

d = 0.06 ⇒ V = 0.94

Step 1 Determine px
668 + 258vpx = 1000vqx + 1000v 2 px ( px +1 + qx +1 )
668 + 258 ( 0.94 ) px = 1000 ( 0.94 ) (1 − px ) + 1000 ( 0.8836 ) px (1)
668 + 242.52 px = 940 (1 − px ) + 883.6 px
px = 272 / 298.92 = 0.91

Step 2 Determine 1000 Px:2


668 + 258 ( 0.94 )( 0.91) = 1000 Px:2 ⎡⎣1 + ( 0.94 )( 0.91) ⎤⎦

1000 Px:2 =
[ 220.69 + 668] = 479
1.8554

MCL-09-08 - 96 -
Question #158
Key: D

100,000 ( IA )40:10 = 100,000 v p40 ⎡( IA )41:10 − 10 v10 9 p41 q50 ⎤ + A40:10


1

1

1
(100,000 ) [see comment ]
⎡ ⎛ 8,950,901 ⎞ ⎤
⎢ 10 ⎜ ⎟ ⎥
0.16736 − ⎝
0.99722 ⎢ 9, 287, 264 ⎠
= 100,000 × ( 0.00592 )⎥
1.06 ⎢ 1.0610 ⎥
⎢ ⎥
⎣ ⎦
+ ( 0.02766 × 100,000 )
=15,513

1
Where A40:10 = A40 − 10 E40 A50
= 0.16132 − ( 0.53667 )( 0.24905 )
= 0.02766

Comment: the first line comes from comparing the benefits of the two insurances. At
each of age 40, 41, 42,…,49 ( IA )40:10 provides a death benefit 1 greater than ( IA )41:10 .
1 1

term. But ( IA )41:10 provides a death benefit at 50 of 10, while ( IA )40:10


1 1 1
Hence the A40:10
provides 0. Hence a term involving 9 q41 = 9 p41 q50 . The various v’s and p’s just get all
actuarial present values at age 40.

Question #159
Key: A

10001Vx = π (1 + i ) − qx (1000 − 10001Vx )


40 = 80 (1.1) − qx (1000 − 40 )
88 − 40
qx = = 0.05
960

=
(G − expenses )(1 + i ) − 1000qx
1 AS
px

=
(100 − ( 0.4 )(100 ) ) (1.1) − (1000 )( 0.05)
1 − 0.05
60 (1.1) − 50
= = 16.8
0.95

MCL-09-08 - 97 -
Question #160
Key: C

At any age, p′x ( ) = e −0.02 = 0.9802


1

q′x ( ) = 1 − 0.9802 = 0.0198 , which is also qx( ) , since decrement 2 occurs only at the end of
1 1

the year.

Actuarial present value (APV) at the start of each year for that year’s death benefits
= 10,000*0.0198 v = 188.1

px( ) = 0.9802*0.96 = 0.9410


τ

Ex = px( )v = 0.941 v = 0.941*0.95 = 0.8940


τ

APV of death benefit for 3 years 188.1 + E40 *188.1 + E40 * E41 *188.1 = 506.60

Question #161
Key: B

40

∫ t p30dt
o
e30:40 =
0

ω − 30 − t
40
= ∫ ω − 30
dt
0

t2 40
=t−
2 (ω − 30 ) 0

800
= 40 −
ω − 30
= 27.692

ω = 95

Or, with De Moivre’s law, it may be simpler to draw a picture:

0 p30 = 1 40 p30
30 70

MCL-09-08 - 98 -
o
e30:40 = area =27.692 = 40
(1 + 40 p30 )
2
p30 = 0.3846
40
ω − 70
= 0.3846
ω − 30
ω = 95
65 − t
t p30 =
65

Var = E (T ) − ( E (T ) )
2 2

One way to evaluate this expression is based on Equation 3.5.4 in Actuarial


Mathematics

Var (T ) = ∫ 2 t t px dt − ex2
o
0
65
⎛ t ⎞ ⎛ 65 ⎛ t ⎞
= 2 ∫ t ⎜1 − ⎟dt − ⎜ ∫ ⎜1 − ⎟ dt 2

0 ⎝
65 ⎠ ⎝ 0 ⎝ 65 ⎠
= 2* ( 2112.5 − 1408.333) − ( 65 − 65 / 2 )
2

= 1408.333 − 1056.25 = 352.08

Another way, easy to calculate for De Moivre’s law is

(∫ )
∞ ∞ 2
Var (T ) = ∫ t 2 t px μ x ( t ) dt − t t px μ x ( t ) dt
0 0
2
65 2 1 ⎛ 65 1 ⎞
=∫ t × dt − ⎜ ∫ t × dt ⎟
0 65 ⎝ 0 65 ⎠
2
t3 65 ⎛ t2 65 ⎞
= −⎜ ⎟
3 × 65 0
⎝ 2 × 65 0

= 1408.33 − ( 32.5 ) = 352.08
2

With De Moivre’s law and a maximum future lifetime of 65 years, you probably didn’t
need to integrate to get E (T ( 30 ) ) = e30 = 32.5
o

Likewise, if you realize (after getting ω = 95 ) that T ( 30 ) is uniformly on (0, 65), its
variance is just the variance of a continuous uniform random variable:

MCL-09-08 - 99 -
Var =
( 65 − 0 )
2
= 352.08
12

Question #162
Key: E

218.15 (1.06 ) − 10,000 ( 0.02 )


1V = = 31.88
1 − 0.02
( 31.88 + 218.15)(1.06 ) − ( 9,000 )( 0.021) = 77.66
2V =
1 − 0.021

Question #163
Key: D


ex = e y = ∑ t px = 0.95 + 0.952 + ...
k =1
0.95
= = 19
1 − 0.95
exy = pxy + 2 pxy + ...
= 1.02 ( 0.95 )( 0.95 ) + 1.02 ( 0.95 ) ( 0.95 ) + ...
2 2

1.02 ( 0.95 )
2
= 1.02 ⎡⎣0.95 + 0.95 + ...⎤⎦ =
2 4
= 9.44152
1 − 0.952
exy = ex + e y − exy = 28.56

Question #164
Key: A

Local comes first. I board

So I get there first if he waits more than 28 – 16 = 12 minutes after the local arrived.

His wait time is exponential with mean 12


The wait before the local arrived is irrelevant; the exponential distribution is memoryless
−12
Prob(exp with mean 12>12) = e 12 = e −1 = 36.8%

MCL-09-08 - 100 -
Question #165
Key: E

Deer hit at time s are found by time t (here, t = 10) with probability F(t – s), where F is
the exponential distribution with mean 7 days.
We can split the Poisson process “deer being hit” into “deer hit, not found by day 10”
and “deer hit, found by day 10”. By proposition 5.3, these processes are independent
Poisson processes.
Deer hit, found by day 10, at time s has Poisson rate 20 × F(t – s). The expected
number hit and found by day 10 is its integral from 0 to 10.

t
E ( N ( t ) ) = 20∫ F ( t − s )ds
0
10 −(10 − s )
E ( N (10 ) ) = 20 ∫ 1 − e 7 ds
0
s −10
⎛ 10 ⎞
= 20 ⎜ 10 − 7e 7 ⎟
⎜ ⎟
⎝ 0

(
= 20 10 − 7 + 7e
−10 7
) = 94
Question #166
Key: E


ax = ∫ e −0.08t dt = 12.5
0
∞ 3
Ax = ∫ e −0.08t ( 0.03) dt = = 0.375
0 8
∞ 3
2
Ax = ∫ e −0.13t ( 0.03) dt = = 0.23077
0 13

( ) 1 ⎡2
Ax − ( Ax ) ⎤ = 400 ⎡ 0.23077 − ( 0.375 ) ⎤ = 6.0048
2
σ aT = Var ⎡⎣ aT ⎤⎦ =
2
2 ⎢ ⎥ ⎣ ⎦
δ ⎣ ⎦
( )
Pr ⎡⎣ aT > ax − σ aT ⎤⎦ = Pr ⎡⎣ aT > 12.5 − 6.0048⎤⎦
⎡ 1 − vT ⎤
= Pr ⎢ > 6.4952 ⎥ = Pr ⎡⎣ 0.67524 > e−0.05T ⎤⎦
⎣ 0.05 ⎦
⎡ − ln 0.67524 ⎤
= Pr ⎢T >
⎣ 0.05 ⎥⎦ = Pr [T > 7.85374]
= e −0.03×7.85374 = 0.79
Question #167
Key: A

MCL-09-08 - 101 -
(τ )
= e ( )( ) = e −0.25 = 0.7788
− 0.05 5
5 p50
(1) 5 (1)
( t ) × e−( 0.03+0.02)t dt = − ( 0.02 / 0.05 ) e−0.05t
5
5 q55 = ∫ μ55
0 0

(
= 0.4 1 − e −0.25
)
= 0.0885

( ) () τ
Probability of retiring before 60 = 5 p50 × 5 q55
1

= 0.7788*0.0885
= 0.0689

Question #168
Key: C

Complete the table:


l81 = l[80] − d[80] = 910
l82 = l[81] − d[81] = 830 (not really needed)
o 1 ⎛1 ⎞
e x = ex + ⎜ since UDD ⎟
2 ⎝2 ⎠
o
e[ x] = e[ x] + 1 2
o ⎡ l + l + l +K⎤ 1
e[ x] = ⎢ 81 82 83 ⎥+
⎢⎣ l[80] ⎥⎦ 2
⎡ ⎤
⎢ eo − 1 ⎥ l = l + l + K Call this equation (A)
⎢ [80] 2 ⎥ [80] 81 82
⎣ ⎦
⎡ ⎤
⎢ eo − 1 ⎥ l = l + K Formula like (A), one age later. Call this (B)
⎢ [81] 2 ⎥ [81] 82
⎣ ⎦

Subtract equation (B) from equation (A) to get

⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤
⎢ o 1⎥ ⎢ o 1⎥
l81 = e[80] − l[80] − e[81] − l[81]
⎢ 2⎥ ⎢ 2⎥
⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦
⎡o ⎤
910 = [8.5 − 0.5]1000 − ⎢e[81] − 0.5⎥ 920
⎣ ⎦

MCL-09-08 - 102 -
o 8000 + 460 − 910
e[81] = = 8.21
920

Alternatively, and more straightforward,

910
p[80] = = 0.91
1000
830
p[81] = = 0.902
920
830
p81 = = 0.912
910

e[80] = 1 q 80 + p 80 ⎛⎜1 + eo 81 ⎞⎟
o

2 [ ] [ ]
⎝ ⎠
1
where q[80] contributes since UDD
2
1 ⎛ o ⎞
8.5 = (1 − 0.91) + ( 0.91) ⎜1 + e81 ⎟
2 ⎝ ⎠
o
e81 = 8.291

o 1 ⎛ o ⎞
e81 = q81 + p81 ⎜ 1 + e82 ⎟
2 ⎝ ⎠
1 ⎛ o ⎞
8.291 = (1 − 0.912 ) + 0.912 ⎜ 1 + e82 ⎟
2 ⎝ ⎠
o
e82 = 8.043
o 1 ⎛ o ⎞
e[81] = q[81] + p[81] ⎜ 1 + e82 ⎟
2 ⎝ ⎠
1
= (1 − 0.902 ) + ( 0.902 )(1 + 8.043)
2
= 8.206

o
Or, do all the recursions in terms of e, not e , starting with e[80] = 8.5 − 0.5 = 8.0 , then final
o
step e[81] = e[81] + 0.5

MCL-09-08 - 103 -
Question #169
Key: A

T px +t t px vt vt t px
0 0.7 1 1 1
1 0.7 0.7 0.95238 0.6667
2 − 0.49 0.90703 0.4444
3 − − – −

2
From above a&&x:3 = ∑ vt t px = 2.1111
t =0

⎛ a&& ⎞ ⎛ 1 ⎞
1000 2Vx:3 = 1000 ⎜ 1 − x + 2:1 ⎟ = 1000 ⎜1 − ⎟ = 526
⎜ a&&x:3 ⎟ ⎝ 2.1111 ⎠
⎝ ⎠

Alternatively,

1
Px:3 = − d = 0.4261
a&&x:3

(
1000 2Vx:3 = 1000 v − Px:3 )
= 1000 ( 0.95238 − 0.4261)
= 526

You could also calculate Ax:3 and use it to calculate Px:3 .

MCL-09-08 - 104 -
Question #170
Key: E

Let G be the expense-loaded premium.


Actuarial present value (APV) of benefits = 1000A50 .
APV of expenses, except claim expense = 15 + 1× a&&50
APV of claim expense = 50A50 (50 is paid when the claim is paid)
APV of premiums = G a&&50
Equivalence principle: Ga&&50 = 1000 A50 + 15 + 1× a&&50 + 50 A50
1050 A50 + 15 + a&&50
G=
a&&50
a
For De Moivre’s with ω = 100, x = 50 A50 = 50 = 0.36512
50
1 − A50
a&&50 = = 13.33248
d

Solving for G, G = 30.88

Question #171
Key: A

p50 = e ( )( ) = 0.8187
− 0.05 4
4

p50 = e ( )( ) = 0.6065
− 0.05 10
10

p60 = e ( )( ) = 0.7261
− 0.04 8
8

18 p50 = ( 10 p50 )( 8 p60 ) = 0.6065 × 0.7261


= 0.4404

414 q50 = 4 p50 − 18 p50 = 0.8187 − 0.4404 = 0.3783

MCL-09-08 - 105 -
Question #172
Key: D

a&&40:5 = a&&40 − 5 E40 a&&45


= 14.8166 − ( 0.73529 )(14.1121)
= 4.4401
π a&&40:5 = 100,000 A45 v5 5 p40 + π ( IA )40:5
1

(
π = 100,000 A45 × 5 E40 / a&&40:5 − ( IA )40:5
1
)
= 100,000 ( 0.20120 )( 0.73529 ) / ( 4.4401 − 0.04042 )
= 3363

Question #173
Key: B

Calculate the probability that both are alive or both are dead.
P(both alive) = k pxy = k px ⋅ k p y
P(both dead) = k qxy = k q x k q y
P(exactly one alive) = 1 − k pxy − k qxy
Only have to do two year’s worth so have table

Pr(both alive) Pr(both dead) Pr(only one alive)


1 0 0
(0.91)(0.91) = 0.8281 (0.09)(0.09) = 0.0081 0.1638
(0.82)(0.82) = 0.6724 (0.18)(0.18) = 0.0324 0.2952

⎛ 1 0.8281 0.6724 ⎞ ⎛ 0 0.1638 0.2952 ⎞


APV Annuity = 30,000 ⎜ + + 2 ⎟
+ 20,000 ⎜ + + ⎟ = 80, 431
⎝ 1.05 1.05 ⎠ ⎝ 1.05 1.052 ⎠
0 1 0
1.05 1.051

Alternatively,

0.8281 0.6724
a&&xy = 1 + + = 2.3986
1.05 1.052
0.91 0.82
a&&x = a&&y = 1 + + = 2.6104
1.05 1.052
APV = 20,000 a&&x + 20,000 a&&y − 10,000 a&&xy
(it pays 20,000 if x alive and 20,000 if y alive, but 10,000 less than that if both are
alive)

MCL-09-08 - 106 -
= ( 20,000 )( 2.6104 ) + ( 20,000 )( 2.6104 ) − (10,000 ) 2.3986
= 80, 430

Other alternatives also work.

Question #174
Key: C

Let P denote the contract premium.

∞ ∞
P = ax = ∫ e −δ t e − μ t dt = ∫ e−0.05t dt = 20
0 0

E [ L] = axIMP −P
10 ∞
−0.03(10 ) −0.02(10 )
axIMP = ∫e −0.03t −0.02t
e dt + e e ∫e
−0.03t −0.01t
e dt
0 0

l − e −0.5 e−0.5
= + = 23
0.05 0.04
E [ L ] = 23 − 20 = 3
E [ L] 3
= = 15%
P 20

Question #175
Key: C

1
A30:2 = 1000vq30 + 500v 2 1 q 30
2
⎛ 1 ⎞ ⎛ 1 ⎞
= 1000 ⎜ ⎟ ( 0.00153) + 500 ⎜ ⎟ ( 0.99847 )( 0.00161)
⎝ 1.06 ⎠ ⎝ 1.06 ⎠
= 2.15875
Initial fund = 2.15875 × 1000 participants = 2158.75

Let Fn denote the size of Fund 1 at the end of year n.

F1 = 2158.75 (1.07 ) − 1000 = 1309.86


F2 = 1309.86 (1.065 ) − 500 = 895.00

Expected size of Fund 2 at end of year 2 = 0 (since the amount paid was the single
benefit premium). Difference is 895.

MCL-09-08 - 107 -
Question #176
Key: C

Var [ Z ] = E ⎡⎣ Z 2 ⎤⎦ − E [ Z ]
2

(v b )
∞ ∞
E [Z ] = ∫ t
t t p x μ x ( t ) dt = ∫ e −0.08t e0.03t e −0.02t ( 0.02 ) dt
0 0
∞ 0.02 2
=∫ ( 0.02 ) e−0.07t dt = =
7
0 0.07

(e )
∞ 2 ∞
( vt bt ) t px μ x ( t ) dt = ∫ e −0.02t ( 0.02 ) dt
2
E ⎡⎣ Z 2 ⎤⎦ = ∫ −0.05t
0 0

= ∫ 0.02 e −0.12t μ x ( t ) dt = 2 =1
0 12 6
1 2
( ) 1 4
2
Var [ Z ] = − = − = 0.08503
6 7 6 49

Question #177
Key: C

0.1
From Ax = 1 − d ax
&& we have Ax = 1 − (8 ) = 311
1.1
0.1
Ax +10 = 1− ( 6 ) = 511
1.1
Ax = Ax × i
δ

3 0.1
Ax = × = 0.2861
11 ln (1.1)
5 0.1
Ax +10 = × = 0.4769
11 ln (1.1)

10Vx = Ax +10 − P ( Ax ) × a&&x +10


⎛ 0.2861 ⎞
= 0.4769 − ⎜ ⎟6
⎝ 8 ⎠
= 0.2623

There are many other equivalent formulas that could be used.

MCL-09-08 - 108 -
Question #178
Key: C


Regular death benefit = ∫ 100,000 × e −0.06t × e −0.001t 0.001dt
0

⎛ 0.001 ⎞
= 100,000 ⎜ ⎟
⎝ 0.06 + 0.001 ⎠

= 1639.34

= ∫ 100,000 e −0.06t e −0.001t ( 0.0002 ) dt


10
Accidental death
0

10
= 20 ∫ e −0.061t dt
0

⎡1 − e −0.61 ⎤
= 20 ⎢ ⎥ = 149.72
⎣ 0.061 ⎦

Actuarial Present Value = 1639.34 + 149.72 = 1789.06

Question #179
Key: D

Once you are dead, you are dead. Thus, you never leave state 2 or 3, and rows 2 and
3 of the matrix must be (0 1 0) and (0 0 1).

Probability of dying from cause 1 within the year, given alive at age 61, is 160/800 =
0.20.

Probability of dying from cause 2 within the year, given alive at age 61, is 80/800 = 0.10

Probability of surviving to 62, given alive at 61, is 560/800 = 0.70


(alternatively, 1 – 0.20 – 0.10), so correct answer is D.

MCL-09-08 - 109 -
Question #180
Key: C

This first solution uses the method on the top of page 9 of the study note.

Note that if the species is it is not extinct after Q3 it will never be extinct.
This solution parallels the example at the top of page 9 of the Daniel study note. We
want the second entry of the product ( Q1 × Q2 × Q3 ) e3 which is equal to
Q1 × ( Q2 × ( Q3 × e3 ) ) .

0 0
Q3 0 = 0.1
1 1
0 0.01
Q2 0.1 = 0.27
1 1
0.01 0.049
Q1 0.27 = 0.489
1 1

The second entry is 0.489; that’s our answer.

Alternatively, start with the row matrix (0 1 0) and project it forward 3 years.

(0 1 0 ) Q1 = (0.00 0.70 0.30)


(0 0.70 0.30) Q2 = (0.07 0.49 0.44)
(0.07 0.49 0.44) Q3 = (0.16 0.35 0.49)

Thus, the probability that it is in state 3 after three transitions is 0.49.

Yet another approach would be to multiply Q1 × Q2 × Q3 , and take the entry in row 2,
column 3. That would work but it requires more effort.

MCL-09-08 - 110 -
Question #181
Key: B

Probabilities of being in each state at time t:

t Active Disabled Dead Deaths


0 1.0 0.0 0.0
1 0.8 0.1 0.1 0.1
2 0.65 0.15 0.2 0.1
3 not needed not needed 0.295 0.095

We built the Active Disabled Dead columns of that table by multiplying each row times
the transition matrix. E.g., to move from t = 1 to t = 2, (0.8 0.1 0.1) Q = (0.65 0.15
0.2)
The deaths column is just the increase in Dead. E.g., for t = 2, 0.2 – 0.1 = 0.1.

v = 0.9
( )
APV of death benefits = 100,000* 0.1v + 0.1v 2 + 0.095v3 = 24,025.5
APV of $1 of premium = 1 + 0.8v + 0.65v 2 = 2.2465

24,025.5
Benefit premium = = 10,695
2.2465

Question #182
Key: A

Split into three independent processes:


Deposits, with λ * = ( 0.2 )(100 )( 8 ) = 160 per day
Withdrawals, with λ * = ( 0.3)(100 )( 8 ) = 240 per day
Complaints. Ignore, no cash impact.

For aggregate deposits,


E ( D ) = (160 )( 8000 ) = 1, 280,000
Var ( D ) = (160 )(1000 ) + (160 )( 8000 )
2 2

= 1.04 × 1010

For aggregate withdrawals


E (W ) = ( 240 )( 5000 ) = 1, 200,000
Var (W ) = ( 240 )( 2000 ) + ( 240 )( 5000 )
2 2

= 0.696 ×1010

MCL-09-08 - 111 -
E (W − D ) = 1, 200,000 − 1, 280,000 = −80,000
Var (W − D ) = 0.696 ×1010 + 1.04 × 1010 = 1.736 × 1010
SD (W − D ) = 131,757
⎛ W − D + 80,000 80,000 ⎞
Pr (W > D ) = Pr (W − D > 0 ) = Pr ⎜ >
⎝ 131,757 131,757 ⎟⎠
= 1 − Φ ( 0.607 )
= 0.27

Question #183
Key: D

Exponential inter-event times and independent implies Poisson process (imagine


additional batteries being activated as necessary; we don’t care what happens after two
have failed).

Poisson rate of 1 per year implies failures in 3 years is Poisson with λ = 3 .

x f(x) F(x)
0 0.050 0.050
1 0.149 0.199

Probe works provided that there have been fewer than two failures, so we want F(1) =
0.199.

Alternatively, the sum of two independent exponential θ = 1 random variables is Gamma


with α = 2, θ = 1
1 3 −t
F ( 3) = Γ ( 2;3) =
Γ ( 2 ) ∫0
t e dt

= ( −t − 1) e −t
3

0
−3
= 1− 4e
= 0.80 is probability 2 have occurred
1 – 0.80 = 0.20

MCL-09-08 - 112 -
Question #184
Key: B

1000 P45a&&45:15 + π a&&60:15 × 15 E45 = 1000 A45


A45
1000 ( a&&45 − 15 E45 a&&60 ) + π ( a&&60 − 15 E60 a&&75 )( 15 E45 ) = 1000 A45
a&&45

201.20
14.1121
(14.1121 − ( 0.72988)( 0.51081)(11.1454 )
+π (11.1454 − ( 0.68756 )( 0.39994 )( 7.2170 ) ) × ( 0.72988 )( 0.51081) = 201.20
where 15 E x was evaluated as 5 Ex × 10 Ex +5

14.2573 ( 9.9568 ) + (π )( 3.4154 ) = 201.20

π = 17.346

Question #185
Key: A

1V = ( 0 V + π ) (1 + i ) − (1000 + 1V − 1V ) qx
2V = ( 1V + π )(1 + i ) − ( 2000 + 2V − 2V ) qx +1 = 2000
( (π (1 + i ) − 1000q ) +π )(1 + i ) − 2000q = 2000
x x +1

( (π (1.08) − 1000 × 0.1) + π ) (1.08) − 2000 × 0.1 = 2000


π = 1027.42

MCL-09-08 - 113 -
Question #186
Key: A

Let Y be the present value of payments to 1 person.


Let S be the present value of the aggregate payments.

E [Y ] = 500 a&&x = 500


(1 − Ax ) = 5572.68
d

σ Y = Var [Y ] = ( 500 )2
1
d2
( 2
)
Ax − Ax2 = 1791.96

S = Y1 + Y2 + ... + Y250
E ( S ) = 250 E [Y ] = 1,393,170
σ S = 250 × σ Y = 15.811388σ Y = 28,333
⎡ S − 1,393,170 F − 1,393,170 ⎤
0.90 = Pr ( S ≤ F ) = Pr ⎢ ≤
⎣ 28,333 28,333 ⎥⎦
⎡ F − 1,393,170 ⎤
≈ Pr ⎢ N ( 0,1) ≤
⎣ 28,333 ⎥⎦
0.90 = Pr ( N ( 0,1) ≤ 1.28 )
F = 1,393,170 + 1.28 ( 28,333)
=1.43 million

Question #187
Key: A

q41 1 bg
q ′ b1g = 1 − p′ b1g = 1 − e p bτ g j
bg
q41 τ
41 41 41

l41( ) = l40( ) − d 40( ) − d 40( ) = 1000 − 60 − 55 = 885


τ τ 1 2

d 41( ) = l41( ) − d 41( ) − l42( ) = 885 − 70 − 750 = 65


1 τ 2 τ

q41( )
1
(τ ) 750 65
p41 = (τ )
=
885 q41 135

65

′ (1) = 1 − ⎛⎜
750 ⎞ 135
q41 ⎟ = 0.0766
⎝ 885 ⎠

MCL-09-08 - 114 -
Question #188
Key: D

α
⎛ x⎞
s ( x ) = ⎜1 − ⎟
⎝ ω⎠
α
log ( s ( x ) ) =
d
μ ( x) =
dx ω−x
α
ω −x ⎛ t ⎞ ω−x
ex = ∫
o
⎜1 − ⎟ dt =
0 ⎝ ω −x⎠ α +1

o 1 ω ω
e0new = × old = new ⇒ α new = 2α old + 1
2 α +1 α +1
2α + 1 9 α
old old
μ (0new ) = = × ⇒ α old = 4
ω 4 ω

Question #189
Key: C

Constant force implies exponential lifetime

2
⎛1⎞
Var [T ] = E ⎡⎣T ⎤⎦ − ( E [T ])
2 2 1
2
= 2 − ⎜ ⎟ = 2 = 100
μ ⎝μ⎠ μ
μ = 0.1


E ⎡⎣ min (T ,10 ) ⎤⎦ = ∫ t ( 0.1)e −.1t dt + ∫ 10 ( 0.1)e−.1t dt
10

0 10
−.1t −.1t 10 ∞
= −te − 10e − 10e−.1t
0 10
−1 −1 −1
= −10e − 10e + 10 + 10e
= 10 (1 − e −1 ) = 6.3

Question #190

MCL-09-08 - 115 -
Key: A

% premium amount for 15 years


644474448
Ga&&x:15 ( 144244
)
= 100,000 Ax + 0.08G + 0.02Ga&&x:15 + ( ( x − 5 ) + 5a&&x )
3
Per policy for life

4669.95 (11.35 ) = 51, 481.97 + ( 0.08 )( 4669.95 ) + ( 0.02 )(11.35 )( 4669.95 ) + ( ( x − 5 ) + 5a&&x )

1 − Ax 1 − 0.5148197
a&&x = = = 16.66
d 0.02913

53,003.93 = 51, 481.97 + 1433.67 + ( x − 5 ) + 83.30


4.99 = ( x − 5 )
x = 9.99

The % of premium expenses could equally well have been expressed as


0.10G + 0.02G ax:14 .
The per policy expenses could also be expressed in terms of an annuity-immediate.

Question #191
Key: D

For the density where T ( x ) ≠ T ( y ) ,

Pr (T ( x ) < T ( y ) ) = ∫
40 y 50 40
y = 0 ∫x = 0
0.0005dxdy + ∫
y = 40 ∫x = 0
0.0005dxdy

40 y 50 40
=∫ 0.0005 x dy + ∫ 0.0005 x dy
y =0 0 y = 40 0

40 50
= ∫ 0.0005 ydy + ∫ 0.02 dy
0 y = 40

0.0005 y 2 40 50
= + 0.02 y
2 0 40

= 0.40 + 0.20 = 0.60

For the overall density,

MCL-09-08 - 116 -
Pr (T ( x ) < T ( y ) ) = 0.4 × 0 + 0.6 × 0.6 = 0.36
where the first 0.4 is the probability that T ( x ) = T ( y ) and the first 0.6 is the probability
that T ( x ) ≠ T ( y ) .

Question #192
Key: B

1
The conditional expected value of the annuity, given μ , is .
0.01 + μ
The unconditional expected value is
0.02 1 ⎛ 0.01 + 0.02 ⎞
ax = 100∫ d μ = 100 ln ⎜ ⎟ = 40.5
0.01 0.01 + μ ⎝ 0.01 + 0.01 ⎠

100 is the constant density of μ on the internal [ 0.01,0.02] . If the density were not
constant, it would have to go inside the integral.

Question #193
Key: E

o ω−x
Recall ex =
2
o o o o
ex:x = ex + ex − ex:x
ω−x ⎛ t ⎞⎛ t ⎞
ex:x = ∫
o
⎜1 − ⎟ ⎜1 − ⎟ dt
0 ⎝ ω − x ⎠⎝ ω − y ⎠

Performing the integration we obtain


o ω−x
ex:x =
3
o 2 (ω − x )
ex:x =
3

2 (ω − 2a ) 2 (ω − 3a )
(i) = 3× ⇒ 2ω = 7a
3 3
2 2 (ω − 3a )
(ii) (ω − a ) = k ×
3 3
3.5a − a = k ( 3.5a − 3a )

MCL-09-08 - 117 -
k =5

The solution assumes that all lifetimes are independent.

Question #194
Key: B

μ ⎛ 0.10 ⎞
Upon the first death, the survivor receives 10,000 = 10,000 ⎜ ⎟ = 7143
μ +δ ⎝ 0.10 + 0.04 ⎠
The actuarial present value of the insurance of 7143 is
μ xy ⎛ 0.12 ⎞
7,143 = ( 7,143) ⎜ ⎟ = 5357
μ xy + δ ⎝ 0.12 + 0.04 ⎠

If the force of mortality were not constant during each insurance period, integrals would
be required to express the actuarial present value.

Question #195
Key: E

Let k p0 = Probability someone answers the first k problems correctly.


p0 = ( 0.8 ) = 0.64 p0 = ( 0.8 ) = 0.41
2 4
2 4

p0:0 = ( 2 p0 ) = 0.642 = 0.41 p0:0 = ( 0.41) = 0.168


2 2
2 4

2 p0:0 = 2 p0 + 2 p0 − 2 p0:0 = 0.87 4 p0:0 = 0.41 + 0.41 − 0.168 = 0.652

Prob(second child loses in round 3 or 4) = 2 p0:0 − 4 p0:0


= 0.87-0.652
= 0.218

2 p0:0 − 4 p0:0
Prob(second loses in round 3 or 4 second loses after round 2) =
2 p0:0
0.218
= = 0.25
0.87

Question #196
Key: E

MCL-09-08 - 118 -
If (40) dies before 70, he receives one payment of 10, and Y = 10. Under DeMoivre, the
probability of this is (70 – 40)/(110 – 40) = 3/7

If (40) reaches 70 but dies before 100, he receives 2 payments.


Y = 10 + 20v30 = 16.16637
The probability of this is also 3/7. (Under DeMoivre, all intervals of the same length,
here 30 years, have the same probability).

If (40) survives to 100, he receives 3 payments.


Y = 10 + 20v30 + 30v 60 = 19.01819
The probability of this is 1 – 3/7 – 3/7 = 1/7
E (Y ) = ( 3/ 7 ) ×10 + ( 3/ 7 ) × 16.16637 + (1/ 7 ) × 19.01819 = 13.93104

( )
E Y 2 = ( 3/ 7 ) × 102 + ( 3/ 7 ) × 16.16637 2 + (1/ 7 ) × 19.018192 = 206.53515

( )
Var (Y ) = E Y 2 − ⎡⎣ E (Y ) ⎤⎦ = 12.46
2

Since everyone receives the first payment of 10, you could have ignored it in the
calculation.

Question #197
Key: C

( )
2
E ( Z ) = ∑ v k +1bk +1 k px qx+ k
k =0

= ⎡⎣ v ( 300 ) × 0.02 + v 2 ( 350 )( 0.98 )( 0.04 ) + v3 400 ( 0.98 )( 0.96 )( 0.06 ) ⎤⎦


= 36.8

( ) = ∑ (v )
2 2
2 k +1
E Z bk +1 k px qx + k
k =0

= v 2 ( 300 ) × 0.02 + v 4 ( 350 ) ( 0.98 )( 0.04 ) + v 6 4002 ( 0.98 )( 0.96 ) 0.06


2 2

= 11,773
( )
Var [ Z ] = E Z 2 − E ( Z )
2

= 11,773 − 36.82
= 10, 419

MCL-09-08 - 119 -
Question #198
Key: A

Benefits + Expenses – Premiums


0 Le = 1000v +
3
( 0.20G + 8) + ( 0.06G + 2 ) v + ( 0.06G + 2 ) v 2 − G a&&3

at G = 41.20 and i = 0.05,


0 Le ( for K = 2 ) = 770.59
Question #199
Key: D

P = 1000 P40

( 235 + P )(1 + i ) − 0.015 (1000 − 255) = 255 [A]

( 255 + P )(1 + i ) − 0.020 (1000 − 272 ) = 272 [B]

Subtract [A] from [B]

20 (1 + i ) − 3.385 = 17

20.385
1+ i = = 1.01925
20

Plug into [A] ( 235 + P )(1.01925 ) − 0.015 (1000 − 255 ) = 255


255 + 11.175
235 + P =
1.01925

P = 261.15 − 235 = 26.15

1000 25V40 =
( 272 + 26.15 )(1.01925 ) − ( 0.025)(1000 )
1 − 0.025

= 286

MCL-09-08 - 120 -
Question #200
Key: A

1.2

1 1

0.8

0.6
0.5
0.4 0.4

0.2

0 0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

Give Give Give


Given
n n n
x 0 15 25 35 75 90 100
s ( x) 1 0.70 0.50 0.48 0.4 0.16 0
Linear Linear Linear
Interpolation Interpolation Interpolation

s ( 90 ) 0.16 32
55 q35 = 1− = 1− = = 0.6667
s ( 35 ) 0.48 48

s ( 35 ) − s ( 90 ) 0.48 − 0.16 32
20 55 q15 = = = = 0.4571
s (15 ) 0.70 70

20 55 q15 0.4571
= = 0.6856
55 q35 0.6667

Alternatively,

20 55 q15 20 p15 × 55 q35 s ( 35 )


= = 20 p15 =
55 q35 55 q35 s (15 )
0.48
=
0.70
= 0.6856

MCL-09-08 - 121 -
Question #201
Key: A

s ( 80 ) = 1 * ( e ^ ( −0.16*50 ) + e ^ ( −0.08*50 ) ) = 0.00932555


2
s ( 81) = 1 * ( e ^ ( −0.16*51) + e ^ ( −0.08*51) ) = 0.008596664
2

p80 = s ( 81) / s ( 80 ) = 0.008596664 / 0.00932555 = 0.9218


q80 = 1 − 0.9218 = 0.078

Alternatively (and equivalent to the above)


For non-smokers, px = e −0.08 = 0.923116
50 px = 0.018316
For smokers, px = e −0.16 = 0.852144
50 p x = 0.000335

So the probability of dying at 80, weighted by the probability of surviving to 80, is

0.018316 × (1 − 0.923116 ) + 0.000335 × (1 − 0.852144 )


= 0.078
0.018316 + 0.000335

Question #202
Key: B

lx( ) d x( ) d x( )
x τ 1 2

40 2000 20 60
41 1920 30 50
42 1840 40

because 2000 − 20 − 60 = 1920 ; 1920 − 30 − 50 = 1840

Let premium = P
⎛ 2000 1920 1840 2 ⎞
APV premiums = ⎜ + v+ v ⎟ P = 2.749 P
⎝ 2000 2000 2000 ⎠
⎛ 20 30 2 40 3 ⎞
APV benefits = 1000 ⎜ v+ v + v ⎟ = 40.41
⎝ 2000 2000 2000 ⎠
40.41
P= = 14.7
2.749

MCL-09-08 - 122 -
Question #203
Key: A

10 ∞
a30 = ∫ e−0.08t e −0.05dt + 10 Ex ∫ e−0.08t e−0.08t dt
0 0
10 −0.13t −1.3 ∞ −0.16
=∫ e dt + e ∫0 e dt
0

−e −0.13t 10 −e −0.16t
( )

+ e −1.3
0.13 0 0.16 0
−1.3
−e 1.3
1 e
= + +
0.13 0.13 0.16
= 7.2992

A30 = ∫ e −0.08t e −0.05t ( 0.05 ) dt + e−1.3 ∫ e−0.16t ( 0.08 ) dt
10
0 0

⎛ 1 e ⎞ −1.3
e −1.3
= 0.05 ⎜ − ⎟ + ( 0.08 )
⎝ 0.13 0.13 ⎠ 0.16
= 0.41606

= P ( A30 ) =
A30 0.41606
= = 0.057
a30 7.29923
1 1
a40 = =
0.08 + 0.08 0.16
A40 = 1 − δ a40
= 1 − ( 0.08 / 0.16 ) = 0.5

10V ( A40 ) = A40 − P ( A40 ) a40


= 0.5 −
( 0.057 ) = 0.14375
0.16

Question #204
Key: C

Let T be the future lifetime of Pat, and [T] denote the greatest integer in T. ([T] is the
same as K, the curtate future lifetime).

L = 100,000 vT − 1600 a&& T 0 < T ≤10


[ ]+1
= 100,000vT − 1600 a&&10 10 < t ≤ 20
−1600 a&&10 20<t

Minimum is −1600 a&&10 when evaluated at i = 0.05


= −12,973

MCL-09-08 - 123 -
Question #205
Key: B

Method 1: as three independent processes, based on the amount deposited. Within


each
process, since the amount deposited is always the same, Var ( X ) = 0 .

Rate of depositing 10 = 0.05 * 22 = 1.1


Rate of depositing 5 = 0.15 * 22 = 3.3
Rate of depositing 1 = 0.80 * 22 = 17.6

Variance of depositing 10 = 1.1 * 10 * 10 = 110


Variance of depositing 5 = 3.3 * 5 * 5 = 82.5
Variance of depositing 1 = 17.6 * 1 *1 = 17.6

Total Variance = 110 + 82.5 + 17.6 = 210.1

Method 2: as a single compound Poisson process


E ( X ) = 0.8 × 1 + 0.15 × 5 + 0.05 × 10 = 2.05

( )
E X 2 = 0.8 ×12 + 0.15 × 52 + 0.05 × 102 = 9.55

Var ( S ) = E ( N )Var ( X ) + Var ( N ) ( E ( X ) )


2

(
= ( 22 )( 5.3475 ) + ( 22 ) 2.052 )
= 210.1

Question #206
Key: A

Pa&&x:3 = APV (stunt deaths)


⎡ 2500 + 2486 /1.08 + 2466 / (1.08 )2 ⎤ ⎛ 4 /1.08 + 5 / (1.08 )2 + 6 / (1.08 )3 ⎞
P⎢ ⎥ = 500000 ⎜ ⎟
⎢⎣ 2500 ⎥⎦ ⎜ 2500 ⎟
⎝ ⎠
P ( 2.77 ) = 2550.68
⇒ p = 921

MCL-09-08 - 124 -
Question #207
Key: D

80 ⎛ x2 ⎞
o ∫30 s ( x ) dx =
80
∫30 ⎜⎝ 1 − 10,000 ⎟⎠ dx
e30:50 =
s ( 30 ) ⎛ 30 ⎞
2
1− ⎜ ⎟
⎝ 100 ⎠
⎛ x3 ⎞ 80
⎜ x − ⎟
⎝ 30,000 ⎠ 30
=
0.91
33.833
=
0.91
= 37.18

Question #208
Key: B

A60 = v × ( p60 × A61 + q60 )


= (1/1.06 ) × ( 0.98 × 0.440 + 0.02 )
= 0.42566
a&&60 = (1 − A60 ) / d
= (1 − 0.42566 ) / ( 0.06 /1.06 )
= 10.147
100010V50 = 1000 A60 − 1000 P50 × a&&60
= 425.66 − 10.147 × 25
= 172

MCL-09-08 - 125 -
Question #209
Key: E

Let Portfolio be the present value random variable for the aggregate payments.

Let Y65 = present value random variable for an annuity due of one on one life age 65.
Thus E (Y65 ) = a&&65
Let Y75 = present value random variable for an annuity due of one on one life age 75.
Thus E (Y75 ) = a&&75

Let X represent the 95th percentile.

E (Portfolio) = 50 ( 2 ) a&&65 + 30 (1) a&&75


= 100 ( 9.8969 ) + 30 ( 7.217 ) = 1206.20
Var (Portfolio) = 50 × 22Var [Y65 ] + 30 (1) Var [Y75 ] = 200 (13.2996 ) + 30 (11.5339 ) = 3005.94
2

where Var [Y65 ] =


1
d2
( 2
A65 − A65
2
)
=
1
( 0.05660 ) 2
⎡0.23603 − ( 0.4398 )2 ⎤ = 13.2996
⎣ ⎦

and Var [Y75 ] =


1
d2
( 2
A75 − A75
2
= ) 1
( 0.05660 ) 2
⎡0.38681 − ( 0.59149 )2 ⎤ = 11.5339
⎣ ⎦

⎡⎛ X − E ( Portfolio ) ⎞ ⎤
Pr ⎢⎜ ⎟ ≤ 1.645⎥ = 0.95 ⇒ X = E ( Portfolio ) + 1.645 Var [ Portfolio ]
⎢⎜⎝ Var ( Portfolio ) ⎟⎠ ⎥
⎣ ⎦
= 1206.20 + 1.645 ( 54.826 )
= 1296.39

Question #210
Key: C

∞ 1
a = ∫ e −δ t × e− μt dt =
0 δ +μ
1 1
∫ 0.5 δ + μ d μ = 100,000 × ⎡⎣ln (δ + 1) − ln (δ + 0.5)⎤⎦
1
APV = 50,000 ×
0.5
⎛ 0.045 + 1 ⎞
= 100,000 × ln ⎜ ⎟
⎝ 0.045 + 0.5 ⎠
= 65,099

MCL-09-08 - 126 -
Question #211
Key: E

The process described, where a key feature is the exponential time between events, is
a
Poisson process with λ = 1 5 per minute.
The number of claims in any interval of length n minutes has a Poisson distribution with
mean
λn = n / 5 .

Here n = 10. So parameter = 10/5 = 2


Pr ( N ≥ 2 ) = 1 − Pr ( N = 0 ) − Pr ( N = 1)
= 1 − e −2 − e −2 2
= 1 − 0.135 − 0.271 = 0.594

Question #212
Key: D

The payouts in any time period of length t have a Poisson distribution with parameter
5t .

The payouts can be grouped by size. For each i, the number of payouts of size i is a
Poisson random variable with mean 5t / 2i , and these random variables are
independent.
Since they are independent Poisson random variables, the sum of the payouts of size 1,
⎛ 5t 5t 5t ⎞ 35t
2 or 3 is a Poisson random variable with mean ⎜ + + ⎟ =
⎝2 4 8⎠ 8

35 1
For t = 1/ 3 hour, the mean is × = 1.4583
8 3
f (0) = e −1.4583 = 0.23

MCL-09-08 - 127 -
Question #213
Key: D

How long was the expected wait during first 45 minutes? In that interval, wait is
exponential with
θ = 30, so

1 − 30x ∞ 1 − 30x
E ⎡⎣ min ( X , 45 ) ⎤⎦ = ∫ x e dx + ∫ 45 e dx
45

0 30 45 30
⎛ −
45

= 30 ⎜ 1 − e 30 ⎟ = 23.31
⎝ ⎠

Expected trains =
45
= 1.5 , so f ( 0 trains ) =
e −1.5
(1.5)0 = 0.223
30 0!

If 0, wait an additional 15 minutes (expected) so

Total expected wait = 23.31 + ( 0.223)(15 ) = 26.65

o
Note that this problem is equivalent to calculate e x

⎧1/ 30, 0 ≤ t < 45


where μ x ( t ) = ⎨
⎩1/15, t ≥ 45

o o o
and solution is e x = e x:45 + 45 p x e x + 45

Question #214
Key: A

Let π be the benefit premium at issue.

A45:20 ⎡0.20120 − 0.25634 ( 0.43980 ) + 0.25634 ⎤⎦


π = 10,000 = 10,000 ⎣
a&&45:20 14.1121 − 0.25634 ( 9.8969 )
= 297.88

The expected prospective loss at age 60 is

MCL-09-08 - 128 -
10,00015V45:20 = 10,000 A60:5 − 297.88 a&&60:5
= 10,000 × 0.7543 − 297.88 × 4.3407
= 6250

1
where A60:5 = 0.36913 − 0.68756 ( 0.4398 ) = 0.06674
A60:51 = 0.68756
A60:5 = 0.06674 + 0.68756 = 0.7543
a&&60:5 = 11.1454 − 0.68756 × 9.8969 = 4.3407

1
After the change, expected prospective loss = 10,000 A60:5 + (Reduced Amount) A60:51
Since the expected prospective loss is the same
6250 = (10,000 )( 0.06674 ) + ( Reduced Amount )( 0.68756 )
Reduced Amount = 8119

Question #215
Key: D

Ax = Ax1:5 + 5 Ex Ax1+5 :7 + 12 Ex Ax +12


where
−5( 0.04 + 0.02 )
5 Ex = e = 0.7408
0.04
Ax1:5 = × (1 − 0.7408 ) = 0.1728
0.04 + 0.02
−7 ( 0.05+ 0.02 )
7 E x +5 = e = 0.6126
⎛ 0.05 ⎞
Ax +1 5 :7 = ⎜ ⎟ (1 − 0.6126 ) = 0.2767
⎝ 0.05 + 0.02 ⎠
12 E x = 5 E x × 7 E x + 5 = 0.7408 × 0.6126 = 0.4538
0.05
Ax +12 = = 0.625
0.05 + 0.03
Ax = 0.1728 + ( 0.7408 )( 0.2767 ) + ( 0.4538 )( 0.625 )
= 0.6614

Question #216
Key: A

APV of Accidental death benefit and related settlement expense =


0.004
( 2000 ×1.05) × = 89.36
0.004 + 0.04 + 0.05
0.04
APV of other DB and related settlement expense = (1000 ×1.05 ) × = 446.81
0.094

MCL-09-08 - 129 -
APV of Initial expense = 50
3
APV of Maintenance expense = = 31.91
0.094
100
APV of future premiums = = 1063.83
0.094
APV of 0 Le = 89.36 + 446.81 + 50 + 31.91 − 1063.83
= −445.75

Question #217
Key: C

Compute the probabilities of moving from healthy to NH. There are three paths.

H to H to NH: (0.8)(0.05) = 0.04


H to HHC to NH: (0.15)(0.05) = 0.0075
H to NH to NH: (0.05)(1) = 0.05

Summing, we get 0.0975 as the probability for each member.


Variance for m members = mpq, here = 50*(0.0975)(0.9025) = 4.40

Question #218
Key: C

⎛ 0.6 0.3 0.1⎞ ⎛ 0.36 0.18 0.46 ⎞


⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟
Q0 = ⎜ 0 0 1 ⎟ Q0 × Q1 = ⎜ 0 0 1 ⎟
⎜ 0 1 ⎟⎠ ⎜ 0 1 ⎟⎠
⎝ 0 ⎝ 0

⎛ 0 0.108 0.892 ⎞
⎜ ⎟
Q0 × Q1 × Q2 = ⎜ 0 0 1 ⎟
⎜0 1 ⎟⎠
⎝ 0

APV ( Premiums ) = 1 + 0.9v + 0.54v 2 + 0.108v3 = 2.35

( )
APV ( Benefits ) = 4 0.3v + 0.18v 2 + 0.108v3 = 2.01

Difference = 2.35 – 2.01 = 0.34

In the formula for APV (Premiums), states 0 and 1 are combined. For example, the
0.54 v 2 term represents a 0.36 probability of being in state 0 plus a 0.18 probability of
being in
state 1.

MCL-09-08 - 130 -
Alternatively, the same effort here but often shorter when everyone is in the same initial
state:

(1.00 0.00 0.00 ) × Q0 = ( 0.6 0.3 1)


( 0.60 0.30 0.10 ) × Q1 = ( 0.36 0.18 0.46 )
( 0.36 0.18 0.46 ) × Q2 = ( 0 0.108 0.892 )

This method just calculates the top row of the cumulative transition matrix. It gives the
same elements you use if you calculate the complete cumulative transition matrix, so
you finish the problem the same way as before.

Question #219
Key: E

0.25 1.5 q x = 0.25 px − 1.75 px


Let μ be the force of mortality in year 1, so 3 μ is the force of mortality in year 2.
Probability of surviving 2 years is 10%
⎧ 0.10 = px px +1 = e − μ e −3μ = e −4 μ

⎨ ln ( 0.1)
⎪μ = = 0.5756
⎩ 4
px = e − 4( 0.5756 ) = 0.8660
1
0.25
3 13
−μ
− ( 3μ ) − ( 0.5756 )
1.75 px = px × 0.75 px +1 = e e 4 =e 4 = 0.1540

0.251.5 q x px − 1.75 px 0.866 − 0.154


1.5 q x + 0.25 = = = = 0.82
0.25

0.25 px 0.25 p x 0.866

Question #220
Key: C

The form of lx for non-smokers matches DeMoivre’s law, so


1
μ xNS =
110 − x
2
= 1 μ xS ⇒ μ xS =
2 110 − x
⇒ l xS = l0S (110 − x ) [see note below]
2

MCL-09-08 - 131 -
Thus S
S
l20
= S+t =
( 90 − t ) 2

t p20
l20 902

NS
l25 +t (85 − t )
t p25 = =
NS
NS
l25 85

85
e 20:25 = ∫
o
p20:25dt
0 t

=∫
85
pS NS
p25 dt =∫
( 90 − t ) ( 85 − t )
85
2
dt
0 t 20 t 0
( 90 )2 85
1
( 90 − t )2 ( 90 − t − 5) dt
85
=
688,500 ∫ 0

1 ⎡ 85 ( 90 − t )3 dt − 5 85 ( 90 − t )2 dt
688,500 ⎢⎣ ∫ 0 ∫0
=
85
1 ⎡ − ( 90 − t )4 5 ( 90 − t )3 ⎤
= ⎢ + ⎥
688,500 ⎢ 4 3 ⎥⎦ 0

1
= [ −156.25 + 208.33 + 16, 402,500 − 1, 215,000]
688,500
= 22.1

[There are other ways to evaluate the integral, leading to the same result].

Note: the solution above assumes the candidate will recognize that the smoker mortality
is modified DeMoivre and can proceed directly to the lx or s ( x ) form. The s ( x ) form is
x⎛ 2 ⎞
−∫ ⎜ x 2
0 ⎝ 110 −t ⎟⎠ 2ln (110−t ) ⎛ 110 − x ⎞
derived as s ( x ) = e dt = e 0 =⎜ ⎟
⎝ 110 ⎠
The lx form is equivalent.

Question #221
Key: B

a&&30:20 = a&&30:10 + 10 E30 × a&&40:10


15.0364 = 8.7201 + 10 E30 × 8.6602
10 E30 = (15.0364 − 8.7201) / 8.6602 = 0.72935
Actuarial present value (APV) of benefits =

MCL-09-08 - 132 -
= 1000 × A40:10
1
+ 2000 × 10 E30 × A50:10
1

= 16.66 + 2 × 0.72935 × 32.61 = 64.23


APV of premiums = π × a&&30:10 + 2π × 0.72935 × a&&40:10
= π × 8.7201 + 2 × π × 0.72935 × 8.6602
= 21.3527π

π = 64.23/ 21.3527 = 3.01

MCL-09-08 - 133 -
Question #222
Key: A

1
A25:15
15V25 = P25 &&
s25:15 − (this is the retrospective reserve calculation)
15 E25
1
P25:15 = P25:15 − P25:151 = 0.05332 − 0.05107
= 0.00225
1
A25:15
=
a&&25:15
15 E25 1
0.05107 = P25:151 = =
a&&25:15 &&
s25:15
1
1
A25:15 A25:15 / a&&25:15 0.00225
= = = 0.04406
15 E25 15 E25 / a&&25:15 0.05107
0.01128
s25:15 =
P25 && = 0.22087
0.05107
25,00015V25 = 25,000 ( 0.22087 − 0.04406 ) = 25,000 ( 0.17681) = 4420

There are other ways of getting to the answer, for example writing
A: the retrospective reserve formula for 15V25 .
1
B: the retrospective reserve formula for 15V25:15 , which = 0
Subtract B from A to get
(P25 − P25:15
1
)
s25:15 = 15V25
&&

Question #223
Key: C

ILT:
We have p70 = 6,396,609 / 6,616,155 = 0.96682
2 p70 = 6,164,663/ 6,616,155 = 0.93176

e70:2 = 0.96682 + 0.93176 = 1.89858


CF: 0.93176 = 2 p70 = e −2 μ ⇒ μ = 0.03534
Hence e70:2 = p70 + 2 p71 = e − μ + e−2 μ = 1.89704

DM: Since l70 and 2 p70 for the DM model equal the ILT, therefore l72 for the DM
model

MCL-09-08 - 134 -
also equals the ILT. For DM we have l70 − l71 = l71 − l72 ⇒ l71(
DM )
= 6,390, 409

Hence e70:2 = 6,390, 409 / 6,616,155 + 6,164,663/ 6,616,155 = 1.89763

So the correct order is CF < DM < ILT


You could also work with p’s instead of l’s. For example, with the ILT,

p70 = (1 − 0.03318 ) = 0.96682


2 p70 = ( 0.96682 )(1 − 0.03626 ) = 0.93176

Note also, since e70:2 = p70 + 2 p70 , and 2 p70 is the same for all three, you could just
order p70 .

Question #224
Key: D

( )τ
l60 = 1000
( )
= 1000 ( 0.99 )( 0.97 )( 0.90 ) = 864.27
τ
l61
( ) τ
d 60 = 1000 − 864.27 = 135.73
( ) − ln ( 0.9 ) 0.1054
= 135.73 × = = 98.05
3
d 60
− ln ⎡⎣( 0.99 )( 0.97 )( 0.9 ) ⎤⎦ 0.1459
( )
= 864.27 ( 0.987 )( 0.95 )( 0.80 ) = 648.31
τ
l62
( ) τ
d 61 = 864.27 − 648.31 = 215.96
( ) − ln ( 0.80 ) 0.2231
= 215.96 × = = 167.58
3
d 61
− ln ⎡⎣( 0.987 )( 0.95 )( 0.80 ) ⎤⎦ 0.2875

( ) ( )
+ d 61 = 98.05 + 167.58 = 265.63
3 3
So d60

Question #225
Key: B

t p40 = e −0.05t
t p50 = ( 60 − t ) / 60
μ50+t = 1/ ( 60 − t )

MCL-09-08 - 135 -
10
−0.05t
10 10 e 1 e−0.05t
∫0 t p40:50 μ50+t dt = ∫
0 60
dt = −
60 ( 0.05 ) 0

=
20
60
( )
1 − e −0.5 = 0.13115

Question #226
Key: A

3 5
Actual payment (in millions) = + 2 = 6.860
1.1 1.1
0.30
q3 = 1 − = 0.5
0.60

0.30 − 0.10
1 q3 = = 0.333
0.60
⎛ 0.5 0.333 ⎞
Expected payment = 10 ⎜ + 2 ⎟
= 7.298
⎝ 1.1 1.1 ⎠

6.860
Ratio = 94%
7.298

Question #227
Key: E

At duration 1

K ( x) 1L Prob
1 v− Px1:2 qx +1
>1 0 − Px1:2 1 − qx +1

So Var ( 1 L ) = v 2 qx +1 (1 − qx +1 ) = 0.1296

That really short formula takes advantage of


Var ( a X + b ) = a 2Var ( X ) , if a and b are constants.
Here a = v; b = Px1:2 ; X is binomial with p ( X = 1) = qx +1 .

Alternatively, that same formula for Var arises from Hattendorf, since

MCL-09-08 - 136 -
2V = 0 and Var ( 2 L ) = 0
Alternatively, evaluate Px1:2 = 0.1303
1L = 0.9 − 0.1303 = 0.7697 if K ( x ) = 1
1L = 0 − 0.1303 = −0.1303 if K ( X ) > 1
E ( 1 L ) = ( 0.2 )( 0.7697 ) + ( 0.8 )( −0.1303) = 0.0497

( )
E 1 L2 = ( 0.2 )( 0.7697 ) + ( 0.8 )( −0.1303) = 0.1320
2 2

Var ( 1 L ) = 0.1320 − ( 0.0497 ) = 0.1295


2

Question #228
Key: C

δ Ax ( 0.1) ( 13 )
P ( Ax ) =
Ax Ax
= = = = 0.05
ax ⎛ 1 − Ax ⎞ 1 − Ax (1 − 13 )
⎜ δ ⎟
⎝ ⎠
⎛ P ( Ax ) ⎞
2

Var ( L ) = ⎜ 1 +
⎜ δ

⎟ ( 2
Ax − Ax2 )
⎝ ⎠
2
1 ⎛ 0.05 ⎞
= ⎜1 + ⎟
5 ⎝ 0.10 ⎠
( 2
Ax − Ax2 )
( 2
)
Ax − Ax2 = 0.08888

⎛ π⎞
2
Var [ L′] = ⎜1 + ⎟
⎝ δ⎠
( 2
Ax − Ax2 )
π ⎞
2
16 ⎛
= ⎜1 + ⎟ ( 0.08888 )
45 ⎝ 0.1 ⎠
π ⎞
2

⎜1 + ⎟ =4
⎝ 0.1 ⎠
π = 0.1

Question #229
Key: E

Seek g such that Pr aT ( 40 ) > g = 0.25 { }


aT is a strictly increasing function of T.

MCL-09-08 - 137 -
100 − 40
Pr {T ( 40 ) > 60} = 0.25 since p40 = = 0.25
120 − 40
60

{
∴ Pr aT
( 40 ) }
> a60 = 0.25

g = a60 = 19.00

Question 230
Key: B

⎛ 0.05 ⎞
A51:9 = 1 − da&&51:9 = 1 − ⎜ ⎟ ( 7.1) = 0.6619
⎝ 1.05 ⎠

11V = ( 2000 )( 0.6619 ) − (100 )( 7.1) = 613.80

( 10V + P ) (1.05) = 11V + q50 ( 2000 − 11V )

( 10V + 100 ) (1.05) = 613.80 + ( 0.011)( 2000 − 613.80 )

10V = 499.09

where q50 = ( 0.001)(10 ) + ( 0.001) = 0.011

Alternatively, you could have used recursion to calculate A50:10 from A51:9 , then a&&50:10
from A50:10 , and used the prospective reserve formula for 10V .

Question #231
Key: C

1000 A81 = (1000 A80 ) (1 + i ) − q80 (1000 − A81 )

689.52 = ( 679.80 )(1.06 ) − q80 (1000 − 689.52 )

720.59 − 689.52
q80 = = 0.10
310.48

MCL-09-08 - 138 -
q[80] = 0.5q80 = 0.05

1000 A[80] = 1000vq[80] + vp[80] 1000 A81


0.05 0.95
= 1000 × + 689.52 × = 665.14
1.06 1.06

Question #232
Key: D

lx( ) d x( ) d x( )
τ 1 2

42 776 8 16
43 752 8 16

(τ ) (τ )
came from lx( +1) = lx( ) − d x( ) − d x( )
τ τ 1 2
l42 and l43

APV Benefits =
( )
2000 8v + 8v 2 + 1000 16v + 16v 2 ( ) = 76.40
776

⎛ 776 + 752v ⎞
APV Premiums = 34 ⎜ ⎟ = ( 34 )(1.92 ) = 65.28
⎝ 776 ⎠

2V = 76.40 − 65.28 = 11.12

Question #233
Key: B

pxx = 1 − qxx = 0.96

px = 0.96 = 0.9798

px +1:x +1 = 1 − qx +1:x +1 = 0.99

px +1 = 0.99 = 0.995

0.9798 ( 0.9798 )( 0.995 )


a&&x = 1 + vpx + v 2 × 2 px = 1 + +
1.05 1.052
= 2.8174

MCL-09-08 - 139 -
0.96 ( 0.96 )( 0.99 )
a&&xx = 1 + vpxx + v 2 × 2 pxx = 1 + + = 2.7763
1.05 1.052
APV = 2000 a&&x + 2000 a&&x + 6000 a&&xx
= ( 4000 )( 2.8174 ) + ( 6000 )( 2.7763)
= 27,927

Notes: The solution assumes that the future lifetimes are identically distributed. The
precise description of the benefit would be a special 3-year temporary life annuity-due.

Question #234
Key: B

p′x( ) μ x( ) ( t ) = q′x( ) = 0.20


1 1 1
t

p′x( ) = 1 − tq′x( ) = 1 − 0.08t


2 2
t

p′x( ) = 1 − tq′x( ) = 1 − 0.125t


3 3
t

qx( ) = ∫ px( ) μ x( ) ( t ) dt = ∫ t p′x( ) t p′x( ) t p′x( ) μ x( ) ( t ) dt


1 1 τ 1 1 2 3 1 1
0t 0

= ∫ (1 − 0.08t )(1 − 0.125t )( 0.20 ) dt


1
0

( )
1
= 0.2 ∫ 1 − 0.205t + 0.01t 2 dt
0
1
⎡ 0.205t 2 0.01t 3 ⎤
= 0.2 ⎢t − + ⎥
⎣ 2 3 ⎦0
⎡ 0.01 ⎤
= ( 0.2 ) ⎢1 − 0.1025 + = 0.1802
⎣ 3 ⎥⎦

Question #235
Key: B

a&&41 14.6864
1V40 = 1− = 1− = 0.00879
a&&40 14.8166
(1000 )(1)
1 CV40 = ( 0.00879 ) = 2.93
3

MCL-09-08 - 140 -
AS =
( G − 0.1G − (1.50 )(1) ) (1.06 ) − 1000q40
(d ) ( w)
− 1CV40 × q40
1 ( ) ( )
1 − q40 − q40
d w

=
( 0.9G − 1.50 )(1.06 ) − (1000 )( 0.00278) − ( 2.93)( 0.2 )
1 − 0.00278 − 0.2

0.954G − 1.59 − 2.78 − 0.59


=
0.79722

= 1.197G − 6.22

AS =
( 1 AS + G − 0.1G − (1.50 )(1) ) (1.06 ) − 1000q41 − 2 CV40 × q41
(d ) ( w)
2 ( ) ( )
1 − q41 − q41
d w

=
(1.197G − 6.22 + G − 0.1G − 1.50 )(1.06 ) − (1000 )( 0.00298) − 2 CV40 × 0
1 − 0.00298 − 0

=
( 2.097G − 7.72 )(1.06 ) − 2.98
0.99702

= 2.229G − 11.20

2.229G − 11.20 = 24
G = 15.8

Question #236
Key: A

AS =
( 4 AS + G (1 − c4 ) − e4 ) (1 + i ) − 1000q x + 4 − 5 CV × q x + 4
(1) ( 2)

1 − qx(+)4 − qx(+ 4)
5 1 2

=
( 396.63 + 281.77 (1 − 0.05) − 7 ) (1 + i ) − 90 − 572.12 × 0.26
1 − 0.09 − 0.26

=
( 657.31)(1 + i ) − 90 − 148.75
0.65
= 694.50

MCL-09-08 - 141 -
( 657.31)(1 + i ) = 90 + 148.75 + ( 0.65)( 694.50 )
690.18
1+ i = = 1.05
657.31
i = 0.05

Question #237
Key: C

Excluding per policy expenses, policy fee, and expenses associated with policy fee.
APV (actuarial present value) of benefits = 25,000 Ax:20 = ( 25,000 )( 0.4058 ) = 10,145

Let G denote the expense-loaded premium, excluding policy fee.

APV of expenses = ( 0.25 − 0.05 ) G + 0.05G a&&x:20 + ⎡⎣( 2.00 − 0.50 ) + 0.50 a&&x:20 ⎤⎦ ( 25,000 /1000 )
= ⎡⎣0.20 + ( 0.05 )(12.522 ) ⎤⎦ G + ⎡⎣1.50 + ( 0.50 )(12.522 ) ⎤⎦ 25
= 0.8261G + 194.025

APV of premiums = G a&&x:20 = 12.522 G

Equivalence principle:

APV premium = APV benefits + APV expenses


12.522 G = 10,145 + 0.8261G + 194.025
10,339.025
G= = 883.99
(12.522 − 0.8261)
This G is the premium excluding policy fee.

Now consider only year 1 per policy expenses, the year one policy fee (call it F1 ), and
expenses associated with F1 .

APV benefits = 0
APV premium = F1

Equivalence principle

F1 = 15 + 0.25 F1
15
F1 = = 20
0.75

MCL-09-08 - 142 -
Total year one premium = G + F1
= 884+20
= 904

Question #238
Key: B

Get G as in problem 3; G = 884

Now consider renewal per policy expenses, renewal policy fees (here called FR ) and expenses
associated with FR .

APV benefits = 0

APV expenses = ( 3 + 0.05 FR ) ax:19


= ( 3 + 0.05 FR )(12.522 − 1)
= 34.566 + 0.5761FR

APV premiums = ax:19 FR


= (12.522 − i ) FR
= 11.522 FR

Equivalence principle:

11.522 FR = 34.566 + 0.5761 FR


34.566
FR = = 3.158
11.522 − 0.5761

Total renewal premium = G + FR


= 884 + 3.16
= 887

Since all the renewal expenses are level, you could reason that at the start of every renewal year,
3
you collect FR and pay expenses of 3 + 0.05 FR , thus FR = = 3.16
1 − 0.05

Such reasoning is valid, but only in the case the policy fee and all expenses in the policy fee
calculation are level.

MCL-09-08 - 143 -
Question #239
Key: B

Let P denote the expense-loaded premium

From problem 3, APV of benefits = 10,145


From calculation exactly like problem 3,
APV of premiums = 12.522 P

APV of expenses = ( 0.25 − 0.05 ) P + 0.05 P a&&x:20 + ⎡⎣( 2.00 − 0.50 ) + 0.50 a&&x:20 ⎤⎦ ( 25000 /1000 )
+ (15 − 3) + 3 a&&x:20
= 0.20 P + ( 0.05 P )(12.522 ) + (1.50 + ( 0.50 )(12.522 ) ) ( 25 ) + 12 + ( 3)(12.522 )
= 0.8261 P + 243.59

Equivalence principle:

12.522 P = 10,145 + 0.8261 P + 244


10,389
P=
12.522 − 0.8261
= 888

Question #240
Key: D

Let G denote the expense-loaded premium.


Actuarial present value (APV) of benefits = 1000A40:20

APV of premiums = G a&&40:10

APV of expenses = ( 0.04 + 0.25 ) G + 10 + ( 0.04 + 0.05 ) G a40:9 + 5a40:19


= 0.29G + 10 + 0.09G a40:9 + 5a40:19
= 0.2G + 10 + 0.09G a&&40:10 + 5a40:19

(The above step is getting an a&&40:10 term since all the answer choices have one. It could
equally well have been done later on).

Equivalence principle:

MCL-09-08 - 144 -
G a&&40:10 = 1000 A40:20 + 0.2G + 10 + 0.09G a&&40:10 + 5 a40:19
( )
G a&&40:10 − 0.2 − 0.09 a&&40:10 = 1000 A40:20 + 10 + 5 a40:19
1000 A40:20 + 10 + 5 a40:19
G=
0.91a&&40:10 − 0.2

Question #241
Key: C

Let G denote the expense-loaded premium excluding policy fee.


Actuarial Present Value (APV) of benefits = 1000 Ax
= 100,000 (1 − d a&&x )
⎛ ⎛ 0.04 ⎞ ⎞
= 100,000 ⎜1 − ⎜ ⎟ (10.8 ) ⎟
⎝ ⎝ 1.04 ⎠ ⎠
= 58, 462

APV of premiums = G a&&x = 10.8 G

Excluding per policy expenses and expenses on the policy fee,


APV(expenses) = 0.5 G + ( 2.0 )(100 ) + ( 0.04 G + ( 0.5 )(100 ) ) ax
= 0.5 G + 200 + ( 0.04 G + 50 )( 9.8 )
= 0.892 G + 690

Equivalence principle:
10.8 G = 58, 462 + 0.892 G + 690
59,152
G= = 5970.13
9.908

Let F denote the policy fee.


APV of benefits = 0
APV of premiums = F a&&x = 10.8 F
APV of expenses = 150 + 25 ax + 0.5 F + 0.04 F ax
= 150 + 25 ( 9.8 ) + 0.5 F + 0.04 F ( 9.8 )
= 395 + 0.892 F

Equivalence principle:

MCL-09-08 - 145 -
10.8 F = 395 + 0.892 F
395
F=
10.8 − 0.892
= 39.87
Total premium = G + F
= 5970.13 + 39.87
= 6010

Note: Because both the total expense-loaded premium and the policy fee are level, it was not
necessary to calculate the policy fee separately. Let P be the combined expense-loaded
premium.

APV benefits = 58,462


APV premiums = 10.8P
APV expenses = 0.892 P + 690 + 150 + ( 25 )( 9.8 )
= 0.892 P + 1085

where 0.892P + 690 is comparable to the expenses in G above, now including all
percent of premium expense.

Equivalence principle:
10.8 P = 58, 462 + 0.892 P + 1085
59547
P=
10.8 − 0.892
= 6010

This (not calculating the policy fee separately, even though there is one) only works with
level premiums and level policy fees.

Question #242
Key: C

(d ) ( w)
AS =
( 10 AS + G − c10 G − e10 ) (1 + i ) − 10,000q x +10 − 11 CV q x +10

1 − qx(+10) − qx(+10)
11 d w

=
(1600 + 200 − ( 0.04 )( 200 ) − 70 ) (1.05) − (10,000 )( 0.02 ) − (1700 )( 0.18)
1 − 0.02 − 0.18

MCL-09-08 - 146 -
1302.1
=
0.8

= 1627.63

Question #243
Key: E

Let G denote the expense-loaded premium.


G = benefit premium plus level premium (e) for expenses.
Expense reserve = Actuarial Present Value (APV) of future expenses – APV of future
expense premiums.

At duration 9, there is only one future year’s expenses and due future premium, both
payable at the start of year 10.

Expense reserve = APV of expenses – APV of expense premiums


= 0.10G + 5 – e
( )
= 0.10 1000 P35:10 + e + 5 − e
= ( 0.10 )( 76.87 ) + 5 − 0.9e
= 12.687 – 0.9e

12.687 – 0.9e = – 1.67


e = 15.95

G = 1000 P35:10 + e
= 76.87 + 15.95
= 92.82

MCL-09-08 - 147 -
Question #244
Key: C

( 3 AS + G − c4G − e4 ) (1 + i ) − 1000qx(+d3) − 4 CVqx(+w3)


4 AS =
1 − qx( +3) − qx( +3)
d w

Plugging in the given values:

=
( 25.22 + 30 − ( 0.02 )( 30 ) − 5) (1.05) − 1000 ( 0.013) − 75 ( 0.05)
4 AS
1 − 0.013 − 0.05

35.351
=
0.937

= 37.73

With higher expenses and withdrawals:

25.22 + 30 − (1.2 ) ( ( 0.02 )( 30 ) + 5 ) (1.05 ) − 1000 ( 0.013) − 75 (1.2 )( 0.05 )


4 AS
revised
=
1 − 0.013 − (1.2 )( 0.05 )

=
( 48.5)(1.05) − 13 − 4.5
0.927

33.425
=
0.927

= 36.06

4 AS − 4 AS revised = 37.73 − 36.06


= 1.67

MCL-09-08 - 148 -
Question #245
Key: E

Let G denote the expense-loaded premium.


APV (actuarial present value) of benefits = 100010 20 A30 .
APV of premiums = Ga&&30:5 .
APV of expenses = ( 0.05 + 0.25 ) G + 20 first year
+ ⎡⎣( 0.05 + 0.10 ) G + 10 ⎤⎦ a 30:4 years 2-5
+10 5 a&&35:4 years 6-10 (there is no premium)
= 0.30G + 0.15G a30:4 + 20 + 10 a30:4 + 10 5 a&& 30:5
= 0.15G + 0.15Ga&&30:5 + 20 + 10 a30:9

(The step above is motivated by the form of the answer. You could equally well put it that form
later).

Equivalence principle:
Ga&&30:5 = 100010 20 A30 + 0.15G + 0.15G a&&30:5 + 20 + 10 a30:9

G=
(1000 10 20 A30 + 20 + 10 a 30:9 )
(1 − 0.15) a&&30:5 − 0.15

=
(1000 10 20 A30 + 20 + 10 a30:9 )
0.85 a&&30:5 − 0.15

MCL-09-08 - 149 -
Question #246
Key: E

Let G denote the expense-loaded premium


APV (actuarial present value) of benefits
= ( 0.1)( 3000 ) v + ( 0.9 )( 0.2 )( 2000 ) v 2 + ( 0.9 )( 0.8 )1000v 2
300 360 720
= + + = 1286.98
1.04 1.04 1.042
2

APV of premium = G
APV of expenses = 0.02G + 0.03G + 15 + ( 0.9 )( 2 ) v
16.8
= 0.05G +
1.04
= 0.05G + 16.15

Equivalence principle: G = 1286.98 + 0.05G + 16.15


1303.13
G= = 1371.72
1 − 0.05

Question #247
Key: C

APV (actuarial present value) of benefits = 3499 (given)

APV of premiums = G + ( 0.9 )( G ) v


0.9G
=G+ = 1.8571G
1.05

APV of expenses, except settlement expenses,


= ⎡⎣ 25 + ( 4.5 )(10 ) + 0.2 G ⎤⎦ + ( 0.9 ) ⎡⎣10 + (1.5 )(10 ) + 0.1G ⎤⎦ v + ( 0.9 )( 0.85 ) ⎡⎣10 + (1.5 )(10 ) ⎤⎦ v 2
0.9 ( 25 + 0.1G ) 0.765 ( 25 )
= 70 + 0.2G + +
1.05 1.052
=108.78+0.2857G

Settlement expenses are 20 + (1)(10 ) = 30 , payable at the same time the death benefit is
paid.
⎛ 30 ⎞
So APV of settlement expenses = ⎜ ⎟ APV of benefits
⎝ 10,000 ⎠

MLC-09-08 - 150 -
= ( 0.003)( 3499 )
= 10.50

Equivalence principle:

1.8571G = 3499 + 108.78 + 0.2857G + 10.50


3618.28
G= = 2302.59
1.8571 − 0.2857

Question #248
Key: D

a&&50:20 = a&&50 − 20 E50 a&&70


= 13.2668 − ( 0.23047 )( 8.5693)
= 11.2918
⎛ 0.06 ⎞
A50:20 = 1 − d a&&50:20 = 1 − ⎜ ⎟ (11.2918 )
⎝ 1.06 ⎠
= 0.36084

Actuarial present value (APV) of benefits = 10,000 A50:20


= 3608.40

APV of premiums = 495 a&&50:20


= 5589.44

APV of expenses = ( 0.35 )( 495 ) + 20 + (15 )(10 ) + ⎡⎣( 0.05 )( 495 ) + 5 + (1.50 )(10 ) ⎤⎦ a50:19
= 343.25 + ( 44.75 )(11.2918 − 1)
= 803.81

APV of amounts available for profit and contingencies


= APV premium – APV benefits – APV expenses
= 5589.44 – 3608.40 – 803.81
= 1177.23

MLC-09-08 - 151 -

You might also like