You are on page 1of 117

The Venezuelan Petro State and Foreign Policy

Oil Rents and Soft Balancing Strategies

Master thesis Political Science: International Relations Student: Remi Lehmann (s6190596) Supervisor: Dr. Reinoud Leenders Second reader: Dr. Antonio Carmona Baez Date: July 31st, 2010

Table of Contents
Abstract ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ 5 Introduction ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 6 A balance of power ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 6 The Natural Resource Curse -------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 8 Relevancy for theory and policy --------------------------------------------------------------------------- 9 Methodological considerations and case study -------------------------------------------------------- 9 Case selection: Venezuela --------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 10 Structure of the thesis ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 11 1 | Theoretical framework ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 12 1.1 The post-Cold War balance of power -------------------------------------------------------------- 12 1.1.1 The Absence of balancing behavior ----------------------------------------------------------- 13 1.1.2 The Soft Balancing Alternative ----------------------------------------------------------------- 15 1.1.3 Conceptualizing Soft Balancing ---------------------------------------------------------------- 16 1.1.4 Critics of soft balancing -------------------------------------------------------------------------- 18 1.1.5 Soft Balancing as an integral part of foreign policy --------------------------------------- 20 1.2 The Natural Resource Curse ------------------------------------------------------------------------- 21 1.2.1 The Rentier state ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 23 1.2.1.2 A Political-Economic dimension ---------------------------------------------------------- 24 1.3 The Petro State ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 25 1.3.1 The Political Economy of the Petro State ---------------------------------------------------- 26 1.3.2 An International dimension? ------------------------------------------------------------------- 27 1.4 Methodological considerations --------------------------------------------------------------------- 30 1.4.1 Methods of research ----------------------------------------------------------------------------- 31 1.5 Case Selection: Venezuela ---------------------------------------------------------------------------- 33 1.6 Use of sources------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 33 2 | The Venezuelan Petro State----------------------------------------------------------------------------- 35 2.1 From Colonial Outpost to Independent Nation (1498 1900) ------------------------------ 35 2.2 The birth of the Petro State (1901 1942) ------------------------------------------------------- 36 2.3 The Developmental Petro State (1943 1988) -------------------------------------------------- 37 2.3.1 Experiments with democracy and PuntoFijismo ------------------------------------------- 38 2.3.2 Nationalization, boom and bust --------------------------------------------------------------- 40 2.4 The Oil Opening and Neoliberal reforms (1989 1999) --------------------------------------- 42 2

2.4.1 Prez: The Shock Doctrine ---------------------------------------------------------------------- 42 2.4.2 Caldera: gradual reforms and PDVSA privatization --------------------------------------- 45 2.5 The Chavista Petro State (1998 present day) -------------------------------------------------- 46 2.5.1 Reversing neoliberalism ------------------------------------------------------------------------- 47 2.5.2 Petro-boom and deepening the process ---------------------------------------------------- 52 2.5.3 Ten Years of Chvez ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ 54 3 | Venezuelan Foreign Policy ------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 56 3.1 The 4th Republic and the World ------------------------------------------------------------------ 56 3.1.2 Traditional balancing behavior -------------------------------------------------------------- 59 3.1.3 Carlos Andres Prez --------------------------------------------------------------------------- 62 3.1.4 Rafael Caldera (feb 94 feb99) ----------------------------------------------------------- 63 3.2 Bolivarian foreign policy --------------------------------------------------------------------------- 66 3.2.1 Signs of hard balancing? ---------------------------------------------------------------------- 68 3.2.2 Spreading the oil wealth: petro dollar diplomacy -------------------------------------- 70 3.2.3 UNASUR: Defending Latin-American sovereignty -------------------------------------- 74 3.2.4 ALBA and the Banco del Sur: Alternative models for economic integration ----- 77 3.2.5 The role of International Financial Institutions------------------------------------------ 80 3.2.6 OPEC: Multilateral oil diplomacy ----------------------------------------------------------- 81 3.2.7 Eschewing cooperation and promoting sovereignty ----------------------------------- 86 3.2.8 The Obama administration and Chvez --------------------------------------------------- 87 4 | Analysis ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ 88 4.1 Near absence of traditional balancing ------------------------------------------------------------- 88 4.2 Soft balancing ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 90 4.2.1 OPEC and the Oil Weapon revisited ---------------------------------------------------------- 91 4.2.2 Economic Integration Alternatives ------------------------------------------------------------ 93 4.3 The role of domestic institutions and petrodollars --------------------------------------------- 94 4.4 Soft Balancing a success? ----------------------------------------------------------------------------- 96 Conclusion ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 98 Research Question ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ 98 The Venezuelan case --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 98 Main Findings ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ 99 Theoretical implications --------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 100

Implications for policymakers -------------------------------------------------------------------------- 101 Methodological and theoretical remarks ------------------------------------------------------------ 103 Suggestions for further research ---------------------------------------------------------------------- 104 Cited Works ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ 106

Abstract
Het onvermogen van het Neorealisme om het gedrag van staten te verklaren binnen de context van een unipolair statensysteem heeft het debat over de verklaringskracht van het neorealisme aangewakkerd. De theorie kan niet aannemelijk maken waarom staten zich niet tegen de enige overgebleven supermacht de VS keren. Deze thesis richt zich op een theorie die aangeeft dat staten wel degelijk balancen, maar in kiezen voor minder risicovolle en minder kostbaardere non-militaire middelen, ook wel soft balancing genoemd. Er is echter nog veel onduidelijkheid over omstandigheden en oorzaken van soft balancing, en welke rol de kosten van een dergelijke politiek spelen. Oliestaten, staten die voor hun inkomsten grotendeels afhankelijk zijn van het exporteren van olie, hebben een grillig verlopend inkomstenpatroon. Aan de hand van de casus Venezuela (1989-heden) wordt nagegaan of de verandering van de hoogte van olie-inkomsten ook daadwerkelijk tot veranderingen in buitenlands beleid hebben geleid. Immers, met een dusdanig grillig inkomstenpatroon zou men een dito beleid verwachten. Omdat Venezuela de afgelopen twintig jaar vele politieke- en economische ontwikkelingen ondergaan, kan er gecontroleerd worden voor andere variabelen. De belangrijkste bevindingen van het onderzoek zijn: Venezuela heeft verscheidene vormen van soft balancing toegepast. De intensiteit, schaal en duur van deze initiatieven verschilt echter sterk en lijkt samen te vallen met verloop van olie-inkomsten tussen 1991 2008. In tijden van (relatief) lage olieprijzen gedurende de jaren 90 was soft balancing beperkt. Dit geldt ook voor de eerste jaren van het Chvez regime. Sinds de olieboom (2004-2008) nam soft balancing in intensiteit, schaal en duur toe tot ongekende hoogten. Echter, van een duidelijk causaal verband lijkt geen sprake te zijn vanwege drie redenen. Ten eerste heeft de Chvez regering in verscheidene beleidsdocumenten soft balancing initiatieven aangekondigd, ruim voor de olieboom. De wil om te soft balancen was al sinds 2001 aanwezig. Dit hangt mogelijk samen met het de agressieve, imperialistische buitenlandpolitiek van de regering van G.W. Bush, zoals enkele proponenten van de soft balancing theorie al aangaven. Ten tweede gaat de regering Chvez door met de soft balancing initiatieven, ook al zijn de olieprijzen (en dus inkomsten voor de Venezolaanse staat) aanzienlijk teruggelopen sinds mid-2008. Het lijkt er dan ook ten sterkste op dat olieinkomsten an sich geen oorzaak van soft balancing zijn, maar dit gedrag slechts faciliteren in materile zin. Enkele kanttekeningen dienen bij de conclusies geplaatst te worden: 1) de bevindingen slechts in beperkte mate te generaliseren naar andere oliestaten vanwege het ontbreken van een vergelijking van verscheidene oliestaten. 2) De soft balancing theorie nog niet voldoende ontwikkeld om wezenlijke verschillen tussen strategien te kunnen duiden.

Introduction
A balance of power
Since the end of the Cold War, the United States of America has been the undisputed world power. Since the fall of the Soviet Union it has surpassed any other power in economic, political and military capabilities. Since George W. Bush assumed office in 2001, in many countries concern has grown over American foreign policy. The aggressive, unilateral, national security strategy of Bushs administration has attracted widespread criticism from traditional allies and criticasters alike. Why did the US change its foreign policy course so profoundly? For over more than a century, International Relations scholars have been trying to determine why states act the way they do in this seemingly anarchic world system. Especially Realist thinkers have been explaining state behavior by referring to the balance of power: whenever a certain state is becoming (too) powerful, other states will invest in their military apparatus or forge military alliances to counter the power of the hegemon, for the sake of their own security.1 This type of behavior is generally referred to as balancing (Waltz, 1979). Indeed, there is some evidence that states have enhanced their military capabilities: after a global decrease that started in 1985 and lasted till the late 1990s (Schiff & Clements, 1996), global military spending has grown over 45% since 1999 (Stockholm International Peace Research Institute, 2009, p. 10). However, spending varies greatly per country and the US defense budget is still much larger than that of all other nations combined. Even more importantly: we are yet to witness the formation of military alliances against US hegemony. There seem to be various reasons why states have not resorted to balancing: some states see the US as a close ally and do not fear its foreign policy. Others argue that balancing could spur an arms race they are unlikely to win. However, most states simply do not possess sufficient means to increase military spending let alone to match the military power of the US.

The core tenant of the Realist school of International Relations theory argues that the state is the most important actor in world politics, and that other actors are of lesser relevance. The primary objective of a state is survival. This is the supreme national interest to which all political leaders must adhere. Since no other state or institution can be relied upon to guarantee the survival of the state, nations can only rely on self-help (Dunne & Schmidt, 2008, p. 103).

Although at first glance it seems that other countries have little opportunity to directly balance the hegemon, this does not mean that other countries have given the US a carte blanche. According to various authors (Pape, 2005) (Paul, 2005) (Corrales) (Hurrell, 2006), several countries have pursued non-military alternative strategies to block or hamper foreign policy initiatives by the US which are deemed hurtful to other nations. These strategies are aptly dubbed soft balancing (Paul, 2005, pp. 58-59). Examples of soft balancing include giving (financial) support to political actors in other countries that oppose the hegemon, blocking policy-making by the hegemon in international organizations or providing developing nations with development aid under very favorable (or simply no) conditions (Corrales). This new explanation for state behavior in the current unipolar context has sparked a debate among both defenders and skeptics of the soft balancing approach. Brooks and Wohlforth (2005, p. 74). argued that the main analytical flaw in the soft balancing argument is the little attention for alternative explanations of state behavior: even if states act contrary to US interests, it might be simply to achieve their own foreign policy goals instead of intentionally balancing US power. Even among proponents of the approach there remain important differences of opinion. Most authors (Paul, 2005) (Pape, 2005) argue that soft balancing policies are primarily the result of the behavior of the hegemon and have little to do with state-specific characteristics. Soft balancing behavior then seems to be a product of the anarchic international system instead of conscious foreign policy choices by nations. Other authors, such as Andrew Hurrell leave more room for the idiosyncrasy of the state involved: states that soft balance typically believe they are entitled to a more influential role in world politics (2006, p. 2). Irrespective of beliefs or values that a state may hold, the majority of IR scholars argue that foreign policy options are heavily dependent on the capabilities of a state. For example: richer states can invest more in military personnel and equipment than poorer nations because they dispose over more financial capabilities. Within the soft balancing debate so far, (too) little attention has been paid to the sources of these capabilities.

The Natural Resource Curse


One possible, and potentially significant source of income, is the rent that natural resources generate. Much has been written about the supposed (negative) impact that significant resource rents have on the domestic characteristics of politics, the economy and society in resource-rich nations. Yet, less has been written on possible implications of natural resource (rent)s for foreign policy within the current unipolar context. I think such a debate is long overdue and justified because these rents may be argued to influence foreign policy, whether they be soft- or traditional balancing initiatives. Like any other type of (foreign) policy, costs are involved. Resource abundant countries, and especially petro states dispose over significant rents which usually can be used discretely by the executive. 2 More than in resource-poor countries these rents can be used to fund soft balancing strategies. Going beyond the rent generated, lowering oil production or threatening to close the tap (which happened in 1973 when several Arab petro states refused to sell oil to the US and the Netherlands because of their support for Israel) can function as instruments for soft balancing too. What is unknown, however, is whether this access to oil rents simply functions as an enabler for certain policies (altering the cost/benefit analysis of said policies) or whether alleged intrinsic characteristics of oil production actually encourage (or perhaps discourage) soft balancing policy initiatives. Only very few authors, such as Michael T. Klare (2001) seem to have ventured in the foreign policy dimension of resource abundance. His work on natural resources and conflict paints a rather grim picture; the worlds powers need oil to maintain their economic and military power and will therefore resort to force to secure these energy sources when necessary. Klare clearly focuses on the needs of the oilconsuming countries and to some extent seems to justify conflict in order to meet these needs. Susanne Peters (2005) shares similar concerns about oil-consuming countries resorting to violence (especially within the context of ever shrinking oil reserves), but sees the relation as less deterministic: In her view, a more equitable distribution of oil and international energy regimes may mitigate hostile behavior by the oil consuming countries. Another scholar that studied natural resources and international conflicts is Helga Haftendorn (2000). Her study on water conflicts argues that water as a resource structures
2

A Petro state in short is a nation heavily dependent on oil rents, generated by the export of this commodity. The states institutions and its relations to the citizenry and the economy for a large part have been shaped through the development of the oil industry (Karl, The Perils of the Petro-State: Reflections on the Paradox of Plenty, 1999, p. 34). For a more detailed description of the Petro state, see section 1.3

conflicts between states in such a way that it generates an asymmetric relationship between upstream and downstream countries, which makes it very hard to resolve conflicts among them. Oil may then also structure conflicts between states in a certain way, as oil is traded internationally. All in all, the works by these authors hint that there may be a domestic dimension of natural resource rents to foreign policy which cannot be captured in the systemic approach of the anarchic international state system. As such, this dimension deserves closer attention. This led to the following research question: To what extent and how does access to significant oil rents generate incentives for soft balancing behavior?

Relevancy for theory and policy


The debate on the effects of abundance of natural resources has mainly focused on the political and economic dimension of the state. Less attention has been paid to possible consequences for foreign policy. This thesis explores this largely ignored field of study. Furthermore, I think this thesis could also make a contribution to the soft balancing debate as to whether incentives for such policies should be viewed as largely systemic in the context of the international system or whether they can also be caused by domestic factors. The thesis nevertheless has the potential to go beyond the theoretical dimension and could help policy makers in resource abundant countries to develop (soft) balancing strategies when a super power seems to excessively use its privileged position in the international anarchic system to prey upon other countries resources. It may also instruct the hegemon in how to deal with such soft balancing strategies.

Methodological considerations and case study


It is very hard to determine the existence of a causal link between access to significant oil rents and the application of soft balancing strategies. The limited amount of time and means available for the realization of this thesis greatly hampers answering the ambitious research question in full depth. However, since this thesis ventures into relatively unexplored territory I see great value in exploring the possibilities of such a link, which further research may (or may not) qualify and specify. I deem a case study to be the most useful way to investigate such a matter. To investigate the possibility of a causal link, it is very important that many different processes (decision-making, flow of oil rents to governments,

distribution and allocation of rents etcetera) are being studied instead of a mere quantitative approach involving calculating alleged correlation between the variables soft balancing initiatives and access to significant oil rents. An in-depth case study also allows for close attention to possible intervening variables (which are much harder to discover in quantitative research). That being said, following the logic of the research question, some expectations are warranted: if oil rents enable or actually give incentives to soft balancing behavior we should see nations with significant oil rents embarking on soft balancing initiatives more than countries that do not have access to such rents. Another expectation would be that higher rents entail more intense soft balancing behavior. Nevertheless, before such claims can be proven, it is necessary to dive deeper into the logic of the argument than simply demonstrating a correlation between the aforementioned variables.

Case selection: Venezuela


The majority of literature on soft balancing is framed within the (Realist) logic of the anarchic state system, which currently is unipolar. As rules of the balance of power change according to the number of major powers within the international system (Waltz, 1979), to ensure comparable results it is necessary to study foreign policy initiatives since 1991 (the collapse of the Soviet Union) onwards. It goes without saying that a case study should at least involve a country that has access to significant oil rents if one wants to study the alleged effects of oil rents on foreign policy. The Bolivarian Republic of Venezuela is a textbook example of a country which has access to significant oil rents. According to the latest figures on the share of oil in the Venezuelan economy, in 2008: oil accounted for 90% of all export income (about 30 billion USD), 50% of fiscal revenue and 23% of GDP (Banco Mercantil, 2009). Furthermore, Venezuela has seen many changes taking place over the past 20 years: high and low oil prices, socialist and market-oriented regimes, high and low economic growth. Therefore it seems the ideal candidate to control for different variables when trying to measure the alleged impact of significant oil-rents in soft balancing strategies of foreign policy. Another reason why Venezuela is an excellent candidate for this case study, is that it has been an active player (with differing roles over time) in world politics. It is co-founder of the OPEC oil cartel, was a close ally of the US for many years, and now strives for the construction of a multipolar 10

world order (Ministerio del Poder Popular para La Comunicacin y la Informacin, 2007, p. 46). The current government furthermore sees the interests of the United States as a threat to political stability, peace and human rights in the region (Buxton, 2009, pp. 61-72). Limited time and means strongly discourage an in-depth comparison of the foreign policies of multiple countries. Therefore I will compare Venezuelan foreign policy under two strikingly different regimes: the neoliberal-oriented governments of the 1990s and the successive governments of Hugo Chvez Fras. This allows me to control for the Chvez factor. This refers to the idea that Venezuelas foreign policy might simply be an anomaly, explained by the idiosyncrasy of current president Chvez Fras.

Structure of the thesis


Chapter 1 will be dedicated to a thorough analysis of the debates on soft balancing and the foreign policy dimension of the natural resource curse. Special attention will be paid to the conceptualization of key concepts such as soft balancing strategies and the petro state. Also, the methodological design of the thesis will be explained and justified. Chapter 2 will consist of a description of the Venezuelan petro state, followed by a close look on its foreign policy in Chapter 3. In Chapter 4 the data found in the previous chapters will be analyzed by means of the theoretical framework. In the Conclusion I will present the main findings of the thesis, the implications of the thesis for both the academic community and policy makers. Finally, suggestions for further research will be given, based upon the findings of the thesis.

11

1 | Theoretical framework
This chapter will provide the theoretical framework for the thesis. First, a brief overview of Neorealist International Relations theory will be compared with developments in the international state system since the end of the Cold War. We then proceed with an analysis of the role of natural resources in rentier states, and discuss a special type of rentier state: the petro state. Finally we return the discussion of how foreign policy of petro states may be (partly) shaped by its dependence on oil rents and how to research this subject.

1.1 The post-Cold War balance of power


The soft balancing argument is best explained when framed into the post-Cold War context and the challenges this situation poses on traditional IR theories. One of the most influential theories on International Relations was developed during the Cold War by Kenneth N. Waltz. In his seminal work, Theory of International Politics (1979), he described state behavior in the international system. He accepted the realist premises that states are primarily interested in their own survival, constantly fear losing their sovereignty and are predominantly reliant on self-help in realizing the aforementioned goals. The innovation of Waltz theory was that he deduced state behavior from the logic of the international system. According to Waltz, the international system is ordered in an anarchic fashion. Unlike within nation states, there is no supreme authority. Second, the international system is comprised of like units: nation states. Every nation state is alike in the sense that it is a sovereign political entity. This is not to say that all states are equal in all aspects, but states perform similar functions. States however differ greatly in their power capabilities. This distribution of power capabilities determines the structure of the international system. When three or more states have much more capabilities than other states, such a system is categorized as a multipolar system. When two states have much more capabilities than the other states, it is called a bipolar system. When one country has far greater capabilities than all other states it is called a unipolar system. As stated before, according to Waltz this structure largely determines the behavior of states and what outcomes are produced. Waltz argues that a multipolar system is more unstable than a bipolar system. First, because powers have a hard time drawing a clear line between friends and foes. Second, because of this uncertainty, it needs to monitor multiple powers, which leaves room for misinterpretations of risk-

12

assessment. Even when alliances are formed to counter this problem, the defection of one state can alter the balance of power and thus elevate tensions among the other states (Waltz, 1979, pp. 168-169). In a bipolar system, states suffer less from these problems. Because there are only two significant powers, monitoring problems are less common. Second, even though the powers form alliances with other states, defection is less of a problem because the powerful state itself does not depend on other states for its own security. Using Waltz theory to identify the structure of the international system during the Cold War era, we can conclude that it was a typical example of a bipolar international system. Both the United States and the Soviet Union had far greater military capabilities than the other nations. During the Cold War, both powers constantly tried to enhance their military might through investments in military power (for example the nuclear arms race) and the formation of military alliances (such as the NATO and the Warsaw Pact) in order to prevent the other pole from becoming too powerful. In that sense the behavior of both the US and the SU form a perfect example of traditional balancing. Many secondary states chose to side with either the US or the SU to safeguard their sovereignty and assure the survival of their state.3

1.1.1 The Absence of balancing behavior


The collapse of the Soviet Union radically transformed the structure of the international system and reduced the number of world powers to one: the United States. As Waltz had argued, this changed structure of the international system would change expectations about state behavior within the system (1979, p. 97). Neorealists predicted that the situation of unipolarity would not last very long. An ever more powerful United States would mean that secondary states would have growing fears of losing their sovereignty and ultimately would jeopardize the survival of the state. Within this context, the logical thing to do for secondary states was to invest heavily in military capabilities (internal balancing) and form military alliances with other states (external balancing) to counter the US. Yet since the end of the Cold War very little balancing among nations has taken place. Although there has been a significant increase in military expenditure (Stockholm International Peace Research
3

It is important to notice that not every state had the same degree of liberty in choosing its side, especially in the Global South. This was due to imperialist policies by both the US and the Soviet Union. Furthermore, a great number of countries (among which Venezuela) chose not to side formally with one of the powers and formed the Non-Aligned Movement. Nowadays it is comprised of Latin-American countries, almost all African nations and various countries in the Middle East and Asia .

13

Institute, 2009), we are yet to witness a military alliance of lesser powers to balance the US. This led authors such as Thaza Varkey Paul, Robert Pape and Andrew Hurrell to question the explanatory power of neorealist theory concerning the longevity of the post-Cold War unipolarity and the seemingly irrational behavior of states within the system. Paul argues that the most important incentive to balance has been absent since the US has become the hegemon: the majority of the states do not fear that the US will threaten their existence as a nation state or erode the national sovereignty of other states.4 They perceive that the US is constrained by various factors, and Paul identifies three of them as being the most important ones (2005, p. 53). First, because of the proliferation of nuclear weapons, many lesser powers now possess nuclear arms. These arms more or less guarantee the prevention of a direct attack of the hegemon because it would trigger the use of nuclear weapons and would thus render the enterprise by the US pointless. Second, the US have largely abstained from direct intervention in secessionist movements in the main other powers such as China, Russia and India. Third, the powerful force of nationalism and the asymmetric strategies of (nationalist) groups make permanent occupation of another state infeasible (Paul, 2005, p. 56). The problems the US and its partners encounter in Iraq and Afghanistan are vivid examples of these contemporary challenges. Both Paul and Pape (2005, p. 10) agree that the unilateral, quasi imperialist and aggressive US security policy implemented during the GW Bush administration has deeply worried a number of smaller powers. Especially the invasion of Iraq in 2003 in spite of fierce resistance within the most important international organization to preserve peace The UN , has made these states question whether the US is largely respectful of territorial integrity and national sovereignty. Now, according to realists these doubts would mean the return of balancing behavior. However, there is little evidence for such behavior.

Paul and Pape state that the vast majority of nations do not view the US as a threat to their sovereignty and but mention certain exceptions such as Iran. I think they underestimate anti-US sentiments in Latin America. In many Latin-American countries the US have intervened (in)directly in domestic affairs. Although interference by the US seems to have diminished in scale and intensity since the Cold War, it has caused a deep sense of mistrust of US foreign policy among Latin-American policy makers and citizens alike (Livingstone, 2009). Recent examples of at least alleged US interference in domestic issues in Latin America are financial support for the political opposition and support for the de facto regime in Venezuela in 2002 (Buxton, 2009, pp. 69-70) and support of autonomist movements in East-Bolivia (Golinger, 2009).

14

1.1.2 The Soft Balancing Alternative


What has been missing (especially) in realist works, is the option of alternative strategies for lesser powers when traditional balancing is either impossible, unfeasible or unwanted. This need not surprise us as a majority of neorealist writers only deem military build-ups and alliances (which enhance the capability of the state) as relevant in international relations among states. Paul and Pope have analyzed the behavior of a number of lesser great powers and came to the following conclusion (Paul, 2005, p. 58):
In the post-Cold War era, second-tier states have been pursuing limited, tacit, or indirect balancing strategies largely through coalition building and diplomatic bargaining within international institutions short of formal bilateral and multilateral military alliances. These institutional and diplomatic strategies which are intended to constrain US power, constitute forms of soft balancing.

However, soft balancing strategies do not simply emerge when traditional balancing is not a policy option. Paul identifies several conditions which need to be met: First, the power position of the hegemon and its military behavior are of growing concern but do not yet pose a serious challenge to the sovereignty of second-tier powers. Second, the hegemon is a major source of public goods in both the economic and security areas that cannot simply be replaced. Finally, the hegemon cannot easily retaliate because the balancing efforts are not overt or because they do not directly challenge its power position with military means. This makes soft balancing such an attractive option for lesser powers since it poses less risks, has lower costs and in most cases - is easier to realize. Although both Paul and Pape agree that the perception that countries hold of the intentions of the hegemon matter, Pape has a slightly different explanation as why states do not balance, but soft balance: it is extremely difficult to balance a hegemon in a unipolar system. Internal balancing is not a viable option because no increase in military might and economic strength by just one state is sufficient to balance the hegemon. A state that undertakes such an enterprise would most certainly be met with a harsh response by the hegemon. Within this context only external balancing has a promising perspective. Nevertheless, as external balancing implies joint effort by multiple actors, collective action problems are just around the corner. Even though each nation is better off cooperating with other nations to balance the unipolar power, each nations decisions on whether to balance or not, depends highly on 15

the expectation that others will cooperate (which in turn depends on whether those states expectations about other states commitment to cooperation). As states do not wish to confront the unipolar power before the coalition is complete, only when expectations about cooperation have converged, will there be the possibility to balance. This means that balancing will take place abruptly or not at all (Pape, 2005, pp. 16-17). This is a gloomy perspective for states wishing to balance. They therefore might turn to soft balancing as a second-best policy option. Because soft balancing strategies do not confront the unipolar power directly and do not involve the military, both risks and costs are lower. Although this will not greatly alter the power relations directly (benefits are lower as well), it can delay, complicate or generate substantial costs for the unipolar power to use its power. Furthermore, it can serve as a basis for future military balancing efforts by generating converging expectations (Pape, 2005, p. 17).

1.1.3 Conceptualizing Soft Balancing


There seems to be little discussion among the protagonists of the soft balancing debate as to what constitutes soft balancing. Yet, the abstract formulation of the concept of soft balancing might be confusing to outsiders. It might therefore be hard to identify typical examples of soft balancing strategies in foreign policy of countries. Discussing some examples of such behavior can prove helpful in clarifying the concept of soft balancing. One example of soft balancing strategy is to entangle the more powerful nation in a diplomatic context. Even strong states cannot completely ignore the rules and procedures of important international organizations or accepted diplomatic practices without losing substantial support for their objectives (Pape, 2005, p. 36). As states bind themselves to certain international regimes to solve problems they cannot tackle alone, they effectively limit their policy options because of the aforementioned reasons. At the same time they also enhance their policy options because certain international regimes give legitimacy to actions (by the hegemon) which otherwise would not have been acceptable.5

For example, if the US was to unilateraly- invade a certain country, it would be heavily criticized by other states. Yet if this invasion would be according to the procedures and rules of international law and the UN Security Council, it would gain legitimacy as almost all states have voluntarily committed themselves to these rules and procedures.

16

The United Nations Security Council (UNSC) is an institution of the international peace regime. Several major powers have a vote within the council, and acting on behalf of the UNSC requires unanimous support of these major powers. This gives permanent members China, Russia, France, the United Kingdom and the United States an effective veto. Another soft balancing option is to invest in certain international regimes to the detriment of others (Corrales). In Latin America, regional security issues were usually either addressed by the UN or the Organization of American States (Livingstone, 2009, p. 24).6 However, the role of these organizations had come under increasing criticism of the predominantly left-wing governments in the region. First, the dominant role of the US in these organizations (especially the OAS) had damaged the neutrality of these institutions. Second, both organizations have a poor track-record in the region. This spurred leaders in South America to found the UNASUR in 2008 as a regional organization to secure peace and foment political and economic integration in the region. In several occasions the UNASUR proved to be the dominant international platform were crisis were discussed by the stakeholders, sidelining the UN, OAS and the influence of the US. A further example of soft balancing is social power policy projection (Corrales), which involves the use of heavy investments abroad, usually in the form of donations and/or loans to supposedly provide poverty relief or promote development. In practice, Corrales views them as instruments to buy political support abroad. This could be donations to the political campaigns of allied political actors in other countries or providing credit lines for governments experiencing financial difficulties. Another option is offering developmental aid with very low conditionality. This aid competes with aid by the US which comes with very high conditionality. The former form of development aid is very attractive to the receiving party as it means access to significant sums of money which can be spent in a highly discrete manner, whereas the second form of development aid cannot be spent that way. Territorial denial is yet another way to soft balance. A secondary power can deny the super power access to its territory for (quasi) military purposes. By denying access, it makes it harder for the unipolar power to act in that region, complicate its logistical processes and
6

The OAS is a regional multilateral international organization, founded in 1948 to promote solidarity and cooperation among members and to defend their territorial integrity and sovereignty (OAS, 2010).

17

thus make the employment of the military more costly and thus less attractive. Although Pape (2005, p. 36) sees this strategy very useful when the unipolar is in war with yet another weaker state, this tactic could also apply to anti-terrorist or drug enforcement policies of the hegemon outside its territory. For example, the American military used an Ecuadorian military base to conduct routine flights to monitor drug-trafficking in the region for over ten years. However, when a new president was elected on a strong anti-imperialist platform, the lease of the airbase was not renewed, and so hampered US drug-trafficking monitoring and forced the US to intensify cooperation with other states in the region (Solano, 2009). All the aforementioned soft balancing strategies correspond to the description of soft balancing strategies by Pape (2005, p. 17): what these soft balancing strategies have in common, is that they do not directly challenge the military supremacy of the unipolar power, but can delay, complicate or increase the cost of using its extraordinary power. Even though they are non-military measures, they have an (in)direct effect on the military prospects of the unipolar power.

1.1.4 Critics of soft balancing


Although the introduction of soft balancing as an analytical tool to account for state behavior in a unipolar context was generally seen as a welcome critique of neorealism, there has also been criticism. Critics can be divided in two categories: the first category denies the existence of soft balancing as a description for certain foreign policy strategies by weaker states and do not see its analytical relevance. Other critics do accept soft balancing as a strategy, but argue that its context is not limited to the current unipolar world order. One of the most important criticisms belonging to the first category has been put forward by Brooks & Wohlforth (2005, p. 74): they argue that although weaker states adopt foreign policies that hurt US (military) interests, this might be a mere coincidence and not so much a specific desire to balance US foreign policy. The main analytical flaw of the theory according to these academics is the lack of attention for competing explanations such as economic interests, regional security concerns, policy disputes and domestic political incentives. Another argument that goes against the soft balancing theory is that the concept of soft balancing is not distinguishable from normal diplomatic friction, and therefore has little analytical value (Lieber & Alexander, 2005, p. 125). A third important critique, coming from

18

the second strand, argues that it is unnecessary to place soft balancing within the current unipolar context. He & Feng (2006) argue that soft balancing is a rational foreign policy choice for weaker states that are to a certain extent economically dependent on the hegemon. The greater the power disparities and economic interdependence, the more attractive soft balancing policies become. The first category of criticism has been party redressed by academics of the second strand. He & Feng argue that it is important to distinguish between short term tactics and long term strategies. Although certain actions by weaker states can (also) be explained by economic interest, domestic political incentives or policy disputes, they are tactics that in general should amount to the objective of long term strategies. In a unipolar context the long term strategy would be the reduction of the power of the hegemon (He & Feng, 2006, pp. 7-9). They also strongly criticize the notion that soft balancing is just another term for diplomatic friction. Whereas in a situation of diplomatic friction, two parties seek to achieve the best possible outcome on a basis of certain different policy options, the soft balancing strategy actually broadens (future) policy options for the weaker state. The example of soft balancing strategies I gave earlier illustrates this difference: in the situation of the Bolivian crisis, normal diplomatic friction would have let to a clash of interests in the OAS, where regional political disputes were normally discussed. However, the unanimous decision of SouthAmerican heads of state to discuss the matter within the framework of the UNASUR gave the leaders of this country the possibility to condemn the violence of the autonomist movement in Bolivia, which the US allegedly supported. By investing in one international regime to the detriment of another, they broadened their policy options to produce an outcome which would have been very unlikely within the OAS. The second category of criticism argues that soft balancing does not only take place within a unipolar context, and should therefore not be solely linked to the rational logic of states in such a context. I agree with He & Feng that soft balancing could also take place within a bior multipolar context. Although it would probably make soft balancing less likely as there are other (perhaps more effective) strategies such as bandwagoning or traditional balancing instead. I also agree that disparities in military power are an important predictor of soft balancing power, irrespective of structure the international state system. Yet I do not agree

19

that a higher level of economic dependence on the unipolar power means a higher possibility for soft balancing. I argue that higher levels of economic interdependence also makes soft balancing harder and less feasible for weaker states. The exact reasoning behind this argument has to do with the type of economic interdependence, and especially that of petro states. If a weaker state is heavily dependent on oil exports for its income, it makes it harder to soft balance the hegemon, if this hegemon is the most important and nonreplaceable costumer of this commodity. I will dive in to this argument more deeper in the section on oil as a commodity that structures relations between states in section 1.3.2

1.1.5 Soft Balancing as an integral part of foreign policy


In the ongoing debate it seems as if soft balancing simply is an alternative strategy for traditional balancing. However, in practice often simultaneous traditional and soft balancing policies are pursued. It is perfectly possible to spend on the enhancement of military capabilities of a country, while at the same time trying to block foreign policy initiatives by the hegemon in international organizations. For example, both China and Russia have invested heavily in their military apparatus the past ten years. At the same time, both countries have consistently vetoed US initiatives within the UNSC, that call for actions against countries that the US deems dangerous for the stability of the international system, such as Iran and North Korea.7 That being said, every countrys policy mix is different. Some states may invest heavily in military capabilities while at the same time refraining from too overt soft balancing initiatives. Other countries might play a lead role in soft balancing initiatives while at the same time spending moderately on military capabilities. Here we stumble upon a fascinating paradox. Although Paul and Pape are highly critical of the systemic and deterministic nature of neorealism, they do to a great extent argue that soft balancing behavior is caused by the behavior of the hegemon (Pape, 2005, p. 38) and as such has less to do with the domestic characteristics of the weaker country. I find this assumption somewhat problematic for various reasons: first, the perception of whether an act of the hegemon is deemed dangerous for the country at hand may depend heavily on the
7

A fairly recent example of Russia and China blocking US foreign policy took place in the UNSC. In 2008 NorthKorea launched a long-range rocket. According to The United States the launch of such a missile was a clear violation of a Security Council resolution and called for a Security Council meeting to discuss the topic (and to take measures against North Korea). Although all members of the Security Council expressed their concern over the launch of the Rocket, China and Russia called for restraint in the councils response and effectively blocked the possibility of sanctions as the Security Council can only act unanimously (The Australian, 2009).

20

existing relations with the hegemon, something which Pape acknowledges (2005, p. 14). Stationing American military personnel in Colombian military bases to fight terrorism and combat drug-traffickers is seen as very welcome by the Colombian government, while at the same time it can be considered a threat to regional peace and sovereignty by neighboring countries Ecuador and Venezuela. Second, every foreign policy initiative has its calculated costs and benefits. Dependent on for instance financial capabilities, certain foreign policy initiatives are more viable for some governments than for others. Third, even if two states have the same view on a certain action of a government, and have roughly equal economic capabilities, the viability of certain foreign policy options might depend on the type of economic relation the country has with the hegemon: a state with diverse trade relations and a diversified economy can afford to damage relations with the hegemon. A state that is dependent on the export of a single commodity with the hegemon being its important (and non-replaceable) client cannot afford to damage relations too much. Therefore I think it is necessary to look into the sources of the very capabilities neorealists argue are so important in determining the role a state can play within the international anarchic system.

1.2 The Natural Resource Curse


As noted in the previous chapter, states differ greatly in capabilities. These capabilities are very important to neorealists as they determine a states power position vis--vis other states, including the hegemon. In this sense, a states capabilities shapes its foreign policy options. Although neorealists are predominantly interested in a states military capabilities, neorealists all too often seem to forget that these capabilities stem from different sources, such as a countrys demographics, geographical location, strength of the economy and access to certain natural resources. Although neorealists emphasize the importance of capabilities, the sources of these very capabilities are not considered relevant because the sources of capabilities themselves do not determine the power position of the state in relation to other states, they are only instrumental to the development of capabilities. This stands in stark contrast with the academic works by Economists, Political Scientists and Social Geography scholars alike who have studied the implications of natural resources for

21

the economy, polity, civil society and the environment of the nation state.8 The ongoing academic debate on this topic is usually referred to as the natural resource curse. At first sight, large amounts of natural resources seem a blessing for states as they provide a significant source of income, which the government can use for development policies and the acquisition of wealth. Especially for less developed countries, the revenues of these natural resources would allow the governments to buy the status of a developed country. This would also empower the state within the international system, as the enhanced capabilities of these type of states would better their power position vis--vis other states. Until the late 1980s, this was the generally accepted discourse on the role of natural resources (Rosser, 2006, p. 7). However at the end of the 20th century the vast majority of less developed resource abundant countries had still not acquired the level of development associated with most of the Western world. Several studies have shown that economic growth in resource abundant countries was actually lower than countries that did not possess many natural resources (Sachs & Warner, 2001), that states dependent on mineral exports had worsened living conditions for the poor (Ross, 2003) and that per capita incomes of resource-poor countries grew much faster than resource abundant countries (Auty, 2001). So, at least in economic terms these countries had not lived up to expectations associated with resource abundance. Yet, the curse does not seem to be limited to a states economy. It is also associated with political instability and civil war. Especially the works by Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler have shed light on the link between natural resource wealth and the onset of civil war. They found (2000, pp. 26-27) that natural resource wealth increased the risk of civil war because it provides an opportunity for predation of these resources by rebel groups. These groups, predominantly acting out of greed would generate (further) grievance among other groups. This, combined with the possibility to finance the conflict through the export of the resources prolongs the conflict. However, Collier and Hoeffler also conclude that after a certain level of exports, chances at civil war are actually reduced. Other authors have argued that natural resources prolong conflicts (Doyle & Sambanis, 2000) or worsen the intensity (number of casualties) of the violent conflicts in those countries (Ross, 2004).
8

See Rosser (2006) for an interesting overview of literature on the political economy of the Natural Resource Curse.

22

Besides these domestic dimensions of the natural resource curse, there is an international dimension to the natural resource curse. The dependence of the West on natural resources relevant to the growth and maintenance of their economies and military power, has generated interest of these countries in the states that provide these natural resources (Klare, 2001). Because the Western states want to secure their access to energy, and these states are quintessential to that goal, the use of (indirect) military power makes inter-state conflict more likely (Peters, 2005). The US military intervention in Iraq in 2003 is a often cited example of an aggressive energy security policy of resource-consuming states versus oil producing states. So, instead of being a blessing, natural resources seem to condemn states to slow economic growth, worsening development indicators for the poor and increased risks of prolonged and intense civil wars. As if these resources do not spell enough trouble, they also seem to make these countries easy targets for military intervention by Western, resource-consuming countries. This is not to say that there is a consensus that the exploitation of natural resources causes economic underperformance, erosion of the quality of state institutions and/or (violent) political conflict. Yet the correlation of natural resource abundance and dependence in less developed countries and economic underperformance, diminished stateness and the prominence of violent conflicts has puzzled many academics. In the literature on the Natural Resource Curse various types of resource-abundant countries are described. In the next section I will present a special variety of such a state: the rentier state.

1.2.1 The Rentier state


Natural resources are not evenly distributed across the world. Some states possess significant oil and gas reserves, while other countries do not even possess the smallest amount of fertile land. Often, these natural resources are traded abroad and thus provide the exporting state with external income. In the literature on natural resources a distinction is made between states that have a diversified economy and where the rents of some of these resources is one source of income for the state (but less significant than domestic taxes and revenues), and states whose economies are practically dominated by such rents. The former are then classified as diversified economies (Karl, The Paradox of Plenty: Oil booms and petro-states, 1997, p. 12) or esoteric states (Luciani, 1987, p. 69), while the latter are referred to as rentier states. The term was first coined by Hossein Mahdavy to refer to 23

the oil economy of Iran prior to the Revolution (Yates, 1996) and has since then been used by various authors to refer to countries that receive significant amounts of external rents on a regular base (Mahdavy, 1970, p. 428). Since then, the concept has been refined and one of the most accepted conceptualizations of the rentier state has been put forward by Hezam Beblawi. According to Beblawi (1987, pp. 51-52), rentier states share four characteristics that set them apart from other states with access to natural resource rents. First, in a rentier economy, rents over natural resources dominate the economy. Second, the economy relies heavily on external rents. These external rents sustain a non-productive economy and the state. Only a small group is actually involved in rent-generation. Third, the majority of the population is engaged in rent-seeking behavior: the distribution and utilization of the aforementioned rents. Fourth, the government is the most important beneficiary of these rents. 1.2.1.2 A Political-Economic dimension A very useful conceptual approach to the differences in the role of the state in rentier economies compared to diversified economies is the production state versus the allocation state, a concept developed by Giacomo Luciani. He sees the source of income of states as a determinant for the role the state plays vis--vis its population. In states where the main source of income of the state is taxation of the local economy and its residents, there is a mutually dependent relation between the state and its population. For the state to perform its allocative functions (in providing health care, infrastructure and education) it needs the revenues generated by the local economy. Strengthening the local economy therefore is an important task (if not the most important) for the survival of the state. How tax money is being spent is subject to political debate. Although at times the population does not agree with the spending politics of a certain government, the system of taxation can only be maintained if it is being considered legitimate by the population (hence the saying no taxation without representation). This is the main relation between the population and the state in a production state (Luciani, 1987, p. 73). In rentier states, the state is predominantly dependent on income earned abroad: the rents proceeding from exploitation of natural resources are received when traded on the world market. This world market largely determines how rentable a specific natural resource is. As Jacks et al. (2009, pp. 3-4) demonstrate, the market for commodities (under which natural

24

resources fall) is characterized by a higher price volatility than for services or manufactures. The very rent these rentier states rely upon is highly volatile. As these rents accrue directly to the government, it is the main source of income for the state. The challenge for an allocation state is to gain as much revenue from the rest of the world. The only link to the domestic economy is the spending of state revenues and therefore the local economy has no priority. Even though strengthening the local economy can be one of the goals for which the rents are used, as long as the domestic economy is not tapped to raise the income of the state (through taxation), the strengthening of the economy does not entail growing income for the state. The state therefore has a predominantly allocative function. Since there is little or no taxation, there is little incentive for the local population to demand a change in political institutions. What is typical for these kind of rentier economies, is a different kind of economic behavior in comparison to productive states. In conventional economies, effort and reward are closely connected: income and wealth are linked to work and/or risk-bearing entrepreneurship. Rewards are thus seen as the end result of a (long, systematic, organized) production circuit. In rentier states such a link hardly exists and the acquisition of income and wealth is more related to chance or situation instead of work and risk-bearing (Beblawi, 1987, pp. 51-52). The context of the rentier economy radically changes what is considered to be rational behavior in an economy. In normal economies the rational approach for gaining income and/or wealth would be investing and/or participating in a productive process as this yields the best results. In a rentier economy however, trying to tap in to government distribution of rents yields better results and is less risky than participating or investing in a productive process or changing the political system. This deviant behavior is called the rentier mentality. Now, whether such behavior is deemed virtuous or not, is a more philosophical debate and need not interest us now.9

1.3 The Petro State


Now the difference between a rentier state and a tax and spend or production state is clear, a new problem surges: the definition of the rentier state by Beblawi does not specify nor places much relevance on the kind of natural resource that is being exploited. Yet,
9

For an interesting (historical) overview on rentier behavior and whether it is judged as virtuous or not, see Yates (1996).

25

looking at some of the general arguments presented by the various strands in the debate on natural resources, there are reasons to believe that this may matter. States that are compliant with the rentier state model, and are mostly dependent on oil for their income are called petro states. This section will explore the notion of the petro state, and why it is different from other rentier states, and what consequences this has for the political economy of petro states. An insightful approach to the petro state is presented by Terry Lynn Karl. According to Karl, Petro states, share a set of properties arising from the exploitation of petroleum (1999, p. 34): first, the petro state is dependent on a single commodity, oil. Second, the exploitation of petroleum is more depletable, more capitalintensive, more enclave-oriented, more centralized in the state and more rent producing than any other commodity. These characteristics influence the political economy of such states to a great extent. According to Karl, the overreliance on petrodollars to support virtually all other economic activities tends to make the needs of the oil industry a toppriority for governments above all else; a lack of productive linkages and the dominance of fiscal ones; the perceived mentality to accelerate development before the oil reserves are depleted and the primacy of the state in the oil industry (1999, pp. 34-35). But perhaps more interesting is that the political and economic institutions of petro states have been shaped by the main source of income and that these political and economic institutions tend to be highly dysfunctional.

1.3.1 The Political Economy of the Petro State


After a comparison of several petro states (Venezuela, Iran, Nigeria and Algeria), Karl identifies similar political and economic developments in those states. First, the process of modern state formation and exploitation of oil by international oil companies coincided: international oil companies moved into countries with significant oil reserves and limited stateness. This means that none of the aforementioned countries had administrative structures capable of resisting the petrolization of the state. Executive power became linked to the fate of the oil industry and the dynamic process of both state centralization and expansion were thus propelled by oil (Karl, The Paradox of Plenty: Oil booms and petrostates, 1997, p. 196). Second, the imposition of income taxes as a prime source of a states fiscal revenues and regime changes that either reinforce or counteract reliance on oil rents (Karl, The Paradox of 26

Plenty: Oil booms and petro-states, 1997, p. 197). With the growing importance of the oilsector for the export economy, state decision-making frameworks were molded to facilitate oil-led development. The outcome of this process is the dependence on petrodollars. Almost all states that developed oil industries in the past century were characterized by the same economic policy pattern: maximizing oil extraction rents for domestic distribution through public spending (according to certain political preferences). The structure of taxation in oil countries is strikingly different from developed countries with similar GNP per capita: non-oil taxes are significantly lower and corporate taxes are higher than in developed countries (Karl, The Paradox of Plenty: Oil booms and petro-states, 1997, p. 198). This access to easy money radically altered the mentality of both the public and private sector. The public sector had little incentive for a fiscal discipline, while for the private sector it lowered incentives for entrepreneurship and work ethics. This then creates an ever greater dependence on oil income (Karl, The Perils of the Petro-State: Reflections on the Paradox of Plenty, 1999, p. 35), because the oil industry can sustain the rest of the non-productive economy. This illustrates the typical relation that the state has in a rentier economy: the capacity to extract the external rents and then distribute this rent internally. According to Karl, in petro states this principle is taken to the next level. The high rentability of oil compared to other natural resources, provides the state a exceptional amount of income which is spent in an inefficient and rather discrete manner: an ever expanding state bureaucracy and white elephant projects place a heavy burden on the states income - a burden still bearable when oil prices are high. When oil prices are somewhat lower, future oil rents can be used as collateral to borrow on the international market to maintain government spending even when there is a budgetary deficit. This makes it very hard for petro states make policy adjustments and improve fiscal discipline, compared to tax and spend states. This inability to adjust to new circumstances and lack of sustainable development policies leads to the piling up of problems which in the long run leads to political and economic crises (Karl, The Perils of the Petro-State: Reflections on the Paradox of Plenty, 1999, pp. 35-37).

1.3.2 An International dimension?


As much as Karls approach tells us about the exceptional characteristics of oil in shaping a countries economy and political institutions, it tells us little about the foreign policy of a rentier state. Other authors have shed some light on this issue. Luciani (1987, p. 78) argues 27

that the foreign policy of allocation states are similar to its domestic policies. As allocation states feel vulnerable because of their abundance of natural resources and the uncertainty about intentions of other states, governments of allocation states tend to give neighboring production states a share of the income to appease them, making the allocation state less vulnerable to military threats from its neighbors. Now the question surges if it matters what kind natural resources a state possesses, for its relations with other states. Helga Haftendorn (2000) studied several international conflicts about freshwater and came to the conclusion that irrespective of the cause of the conflict all water conflicts shared the same asymmetric structure. In such a conflict, one country is (geographically) the source of freshwater. This state, dubbed upper-lying riparian, can control the quantity and quality of the water flow to the other country. When not willing to wage war, the lower lying state is completely dependent on how the upper-riparian manages the freshwater source. Haftendorn translates this situation in a game model and concludes that there is little chance for a satisfactory resolution of the conflict, because there is little incentive for the upper-riparian state to solve the conflict: it has a privileged position in terms of freshwater access, and thus has a source of power in hands it will not likely yield, unless it will be compensated in the form of economic and/or political benefits. However, for the disadvantaged state it is of the utmost importance that such a conflict will be resolved, but the aforementioned compensation can put a heavy burden on the disadvantaged state. Nonetheless, Haftendorn argues that conflicts can be mitigated when the water conflict is balanced by other factors. For example, the lower riparian may dispose over resources on which the upper-riparian is dependent. In this mutually dependent relationship states have an actual interest to provide access to the resource, because when it fails to do so, the other state can retaliate by withholding their natural resource as well (2000, pp. 62-63). For some time, it was believed that oil conflicts were structured asymmetrically too. Because oil is an irreplaceable commodity to ensure economic and military power of oil consuming countries, oil producing countries could cripple these states by lowering production quota or refusing to sell oil to certain countries. In the literature this is referred to as the oil weapon. This would then render the oil consuming countries (and especially the US) powerless vis--

28

vis the oil producing states in the Middle East (Paust & Blaustein, 1974). Often, the 19731974 oil crisis is used to illustrate the use of the oil weapon to influence the foreign policy of oil-consuming countries. In 1973 a coalition of Arab states attacked Israel to re-occupy territory that had been lost during the Six-Day War of 1967. However, several Western countries supported Israel. To pressure these Western countries to stop selling weapons to Israel and make Israel respect the borders as they were drawn prior to the 1967 war, the Organization of Arab Petroleum Exporting Countries (OAPEC) threatened with 5% production cutbacks as long as these demands were not met. Also, an embargo was imposed on the sale of oil to Israels most staunch supporters: the US and The Netherlands. As a result of the lower oil production and the political instability of the worlds most important oil-producing region, oil prices skyrocketed to the detriment of the economic position of the oil-consuming countries (Stern, 2006). However, the debate about the oil weapon progressed as the 19731974 oil crisis was repeatedly studied by academics. Serious doubts were cast on the effectiveness of the oil weapon and the alleged dependency of the West on oil from the Middle-East (Blair, Yali, & Hagt, 2006) (Licklider, 1988) (Stern, 2006). The weapon was ineffective because it did not produce the desired results: the United States did not change, and the Netherlands hardly changed their foreign policy concerning the Arab-Israeli conflict after the oil weapon had been applied (Licklider, 1988, pp. 216-217). It was also ineffective because although production cuts were actually made supply contraction may have been as little as 4% (Adelman, 1995, pp. 89-140) because of third countries reselling oil and the availability of non-AOPEC sellers. Translating this knowledge in the structure-model as proposed by Haftendorn it seems like oil-producing and oil-consuming countries have a more symmetric relation. The oilproducing country may have an advantage because it can close the tap or acting through cartels it can artificially raise the prices. However, this power position is balanced by the fact that these countries are overly dependent on the rents that petroleum exports generate for the survival of the regime and ultimately the state. Therefore the advantaged states will have an interest in resolving the conflict because they need to sell oil for their survival. The discussion on the oil weapon had a predominantly oil-consuming country perspective as oil is the single most important resource for economic growth and military power of the oil-

29

consuming countries (Klare, 2001). As balanced as this relation might be, it does not mean that petro states need not fear about their survival in the international system. As Susan Peters (2005) points out, the growing demand and declining reserves will lead to an oil crisis in the near future. This will lead to growing tensions between oil-consuming states and oilproducing states, as some oil-consuming states (such as the United States) will probably not abstain from the use of force to obtain the resources they need for maintaining their economic and military power. From the perspective of the oil-producing country, this places extra importance on a cautious foreign policy which reduces tensions with oil-consuming states while at the same time investing in achieving greater military capabilities (a form of internal balancing) or forming international military alliances (external balancing) or put use funds for soft balancing strategies. Because financial means are indispensable when trying to implement foreign policy, and rents from natural resources can be a big source of government income, I think it pays to study more closely the alleged relation between resource rents and foreign policy

1.4 Methodological considerations


The starting point of the thesis was the failure of neorealist theory to explain the absence of balancing behavior by secondary states against the current world power, the US. According to neorealists, this balancing behavior is almost law-like and prevents states from becoming too powerful. This is necessary, because ultimately a too powerful state will threaten the sovereignty and existence of secondary states. Yet instead of outright balancing behavior we have been witnessing soft balancing strategies: the use of non-military strategies to hamper US foreign policy that is perceived as threatening to secondary states. There seems to be a consensus (Pape, 2005) (Paul, 2005) that these strategies were caused by a more aggressive US policy and have little to do with the characteristics of the secondary state itself. Only Andrew Hurrell (2006) thinks that beliefs about what role a certain state should play in the international system can be an important factor for the type of foreign policy. However, there is something missing in these analyses: in order to realize a certain foreign policy, a state needs capabilities to do so. These capabilities stem from different resources and these resources are frequently overlooked when analyzing inter-state relations. Singling out natural resources seems justified for analysis as they 1) generate rents that can be used 30

to enhance capabilities of a state and 2) there seems to be some evidence that natural resources structure relations with other nations. When talking about the relevance of natural resource for a state (and not just foreign policy) I made a distinction between states with a diversified economy and rentier states. In the former natural resource rents are just a part of the states income and domestic taxation and revenues are the most important source of income for the government, while in rentier states the government is highly dependent on external rents generated by natural resources. Whilst discussing the relevancy of natural resources in generating both rents and structuring international relations, I remarked that oil seems to have certain characteristics (its high rentability, and its tendency to structure foreign relations in a symmetric way). Therefore I have chosen to focus on a very specific kind of rentier state: the petro state. Studying the relevancy of oil for foreign policy of the petro state has been done to some extent before (especially the earlier mentioned oil weapon), but usually from the perspective of the oilconsuming nation and not the oil-producing state. Studying the role of oil in foreign policy of petro states can be a small step into answering more general questions of the soft balancing debate (such as if foreign policy is largely determined by systemic features or characteristics of specific states) but at the same time can shed new light on questions of the relevancy of the type of resources for the generation of capabilities which are essential to a states position in the international system. This resulted in the following preliminary research question: To what extent and how does access to significant oil rents generate incentives for soft balancing behavior?

1.4.1 Methods of research


As I stated before it is very hard to determine the existence of a causal link between the access to significant oil rents and the use of soft balancing strategies in foreign policy. Since the specific subject covered in this thesis is relatively unknown territory, both the research design and the thesis itself will have a largely explorative character. However, for the purpose of theory testing it is necessary to formulate some sound hypotheses that will help us answer the research question. First, we need to know whether petro states actually soft balance. If significant oil rents enable or give incentives to soft balancing behavior, petro

31

states should be involved in soft balancing efforts. The second hypothesis has to do with the volatility of oil rents: if the capability to soft balance depends heavily on the level of oil rents, petro states should demonstrate more soft balancing behavior when oil prices are high, than when prices are low. As the main source of generating the capabilities of the state, oil is traded on a very volatile market, so the amount of petrodollars available for soft balancing efforts varies greatly. It would be tempting to simply quantify soft balancing behavior and oil rents and try to determine whether those two hypotheses hold in the real world. Quantitative research with statistical analysis will just show correlation of the variables, but tell us next to nothing about the alleged processes at work. While these processes are the main reason for designing this research. This is not to say there is no merit in using quantitative data at all: it has been exactly the extensive quantitative research on natural resource dependence that has identified possible relations between oil rents and certain policy behavior. However, gathering and analyzing this data is not the sole goal of this thesis. The data is a mere instrument in trying to identify the aforementioned causal link. An in-depth case study of the foreign policy of a petro state may help us out here. It allows me to dive deeper into questions of foreign policy decision making, soft balancing initiatives, and the characteristics of the petro state. Both hypotheses can be tested by analyzing the characteristics of the petro state and the foreign policy of an oil dependent country. What do official policy documents and statements tell us about the role a government sees for its nation in the international system? How does it think its policy can be implemented? And what role does oil (if any) play in these plans? At the same time we should look beyond words. What is the foreignpolicy track record of said state? How does traditional balancing and soft balancing relate to each other in the foreign policy mix of state and (how) do they change over time as oil rents go up and down? This is the somewhat more qualitative part of the research. But to see how both variables connect, the theories about the petro state need to guide us in the research. Having added the hypotheses, the research question has become more specific:

32

To what extent and how does access to significant oil rents generate incentives for soft balancing behavior by the Venezuelan petro state?

1.5 Case Selection: Venezuela


The majority of literature on soft balancing is framed within the (realist logic) of the anarchic state system, which currently is unipolar. As rules of the balance of power change according to the number of major powers within the international system, to ensure comparable results it is necessary to study foreign policy initiatives since 1991 (collapse of the Soviet Union) onwards. It goes without saying that a case study should at least involve a country that has access to significant oil rents if one wants to study the alleged effects of oil rents on foreign policy. The Bolivarian Republic of Venezuela is a textbook example of a country which has access to significant oil rents. According to the latest figures on the share of oil in the Venezuelan economy, in 2008: oil accounted for 90% of all export income (about 30 billion USD), 50% of fiscal revenue and 23% of GDP (Banco Mercantil, 2009). Furthermore, Venezuela has seen many changes taking place over the past 20 years: high and low oil prices, socialist and market-oriented regimes, high and low economic growth. Therefore it seems the ideal candidate to control for different variables when trying to measure the alleged impact of significant oil-rents in soft balancing strategies of foreign policy. Another reason why Venezuela is an excellent candidate for this case study, is that Venezuela has been an active player (with differing roles over time) in world politics (Corrales). It is co-founder of the OPEC-cartel, was a close ally of the US for many years, and now strives for the construction of a multipolar world order (Ministerio del Poder Popular para La Comunicacin y la Informacin, 2007, p. 46). The current government furthermore sees the interests of the United States as a threat to political stability, peace and human rights in Latin America (Buxton, 2009, pp. 61-72).

1.6 Use of sources


In order to answer the research question, a case study is constructed by means of a wide range of different sources from different academic disciplines (Political Science, Economy, History), government documents, interviews with policy makers and reports by international 33

(governmental) organizations. The vast and rich literature on Venezuelan politics and its petro economy provides very detailed and useful information, yet it poses challenges too: First, there are very different narratives of the past twenty years in Venezuelan history. Even the academic debate is so polarized to the extent that there exists disagreement about certain factual events and statistics. The controversy of the person of Hugo Chvez also contributes to this situation. Whenever there is great disparity in the narrative of the case study, this will be explicitly mentioned. Second, a significant amount of the authors of the aforementioned works are (or have been) stakeholders. For instance Bernard Mommer, a well respected academic expert on economics and oil, has worked for as vice-president for PDVSA and vice-minister of the Ministry of Mines and Energy during Chvez regimes, but also supported Calderas presidential candidature in 1994. Another example is Gregory Wilpert, who is married to a high-ranking PSUV member which is currently Consul of Venezuela in New York. Another source that should be interpreted with care is US SOUTHCOM (which is responsible for all military activities in Latin America and thus acts in US interests). Nevertheless, all these various viewpoints shed a bright light on the existing literature and help highlight the different dimensions (which are frequently obscured or omitted from other academic analyses) of the Venezuelan economy, politics and international relations. Another problem is the lack of reliable statistics and consistent time series of relevant data. Even though some institutions like the World Bank or United Nations provide vast amounts of information, often the data they use is provided by national governments. Unfortunately the Venezuelan bureaucracy has a cumbersome reputation when it comes to providing data, especially since Hugo Chvez assumed power.

34

2 | The Venezuelan Petro State


This chapter provides an extensive description of Venezuelas development into a petro state. Although the thesis is focused on oil and foreign policy since the 1990s, it is important to have a general idea of how Venezuelan history has shaped contemporary developments. Therefore this chapter starts with a brief overview of Venezuelan history which sets out the context in which political and economic institutions were built and oil-policies have been developed.

2.1 From Colonial Outpost to Independent Nation (1498 1900)


Like many other Latin American nations, Venezuela was discovered at the turn of the 16th century. The Spanish conquerors showed little interest in the territory that nowadays comprises Venezuela as there were no precious metals to be found. After the conquest of the territory, exploitation of natural resources started at a modest scale (Lombardi, 1982, pp. 59-66). By the beginning of the 18th century Venezuela as a colony had achieved some prosperity thanks to the growing cacao trade with Mexico and Spain. Trade turned the city of Caracas into the countrys most modern, dynamic economic and political center (Lombardi, 1982, pp. 83-85). The economic development gave rise to a local elite and bourgeoisie with interests increasingly diverging from those of the Spanish Crown. This proved to be a fertile ground for the growing independence movement in the early 19th century. This movement, led by Simn Bolvar, would after a long, arduous battle that lasted more than 12 years - achieve Venezuelan independence (Lombardi, 1982, pp. 115156). With the common enemy gone, battles ensued on how to shape the country, along a centralist/federalist cleavage. The federalist faction won in the Civil War (1858-1863) and the country would be led by local strongmen until 1935. In this era two figures stand out. First, Antonio Guzman Blanco, whose regimes left a heritage of a technically competent bureaucracy to administer Venezuelas import-export economy and large national revenues from foreign contracts and loans (Lombardi, 1982, p. 197). Second, Juan Vicente Gmez (1908-1935). Modernization of the army allowed him to check the power of the Caracas bureaucracy which he needed to administer Venezuelas economic and political affairs while it could also be used to intimidate, imprison and kill political opposition. Yet his rule

35

provided political stability and a framework for economic growth (Lombardi, 1982, pp. 206208).

2.2 The birth of the Petro State (1901 1942)


Between 1920 and 1960 Venezuela transformed from an isolated, rural society dependent on agricultural exports to an industrializing, urban, extractive society with close ties to North-Atlantic politics and economics (Lombardi, 1982, p. 211). The transformation of Venezuela into a petro state started in the early 20th century. The order and political stability that dictator Juan Vicente Gmez achieved, enabled the petroleum industry to develop (Lombardi, 1982, pp. 205-206). Although minor concessions had been granted during the second half of the 19th century, president Cipriano Castro enacted the first Mining Law that would develop into the legal ground for oil concessions (PDVSA, 2005).10 Lacking funds and knowledge to develop an oil industry, governments were dependent on foreign companies to develop the industry. Therefore a system of concessions was applied: foreign companies could exploit the oil reserves under certain conditions (usually including a lease fee) but could not own the oil riches themselves (Randall, 1987, pp. 19-20). It would not take long for the first commercial oil concessions to be awarded, and international oil companies such as Royal Dutch Shell and Standard Oil soon became the most important producers of oil in Venezuela. These companies and the oil industry in general - demanded a basic infrastructure in telecommunications, roads and ports to export the oil. Also, they demanded more sophisticated, technical and government services (Lombardi, 1982, p. 244). This proved to be the kick-start for the modernization of Venezuela. Between 1920 and 1935 (the end of Vicente Gmez reign), oil exports as share of total exports rose from 1.9% to 91.2% (Tugwell, 1975). It had become the worlds second largest oil producer (290,000 barrels per day), and most important oil exporter (PDVSA, 2005). Although Venezuelas administrative capacity as a state was very weak when the first concessions were awarded, Venezuelan oil politics advanced through a series of reforms: after World War I, the state saw to enhance its income from petro-related activities and to

10

Under Hispanic law, all mineral deposits belonged to the Crown. After gaining independence, ownership was transferred to the newly established governments and these rights formed part of the inalienable patrimony of the nation.

36

renegotiate its concessions, which resulted in the 1920 Hydrocarbons Law. The law was characterized by higher tax and royalty rates. Yet, the foreign oil companies exerted great influence over the Venezuelan state apparatus and managed to get the Minister responsible for the 1920 law to be removed from office and the tax and royalty rates were reduced again (PDVSA, 2005). By 1935 the oil industry had grown so rapidly that Venezuelas per capita GDP had grown from one of the regions lowest to the regions highest (Crow, 1980, pp. 616617).

2.3 The Developmental Petro State (1943 1988)


The petroleum reform of 1943 marked both change and continuity in Venezuelan oil policy: the new Hydrocarbons Law was the first law to especially cover all the oil concessions in the country. These concessions were updated according to new terms, in which the principle of rents and royalties were maintained but higher tariffs would be applied.11 Even though the concession system as such was maintained, the new terms would give the government a bigger slice of the petro cake. One of the most important instruments in achieving this objective was a new income tax, applicable to all the concessions. The level of the tax rate on profits had become the sole prerogative of the Venezuelan government (Mommer, 1996, p. 133). Another important aspect of the 1943 Hydrocarbons Law was that foreign oil companies could not make greater profits than the amount paid to the Venezuelan state in taxes and royalties (Wilpert, 2003). The 1943 Hydrocarbons Law greatly improved the power position of the Venezuelan government vis--vis the foreign oil companies. Nevertheless, national policymakers were less than satisfied with the results of the legislation as they believed that foreign oil companies and major consumer companies kept oil prices artificially low. This way they would lower their profits and minimize their fiscal contributions to the Venezuelan state. Applying this logic, increasing the fiscal share of the government in the oil economy would yield meager results. Therefore a new strategy was adopted by the government, aimed at controlling supply and prices as means to better secure state income from the oil sector (Mommer, 1996, p. 133). Whether or not these assumptions were true is still open to
11

Royalty payments which averaged 9% in the era preceding the 1943 Hydrocarbons Law, would be set at a minimum of 16.66% under the new concessions (PDVSA, 2005).

37

discussion. What is not open to discussion however, is the effect of the development of the petro-industry on the Venezuelan economy: Venezuelas GDP grew by more than 10% per year during the 1940s (Faria, 2008, pp. 520-521).

2.3.1 Experiments with democracy and PuntoFijismo


It was within this context of high economic growth that a short-lived experiment with democracy took place: In October 1945 Accin Democrtica (AD) and a group of young military officers staged a coup dtat to reform Venezuelas political system. Presidential elections were held by the new junta and AD icon Rmulo Gallegos was elected president. What followed was a radical transformation of the political economy of Venezuela: land reform benefitted poor peasants and organized labor movements were legalized. Oil reforms were quite modest: no new requests for concessions would be granted (Tugwell, 1975, p. 45). AD strategists saw these measures as natural steps towards a modern socialdemocratic Venezuela. However, according to Lombardi, the radical agenda and the solistic approach to reform by AD distanced the party from the more moderate political parties COPEI and URD, the military and the Catholic Church. In 1948 the military took over government again, and a 9-year dictatorship by Mrcos Prez Jimnez would follow (1982, pp. 223-225). From the 1950s onwards world oil prices declined because of overproduction, mainly caused by growing production in the Middle East (Wilpert, 2003). Under Jimnez the moratorium on new oil concessions was lifted whilst the regime profited from the oil income generated by earlier enacted laws. The Venezuelan economy boomed: real per capita output grew by 5.4% per year during 1950-1957, resulting in an astonishing 87% increase in real per capita output in the same time span (Faria, 2008, pp. 520-521). A significant amount of oil income was invested in infrastructure works mainly in the Greater Caracas region. The creation of state enterprises in the steel, petrochemical, hydroelectric and telecommunications sector. In spite of economic successes, ruthless repression by the regime helped galvanize the political opposition to form a broad front (the Junta Patritica) against the dictator, consisting of PCV (the communist party), the outlawed AD, COPEI and URD. In January 1958 Prez Jimnez was finally ousted by a military coup, backed by the Junta Patritica (Ellner, 2008, pp. 48-49).

38

For the return to democracy to be sustainable, key actors in Venezuela realized that an equilibrium needed to be found to balance the interests of different sectors. Although AD was by far the most popular party and in theory could rule Venezuela without support from the other parties, its alleged radicalism was not acceptable for the more conservative sectors. Therefore a political pact was signed between AD, COPEI and URD in which the parties promised to form coalition governments irrespective of the winner of the elections effectively making it a power-sharing pact. This inter-party agreement came to be known as the Punto Fijo Pact. Sharing power would also mean shared access to the oil wealth which accrued to the government. The rules established in the pact would dominate Venezuelan political life until the 1990s. Concerning government policies, a minimum program was concluded. The program called for an economic policy that would allow for state intervention within a capitalist framework, respecting the spheres of influence of the Church and the Army and including them in debates about the role of these institutions within Venezuelan society, and negotiations concerning economic policy with organized labor and business organization FEDECAMERAS (Ellner, 2008, pp. 58-59). Now, as much as this pact generated political stability hitherto unknown in Venezuela, it also effectively depoliticized politics and excluded more radical (leftwing) segments of society, of which some would take up an armed struggle during the 1960s. Concerning oil policy, several legal steps were taken to work towards more state involvement in the oil sector. In 1960 the first Venezuelan state oil company was founded, the Corporacin Venezolana de Petrleo (CVP) (Mommer, 1996, p. 133). The goal of CVP was to (ultimately) perform all the tasks that the foreign oil companies had hitherto performed, clearing the way for direct participation in the oil industry. This is a clear hint towards a future nationalization of the oil sector (Novoa Monreal, 1979, p. 28). This was by all means a challenging task, given the fact that by the 1970s about 20 predominantly British, NorthAmerican and Dutch companies had monopolized the technology, production, processing, transport and commercialization of oil products (Novoa Monreal, 1979, p. 22). The 1971 Reversion Act made sure that all terrains and goods belonging to the concessionaries made under the 1943 Hydrocarbons Law (which would expire in 1983) would be transferred to the state upon non-renewal (Novoa Monreal, 1979, p. 22). The nationalization of the gas industry by law in 1971 ensured state control over production and pricing of natural gas. In 39

1973 a law was passed that reserved the exploitation of hydrocarbon products for the domestic market to the state. Policy makers however were well aware that to able to receive better prices for exported petroleum, world market prices needed to rise. The foundation of the Organization Of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) in 1960 (in effect an oil cartel) was a foreign policy tool to introduce production quotas and to secure just oil prices for the oil exporting countries.12

2.3.2 Nationalization, boom and bust


The biggest push towards the realization of the petro state took place under the government of Carlos Andres Prez. In 1975 (Mommer, 1996, p. 133) the Ley Orgnica que Reserva al estado la Industria y el Comercio de los Hidrocarburos effectively nationalized the oil industry. The concessionaries received rather generous compensations for the expropriation given the fact that their concessions would expire in 1983. This however, did not mean that the role for foreign companies was played out. The law reserved the possibility of jointventures in oil exploration (as long as the state had a majority share) and special commercialization and technical assistance contracts were signed with the previous concessionaries (Ellner, 2008, p. 74). The new state entity that would assure that the oil industry would be ran in an orderly, modern and efficient manner was Petrleos de Venezuela, Sociedad Annima (PDVSA), replacing CVP. PDVSA inherited an internal management culture that was above all technocratic and corporate, like the management of the previously owned private companies. Not only was managerial autonomy an important demand of the foreign company managers (who were going to work in PDVSA), but it was also a wish of the government to secure efficient management. This resulted in a special relation between PDVSA and the government: PDVSA and affiliates would run the oil industry as efficient as possible and would pay due taxes. The government in turn, would collect the taxes and spend them according to political preferences, like before the nationalization (Philip, 1999, p. 366). Under the Carlos Andres Prez regime, these political preferences advocated bigger state involvement in the economy to sow the petroleum. More than any other president before him, Prez saw the oil industry as key to the development of Venezuela into a modern

12

See Chapter 4 for an in depth analysis of OPEC as a foreign policy tool of the Venezuelan state.

40

country. The sharp rise of oil prices that coincided with his presidency enabled him to invest in social programs, full employment and the steel, aluminum and electricity sectors (Ellner, 2008, pp. 71-72). As a consequence, since 1958 per capita GDP had risen gradually from 5400 USD to 6500 USD at the end of Prez term, which represents a 20% rise in real terms. Graphic 1 illustrates the development of Venezuelan GDP per capita from 1959 to 1998.

Chart 1. Venezuelan GDP Per Capita


Venezuelan GDP Per Capita $ 7.000 $ 6.000 $ 5.000 $ 4.000 $ 3.000 $ 2.000 $ 1.000 $0

Source: World Bank Catalog (2010)

However, the oil boom also resulted in relaxed financial policies. Even though fiscal revenues tripled under Prez, the government borrowed heavily to finance the government enterprises (Faria, 2008, p. 523). Several developments in the 1980s led to the unraveling of the carefully constructed Punto Fijo pact: 1) Oil rents declined dramatically: crude oil prices had skyrocketed in the late 1970s, but halved during the 1980s. As oil export were the governments primary source of income, less and less petrodollars were available. 2) From Prez government onwards, Venezuela had heavily indebted itself. This was not a problem when oil prices were high and interest rates were low, but with plummeting oil prices and the debt crisis, this became a serious problem: Venezuelas external debt skyrocketed from less than 10% of GNI in 1975 to 81% of GNI in 1989 (World Bank, 2010). So a significant part of the already diminished state income had to be used for debt-servicing. Of the remaining available funds the majority was grossly misspent due to erratic economic policies by the governments of Luis Herrera Campins (1979-1984) and Jaime Lusinchi (1984-1989), further aggravating the economic crisis. These developments had a detrimental effect on 41

government spending on social services, which greatly disillusioned the Venezuelan population which was already heavily hit by the economic recession. But also within the pact, the declining amount of money available to distribute according to the clientelist distribution scheme angered the sectors that were cut out. As the spoils of the pact were distributed under an ever smaller part of society, and widespread disillusion with the political system was met by rising authoritarianism, tensions grew to unpreceded levels (Buxton, 2009, p. 59).

2.4 The Oil Opening and Neoliberal reforms (1989 1999)


The Punto Fijo Pact functioned relatively well in preserving political stability during the 1960s and 1970s when many Latin American states fell prey to ruthless dictatorships. It led many authors, such as Lombardi to believe that Venezuela was a model democracy, achieving political stability, economic growth at little cost. A growing number of academics (Buxton, 2009) (Ellner, 2008) (Karl, The Paradox of Plenty: Oil booms and petro-states, 1997) have questioned this romanticized notion of Venezuelan democracy and see the aforementioned developments in the 1980s as witness to the malfunctioning of the system. In the 1990s, two presidents were entrusted by the Venezuelan people to reform the Venezuelan economy, the political system and the oil industry: Carlos Andres Prez (1989 1993) and Rafael Caldera (1994 1999). As both had been presidents before and in the past had vehemently supported the Punto-Fijo regime, it is remarkable that they were to lead the reform process. What is even more interesting is that although both had campaigned on an anti-neoliberal platform, once in office, they embraced neoliberalism (Ellner, 2008, pp. 89-90).

2.4.1 Prez: The Shock Doctrine


Just weeks after assuming office, Andres Prez presented his neoliberal economic plans for his presidency. Prez apparently had signed a letter of intent with the IMF, promising neoliberal reforms in return for a multi-billion dollar loan to restructure the Venezuelan economy. The proposal, along the lines of the Washington Consensus, meant a departure from the Import Substitution Industrialization model (funded by oil rents) which had been Venezuelas lead development strategy since the 1940s. Instead of investing in the national industry, key state companies were privatized. Instead of protecting local producers, import tariffs were slashed and the country was opened to foreign investment. Also, price controls

42

on many basic commodities were reduced and/or lifted, exposing the population to rapid decreases in purchasing power (Ellner, 2008, pp. 91-92). Although these economic reforms were unprecedented in Venezuelan history, the reforms were far less drastic than in other neoliberal champions in Latin America, such as Argentina, Chile or Peru (CGD Task Force, 2009, p. 44). Yet the economic reform plans triggered widespread popular protest. There are several reasons for these protests which seem to align closely with Javier Corrales (2003, pp. 82-85) approach on resistance to market reforms: first, there was a credibility gap: the state had underperformed and not delivered during the 1980s, making it difficult for the population to believe the promises of the government. Especially Prez credibility was at stake as he made a 180 degree turn on economic policies within weeks in office. Second, the asymmetrical distributive consequences of the reforms: the lifting of price controls, state subsidies, labor market flexibilization and rapid price increases hit the poorest sectors of society most. This was unacceptable to most Venezuelans as they now had to pay for mismanagement by the elite who were left relatively untouched by the reforms. Third, although it is generally believed that political and economic crises raises tolerance for reforms under the population, in Venezuela this was obviously not the case: as subsidies on petrol were lifted, petro prices increased over 100% resulting in huge increases in transportation costs. Infuriated by the neoliberal policies the protests devolved into riots and looting all over the country. The governments response was heavy handed and during the looting some 270 up to 2000 are believed to have been killed (Ellner, 2008, p. 94). However, protest to Prez policies were not limited to the people in the streets: the leaders of his very own party (AD) had supported another candidate from the 1987 primaries onwards. After winning the presidential elections, Prez appointed mainly technocrats instead of important AD members. He had also failed to inform the party of the letter of intent of the IMF. This greatly angered a large part of the orthodox faction of the party, which were not at all fond of Prez neoliberal turn. During the 1991 internal elections for party leadership, the orthodox social democratic faction gained all but complete control over the party. As the party leadership determined the voting behavior of the AD faction in parliament, Prez reform plans were under heavy attack from his own party which resulted

43

in the abandoning of several reform projects (Ellner, 1996, pp. 94-95). Unwilling to moderate his reform projects, Prez had alienated AD from his government. A third key actor in resistance to Prez reform project was the military. In 1992, two failed coup attempts took place: in February military officers linked to Lieutenant Colonel Hugo Chvez clandestine MBR-200 movement took key points in several major cities but vainly waited for popular and air-support. Later that year, in November, Navy and Air Force officers rose up and could count upon substantial yet not sufficient popular support. However, the coup attempts did catalyze support for a more legitimate way to remove Prez from office. An investigation into corruption charges of the Prez government took shape, and the President stepped down in May 1993 (Ellner, 2008, pp. 95-97). It is tempting to think of the protests against neoliberal policies as being purely based on an ideational perspective. This might well be the case, but it is nevertheless useful to look at Prez economic track record: although the Venezuelan economy GDP shrank 8.6% in 1989, overall growth during Prez term was 2.8%, outperforming the 1980-1988 period were growth was 0,8%. Poverty had slightly augmented from 19891993 rising from 9,2 to 10.9%.13 Income inequality had diminished somewhat, reflected in a GINI-index of 44.1 in 1989 to 41.7 in 1993. Unemployment rose to 10,3% in 1990 but fell to 6.7% in 1993. Inflation reached a staggering 84% in 1989, then falling back to 30-40% in 1991-1993. Yet average inflation from 1980 1988 had been 16.2%. State tax-revenues as percentage of GDP fell from 18.1% in 1990 to 13.4% in 1993. Tax levels on income, profits and capital gains fell from 86% in 1989 to 68% in 1993. With hindsight Prez economic reforms do not seem to have delivered what was promised, but with the exception of inflation, the Venezuelan economy performed better during his presidency than during the lost decade of the 1980s. In contrast to the neoliberal economic reform program, Prez oil policy was less ambitious. Calls for changes in the industry came mostly from PDVSA management. During the 1980s, PDVSA had experienced rising production costs, lower oil prices, OPEC quotas and governments unwilling to ease PDVSA taxation. To cope with these problems, PDVSA had plans to increase production (2,8 million b/d to 3,5 million b/d in 1996), refinery and petrochemicals. Although the government initially accepted these plans, two anti-PDVSA
13

Measured as percentage of the population living off of less than 2 USD per day.

44

positions within the government resisted: first, old style politicians who did not have a problem who did not want to alter the status quo and second, Prez market-oriented reforming ministers aiming at opening the oil market to private investment and future privatization of PDVSA instead of committing public funds of the already heavily indebted state for PDVSA projects. PDVSA in turn thought that allowing for too much foreign investment would weaken PDVSAs position in the oil industry and vis--vis the government. Effectively, during the Prez years in office little changed in the oil industry because both reforming forces (PDVSA management and Prez technocrats) could not come to terms to form an alliance against those satisfied with the status quo. A remarkable exception to the lack of new policy was the progress made on opening up the oil sector for foreign investment. Arguing that PDVSA did not have the funds nor the technological skills to develop heavy crude oil fields, Congress approved of foreign investment in joint venture projects which where to exploit these fields (Philip, 1999, pp. 367-369). This legislation would prove to be the backdoor entrance for further privatization during Calderas second term in office.

2.4.2 Caldera: gradual reforms and PDVSA privatization


The winner of the 1994 presidential elections, Rafael Caldera, had opposed Prez neoliberal policies and campaigned on a centre-left platform. During the first 18 months of his term he pursued an economic policy that promoted state intervention in the economy. However, the results of this policy were disappointing (for example, real wages declined fast), and he was confronted with the collapse of the privatized banking sector. 1996 saw the introduction of the Agenda Venezuela, a package of neoliberal reforms, granting access to IMF loans. The states telephone and steel companies were privatized, demands on foreign capital were relaxed and the 1997 reform of the Labor Law opened the door to privatization of the health and retirement branches of the social security system (Ellner, 2008, pp. 99-102). Calderas oil policy however, had been more neoliberal oriented from the start, also allowing for strategic associations with PDVSA minority shares. National Congress was only able to stiffen the terms, but could not prevent the privatization process nor start a public debate on the issue (Ellner, 2008, pp. 102-103). PDVSAs new plans consisted of increasing production while allowing for foreign investment in the sector, thus bridging the gap that had existed during the previous administration. The government backed these plans by 45

approving various oil production contracts involving foreign capital, also for non-heavy oil. It did mean defying the OPEC-production quota, but PDVSA returned the favor by publicly backing all government decisions, creating a strong political alliance with key power groups in the government and society. The opening had mixed results: on the one hand, the increased sales income by PDVSA facilitated investments by the company and resulted in increased tax revenues which reduced the effect of the collapse of the Venezuelan banking system and boosted the local economy somewhat (Philip, 1999, pp. 370-372). On the other hand, the legislation and decision-making procedures had been rather dubious, negatively affecting the legitimacy of the privatization process. Furthermore, some of the joint ventures were highly unprofitable for PDVSA under low oil prices while guaranteeing profits for their foreign counterparts (Buxton, 2009, pp. 61-62). Finally, creative accounting by PDVSA meant that although the company contributions in tax revenues were significant in absolute terms, PDVSA contributed less and less in relative terms.14

2.5 The Chavista Petro State (1998 present day)


During the 1998 presidential elections, Hugo Chvez Fras campaigned under the umbrella of the polo patritico, a multiparty anti-establishment and anti-neoliberal platform consisting of various left-of-centre parties. Having been involved in the February 1992 coup, he had gained a lot of support under part of the population that was fed up with the Punto-Fijo regime. He campaigned for an overhaul of the political system to make it more democratic and transparent. A second key issue of the campaign was the reversal of neoliberal policies of the 1990s. A third issue was the corruption of the establishment, who had enriched themselves over the past 30 years while the vast majority of the Venezuelan population were living in poverty. Chvez provided an attractive alternative to the by that time heavily discredited political class of the ancin rgime. The 1998 presidential elections resulted in a landslide victory for Hugo Chvez, gaining 56% of the votes, versus 40% for Henrique Salas Rmer, the main candidate of the traditional parties (CNE, 1998). The first years of the Chvez regime were geared towards the restructuring of the Venezuelan political institutions and the relation between the state, society, and its natural
14

From 1976 to 1989, PDVSAs tax contributions and operating costs had a 80/20 proportion. From 1990 to 1996 this had changed into 67/33, mounting to 20/80 in 2000: a complete reversal the 1989 situation (PDVSA, 2006).

46

resources. One of the first acts of Chvez was to decree a consultative referendum to establish a National Constituent Assembly (ANC) to rewrite the Constitution. The members of the ANC were elected by the people of Venezuela (but the ANC-elections were boycotted by the opposition), and Chavistas obtained 125 out of the 133 seats (Ellner, 2008, p. 111).15 In December 1999 the new Constitution was ratified by a popular referendum.16 Regarding the content of the Bolivarian Constitution, it combined centralization of power in the executive with some remarkably democratic characteristics.17 Furthermore it explicitly stated that activities in the oil industry are reserved for the state (Article 302) and that all PDVSA stocks should be in hands of the state (Article 303). The articles effectively rendered privatization of PDVSA impossible and clearly defined the role of the state in the oil sector. Because of the new Constitution, all democratically elected positions within the states representative institutions had to be legitimized again. The Megaelections held in the year 2000 were to serve this purpose: Venezuelans could once again choose their own representation; local councils, mayors, governors, national deputies and President. Chvez was reelected by a comfortable majority, his party MVR won 91 seats in the National Assembly and opposition parties Proyecto Venezuela, AD and COPEI combined obtained 45 out of 165 in the National Assembly (CNE, 2000).18

2.5.1 Reversing neoliberalism


The comfortable majority in the National Assembly paved the way for further reforms: the assembly passed the Ley Habilitante (Enabling Law), which gave the executive power the possibility to rule by decree on certain policy terrains during one year.19 Exactly one year later, Chvez issued 49 decrees, the majority of them reversing the neoliberal socioeconomic policies of the 1990s, and thus jeopardizing the interests of those privileged under

15 16

A Chavista is a person that identifies him/herself with the Bolivarian Revolution and its leader Hugo Chvez. 71.8% voted in favor of the new constitution. 55.6% of the electorate did not participate (CNE, 1999) 17 Most important changes were: 1) The expansion of the presidential term from five to six years (including the possibility of a onetime immediate reelection). 2) Complete presidential control over promotions within the Armed Forces. 3) Disbandment of the Senate. 4) Presidential discretion in activating a referendum without authorization by the legislature. 5) No more public financing for political parties. 6) The possibility of recalling the mandate of mayors, governors and the president under certain conditions (Monaldi & Penfold, 2006). 18 Hugo Chvez Fras won the presidential election with 59.8% of the vote, runner-up Francisco Arias Crdenas obtained 37,5% of the vote and abstention reached 43.7% (CNE, 2000). 19 The enabling law authorized the president to rule by decree (but with the judicial status of law) in some in the law itself agreed upon subject matters such as finance, social and economic reforms, infrastructure and the functioning of the state (Gaceta Oficial N. 370076, 2000)

47

the Punto Fijo regime (Ellner, 2008, pp. 112-113). The two most controversial laws were the Ley de Tierras (Law of the Lands), which concerned expropriation and redistribution of idle lands, and the Ley Orgnica de Hidrocarburos (Organic Hydrocarbons Law), reforming the oil industry. The new Hydrocarbons Law stipulated that all primary oil activities are either reserved by the state, or by a joint venture with a minimum of 51% state ownership (Gaceta Oficial N. 37323, 2001). From the perspective of the Venezuelan government, these oil reforms were badly needed: oil production had fallen steeply since 1998, oil exports were down as well, and oil prices (although climbing slowly) were relatively low as well (Santos, 2009). The oil income was badly needed for Chvez socio-economic plans for a more equal and just society. Therefore privatizing PDVSA was not a policy option. However, the new hydrocarbon legislation was not welcomed by PDVSA management, oilexpert politicians and certain other sectors of society, because of their pro-privatization stance. What angered many Venezuelans that did not have a direct stake in the reforms, was the way in which these new laws were passed: without much public debate and by decree. This put anti-government forces (and especially the PDVSA management) head to head with the government and led to the firing of several managers of PDVSA by Chvez (Ellner, 2008, p. 114). The sectors opposed to the new legislation were poorly represented within parliament and took their protests to the streets. Political polarization led to massive street protests and (violent) clashes between Chavistas and anti-Chavistas. On April 11th 2002, after months of protests, strikes and rising political tension a military coup removed Chvez from office. Chairman of FEDECAMARAS, Pedro Carmona, presided the de facto government.20
21

However, the provisional government was weak from the start as it suffered from internal dissent. Only the most reactionary forces within the political opposition were well represented within the new government. Its first measures were to temporarily abolish democratic institutions, to reverse the 49 decrees and to reinstate the 1961 Constitution. The more moderate forces (such as the labor union CTV) by that time had already decided
20

This thesis does not permit sufficient space to extensively clarify all the motives, actors and consequences of the coup, so its description is limited to the most essential aspects of coup and its implications for Chvez policy. However, it still is not clear what the actual motives of the key actors were as investigation into the matter by Venezuelan authorities, private media outlets and academics is heavily biased. 21 FEDECMARAS represents the Venezuelan business community.

48

not to support the new government. As public discontent with the new regime grew, the provisional government became more and more isolated: a civic-military alliance brought Chvez back in power just 48 hours after removal (Ellner, 2008, pp. 114-115). The coup also had an international dimension: the Bush administration had supported the coup in various ways: it had financially supported various opposition organizations, met various opposition leaders without discouraging them from taking power by force, justified the coup by blaming Chvez for the political tension and rallied support for the Carmona regime directly after taking office (Ellner, 2008, pp. 198-199). After the coup, in order to appease the opposition and to depolarize the political climate, Chvez called for a time of reflection and consensus. One of the most symbolic gestures of the government was re-hiring the previously fired PDVSA managers and the appointment of OPEC secretary-general (and political moderate) Al Rodrguez Araque as head of PDVSA. However, this did not prevent the companys management from continuing their political agenda. In December 2002 PDVSA management, FEDECMARAS, CTV and the political opposition parties called for a national strike. The idea was simple: a lock-out of the national economy would foster widespread discontent with the government which would lead to the ousting of Chvez (Ellner, 2008, pp. 118-119). The results of the strike were mixed and an analogy can be drawn from the situation in PDVSA. Where senior- and middle management favored the strike, most petro-unions did not support the strike. Nevertheless, oil production came to a virtual standstill because of the lock-out. In the rest of the economy a similar pattern was visible: the economic elite and a majority of white collar workers supported the strike, whereas blue collar workers and those working in the informal economy needed and wanted to work, but could not because business owners would temporarily shut down their businesses. Yet, for the national economy the outcome was disastrous: plummeting oil production catalyzed a deep economic recession (GDP fell by 7.8% in 2003) and resulted in mounting tensions between the government and PDVSA (Buxton, 2009, p. 67). Although the economic lock-out heavily weakened the Venezuelan economy, the preceding years the economys performance had been weak as well: economic growth had been mainly negative, GDP per capita had not grown since 1998 and had shrunk by 2003 and inflation was hovering around 15-25% per year (Santos, 2009).

49

The coup and the subsequent strikes had made Chvez realize that he could not count upon sufficient support from the business community, labor unions, the infrastructure of the state bureaucracy and other political parties to realize his project. Starting in 2003, Chvez started to invest in parallel government programs, Missions, designed to bypass the bureaucracy and power of the existing government structures, lower dependence on private actors and deliver much needed goods (food) and services (health care and education) to the countrys poorest sectors (Panizza, 2009, p. 206). However, for the missions to really make an impact, funds were needed and PDVSA was to provide them. As the post-coup appeasement politics of the government had not yielded the desired results, the government fired an estimated 18,000 PDVSA employees (predominantly higher- and middle management staff) for supporting the strike and jeopardizing national interests (Economides, Martnez, & Puky, 2007). This gave the government the opportunity to restructure PDVSAs organization and redefine its relation with the company. The most important changes have been that 1) management and workers are now predominantly Chavista.22 2) PDVSA lost virtually all of its autonomy as it is now once again under control of The Ministry of Energy and Petroleum and 3) PDVSA has expanded its role into non-petroleum business; the majority of the aforementioned missions is directly funded by the company and/or is partly executed by PDVSA itself.23 Some argue that this central role that PDVSA plays in financing the missions is detrimental to the investments in the oil sector raising the possibility of lower oil production levels in the future (Buxton, 2009, p. 73). According to PVDSA from 2004-2006, it contributed to the state over 80 billion USD, of which 29% was directly destined for social programs, among which the missions. In the three preceding years it had in total contributed 31.5 billion of which a mere 0.4% was destined for social programs. Graph2 illustrates the changes in PDVSA contributions to the state under the Chvez government.

22

In November 2006, president of PDVSA and Minister of Energy and Petroleum Rafael Ramrez declared that all PDVSA workers and managers should be committed to the Bolivarian revolutionary project and that the company should be roja-rojita (the colors of the Bolivarian movement) (Panizza, 2009, pp. 209-210) 23 A prime example of such a non-core business initiative is Produccin y Distribucin Venezolana de Alimentos (PDVAL), which provides subsidized food articles.

50

Chart 2. PDVSA (Social) Contributions


$ 50 Billion US Dollars $ 40 $ 30 $ 20 $ 10 $0 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 PDVSA Contributions to the State PDVSA Contributions for Social Development

Source: PODES (2006)

After losing the Megaelections in 2000, the disastrous coup in 2002, and the failed economic lock-out in 2002 and 2003, the opposition tried yet another strategy to remove Chvez from office: the recall referendum.24 For months, different polls showed a clear win for the opposition, but in August 2004, 59% of those that went to the polls (70% of the electorate) voted against the recall (CNE, 2004). Although there seems to be disagreement about what caused the change in attitude towards the Chvez government, there is reason to believe that improving social and economic indicators favored the government: poverty went down from 62.1% (2nd semester 2003) to 53.9% (2nd semester 2004), extreme poverty went down from 29.8% (2nd semester 2003) to 22.5% (2nd semester 2004), unemployment shrunk from 19% (January 2004) to 13.9% (2nd semester 2004) and of those employed a growing number participated in the formal economy. Also, the Chvez government had improved its UN Human Development Indicator score from 0.8- (2000) to 0.82 (2005) (Institutio Nacional de Estadstica, 2010). Whether these indicators merely reflect the rebound of the economy after the oil strike or are the first tangible results of the missions: the indicators all favored the government. Another reason why Chvez might have won the recall vote, is the lack of a clear socio-economic policy alternative of the opposition: the main goal had been to oust Chvez and not to present policy alternatives. While that might have been enough for antiChavistas to support the recall, it probably did not convince the swing vote and helped Chvez win the referendum by a comfortable margin (Ellner, 2008, p. 120).

24

Article 72 of the Constitution stipulates that every elected official can be subjugated to a referendum and is subject to removal when a majority of voters think the powers of the elected official should be revoked.

51

2.5.2 Petro-boom and deepening the process


2005 marked the start of the latest petro-boom in Venezuelan history. Although prices had gradually climbed since Chvez assumed office (the price of one barrel of Venezuelan crude 10,57 USD - was at a 17 year low at the time), reaching 40 USD in 2005, oil prices exploded in the following years, topping 129 USD in July of 2008. Although production would decline in 2005, 2006 and 2007, this was compensated by the additional income for the Venezuelan state due to higher oil prices and a bigger share in profits of the PDVSA joint ventures. This is also reflected in public and private consumption.
Table1 / Year 2005 2006 2006 2007 2007 - 2008 Private Cons. growth 18.32% 196% 1.69% Public Cons. growth 6.8% 5.29% 6.03% Total Cons. growth 15.78% 16.69% 2.48%

Source: Banco Central de Venezuela

As Table 1 clearly demonstrates, private consumption grew much faster than public consumption and came to a virtual standstill in 2008 (with oil prices falling in the second semester), while government spending kept growing irrespective of the falling oil prices. The additional income worked in favor of Chvez in two ways: he could increase social spending and expand the missions, while high oil prices also facilitated the payment imports which grew at an annual rate of 44% from 2003 2007 (Santos, 2009)

Chart 3. Ven. Oil Price (Spot Market)


$ 100 $ 90 $ 80 $ 70 $ 60 $ 50 $ 40 $ 30 $ 20 $ 10 $0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

Price Venezuelan Basket

Source: PODE (2006) and OPEC Annual Bulletin (2010)

52

Concerning the oil industry, in 2005 the government published the Plan Siembra Petrolera 2005-2030 (Sowing the Oil Plan, a policy document containing the governments strategic vision on the quintessential sector for Venezuelas development strategy. The first phase (2005 2012) consists of 56 billion USD investments in upgrading and expanding refinery capacity in Venezuela, opening 27 blocks for oil exploitation, investing in off-shore gas exploitation, investments in (industry) infrastructure, international cooperation to assure Latin Americas energy security and integration through PETROCARIBE and PETROSUR and studying the reserves of the Orinoco Belt (Ministerio del Poder Popular para la Comunicacin y la Informacin, 2006). In the same year the Hydrocarbons Law was reformed (Gaceta Oficial N. 38443, 2006) raising royalty tariffs for the heavy crude projects in the Orinoco belt, which had previously been shielded from some of the tax-norms established in the 2001 Hydrocarbons Law. Also foreign interests were forced to accept the Venezuelan states 60% ownership of mixed companies (founded in the 1990s) and employees were transferred to PDVSAs payroll (Ellner, 2008, p. 127). In 2008, when oil prices peaked a windfall oil tax was levied.25 However, when oil prices fell, the tax was quickly lifted again. The latest move of the Chvez government has been the nationalization of service companies and their assets in the primary sector and the transfer of personnel to PDVSA (Gaceta Oficial N. 39173, 2009). Chart 4 illustrates Venezuelas crude oil production level and export earnings under Chvez. Several elections were held during the boom years. In December 2006, Chvez was elected once again as president of Venezuela (CNE, 2006) winning by the highest percentage of vote in democratic Venezuela (62.9%). With the Missions in full effect, skyrocketing oil prices and windfall oil income this need not surprise us. In 2007, the governments attempt to change some articles in the 1999 Constitution (the most controversial one removing term limits for the presidency) lost by a narrow margin. Yet in 2009 succeeded in passing the reforms, extending the removal of term limits for all democratically elected positions.

25

The windfall oil tax was levied over marginal income resulting from oil prices surpassing 70 U$ and 100 U$ per barrel, applying tax rates of 50% and 60% respectively (Gaceta Oficial N. 38910, 2008).

53

Chart 4 Ven. Petroleum Exports and Production


Millions 3,1 3,0 2,9 2,8 2,7 2,6 2,5 2,4 $ 80 $ 70 $ 60 $ 50 $ 40 $ 30 $ 20 $ 10 $0 Value Petroleum Exports in U$ Crude Oil Production Venezuela (barrels/day) Billions 3,2 $ 90

2006

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2007

Source: OPEC Annual Statistics Bulletin 2007 & 2008

2.5.3 Ten Years of Chvez


It has been 10 years since Chvez assumed office, and since then gradual but profound changes have been made in state, society and the oil sector in particular. The institutional changes made in the 1999 Constitution and the subsequent Hydrocarbon Laws of 2001 and 2006 have resulted in bringing PDVSA under state control again and more specifically the Ministry of Energy and Oil. This has transformed the role of PDVSA from a highly autonomous state agency with its own goals and interests to a state company whose goals and interests are aligned with those of the state. This is reflected in the characteristics of the new PDVSA, which has become increasingly participative in the domestic economy, functioning as an executive state agency both inside and outside the oil sector, serving the economic and social interests of the nation. The institutional changes have also led to a relative reduction of foreign participation in the oil sector and new contracts have been concluded mainly with foreign state oil companies that share Venezuelas geostrategic interests. Furthermore, the changes have led to increased state income from Venezuelas natural reserves, reversing the neoliberal high production, low prices strategy of the 1990s. Oil production however, has varied greatly under Chvez rule (see Figure 1: Crude Oil Production Venezuela 1998 2008), thanks to multiple strikes in from 2000 2003, subsequent changes in PDVSAs organizational and operational structure (and the brain 54

2008

drain associated with this process), and alleged underinvestment. Both the fluctuation of production levels and the world oil market prices have influenced Venezuelas export earnings. However it has become clear that the rise in income which in 2004 reached 1998 levels, is mainly due to windfall oil prices in 2008.

55

3 | Venezuelan Foreign Policy


In the introductory chapter, the notion that state behavior is exclusively determined by the international anarchic system was criticized on various grounds. Then, the Natural Resource Curse and possible effects of oil rents on foreign policy were introduced and made reasonable. After the provision of the Venezuelan political and economic context since 1958 (and especially the regimes during unipolarity). Now the reader should be familiar with the characteristics of the Venezuelan petro state, we can direct our attention to the foreign policy to see whether these initiatives correspond more to policies expected on basis of the international system or the characteristics of the petro state, or whether intervening variables apply. This chapter starts with an overview of Venezuelan foreign policy since 1958. This context is very useful in measuring how much policies have actually changed since the surge of the unipolar world system (which neorealist theory predicts). We then fastforward to the Venezuelan governments of 1989 and the Chvez era, comparing the policies of the different governments. Measurement of alleged changes in foreign policy will be made through assessment of policy along the lines of various concepts used by the different theories on state behavior. Within the neorealist school of thought, what matters is whether states are involved in traditional balancing behavior, that is: investing in military capabilities or the construction of military alliances. For the soft balancing school of thought what matters is to what extent soft balancing strategies such as diplomatic entanglement, territorial denial and social power policy projection. Key to both theories are Venezuelan US relations, so special attention will be given to this relation. Given Venezuelas remarkable characteristic of being a petro state, special attention will be paid to international oil-related policies, as various theories in the theoretical framework hinted that the relations of the petro state might be structured by them.

3.1 The 4th Republic and the World


Although the governments of the 4th Republic (19581998) usually have been portrayed by the current regime as close allies (or even subjected to the interests) of the US, empirical evidence suggests a more nuanced assessment. A brief historical context of Venezuelan foreign policy antecedents is offered to better compare and understand foreign policy

56

choices by the administrations of Carlos Andrs Prez and Rafael Caldera in the 1990s and Hugo Chvez governments from 1998 onwards. After the conclusion of the 1958 Punto Fijo Pact, which served as the basis of democratic rule in Venezuela, the subsequent Minimum Program stated the basic values which should underlie Venezuelan (foreign) policy, on what international platforms it should act and in what manner it should promote national interests in the international system. First, Venezuelan policy should be based on the values of peace and cooperation. Second, Venezuela condemns every act against the right to self-determination of any people especially concerning the countries of the Americas. Third, international problems should be solved in a peaceful manner by international institutions deemed competent for the task. The Program therefore called on the ratification of UN and OAS membership. Fourth, Venezuela should honor its international obligations. Fifth, Venezuela should play an active role within the Americas, revising its relations to make sure that these are based upon democratic principles and economic cooperation. Sixth, Venezuela should promote commercial trade by means of bilateral agreements using petroleum and other natural resources as trade instruments (Aveledo, 2007, p. 264). Like many other foreign policy documents, the goals are rather vague and ambiguous. Therefore actual foreign policy initiatives need to be studied. A short assessment already shows that the above stated principles were not always respected to the same degree. In line with a strict interpretation the Betancourt Doctrine Venezuela did not recognize the Castro regime in Cuba during the 1960s (Aveledo, 2007, p. 266).26 Yet Venezuela also condemned the 1965 US military intervention in the Dominican Republic (Kelly & Romero, 2005, p. 37). At the same time Betancourts government condemned Soviet interference in the hemisphere and usually voted in line with the US in the OAS (Kelly & Romero, 2002, p. 29). In the 1970s Venezuelan governments did not automatically back US foreign policy decisions either. The oil bonanza flooded the Venezuelan state with income, providing for a more active foreign policy: Venezuela pursued more equality in international trade, transfer of technology and UN reform trough the Non-Aligned Movement and the G77 (Aveledo,

26

The doctrine stated that Venezuela should not have diplomatic relations with governments which had come to power by undemocratic means, such as a coup dtats or rigged elections (Kelly & Romero, 2005, p. 137).

57

2007, pp. 270-271).27 It also restored formal relations with Cuba, defying the Betancourt Doctrine. Concerning international oil policy, the Venezuelan government did not want to jeopardize its special relation with the US. Facing growing competition from petro states in the Middle East, such as Iran and Saudi-Arabia, the Venezuelan government wanted to present itself as a stable oil supplier for the US. It had already sought preferential access to the US market for its oil products, yet with no success. Furthermore, the nationalization process in Venezuela had worried the US as it saw the interests of some of its petroleum companies jeopardized. In this context it need not surprise us that Venezuela did not join the Arab OPEC members production cuts during the Arab-Israeli War of 1973. Abstaining from the use of the oil weapon worked in two ways: 1) Venezuela could take over market share at the cost of those involved in the boycott. 2) Venezuela could prove its reputation as a stable oil provider. The US took notice of Venezuelan protagonism and its more autonomous line, it valued Venezuelan as a stable oil provider and a beacon of democracy and political stability in the hemisphere (Kelly & Romero, 2002, p. 22) (Tugwell, 1975, pp. 140-141). Given the US support of non-democratic regime in that very time span, one could well argue that the US valued stability over democracy. Nevertheless, the Venezuelan regime provided both and therefore was an interesting ally for the US in a continent which lacked both stability and democracy in the 1970s. In the previous Chapter, the dwindling oil prices and their influence on domestic state finances has already been discussed. Yet there were also international consequences: as the state apparatus could not adapt itself to the new reality of low oil prices and high interest rates, Venezuelas foreign debt skyrocketed in the early 80s and the international activism of its government waned. The governments posture itself changed little. Caracas continued to share Washingtons strategic vision that Soviet and Cuban influence in the region was unwanted. Yet the Venezuelan government was very critical of US intervention and considered them undue meddling in internal affairs. The various armed conflicts in Central America during the 1980s illustrates this point: while the US supported and armed the
27

The Non-Aligned Movement, born in the mid 1950s, represented those countries that did not want to get involved in the Cold War and therefore refused to align with either the US or the Soviet Union. The Movement also had a strong socio-economic agenda: one of the main objectives was to create conditions for sustainable development of the NAM-members. This, stemming from the perception that the more developed nations dominated world politics and this jeopardized the safety and socio-economic development of the non-aligned (Non-Aligned Movement, 2010).

58

Nicaraguan contras, Venezuela supported moderates and tried to mediate in the conflict (Kelly & Romero, 2002, p. 24). During the Malvinas/Falklands War it supported Argentinas cause against one of the last vestiges of colonialism although Argentina was led by a dictatorial regime. In that case Latin-American solidarity took priority over notions of democracy. These examples serve to show that 1) the goals stated in the Minimum Program of 1958 were not always respected and broadly interpreted. 2) Venezuelas foreign policy does not seem to have been a mere copy of US foreign policy. Venezuelan foreign policy formulation during the 4th republic took place within the following institutional context. Although, like in most countries foreign policy formulation is concentrated in the executive and the ministry of Foreign Affairs (Hill, 2003, p. 53), in the 4th Republic various other actors were heavily involved in policy formulation and the distribution of their mutual power relations: 1) The Punto Fijo Pact assured domination of parties AD and COPEI over the political system. 2) The relatively well developed internal organization of COPEI but especially AD gave the parties independent authority and power to challenge the executive, even if office was held by a party member (Levitsky, 2001, pp. 50-51). 3) PDVSA had obtained significant autonomy from the rest of the state apparatus and had developed its own vision on what role the company and state should play in the international system (Trinkunas H. , 2009, pp. 17-18). 4) The ever presence of the Armed Forces, which role is further discussed in the next section. 3.1.2 Traditional balancing behavior Within the realist notion of international relations traditional balancing consists of investing in the military articles and services, or concluding military alliances with other nations. In this section, expenses and civil-military relations are studied (according to the relevance of the institutional setup discussed earlier). In Chapter 2, the tense relation between the military and the democratic governments of the 80s and 90s has already been discussed. The growing discontent of especially younger officers with the regime (because of corruption, mismanagement and neoliberal economic policies) distanced these groups with the senior officers and the government. The militarys heavy handed response to the 1989 riots proved to the young officers that they were serving an illegitimate government and corrupt senior officers. These junior officers identified

59

themselves more with the people than the establishment: like the vast majority of Venezuelan society their economic situation had increasingly deteriorated during the 1980s. Although military spending as such had been left relatively untouched in spite of the economic crisis, spending patterns within the military had changed: more money was spent on the high command and arms, while less was destined for salaries and other social needs of these junior officers (Trinkunas H. A., 2002, pp. 51-53). The Prez government itself had been unaware of the schisms within the military as - because of the autonomous position of the military - the executive branch could only oversee total spending of the military apparatus. Discontent with Prez neoliberal policies and the inept army leadership triggered the two 1992 coups which ultimately signaled the end of Prez presidency. The coups also triggered increasing US-Venezuelan cooperation by intensifying Venezuelan training missions by the US military (Trinkunas H. A., 2002, p. 58). Returning to the topic of military expenditure, Chart X.X demonstrates the level of military spending during the second administrations of both Prez and Caldera.28 Venezuelas military spending as percentage of GDP remained stable during the 1990s, with few exceptions. Starting at 1.9% in 1991, spending declined in 1992 and peaked at 2.2% in 1993. The 1993 spending boom needs to placed in the context of the two subsequent coups in 1992. Acknowledging the rather precarious situation of the Venezuelan democracy after the two failed coups of 1992, Caldera radically altered military-civic relations and restored civil supremacy over the armed forces.29 Even taking into account these appeasement expenses, Venezuelas military spending during the 1990s remained modest comparing to the growing expenses of neighboring Colombia. Like in many other Latin-American countries, Venezuelas spending remained at the same levels or fell modestly (see Chart 6 below). Although military spending in absolute dollar terms fell during the Caldera administration, internal shifts in spending appeased the military: the social needs of the officer corps which had been ignored for a long time, were addressed by generous pay raises (Trinkunas H. A.,
28 29

Reliable data for 1989 and 1990 are not available and therefore are not included in the graph. Caldera reestablished himself as chief of the armed forces by firing his defense minister and replacing him by a junior officer, effectively forcing out various senior generals who would rather resign than server under a junior officer. Soldiers involved in the 1992 coups (amongst others Hugo Chvez) received a presidential pardon under the condition that they would resign from the military. By expelling both the military high command and the MBR- 200, Caldera purged the officer corps of its two most politicized extremes and allowed the rest to return to their professional duties (Trinkunas H. A., 2002, p. 62).

60

2002, p. 63). This seems to indicate that spending on defense articles and services had to be lowered to realize the pay raises.

Chart 6 Mil. Expenditure as %GDP


6,0% 5,0% 4,0% 3,0% 2,0% 1,0% 0,0% 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Argentina Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico United States Venezuela, R.B. de

Source: World Bank Data Catalog (2010)

Statistics on arms and services agreements and sales with Venezuelas hitherto most important military trading partner (the US) seems to confirm this suspicion. 1996 1999 figures on Venezuelan military agreements and defense articles and services from the US are relatively modest: 101 million USD was spent on military agreements, while another 156 million USD was spent on US defense articles and services. Although this places Venezuela in the top 5 of US most important clients within the Americas, the actual amounts pale in comparison to other purchasers in the region.30 The aforementioned figures total a 257 Million USD expense, representing a mere 3.7% of total Venezuelan military expenditure. However, the data mentioned above does not cover all military expenses. According to the IISS, the Venezuelan armed forces have historically received funding from the Ley Paraguas (Umbrella Law) fund up to 500 USD million per year (IISS, 2010, p. 60).31

30

Leading purchasers of US Defense agreements of the Americas (in Millions): 1) Canada 397 USD 2) Colombia 196 USD 3) Brazil 109 USD 4) Venezuela 101 USD 5) Argentina 47 USD. Leading purchasers of US defense articles and services of the Americas (in Millions): 1) Canada 451 USD 2) Colombia 242 USD 3) Brazil 204 USD 4) Venezuela 156 USD 5) Mexico 52 USD. 31 The Ley Paraguas was originally used as a savings fund for newly contracted debts or the repayment of old debts (Ministerio de Finanzas, 2005).

61

Based on the limited data provided in the preceding sections and the spending pattern of the neoliberal governments of the 1990s (especially Caldera), military spending seems to have been geared towards appeasement of the military vis--vis the government rather than bolstering Venezuelas military might. Traditional balancing efforts thus seem to have been completely absent during the governments of both Prez and Caldera. 3.1.3 Carlos Andres Prez The demise of the Soviet Union and the transformation of the international system from a bipolar to a unipolar structure largely coincided with Carlos Andrs Prez second term in office. An important pillar of Prez foreign policy strategy was the strengthening of the Organization of American States. He saw the organization as key to promoting democracy, economic growth (along neoliberal lines), security issues and resolving the US Cuban conflict. However, giving a new impulse to the OAS was only possible getting rid of the old vices of the OAS: its anticommunist bias, tolerance of right-wing dictatorships and inaction against aggressive US unilateralism (Prez, 1990). Proof of Prez dedication to uphold and maintain democratic regimes in the region can be found in his efforts to guide the Nicaraguan transformation to democracy after a bloody civil war in the 1980s and to prevent Haiti fragile democracy from descending into chaos after the overthrow of Aristides government in 1991 (Kelly & Romero, 2005, pp. 202-203). There also seems to be evidence that Prez actively lobbied within the OAS to create a mechanism against coup dtats, not in the last place because he increasingly feared a coup in Venezuela during his presidency, because of his unpopular neoliberal - policies (Bloomfield, 1994, pp. 181-182). 3.1.3.1 OPEC Although production increases were not stimulated by the Prez government due to reasons discussed in Chapter 2, Venezuela raised its production under Prez by 28.3%. Under Prez, OPEC quota discipline was weak, in spite of the significantly higher assigned quota because of the Gulf War and the associated instability of OPEC Middle East oil producers.
Table 2 Venezuela OPEC Quota Discipline under Carlos Andrs Prez32 (in 1000 barrels /p day)
Jan89 Jun89 1636 Jul89 Sep89 1724 Oct89Dec89 1812 Jan90Jul90 1945 Aug90 1945 Apr91Sep91 2235 Feb92Sep92 2147 Jan93Feb93 2360 Mar93Sep93 2257

Quota

32

There were country-specific production allocation agreements from September 1990 March 1991, October 1991 January 1992 and October 1992 December 1992.

62

Production 1910 1910 1910 2140 2140 Overproduction 16.7% 10.8% 5.4% 10% 10% Source: Energy Information Agency, OPEC and own calculations

2380 6.5%

2370 10.4%

2450 3.8%

2450 8.6%

3.1.3.2 Credit lines by International Financial Institutions In the previous chapter the domestic consequences of Prez deal with the IMF have been briefly mentioned. In this very paragraph the international ramifications of the deal are scrutinized. The 1989 IMF was part of the so called Brady Plan which was intended to restructure the economies of states that had large foreign debts to service. The Extended Fund Facility of the IMF offered approximately 3.9 Billion USD (of which 2.3 billion was actually used by the Prez government) (IMF, 2010).33 The funds were conditional upon neoliberal restructuring of the Venezuelan economy. The Prez government tied itself to the US-dominated IFI and reduced its sovereignty in economic policy making. It also legitimized the position of the fund and the neoliberal Washington Agenda. The governments was even more orthodox than the fund in repaying its IMF debt: the 4,5 year grace period was not used and repayments started as soon as 1991 (Ibid.). 3.1.4 Rafael Caldera (feb 94 feb99) Like his predecessor, Rafael Caldera had campaigned on a anti-neoliberal platform, consisting of various left of centre political parties like the Movimiento Al Socialsmo (MAS Movement towards Socialism) promising the Venezuelan electorate a return to the golden days of the 4th Republic. Statist intervention in the economy and a nationalist approach where the cornerstones of Calderas campaign. However, also Caldera would eventually turn to neoliberalist policies. 3.1.4.1 Calderas oil policies Calderas new oil policy, consisting of opening up the oil sector for private companies and raising production levels had important ramifications for Venezuelas behavior within OPEC. As the organization had been assigning production quota per country since 1982 by means of production quota agreements, Venezuela was bound by these rules. Table XX.XX clearly shows that in spite of being granted higher production levels, the Venezuelan government preferred the realization of higher production levels over abiding the OPEC treaties and
33

The Extended Fund Facility is a facility of the IMF to assist member countries in overcoming balance of payments problems that stem largely from structural problems and require a longer period of adjustment than is possible under a Stand-By Arrangement. Countries must repay EFF resources over a period of four and a half to 10 years (IMF, 2003).

63

became a notorious quota buster. The voluntary production cuts were agreed to during the March 1998 Extraordinary Meeting of the OPEC Conference and were due to earlier market misreading, when OPEC raised total production quota by 10% while the Asian economic crisis raged. While demand dwindled, production had been raised, causing the price of crude oil to fall by 40% (Kohl, 2002, p. 211). It is safe to say that for the Caldera administration, OPEC had little relevance.
Table 3 Venezuela OPEC Quota Discipline under the Caldera administration (in 1000 barrels /p day)
Mar93 Jul93 Oct93 Jul96 Jun93 Sep93 Jun96 Dec97 Quota 2257 2257 2359 2359 Production 2450 2450 2699 3166 Overproduction 8.6% 8.6% 14.4% 34,2% Source: Energy Information Agency, OPEC and own calculations Jan98 Mar98 2583 3170 22,7% Apr98 Jun98 [-200] [3170] Jul98 Mar99 2845 3057 7.5%

3.1.4.2 International Financial Institutions and the Caldera government Caldera had highly criticized Prez governments policy of effectively handing monetary and economic policy to international financial institutions such as the IMF and the World Bank. Yet as Venezuela faced the collapse of the national banking system, the Caldera government changed its rhetoric and switched to the same neoliberal discourse of its predecessor. In 1996 Caldera solicited IMF financial assistance. A Standby Agreement was reached and the IMF disbursed 350 million USD (IMF, 2010).34 The IMF provided the funds under the conditions that state-owned companies would be privatized and the public sector would be reformed. Nevertheless, the Caldera government hardly implemented the reforms. To a certain extent Caldera faced the same problems as Prez: the position of his government vis-vis the opposition was weak, and even within the government Caldera had many opponents. In civil society neoliberal reforms were highly unpopular too. In other words, Calderas government was too weak to realize most of the reforms (Lupia & McCubbins, 1998, pp. 37-38).35 Somewhat ironically one could conclude that the only part of the Standby Agreement that was actually honored by the Caldera administration were the imposed repayment conditions.

34

Stand-By Arrangements enable IMF member states to use IMF financing up to a specified amount to overcome short-term or cyclical balance of payments difficulties typically cover a period of one to two years (although they can extend up to three years). Repayments are to be made over a period of three and a quarter to 5 years (IMF, 2003). 35 Chapter 2 provides a more detailed overview of the reform efforts of the second Caldera administration.

64

3.1.4.3 Towards a Free Trade regime Perhaps the most significant hemispheric economic foreign policy initiative by the US during the 1990s was the desire to create a free trade area that would extent over the entire Americas. In 1994 the US had already concluded such an agreement with Canada and Mexico, the North American Free Trade Area (NAFTA). As most Latin American countries were ruled by governments that were convinced of pro-market arguments, the US seized the opportunity to extend the agreements southwards and to construct a Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA). In the ambitious 1994 Declaration of Principles the 34 countries, among which Venezuela committed themselves:
to [..] to construct the "Free Trade Area of the Americas" (FTAA), in which barriers to trade and investment will be progressively eliminated. We [] conclude the negotiation of the "Free Trade Area of the Americas" no later than 2005, and agree that concrete progress [] will be made by the end of this century (1st Summit of the Americas, 1994).

This is not to say that there were no reservations amongst government in Latin America: many feared that the US would reap most of the benefits of the agreement, because of its privileged economic position, while benefits for Latin-American countries would be more uncertain and varied per country. The vast majority of nations in the region therefore chose to negotiate in blocks. Venezuela joined forces with the other members of the Andean Community to have a stronger position in negotiating the terms for the FTAA vis--vis the United States. Yet by 1998 it had become clear that only modest progress had been made in negotiations. Nevertheless, during the second Summit of the Americas in Chile, Venezuela and the other nations nevertheless reiterated their support for the realization of the FTAA by 2005 (Kelly & Romero, 2002, pp. 115-116). This is not to say that Venezuela did not clash with the US during Calderas regime, concerning the conditions on free trade. In 1993 Venezuela summoned the US because of a breach of the GATT Article 3 by discriminatory treatment of Venezuelan gasoline exports to the US. In 1994 the US summoned the Venezuelan government because of alleged dumping of steel tubes (Aveledo, 2007, p. 279). These incidents hint that although the Venezuelan government agreed with the free trade doctrine (actively promoted by the US), they did try to constrain the US by effectively using the rules of the game against its major player, even though Venezuela itself did not always respect the rules of the game either. 65

3.1.4.4 Drug trafficking and environmental issues: clashes with the US. It must be clear by now that various economic issues have both divided and united foreign policy goals of Venezuela and the US. However, narcotrafficking obtained an increasingly important place on the US foreign policy agenda. Although Venezuela has never been a major drug producing country (unlike its neighbor Colombia), the country is considered a major narcotics transit country since the mid-90s by the US Government (USGAO, 2009, p. 5). As far back as 1978 a Memorandum of Understanding was signed between the US and Venezuela to fight trafficking. But by the mid 90s the problems had gotten out of control, at least from a US-perspective. The US increasingly started to monitor and certify anti-narcotics policy in the region and Washington considered Caracas efforts half-hearted. This greatly worried US Government which sought closer cooperation with Caracas. Although a modest Memorandum of Understanding was concluded in September 1994 on the matter, the Caldera government felt little for allowing US radar stations to be placed on Venezuelan territory or far reaching cooperation with the US Drug Enforcement Agency because of sovereignty issues (DEA) (Kelly & Romero, 2002, p. 105). Another dimension of international relations which has slowly but surely emerged on the international agenda was the environment. Especially carbon-dioxide emissions have proven to be an important topic. In 1997 the Kyoto Protocol was signed in order to lower the emission of greenhouse gasses, and the Caldera government supported the initiative, in spite of the fact that Venezuela belongs to the top-5 greenhouse emitters in Latin America and has a share of about 0.5% of worldwide emissions. However, it would be during Chvez second term that the Bolivarian government actually ratified the Kyoto protocol (Gaceta Oficial N. 38081, 2004).

3.2 Bolivarian foreign policy


As the preceding sections show, since its rise as a petro state Venezuela became an ever active player in Latin America. However, through both style and content, Chvez has managed to put Venezuela in the limelight of world politics. Concerning style, the flamboyant discourse of the president and his frequent clashes with world leaders such as George W. Bush and Spanish King Juan Carlos attracted a lot of media attention. Concerning content, what the Bolivarian government is trying to achieve in terms of foreign policy is

66

radically different from its predecessors. Furthermore the lead role Venezuela plays in the surge of the New Left in Latin America has few precedents.36 The Venezuelan government is very clear about its foreign policy objectives, which are explicitly mentioned in the policy document General Lines of the Plan for the Economic and Social Development of the Nation.37 In the document the Bolivarian government explicitly states it seeks to accomplish is the construction of a new multipolar world order, to replace the current unipolar order which is dominated by the United States as the hegemon. This goal is to be achieved by the creation of various counter-hegemonic power blocks (Gobierno Bolivariano de Venezuela, 2007, pp. 42,45-46). The principles on which these blocks are founded are social justice, solidarity, and sovereignty of the people. These terms are to be interpreted as anti-imperialist, anti-neoliberal and anti-globalization. In terms of defense, its goals are to protect the Bolivarian revolution in Venezuela and to minimize the influence of domestic and foreign actors that disagree with the ideals and the manner in which the revolution is carried out (Trinkunas H. , 2009, p. 19). Venezuelas foreign policy documents go beyond mere statements on goals, it also addresses the issue on how to realize the aforementioned goals. They also address how to realize the aforementioned goals. Concerning Venezuela-US relations, Venezuela seeks to better relations at the grassroots level (such as social movements) rather than fomenting bilateral diplomatic relations. Improving information about Venezuela through alternative media is another instrument. Venezuela even promises help for and solidarity with the excluded sectors of US society (Gobierno Bolivariano de Venezuela, 2007, p. 49). Venezuelas agenda for Latin America and the Caribbean is both straightforward and challenging: the most important goals are the political, economic and cultural integration of Latin America and the Caribbean through international organizations such as MERCOSUR and UNASUR. Another important goal is improving relations with Cuba and Bolivia to

36

The New (Latin-American) Left is an umbrella term used to describe the various left of center governments that have governed various nations in Latin-America, usually characterized by the following features: 1) Plurality of strategies and articulation of decentralized forms of organization. 2) Multiplicity of social bases and political agendas. 3) Prominence of Civil Society. 4) Reformism 5) Deepening democracy (Barrett, Chvez, & Rodrguez-Garavito, 2008, pp. 12-17). 37 The most important ones being the Lneas Generales del Plan de Desarollo Econmico y Social de la Nacin 2001 2006 & 2007 2013.

67

develop the ALBA as a viable economic integration alternative to the neoliberal FTAA. Diminishing the relative importance of the US for Central America is key to the integration efforts (2007, p. 48). Regarding international oil policy, Venezuela prioritizes creating tighter relations with OPEC member states and other petroleum-exporting countries (such as Russia). Increasing commercial trade of technological and scientific knowledge, services and goods with countries in the Middle-East is another important goal (2007, p. 49). Relations with countries such as Iran, Syria and China the governments goals concentrate in creating a political antiimperialist alliance against the US. Coordinating a common position within international organizations is a key instrument in this strategy (2007, pp. 48-49). Although policy document analysis is an important instrument to determine a countrys foreign policy (goals), what really interests us here is actual state behavior. The virtue of including actual state behavior is that it can be contrasted with theory to assess hypotheses concerning state behavior in the international system. Another virtue is that including actual state behavior and comparing it to discourse, makes it easier to distinguish between mere diplomatic courtesy and actual goals of states. Earlier in this Chapter we have already been witness to the rather ambiguous foreign policy of various governments of the 4 th Republic, when contrasted to its original foreign policy guidelines as presented in the Minimum Program. The same approach will be used in the next few sections, in which Venezuelan the aforementioned guidelines of foreign policy are contrasted with the behavior of the subsequent Bolivarian governments, headed by Hugo Chvez, in the international system. 3.2.1 Signs of hard balancing? According to the Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (2009), worldwide military expenditure has risen some 45% in real terms since 1999. In the same time span, military consumption by the Chvez government, has remained relatively stable. Government military expenses have been hovering between 1.2% and 1.7% of GDP. Except for the 2003-2007 interval, a slight negative trend is identifiable resulting in a mere 1% of GDP expenditure in 2008 (World Bank, 2010). The table below clearly shows that Venezuelan military spending as percentage of GDP is modest compared to other big countries in the region such as Brazil, Colombia and Mexico. Venezuela under Chvez has stayed well below

68

the regional average of 1,7% and the US (4%) (World Bank, 2010).
5,0% 4,5% 4,0% 3,5% 3,0% 2,5% 2,0% 1,5% 1,0% 0,5% 0,0% Argentina Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico United States Venezuela, R.B. de

Bron enzo. Because of the volatility of Venezuelas GDP (caused by dependence on oil rents), the aforementioned data tells us too little about real military expenditure. After carefully examining statistics provided by the World Bank, a downward trend is identifiable from 1999 (about 2 billion USD) to 2003 (about 1.2 billion USD). Between 2003 and 2006 Venezuelas military budget almost doubled to 2.4 billion USD. After that, military spending plummeted and hit 1,8 billion USD. While worldwide military expenditure rose some 45% in real terms between 1999 and 2008, Venezuelan expenditure rose a mere 8.5%. Venezuelan military consumption therefore does adhere to the overall trend, except for the 2003 2006 interval. Some reservations need to be made concerning the official data. Various analysts (Nueva Mayoria, 2008) suggest that additional military spending has taken place in recent years through extra budgetary funds as the FONDEN (National Development Fund), up to over 3 billion USD in total (IISS, 2010, p. 60). This form of extra budgetary spending seems similar to the aforementioned Paraguas fund of the 4 th Republic. Other analysts claim that there is little reason to believe significant amounts of money are unaccounted for (Snchez, 2009). What has changed under Chvez however, are Venezuelas main providers of military training and defense equipment. Traditionally, Venezuelan military officers had the

69

possibility to get an education in the US or Europe. In 2004, Chvez ordered to cease training of Venezuelan soldiers at the School of the Americas. Some of the key military figures in the 2002 coup were graduates of the School (Catholic New Times, 2004).38 Since 2005, Cuban military personnel is increasingly involved in training Venezuelan soldiers and participates in Venezuelan defense, intelligence and communication systems (James, 2010). Besides military training cooperation, arms purchases have shifted from the US to countries such as Russia, China, Cuba, Iran and Spain (Trinkunas H. , 2009, p. 15) (IISS, 2010, p. 61). This is partly the result of the 2006 US embargo on the sale of defense materials to Venezuela, because it deemed Venezuelan anti-narcotics and terrorism efforts half-hearted (National Archives and Records Administration, 2006).
Reeks1 Billions $ 2,5 $ 2,0 $ 1,5 $ 1,0 $ 0,5 $1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

Source: World Bank Data Catalog (2010)

3.2.2 Spreading the oil wealth: petro dollar diplomacy The vast majority of Venezuelas oil exports are traded on the world oil market and traded against market prices. In this framework, the export of oil functions as the prime source of income for the state. However, over the past few years Venezuela has greatly expanded the number of oil barrels traded under preferential conditions and against discounted prices. A
38

The School of the Americas (now renamed to Western Hemisphere Institute for Security Cooperation) is a training school for Latin-American soldiers. It has the rather dubious reputation of training some of the regions most notorious dictators and human rights abusers. Several training manuals used by the institute advocate the use of torture, illegal executions and the use of coercion against civilians (Livingstone, 2009, pp. 40-42).

70

key example of such an initiative is PETROCARIBE.39 About 198,000 barrels of oil are traded daily within the framework of the program (Ellner, 2008, p. 203), which represents about a quarter of all the Venezuelan oil exports to Latin-American countries. The PETROCARIBE member states buy Venezuelan oil against generous terms: 1) the Venezuelan government offers credit lines for the acquisition of the oil (the higher the oil price, the larger the share to be financed) and annual interest-rates as low as 1%.40 2), there is a two-year grace period on repaying the loans. 3) the agreement allows for the repayment of the debt in services or goods against preferential tariffs (PETROCARIBE, 2005). For the predominantly poor countries of the Caribbean, the Venezuelan oil is attractive for several reasons: since the Caribbean countries themselves do not possess big oil reserves nor refining capacity, their economies are very dependent on oil imports. Since price on the oil market fluctuate heavily, their economies are vulnerable to high oil prices. The generous financing possibilities mediate oil shocks for these countries. The option to repay debt over many years and in goods and services relieves the stress on the scarce foreign currency reserves of these countries. The institutional structure of the PETROCARIBE can be classified as highly intergovernmental and underdeveloped: as Venezuela is the sole provider of the commodity distributed through the organization it is by far the most important player within the organization.41 It is therefore very unlikely that the member state would vote against Venezuela within the organization as this would probably threaten the very existence of the organization (and thus the cheap access to oil of the member states). Since the foundation of PETROCARIBE, several political decisions were made regarding (aspiring) members of PETROCARIBE. In 2005 Haiti was not invited to the summit where the original framework agreement was signed because Venezuela did not recognize the Haitian government as president Jean-Bertrand Aristide was removed from office by the US and

39

Similar agreements have also been concluded with countries in the South of Latin-America such as Argentina and Uruguay, creating the PETROSUR. 40 Antigua and Barbuda, the Bahamas, Belize, Cuba, Dominica, the Dominican Republic, Grenada, Guyana, Jamaica, Nicaragua, Suriname, St Lucia, St Kitts and Nevis, Guatemala, and Saint Vincent and the Grenadines 41 The statutes of the organization identify two organs within the organization. The Ministerial Council (comprised by all the Ministers of Energy of the participating countries), which is the highest advisory organ and decides by unanimous vote. The executive branch of the organization is the Secretariat and is ascribed to the Venezuelan Ministry of Energy and Oil (PETROCARIBE, 2005)

71

France (Ishmael, 2005). Haiti was able to join the PETROCARIBE only after the restoration of democracy. Also in July 2009 the Venezuelan government halted PETROCARIBE oil supplies to Honduras (20,000 b/d). The Honduran president Manuel Zelaya had been ousted by a military coup because he allegedly had breached the countrys constitution. Caracas did not acknowledge the legitimacy of the new de facto government, which it labeled a dictatorship (EFE, 2009). As Zelaya had brought Honduras into PETROCARIBE and ALBA, he had become a close ally of Venezuela. The new de facto regime on the other hand was distinctively pro-US and anti-Chvez. Venezuela therefore used PETROCARIBE as a pressure tool for the de facto government to step down and reinstate Zelaya as the legitimate ruler of the country. However, Caracas attempts failed as new elections were held and a new right-wing president was sworn in. Over more, several countries have reinstated (or promised to restore) diplomatic ties with Honduras, among which the US (Associated Press, 2010). One might ask why Venezuela so generously hands out one of the worlds most valuable commodities when the country itself is still classified only as an upper-middle income country by the World Bank. And in spite of this status, its lopsided income distribution has left the overwhelming majority of society without access the countrys own oil wealth. Given the abundance of oil in Venezuela, it is anything but scarce (domestically) and thus less risky to donate than more scarcer good and services. In literature regarding Chvez foreign oil policy two sets of views dominate: the first perspective lauds Venezuelas commitment to economic, social and humanitarian development of other states in the region creating political goodwill. Also, these cooperation agreements could provide the base for further political and economic integration of Latin America. Such development would greatly enhance the power of Latin American countries vis--vis the US and would contribute to the realization of a multipolar world order, effectively reducing US control over the region (Ellner, 2008, p. 203). In such a framework oil is a means to an end, and the costs can be justified. A more cynical approach to agreements of PETROCARIBE views the social, economic and humanitarian ideals as a simple smokescreen to divert from the real goal of Chvez policy: gain influence in the region by buying support of local allies in international organizations such as the OAS by means of practically giving away oil (Ishmael, 2005) (Corrales).

72

However, these international handouts are not limited to crude oil. Media outlets have repeatedly reported on Venezuelan investments or developmental aid in countries as diverse as Argentina and the US. For example, in the US, the Venezuelan state owned CITGO oil company provided tens of thousands of low-income families in New York with low-cost heating oil (King, 2010). In Argentina, the Venezuelan Socio-economic Development Bank (BANDES) provided a 135 million USD loan to dairy cooperative Sancor (Quixote Center, 2007). Javier Corrales has extensively studied this kind of Venezuelan foreign policy. Two characteristics stand out in this context: 1) Venezuelas investments are predominantly carried out by the state, and 2) the investment projects include large sums for development projects (Corrales, 2009, p. 99). The numbers are impressive: bolstered by oil windfall profits since 2007 Venezuela has surpassed the US in direct funding for the region, pledging some 8.8 billion USD in the fiscal year 2005. The majority of the funds tend to benefit left-leaning governments which are sympathetic to Venezuelas main foreign policy goal: diminishing US influence over the region. For example, Venezuela helped Argentina pay off its IMF debt by buying 5.1 billion USD in Argentine bonds, sponsored 20 million USD worth on eye-clinics in Bolivia and promised 772 USD million on developmental aid for Nicaragua, the Dominican Republic and Haiti (Obiko Pearson & James, 2007). A third but very important feature is the almost non-existent conditionality of the funds. The high discretional nature of the funds makes the funds hard to track down, and the governments receiving them prone to corruption, which endangers the (supposedly laudable) goals of the funds (Corrales, 2009, p. 107) Venezuelan funds are not limited to aid funds. There is reason to believe that Chvez government has provided (im)material support for political allies in Latin America. The most striking example thus far has been Valijagate. In September 2007 a Venezuelan was apprehended while trying to smuggle 800.000 USD (out of 4.000.000 USD) into Argentina in the wake of presidential elections. According to the suspect, the money was destined for the campaign of Cristina Fernndez (wife of close ally and former Argentine president Nestor Kirchner).42 Previously, Chvez had publicly stated his support for particular candidates in
42

Both the Venezuelan and Argentine government deny any involvement in the matter. However, the suspect traveled from Venezuela to Argentina in an airplane rented by both governments and accompanied by PDVSA officials. Furthermore, the suspect was later seen during the ceremony of an oil deal signing between Chvez and the Argentine government in the presidential palace (Alconada Mon, 2008).

73

Peru and Bolivia (Ollanta Humala and Evo Morales respectively), and some argue even financial support although strong evidence is missing to back up these claims. In both cases however, the public support of Chvez was perceived as meddling with domestic affairs and actually benefitted other presidential candidates (Corrales, 2009, p. 109). Yet, this conclusion needs to be nuanced as both Morales and Fernndez won their respective elections with comfortable majorities. 3.2.3 UNASUR: Defending Latin-American sovereignty The Chvez government sees political cooperation and integration of the South-American nations as an important step towards the construction of a multipolar world order. Inspired by the legacy of Venezuelas liberator Simn Bolivar (who envisioned Latin-America as one continent inhabited by a brotherhood of people, and strived to make it a single political unit), Venezuela has been one of the protagonists in the construction of UNASUR (Unin de Naciones Suramericanas). Although UNASUR was recently founded, it was used as a decision-making platform during two recent political crises in South-America. Rising tensions political and civil tensions in Bolivia in 2008 provided the first challenge for UNASUR. Bolivias political unity had come under threat due to a growing divide between the political center of power (La Paz) and concentration of economic prosperity in Santa Cruz province. The divide roughly coincides with an ethnic cleavage (predominantly indigenous in the Highlands and La Paz versus predominantly mestizo and white in the Eastern Lowlands) and the geographical distribution of natural gas reserves (which are concentrated in the Eastern Lowlands) (Segura & Bellamy, 2009, p. 1). 43 In an attempt to address the grave racial and socioeconomic inequality in Bolivian society, the socialist-oriented government of Evo Morales, sought to redistribute (natural gas) wealth, which is concentrated in the Eastern Lowlands and reassert the power of the federal government. The political opposition on the other hand, wanted to secure regional autonomy in order to maintain access to the natural gas rents. Since 2005 the writing of a new constitution and the organization of referenda had been characterized by disrespect for rules and procedures by both camps, further aggravating the political tension. When violent protests erupted and the US government held an ambiguous attitude towards the protesters, the Bolivian government accused that

43

The term mestizo refers to a mix of European and autochthonous ethnicity.

74

the American Embassy in La Paz had played a key role in fomenting separatist sentiments and thus was conspiring against Bolivian unity and democracy. Morales party MAS even went as far as claiming that the US Ambassador, Mr. Goldberg had been involved in secret meetings with right-wing political and business leaders and was also responsible for a media-war against the Morales government to incite the violent takeover of government institutions to force Morales out of office (Friedman-Rudovsky, 2008).44 In solidarity with Evo Morales, Chvez also expelled the US ambassador from Venezuela and recalled his ambassador in Venezuela. During the crisis, various international organizations, such as the UN, the OAS and UNASUR, had expressed their concern and willingness to mediate in the conflict between the government and the opposition. Morales however rejected mediation by the UN (as relations had lukewarm ever since Morales assumed office). Because of US involvement in the autonomist movement, the US-dominated OAS too could not function as a neutral platform for mediation.45 This proved to be an excellent opportunity for the UNASUR to function as an alternative platform for mediation without US intervention. The platform was also attractive because it provided Venezuela and Brazil the opportunity to consolidate themselves as regional powers (Segura & Bellamy, 2009, p. 3), while for other nations like Argentina a quick resolution was of utmost importance because gas-exports from Bolivia had halted since the outbreak of the conflict. All South-American leaders followed suit and called for an extraordinary of meeting of UNASUR to resolve the political crisis (Philips, 2008). The members of UNASUR unanimously decided to back Evo Morales government and issued the Declaracin de la Moneda (UNASUR, 2008). The document stated that the UNASURmembers will not recognize any Bolivian authority but Morales government, condemn the actions of destabilizing groups which jeopardize Bolivian democracy and call for the preservation of the unity of Bolivia. It was a clear message to the political opposition in Bolivia, but even clearer to the US: foreign meddling in domestic affairs by the US is not
44

After extensive research, Eva Golinger and Jim Bigwood indeed conclude that US government and US semigovernmental bureaus such as USAID, had been spending more than 97 U$ million on decentralization and regional autonomy projects, training for opposition politicians and have been the principal funders of the political opposition to Evo Morales government (Golinger, 2009, pp. 1-6) 45 The US has historically used its weight as the hegemonic power to shape the policy and actions of the OAS even if these were contrary to the interests of the member nations as stated in its Charter. US endorsement of the invasion of the Dominican Republic in 1965 was a clear breach of the promotion of territorial integrity and sovereignty of the member state. The expulsion of Cuba from the OAS in 1962 is another example.

75

tolerated by the Bolivian government nor the other UNASUR member states. When political stability in the region is at risk, these events will be discussed among South-American nations and not on platforms which are dominated by the US, such as the OAS. Or to put it in the words of Bolivian President Evo Morales: Now we dont have to go to the United States for solving conflicts in Latin America, because political leaders who before meddled are extinct (Segura & Bellamy, 2009, p. 3). Another important issue within UNASUR is US military presence in the Andean and Caribbean region. Their presence sits uneasy with the majority of the governments in Latin America, given the dubious track record of military and political intervention of the US in Latin American countries. The US rents Forward Operating Locations (FOLs) in El Salvador, Aruba & Curaao (since 2000) and Ecuador (2000 2009) (SOUTHCOM, 2009).46 Yet US military presence is most visible in Colombia, where the US heavily finances the government to fight left-wing insurgents from the FARC and ELN and to diminish coca and poppy cultivation, the basic ingredients of cocaine and heroin production.47 The non-renewal of the FOL lease in Ecuador by the government of Rafael Correa urged the US government to find an alternative host country. A secret Defense Cooperation Agreement (DCA) was signed with Colombia, which went beyond the mere transfer of the FOLs to Colombian territory.48 This triggered widespread protests from various Latin American governments. These bases have been the subject of controversy from the start for several reasons: first, although SOUTHCOM claims that only drug-trafficking activities are monitored, critics say that the bases are also used to protect the host nation against threats from neighboring countries. Second, the uncertainty over the intentions of US military presence in Latin America is certainly not helped by the rather dubious track record of US (military) interventions in domestic affairs. Third, many Latin-American governments view the FOLs as unnecessary as long as drug consumption in the US itself is not reduced.
46 47

FOLs are existing airports which are used to carry out surveillance missions to detect illicit drug trafficking Colombia has received over 5,5 U$ billion from 1997 2008 (over 70 % of all military aid to Latin America). Half of that sum is spent on training the Colombian military, but the US has also provided military equipment. Furthermore, there are about 800 US soldiers permanently stationed in Colombia and 600 private US Contractors who carry out several functions such as operating radar sites, reconnaissance and intelligence sharing (Livingstone, 2009, pp. 162-163). 48 The DCA consists of giving US military personnel access to 7 Colombian military bases, will facilitate effective bilateral cooperation on security matters in Colombia, including narcotics production and trafficking, terrorism, illicit smuggling of all types, and humanitarian and natural disasters (US Department of State, 2009)

76

Given the deep concerns among many South-American heads of state and an extraordinary meeting of the UNASUR was held to address the issue. A clear division was visible among South American leaders: Chvez, Correa and Morales were the most vociferous critics of US military presence in Colombia, arguing that the bases threaten the sovereignty of Latin American nations. This fear is especially present in the highest echelons of Venezuelan government, given the US-backed coup of 2002, the only moderately less hostile current US government and the virtual surrounding of Venezuelan territory by FOLs. Chvez found himself backed by regional allies Morales and Correa who share similar ideas about US presence in Latin America. However, they were unable to convince the moderate left in Latin America such as Chiles Bachelet en Brazils Lula da Silva. The 12 heads of state concluded a joint declaration which called for the preservation of the continent as a peacezone, mutual respect of the sovereignty of member states and that foreign military presence cannot threaten the sovereignty and integrity of any South-American nation and thus the peace and security of the region (UNASUR, 2009). Chvez and allies have thus far not been able to stop the implementation of the DCA. 3.2.4 ALBA and the Banco del Sur: Alternative models for economic integration For many Latin-American countries, the US is an important trading partner. Since the 1990s, one of the main goals of the US has been the creation of a Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA), spanning from Canada to Argentina. In 1994, at the zenith of neoliberal thought hegemony, an agreement was reached among 36 American states (including Venezuela) to progressively reduce trade and investment barriers, fomenting privatization and reducing state intervention in the economy (Vivas-Eugui, 2003). However, by Hugo Chvez, the FTAA is seen as an imperialist organization which primarily benefits the US and has little economic advantages for the less developed countries. During the 4th Summit of the Americas in Mar del Plata (Argentina), Venezuela and the MERCOSUR member states stated their opposition to the FTAA, effectively burying the neoliberal project (Fischer-Hoffman, 2005). Chvez did not only challenge Washingtons FTAA, but constructed an alternative by creating an alternative economic integration platform, the ALBA. The ALBA has radically different notions of economic integration, prioritizing the reduction of poverty and social exclusion, unequal exchange in international relations and renewed attention for state intervention in the economy and political participation in the integration process. In 2005 Venezuela and 77

Cuba founded the ALBA by means of a bilateral agreement which was later joined by Bolivia (2006), Nicaragua (2007) and Dominica and Honduras (2008) (Lievesley & Ludlam, 2009, p. 6). What is typical for ALBAs approach to economic integration is that it is clearly anti-US, anti-capitalist, not mercantile based and a revolutionary and political tool of member states which prioritizes political criteria over economic interests (Bossi, 2009). This is reflected in the success of the ALBA: although economic merits for members of the organization are doubtful, some political goals have been achieved. First, a start has been made with the normalization of relations with Cuba, promoting the reintegration of Cuba into Latin America: under the ALBA umbrella many projects for Cuba have been developed, such as the restoration of oil refineries on the island, the sale of discounted oil (through PETROCARIBE) and the construction of undersea cables for better telecommunication services on Cuba. Other non-ALBA members have also intensified their trade with Cuba, such as Brazil (now the second most important trade partner for Cuba) (Ludlam, 2009, p. 124). The ALBA member states also coordinate their common position within other international institutions such as the OAS and the UN, functioning as an anti-hegemonic block in these organizations. A recent example of such behavior was Chvez speech at the Copenhagen Climate Summit, where he stated ALBAs position on the follow-up to the Kyoto protocol, saying capitalism was to blame for destroying the ecological balance of the world (Cuban News Agency, 2009). However, confronted with the setback in FTAA negotiations, the US has started to negotiate with countries individually in order to conclude free trade agreements. The strong anti-US, anti-capitalist and non-mercantilist characteristics of ALBA has not proven to be an attractive alternative for other Latin-American countries that have a more moderate attitude towards the US. Some of these countries have entered into negotiations with the US. This hurts Chvez interests in two ways: the US bargaining position versus other Latin America is much stronger when negotiating with individual countries instead of blocks of countries. Furthermore, countries that accept the terms of the bilateral FTA will not support Chvez counter-hegemonic block. To date, three South-American countries have entered in such agreements: Chile in 2004, Peru in 2009 and Colombias FTA is currently pending approval in US Congress. When Colombias FTA will enter into force, the US will have FTA with three out of six biggest economies of South America, measured by GDP (CIA, 2009). The signing of the FTAs prompted Venezuela to leave the Andean Community (a customs unions) of which it 78

had been a member for 33 years. Peru and Colombia had failed to notify other members (which they were obligated to do so). Steve Ellner (2008, pp. 201-211), in this context, places emphasis on the potentially disastrous economic consequences for the Venezuelan economy if Venezuela would have stayed in the Community.49 In the light of the attitude of the Bolivarian government towards economic integration along neoliberal lines such as the FTAA or the CAN, its April 2006 declaration to join MERCOSUR might be somewhat surprising. Because it was exactly the MERCOSUR that had risen in the 1990s to become the most successful example of neoliberal oriented economic integration, lowering tariff barriers and spurring free trade among its members. Yet upon close inspection it seems to make sense. MERCOSUR had been envisioned as a trading block to withstand economic pressure by the US and the EU, South Americas most important trading partners. Operating as a block they would improve their economic and power positions vis-vis economic giants the US and the EU. Although it abided the WTO/GATT free trade regime (which corresponds to US interests according to Venezuela), it used special arrangements which allowed for exceptions to the regime: the regional trading blocs (Bouzas & Soltz, 2000). The MERCOSUR countries were able to block progress in the Doha Development round of the WTO since 2003, the 2005 FTAA agreement and are still negotiating for a better deal on a EU-MERCOSUR free trade agreement (EU Council, 2006). One can imagine that for Venezuela, joining MERCOSUR has some distinct advantages: 1) it could function as a gateway for improving relations with the more moderate governments of Brazil, Argentina, Paraguay and Uruguay for which association within the ALBA is unfeasible because of ideological differences. 2) Being a MERCOSUR member it can enjoy economic advantages of the trading block. 3) It can stall MERCOSUR-EU negotiations or negotiate fairer terms instead of becoming isolated within Latin America. For the existing MERCOSUR members, Venezuelas accession is a mixed blessing: access to cheap oil is very welcome for countries like Paraguay, Uruguay which have no significant oil industry, but also for Argentina en Brazil where although significant oil production capacity exists, it does not keep

49

US products would enter the Community easily and would then be re-imported to Venezuela through Colombia or Peru and flood the Venezuelan market. Yet this argument is not very convincing as Venezuela produces virtually next to nothing and the US already has a steady 26-27 % share in Venezuelan imports (INE, 2010)

79

up with demand.50 Also, Venezuelas internal market is an interesting market for producers Argentina and Brazil, especially since Chvez actively seeks to replace US and Colombian imports. On the other hand, Venezuela could be a Trojan horse blocking any proposal towards further free trade arrangements with the US/EU or within the WTO as Venezuela is ideologically opposed to such treaties. In fact, Chvez has already confirmed that although MERCOSUR started out as an economic project, it should now become a distinctly political project prioritizing social issues (Baribeau, 2005). The left-of-centre governments of Brazil and Argentina acknowledge that the social dimension of FTAs and that of MERCOSUR have been ignored too long, but are willing to sign FTAs when conditions are sufficiently favorable for the member states (Klonsky & Hanson, 2009). These worries are reflected in the tedious ratification process of the Venezuelan adherence: the Argentine and Uruguayan parliaments do not need to ratify international agreements according to their respective constitutions, but the Brazilian and Paraguayan Senate have repeatedly expressed their concern over the possible accession of Venezuela to MERCOSUR.51 Thus, Venezuela still is not a full-fledged member of MERCOSUR. 3.2.5 The role of International Financial Institutions Aside from trade agreements and international organizations designed to foment regional economic integration, several international financial institutions (IFIs) and especially the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank have assisted the restructuring of many Latin-American economies along the lines of the Washington Agenda. Chvez sees these IFIs as agents of imperialist policies by the US and thus represent interests that contrast with those of Venezuela and the region. Under governments of the 4th Republic, Venezuela had contracted significant amounts of foreign debts with various IFIs such as the IMF and the World Bank. Under Prez 2.3 Billion USD was borrowed from the IMF, and under Caldera an additional 350 Million USD was disbursed. Another 3.3 billion USD was owed to the World Bank. In line with Chvez criticism of these IFIs, the Bolivarian government sought to repay all outstanding debts as soon as possible. By 2001 all IMF debts had been repaid and the local IMF branch closed (IMF, 2010).

50 51

According to statistics provided by the US Energy Information Administration (EIA, 2010) In December 2009 the Brazilian Senate ratified the accession of Venezuela, yet the Paraguayan Senate still has not ratified the Protocolo de adhesin de Venezuela al Mercosur (El Universal, 2009).

80

In 2007 the entire World Bank debt was returned five years ahead of schedule. Chvez has even announced (but not acted) to withdraw from all US dominated IFIs such as the IMF and the World Bank (World Bank, 2010) (World Bank, 2009) (Tran, 2007). A striking feature of Chvez foreign policy has been that it not only sought to liberate Venezuela from IFIs, but that it has actively helped and encouraged friendly nations in the region to do the same: Chvez bought Argentine state bonds (approximately worth 5 billion USD) to help repay their IMF debts by 2006. Argentina currently has no outstanding loans with the IMF (IMF, 2010). Chvez efforts however have not been limited to bilateral efforts: one of the initiatives in the context of UNASUR (but formally not yet part of the organization), in which Venezuela has played an important role, is the creation of the Banco del Sur (Bank of the South). This institution is supposed to become a viable alternative to the IMF and the Inter-American Development Bank as a source of loans for the states of South America. Countries that have joined the Bank so far are Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay and Venezuela. Its aim is to raise 7 billion USD on the short term, but the Banks funds should finally amount to 20 billion USD. Venezuela would be the largest contributor, having promised 1.4 Billion USD to the banks funds. The seven billion are much more than Latin-American countries contribute on a yearly base to the Inter-American Development Bank (IDB), and comes close to the ten billion USD available for members of the Andean Development Corporation (CAF), it is still a far cry from the more than 100 billion available for Latin-American states through the IDB, IMF or World Bank funds (Bank Information Center, 2008). Yet the Banco del Sur would be the sole multilateral lender without US presence and capital and when its reserves will augment, it can prove to be a viable alternative for South American nations, reducing the power of the US in the region. 3.2.6 OPEC: Multilateral oil diplomacy Venezuelan policy makers soon realized that domestic government policies aimed at maintaining and increasing state income from the petro-industry were severely limited within the framework of the world oil market. The rise (of production output) by the petrostates of the Middle East had lowered crude oil prices, and competition among oil producing states increasingly favored the oil companies power over the market. This provided an important challenge for the Venezuelan government: for the developmental policies to continue, state income needed to be increased. Venezuela could increase output of the oil 81

industry, but this would eventually drive down prices (because total supply for the oil market would grow). An alternative policy option would be to raise taxes and royalties. However, if the tax regime would strain oil companies too much compared to other petro states, the badly needed investments in the oil industry would not materialize (Randall, 1987, p. 35). In the late 1950s, Prez Alfonso, Minister of Mines and Hydrocarbons during the government of Rmulo Betancourt, saw to address this problem by the creation of an international organization of oil exporting countries. This organization was to limit and proration the supply of oil entering the world market. If a significant percentage of oil supply could be administered by the organization, it would give Venezuela and other oil exporting countries the possibility to influence oil prices (Tugwell, 1975, p. 60). Venezuela lobbied intensively to realize the formation of such an organization. It was the 1960 slump in oil prices that convinced many of the Middle-Eastern countries to join the organization. In September Iraq, Iran, Kuwait, Saudi Arabia and Venezuela founded the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) (Tugwell, 1975, pp. 61-62). The main goals of the organization are: 1) Coordination and unification of petroleum policies of member countries and determination of the best means to safeguard their interests. 2) Ensuring the stabilization of oil prices in the world market to eliminate harmful and unnecessary fluctuations. 3) Securing steady income for the producing countries, providing an efficient, economic and steady supply for oil consuming nations and a fair return on capital to those investing in the petroleum industry (OPEC, 1961). OPECs influence as an oil cartel had dwindled steadily since the early 80s: once responsible for about 80% of world crude oil exports, by the late 90s OPECs share had fallen to about 55% (OPEC, 2008, p. 8). Several reasons can be found for the diminished relevance of OPEC: 1) The increased use of nuclear energy, natural gas and coal had substantially reduced the share of oil in primary energy demand from 60% in 1973 to little over 41% in 1996. 2) Non-OPEC oil supply has risen considerably because of investments in countries such as Norway and the United States. 3) Whereas oil used to be traded on the spot market, now the majority of the transactions are being handled on the futures market providing more certainty and transparency for both buyers and sellers.52 4) The revolution in high-tech oil technology had substantially reduced
52

The Futures Oil market has several advantages over the Spot Oil market: 1) It can be used to identify the persistence of oil-price shocks and to provide an indicator of the rate at which the shock will diminish. 2) The

82

the expense and risk of developing oil production in high-cost areas (Chalabi, 1997-1998, pp. 132-136). Besides these external factors, behavior of OPEC-members themselves constitutes an important internal factor of diminishing relevance of the cartel. In 1982 a production allocation system was implemented, assigning specific production quota for each member state to control the total OPEC-supply to the world market, by means of a production allocation agreement. Whenever prices were either too high or too low, production output would be heightened or lowered. However, OPEC member states have tended to defy production quotas (Kaufmann, Dees, Karadeloglou, & Snchez, 2004). Especially Venezuela under the second Caldera administration had built up a reputation of cheating on quota (Kohl, 2002, p. 214). During the 1980s Venezuela had overproduced about 7% of its quota, being one of the minor offenders within the cartel. At the same time that other notorious quota busters such as the United Arab Emirates (UAE) and Kuwait significantly reduced their overproduction, Venezuela became the second biggest quota buster with 10% overproduction, only being surpassed by Qatar with 14% (Molchanov, 2003, p. 7). The motivations given by Philip for Venezuelan non-compliance under Caldera seems credible in the light of other studies that indicate that there is no evidence that real oil prices affect the degree to which OPEC-Members cheat on the quota (Kaufmann, Dees, Karadeloglou, & Snchez, 2004, p. 82).53 As described extensively in Chapter 2, Hugo Chvez had markedly different plans with the domestic oil industry when compared to his predecessors in office. This policy change was also reflected in Venezuelas foreign oil policy strategy: 1) strengthening of the OPEC and 2) sell crude oil structurally at higher prices. This fits within the overall counter-hegemonic strategy of Venezuela trying to limit and diminish US military and economic power. A stronger OPEC could facilitate higher oil prices. As crude oil is an indispensable commodity for the maintenance of US military and economic power, limiting its availability and raising its prices weakens US power.

difference between the current futures price of oil and the spot price can be interpreted as an indicator of the precautionary demand for oil. 3) oil-futures prices can be used to a certain extent to forecast spot prices (Alquist & Arbatli, 2010). 53 Funds needed for investment (PDVSA) and public spending (Caldera Government)

83

Table 3 OPEC Quota Discipline under Hugo Chvez 1st term (in 1000 barrels /p day)

Quota Production Overproduction

Jul98Mar99 2845 3057 7.5%

Apr99 Mar00 2720 2913 7.1%

Apr00Jun00 2845 3160 11.1%

Jul00 Sep00 2926 3160 7.9%

Oct00 3019 3160 4.6%

Nov00 Jan01 3077 3177 3.2%

Feb01 Mar01 2902 3010 3.7%

Apr01 Aug01 2786 3010 8%

However, the previous section clearly demonstrated that OPECs track record has been mixed at best: not only because of the structural non-compliance with production quota and the dependence on petrodollars, but also because of internal divisions between price-hawks, intermediate and moderate OPEC members in developing the organization and improving compliance.54 For Venezuelas strategy to succeed, it needed to reach consensus within OPEC to realize higher prices. So, in 1999 when oil was trading at very low prices, Chvez seized the opportunity to overcome the internal differences in OPEC and formed a coalition with Iran and Saudi Arabia which led the cartel to withdraw 2.1 million barrels per day from the world oil market, driving prices up. This is reflected in the April 1999 March 2000 Production quota, where Venezuela is assigned 125000 barrels per day less than in the previous production allocation agreement. In 2000 Chvez visited all fellow OPEC member nations to successfully rally support for a new proposal to systematically stabilize oil prices at higher oil levels (Ellner, 2008, pp. 206207). However, table XX clearly shows, in spite of these initiatives, that overproduction continued, if to a lesser extent than before.55 Chvez controversial domestic oil policies, implemented during his second term, resulted in various strikes and negatively influenced production levels, especially in 2003. Also the brain-drain within the petro industry, caused by the firing of 18000 PDVSA employees and the alleged underinvestment by the company in the existing oil infrastructure, meant production would not recover pre-strike levels during Chvez second term in office. However, as oil priced slowly but surely started to climb, the loss in production was offset by

54

Price hawks (Algeria, Nigeria, Indonesia) have small oil reserves and big populations and therefore have an interest in higher prices to address the needs of the population. The moderates (Saudi Arabia, Kuwait and UAE) have enormous oil reserves and (relatively) small populations making these states want to extend the commercial life of oil over a long period of time. Intermediate states (Iran and Venezuela) have both big oil reserves and big populations, making their behavior less predictable (Kohl, 2002, p. 225). 55 The goal of the system was to stabilize the price of crude oil between USD 22 28. When oil prices would stabilize under US22, member states would withdraw 500,000 barrels per day. Whenever prices rose steadily to over U$ 28, an equal amount of barrels would be withdrawn from the oil market.

84

higher oil prices. It also meant that Venezuela could easily respect the OPEC allocation quota, without missing out on state income.

Table 4 OPEC Quota Discipline under Hugo Chvez 2nd term (in 1000 barrels /p day)
Time Quota Production Overproduction Time Quota Production Overproduction Sep01Dec01 2670 3010 12.7% Apr 04 Jun 04 2704 2560 -5.3% Jan02 Dec02 2497 2600 4.1% Jul 04 2934 2560 -12.7% Jan03 2647 2340 -11.5% Aug 04 Oct 04 2992 2560 -14.4% Feb03 May03 2819 2340 -16.7% Nov 04 16 Mar 05 3107 2560 -17.1% Jun03 Oct03 2923 2340 -19.9% 17 Mar 05 Jun 05 3165 2560 -19.1% Nov03 Mar04 2819 2472 -12.3% Jul 05 Oct 06 3223 2559 -21.5%

With PDVSA under control, Chvez had eliminated an important obstacle in pursuing his foreign oil policy. Within OPEC however, Venezuela still faced Saudi Arabia: being the worlds biggest producer it plays a pivotal role within the organization. It shares with Venezuela the interest in wanting to strengthen OPEC, to better control oil prices. Yet it does not aim at too high prices and does not share Venezuelas criticism of US hegemony: this greatly hinders Venezuelas counter-hegemonic strategy. But even with full OPEC support Venezuela is not quite there yet. As OPECs production share has diminished substantially, cooperation with non-OPEC producers is necessary to really influence price levels. Therefore Venezuela has sought closer ties with Russia. Russia is an interesting partner for two reasons: 1) it is the worlds second largest crude oil exporter, providing about 10% of total oil export supply. 2) It shares Venezuelas criticism of the unipolar world system dominated by the US. For Russia, Venezuelas oil reserves provide business opportunities to Russian petroleum enterprises and the Venezuelan arms purchases have proven to be very lucrative for Russia (Katz, 2006). After little successful efforts from 2001 2004 because of improved US-Russia relations, from 2005 onwards Chvez has intensified relations with Russia, and has become its most important arms buyer in 2008. Some authors, like Corrales (2009, pp. 105-106) see this as leverage to get Russia on board of OPEC oil restrictions to influence oil prices. In spite of repeated pledges of Russia to support OPEC and cut production, it has done the exact opposite: after OPEC member states reduced output in 2009, Russia actually augmented its production and took advantage of the available market 85

share (Korosec, 2009). This (at least temporarily) defeated Chvez objectives in strengthening OPEC and pushing prices up. 3.2.7 Eschewing cooperation and promoting sovereignty In the very same year Hugo Chvez assumed office, a natural disaster took place in the coastal area of the state of Vargas. The mudslides, caused by torrential rains, killed an estimated 30,000 persons and destroyed a large part of the infrastructure and buildings in the coastal area. Many countries offered humanitarian aid in the form of goods, services and personnel. The US sent 20 million USD, and ships filled with machinery to rebuild the infrastructure, goods to offer personal help to victims and 450 military engineers. Yet Chvez refused entrance of military personnel (claiming that Venezuelas sovereignty would not permit American military personnel on Venezuelan soil), even when he did accept the financial aid and machinery. The ships had to return to the US. Refusing the aid came as a surprise as according to the US Department of State the Venezuelan Minister of Defense had explicitly solicited military engineers (Naim, 2005, p. 205). It remains unclear whether this situation was the result of internal communication problems within the Chvez government, or whether Chvez refused the aid to score a symbolic point. Although intensive cooperation between Venezuela and the US took place from 2002 2005, since then US-Venezuelan anti-narcotics cooperation has diminished. In 2009, the Government Accountability Office reported to the US Senate that it is deeply concerned about the unwillingness and inability of the Venezuelan government to actively fight drugs trafficking. Of the 9 cooperation operations functioning in 2002, only 2 were still functioning in 2009. From 2004 to 2007, the estimated amount of cocaine being trafficked through Venezuela increased fivefold from 50 metric tons to 250 metric tons per year, that increasing corruption of Venezuelan officials hampered anti-drug operations and that since 2005 the Venezuelan government has structurally failed to meet its counternarcotics obligations (USGAO, 2009, pp. 6,15,20). Although the Venezuelan government has acknowledged a rise in trafficking volume, it does not accept that this is due to its unwillingness to cooperate and refers to anti-drug cooperation agreements with various other nations. Furthermore, it dismisses the reports claims on Venezuelas inability to fight drugs, referring to increased success of drug seizures, demolition of drug laboratories, detained drug traffickers etcetera. The statistics used by the GAO are questioned and politicized (because they were produced 86

under the GW Bush administration) and the Venezuelan report reiterates that cooperation with the DEA was halted in 2005 because several officers had been involved in spying (Venezuela Information Office, 2009, pp. 1-3). Unsatisfied with the lack of cooperation of the Venezuelan government concerning anti-terrorist and narcotics, the US Government decided to implement a Defense arms embargo against Venezuela, which effectively means that the United States will no longer authorize the export of defense articles and defense services to Venezuela (National Archives and Records Administration, 2006). 3.2.8 The Obama administration and Chvez Throughout the previous sections and chapters, US-Venezuelan relations have been described from cordial to outright hostile, especially under the G.W. Bush presidency. When Barack Obama assumed office in 2009, there was hope for better relations among Venezuela and the US. And in discourse Obama has delivered change: the administration has sought a moderate strategy to diminish Chvez influence in the political arena. Secretary of State Hillary Clinton (2009) stated the importance of healthy diplomatic relations with Venezuela:
[W]ere trying to lower the temperature. We want to make it clear that there are ways for us to have a conversation with people we dont agree with on many issues. We dont want to see interference with other countries internal affairs. We want to see a vibrant democracy that reflects the very best that countries have to offer. We would like very much to see leaders being effective in helping to create greater economic opportunity for poor people. But we think there are ways that that can work that are not anti-democratic [..] leaving room for constructive and legitimate criticism.

However, confronting rhetoric with deeds the Obama administration shows a rather poor track record in implementing discourse: The ban on military exports to Venezuela is still in place, the military bases deal with Colombia has deteriorated both US-Venezuelan and Colombian-Venezuelan relations (Radio Netherlands Worldwide, 2010), and the re-activation of the 4th fleet (although technically a decision taken by the Bush administration) has not been canceled (US Navy, 2008). Also, apart from a brief encounter during the Summit of the Americas last year, Obama has yet to invite Chvez for an official meeting to discuss problematic relations between the two nations. This while Chvez has repeatedly said he wanted better relations with Obama and the US (Associated Press, 2009). As this gesture has been consistently ignored by the Obama administration it need not surprise us that there is little to no evidence that Chvez has ceased or diminished soft balancing behavior.

87

4 | Analysis
In this fourth chapter, the findings of the case study are linked to the theories presented in Chapter 1. First an assessment is made to what extent Venezuelan foreign policy has included traditional balancing, and how this behavior corresponds to the realist theory on balancing. Second, a closer look will be taken at Venezuelas soft balancing initiatives to see whether they are more in tune with access to oil rents (or maybe other variables that have been identified in the case study). Third, we evaluate how successful soft balancing initiatives have been thus far, by assessing to what extent Venezuelas foreign policy goals have been achieved.

4.1 Near absence of traditional balancing


The case study demonstrates that Venezuela seemingly has not been involved in structural traditional balancing efforts since 1989: first, no explicit military alliances have been formed by the governments of Carlos Andrs Prez, Rafael Caldera nor Hugo Chvez. Second, according to data provided by the IISS, SIPRI and the World Bank, Venezuelan military expenditure has declined modestly both as percentage of GDP and in real dollar terms since 1991. During the neoliberal era of Andrs Prez and Caldera, military spending hovered around 1.7% of GDP. During the Chvez years, average spending on the military has been around 1.4%. Because of Venezuelas volatile GDP, I also looked at real military spending in constant dollar terms. Expressed in year 2000 USD, military spending from 1991-1998 averaged about 1.9 billion. Since 1999, spending declined to 1.74 billion per year in 2008.

88

Chart 6. Ven. Military Expenditure


Military Expenditure in Y2000 U$ 2,5% 2,0% 1,5% 1,0% 0,5% 0,0% Military Expenditure as % of GDP Billion $ 3,0 $ 2,5 $ 2,0 $ 1,5 $ 1,0 $ 0,5 $ 0,0

Some reservations about the data need to be made however. First, because of limited transparency of the military budget, and extra budgetary spending through the Paraguas Fund and FONDEN, all the Venezuelan governments have probably spent more on the military than official statistics suggest. Yet this is not a typical Venezuelan issue as most states in the region lack the same transparency (IISS, 2010, p. 59). Nevertheless, when comparing Venezuelas official spending under Chvez, expenditure in 2008 was 8.4% higher than in 1999. In 2008 worldwide military spending was up 45% from 1999 . For Venezuela to be on par with the rest of the world, it should have spent an additional 640 million USD in 2008. Given the aforementioned extra budgetary spending and extraordinary oil income in 2006 and 2007 this is quite possible, but based on this data one cannot draw definitive conclusions. The absence of conclusion of military alliances under the governments of Prez and Caldera need not surprise us too much. The realist argument that for a state to balance it actually needs to fear (future) belligerent actions by the hegemon seems to hold for the 1990s. The Venezuelan governments in this era did not fear use of excessive power by the US that would jeopardize Venezuelan interests. The case study demonstrates that the Venezuelan governments thought the very opposite: they sought to maintain their special relation to the USA as a stable and trustworthy oil supplier. Also, the military spending by these governments seemed to be geared more towards appeasement of the military

1991 1992 1993 1994 1996 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

89

(understandable considering the two failed coup dtats of 1992) than investing in military equipment or defense services as balancing behavior. Chvez initial stance towards the US government was one of caution, but not outright antiAmerican. The case study indicates that the posture of the US government towards Chvez became more and more aggressive with each initiative the Venezuelan government took that would (potentially) hurt US interests, especially the nationalization of the oil sector (in which many US companies were active). Also the US backed (the failed) coup of 2002, which radicalized Chvez position towards the US and made the government actively strife for a multipolar world order. Yet realist theory cannot account for the absence of military alliances under Chvez, nor the decline in real military spending under his governments, in spite of growing government income. In the midst of an almost unprecedented oil boom, military spending has remained modest compared to regional and worldwide military expenditure (see section 3.1.2.). It thus seems that neorealist theory cannot account for the absence of balancing behavior.

4.2 Soft balancing


According to the proponents of the soft balancing strategy, such as Pape, this need not surprise us: as much as Venezuela spends on expanding its military or might, the spending gap with the US is simply too big to become a real threat to US military might. As we saw in Chapter 3 and the previous section, Venezuela destines a rather modest percentage of its GDP on military spending compared to the US, and US GDP is about 42 times bigger than that of Venezuela. Concerning external balancing, the formation of military alliances in a unipolar world is very hard considering although each nation individually would be better of cooperating against the hegemon there is high uncertainty about the willingness of other countries to balance. For a single country, like Venezuela, to propose a military alliance against the US would be very risky as it does not know on how much support it can count, and retaliation would be just around the corner. According to Paul, Pape and Hurrell, the soft balancing alternative would be a much more attractive policy for states like Venezuela. And indeed, Chapter 3 clearly demonstrates the various soft balancing initiatives that Venezuelan governments have undertaken: from the

90

foundation of the OPEC oil cartel in the 1960s, defying US foreign policy by reestablishing bonds with Cuba in the 1970s, to eschewing anti-narcotics cooperation with the US in the 1990s and the investment in various anti-hegemonic blocks under the Chvez government. By now it must be clear that Venezuela has been showing soft balancing behavior from the very start of the 4th Republic and has continued to do so till present-day. Yet, the case study has also shown us that different soft balancing strategies have been applied over time, and that the intensity and scale of these initiatives has varied greatly and which will be discussed in the following sections.

4.2.1 OPEC and the Oil Weapon revisited


In the previous section the case study seems to suggest that the Venezuelan government has not been involved in traditional balancing efforts. In Chapter 1 we briefly introduced the notion of the oil weapon, a non military but real threat to consuming countries: by limiting the amount of oil available to consuming countries they have a hard time to maintain their economies and armies (which are highly dependent on oil) and/or pay higher prices for oil. Nonetheless, the weapon could only function when 1) producing countries would cooperate instead of filling in each others market share. 2) oil would not be resold by intermediaries. In the case of Venezuela one would then expect at the very least, cooperation from the OPEC member countries. But apart from the behavior of other OPEC allies, the case study shows clearly that under the Venezuelan governments of the 1990s there was actually little interest in strengthening OPEC. Under the Prez and Caldera governments, 16 production quota agreements were cosigned by the Venezuelan government, yet none was respected: Venezuela progressively became known as a notorious quota buster. From day one of the Chvez administration a different approach to OPEC was chosen: the various efforts by the Bolivarian government to revitalize OPEC are testimony to this strategy. This is not to say that under Chvez OPEC production quota agreements were immediately respected: during Chvez first administration overproduction hovered round 8% (see Chapter 3). Yet it is important to recall that PDVSA and the Venezuelan government were on increasingly friendly terms because of Chvez nationalization policy and tougher fiscal regime. Yet, the domestic policies did seem to work: from 1999 to 2002 onwards production gradually declined yet the oil industries contributions to the state had almost doubled since Chvez assumed office. 91

It is true that Venezuelan oil exports to the US have diminished under the Chvez governments. In 1998 1.7 million barrels a day were destined for the US. By 2008 exports had dropped to 1.1 million bpd. This 35% reduction in oil exports to the US roughly corresponds to the 35% reduction in total oil exports. The US thus remains Venezuelas most important export market. At the same time Venezuelas importance as oil supplier for the US has dwindled: whereas under the government of Rafael Caldera, Venezuela was with 16% one of the most important suppliers of oil, this share has been reduced to 9% and Canada, Mexico and Saudi Arabia have larger shares than Venezuela (EIA, 2010). But in spite of Chvez vociferous attacks on the US government, the Bolivarian government has never voluntarily closed the tap to the US. In the case study the effects of the oil strike were compared with US consumption. Thanks to production increases in other countries (including OPEC members), the US strategic reserve had not even been used. In 2002 the US could do without Venezuelan oil for 450 days (USGAO, 2006, p. 35). Using data from the year 2008, now the US could do without Venezuelan oil for 630 days, greatly reducing its dependence on Venezuelan oil. In the case study we also saw that in spite generally close relations, with Russia which shares Venezuelan anti-hegemonic outlook, Russia decided to increase production and fill in the OPEC market share lost. So given the unwillingness of OPEC member states to consequently cooperate, non-OPEC predatory market share behavior and Venezuelas progressive irrelevance as a supplier to the US, the viability of the oil weapon decreases by the day. In Chapter 1, I modified Haftendorns theory, trying to indicate that relations between oil producing and oil consuming countries might result in mutual dependence: although oil consuming countries are dependent on oil to maintain their economic and military might, regimes in petro states need oil income to stay in power. So even in a (for Venezuelan government notions) perfect world where OPEC and non-OPEC members would support production cuts, the US as an important oil consumer needs to be replaced by other buyers. And given todays technological and logistical challenges China cannot fulfill this role, leaving Venezuela very much dependent on US oil imports. The Chvez government therefore has very little room for maneuver if it seeks to deploy the oil weapon. Successful cooperation with (non) OPEC member states to realize higher prices per 92

barrel seem more viable than cutting delivery oil delivery to the US and thus Venezuelan dependence on US imports persist.

4.2.2 Economic Integration Alternatives


Another clear example of the use of different soft balancing strategies are Venezuelan governments positions on economic integration. The case study demonstrates that during the neoliberal governments of the 1990s, both Carlos Andrs Prez and Rafael Caldera embraced neoliberal notions of economic integration once in office. The most striking example of such a policy was the support of the Caldera government for the construction of the FTAA and the declarations signed during the First Summit of the Americas in Miami (1994) and the Second Summit of the Americas in Santiago de Chile (1998). With Chvez in office since 1999, the Venezuelan position on the FTAA started to change. During the Third Summit of the Americas in Quebec (2001) the Venezuelan delegation had already expressed its explicit reservation of FTAA implementation by 2005 as unfeasible because of domestic developments in Venezuela (read: the reservations of the Chvez government concerning free-trade). By 2005 developments in many other Latin-American countries (which were now governed by critics of free trade agreements) had resulted in a strong anti-FTAA coalition. During the Fourth Summit of the Americas in Mar del Plata (2005) the Venezuelan delegation all but buried the FTAA. Where under Caldera, Venezuela sought (in economic terms) to make sure to gather as much economic rewards within the scheme of the FTAA (but adhering to it nevertheless) it virtually accepted the scheme of the FTAA as such. The Chvez government however has rejected the neoliberal notion of economic cooperation and integration but went even further. By constructing the ALBA and the Banco del Sur it realized completely new platforms to realize alternative forms of economic integration. Or to put it in more abstract forms: while previous governments merely used diplomatic friction to secure a somewhat more favorable outcome within an existing set of outcomes, the Bolivarian government has increasingly sought to soft balance and create new outcomes in foreign policy which (potentially) could be more beneficial than any of the pre-existing outcomes.

93

4.3 The role of domestic institutions and petrodollars


The analysis so far suggests two things: first, traditional balancing against the US is not a viable policy option for Venezuela given the economic and military disparity between the countries and the collective action problems related to constructing a military alliance within a unipolar context. Second, Venezuelan governments have resorted to various soft balancing strategies, differing in both scale and intensity, in order to better their position in the international system since 1958. Yet the application of the oil weapon as a soft balancing strategy is not viable since Venezuelas dependence on US petrodollars, as the United States cannot be replaced as Venezuelas major client. However, there are two important variables that have not been taken into account so far by the soft balancing proponents, which have surfaced during the case study. 1) Venezuelas particular institutional setup provides more than a context, and might influence decision making processes concerning foreign policy as well and, 2) Petrodollars have been used to fund the various soft balancing initiatives. First, as Chapter 2 demonstrated, transformations in the institutional setup of the country have radically changed power positions within the state. Venezuela moved from being a formal democracy, dominated by two political parties and several extra-parliamentary actors such as PDVSA, the Church and the Armed Forces to a democracy with a weak party system, concentrated power in the executive and very limited influence of extra-parliamentary actors. It was not just the 1999 Constitution that changed these power positions, but also the post-2002 coup dtat purges that effectively removed political opponents from both PDVSA and the military. Now my point is not that the Venezuelan institutional configuration can better explain foreign policy initiatives than theories on (soft) balancing. What I am arguing however, is that the institutional configuration under Chvez has greatly diminished the influence of actors which (at least in the past) have not favored policies aimed at limiting US power, such as political parties COPEI and AD, PDVSA management and the military. In the Venezuelan case, foreign policy decision making has become the sole prerogative of the executive power. The weak position that both Prez and Caldera held vis--vis their own parties and the other extraparliamentary actors limited their policy options does not exist anno 2010. Now, as I stated before, Venezuelan governments have been soft balancing. So this argument than would not hold, because according to the logic presented above, under the 94

4th Republic soft balancing would not be tolerated by various political actors. However, if we look carefully at the kind of soft balancing initiatives of the 4 th Republic, and compare those with the soft balancing initiatives of the Bolivarian governments there is a clear difference: where soft balancing under Prez and Caldera was incidental, practical and quite limited (in both scope, scale and resources), soft balancing under Chvez government has become more structural clearly anti-hegemonic in nature and has destined considerable resources for this kind of foreign policy. A very clear example of these differences are the posture towards the OAS. Where Prez sought to better Venezuelas position within the OAS, Chvez has tried to sideline the institution all together and construct alternative platforms for international cooperation without influence of the US. Second, the role of petrodollars. In Chapter 2 and 3 oil income has been mentioned several times as an important factor in political economy of the Venezuelan state. Yet its influence on foreign policy has been less clear. The case study clearly demonstrates that, irrespective of the fact that Venezuelan government has been using soft balancing strategies, there are remarkable differences in type, scale and intensity of these strategies. During the 1990s, soft balancing efferts were quite limited, practical and incidental, this coincided with low oil prices and (relatively) low oil rents. Under the Chvez government soft balancing has increased in scale and intensity and practically dominates foreign policy. Yet oil income has not been high ever since Chvez assumed office. During the first five years in office oil prices were low and oil income was modest at best. It was not until 2005 that the oil bonanza flooded the Venezuelan government with additional income, as I demonstrated in section 2.6.1. And it was not until 2005 that Chvez soft balancing efforts really materialized: PETROCARIBE, ALBA, UNASUR, Banco del Sur, and the Argentine bond bailout all took place after the oil boom took off. It would be tempting to draw the conclusion these more structured soft balancing initiatives were caused by the sudden rise in oil income. Yet I think that such a conclusion cannot be drawn that easily for two major reasons. First, since the early 2000s, the Chvez government policy documents have explicitly mentioned the construction of such anti-hegemonic regimes in its most important policy document Lineas Generales... The strategy of the government had thus already been thought out. However, as construction of these regimes have high initial costs and place a constant burden a states budget, given the weak state of Venezuelas economy during the late 90s early 2000s, such a 95

policy was simply not feasible. The second argument is that in spite of dwindling oil prices since the second half of 2008, the Venezuelan government has continued to invest in these regimes or even launched new institutions. Therefore I think that the oil boom has more than anything, facilitated the switch to more capital intensive, structural soft balancing strategies, rather than caused soft balancing.

4.4 Soft Balancing a success?


Now, the question regarding what causes soft balancing behavior is interesting for both academics and policy makers alike. But once confronted with soft balancing strategies employed by an adversary, the policy maker is interested in whether these policies are actually effective. Given the extensive description of various soft balancing initiatives by the Venezuelan government, a first assessment is in order. Assessing the success of soft balancing initiatives can help policy makers in petro states and oil consuming countries develop a more specific cost-benefit analysis of these strategies. The great variety of strategies hitherto discussed makes it clear that it is hard to assess soft balancing as one single category. Therefore I propose two categories, for analytical purposes.56 The first kind of soft balancing strategies has concrete goals and is applied to achieve success in the short term. The second type of soft balancing strategies has more diffuse goals and is to produce results in the medium to long term. Examples from the first type seem to be very effective on the short term. For example, the 5 billion USD of Argentine debt that Venezuela purchased to enable the Argentine government to leave the US-dominated IMF. This directly liberated Argentina from IFI-imposed economic policy making. The social policy projection strategy of offering developmental aid at very low conditionality can achieve the same effects: it can buy influence from the receiving regimes within the context of international institutions such as the OAS or UN. Yet, its effectiveness on the long term can be questioned and is highly uncertain: a simple change of government in a beneficiary country can mean the immediate loss of support for Venezuelan foreign policy. Or, as the case of the Venezuelan arms spending spree in Russia demonstrated:

56

I dive deeper into this matter in my recommendations for further research in the Conclusion.

96

Russia ignored its promises to Venezuela concerning oil production to take advantage of the market gap created by lower OPEC production quota. Examples of the second kind of soft balancing strategies have the following in common: they offer structural alternatives for the goods, services or platforms that hitherto have been provided by the hegemon. They requisite high initial investment costs, yield little result in the short run, but can develop into stable parallel regimes to those of the hegemon in the long term. Examples from the case study are the Banco del Sur, PETROCARIBE, ALBA etcetera. The problem is that these regimes have been developed only recently which makes a premature assessment rather unfair. Yet, for the sake of the argument I will continue the example of the Argentine debt buy. Although it temporarily cut Argentina loose from the USdominated IFIs such as the IMF and the World Bank, it was all but a permanent solution. Whenever Argentina would run into financial trouble again, it had no choice but to return to these IFIs and accept the heavy conditionality imposed upon economic and monetary policy by these organizations. However, the Banco del Sur initiative was started to offer a South-American alternative for countries in need of short-, medium or long term financing. In spite of the high initial investments by Venezuela and the other member states (which placed a heavy burden on these countries budgets), now South-America has its own IFI which is not based on the neoliberal values of the US, but tuned to the interests and plurality of economic policymaking in the region. If the Bank is able to help out countries in financial distress it will prove to be an attractive alternative for South-America and greatly diminish the influence of the US over economic policy making even in times of economic hardship. Yet, such a stable regime can only be created when countries stay committed to investing in these regimes. This poses an heavy challenge on countries like Venezuela who can invest in times of oil boom, but have a hard time investing when oil prices are low. And even when a regime is function, political changes in one of the member states can prompt them to leave the international regime, as the case of Honduras in PETROCARIBE (section 3.2.2) has demonstrated.

97

Conclusion
In the introductory chapter I reminded the reader of the exploratory character of the thesis. Venezuela has proven to be a compelling case study at the junction of International Relations theory and the Natural Resource Curse. In this section, we first return to the original research question, highlight the usefulness of the Venezuelan case, present the main findings of the thesis and review the theoretical and practical implications these findings have. Then several methodological and theoretical remarks are made to better fit the thesis in the ongoing debates on soft balancing and the Natural Resource Curse. Finally, several suggestions for further research will be made.

Research Question
Puzzled by the lack of explanatory power of neorealist theory of contemporary international relations, the various soft balancing approaches promised an intelligent approach because it seemed to more accurately describe state behavior in the current unipolar world system. However the arguments why and when states balance needed further development, as especially the economic dimension of (soft) balancing had received little attention. There was little clarity about the costs of soft balancing. The debate on the Natural Resource Curse on the other hand, has extensively studied the income for countries with natural resources such (and petro states in particular), but had largely ignored the foreign policy of such countries. While combining the two approaches, the (research) surged: To what extent and how does access to significant oil rents generate incentives for soft balancing behavior?

The Venezuelan case


Given the limited time and means, a single case study seemed the best approach to study the processes at work in the alleged relation between external income from oil extraction and foreign policy. Various reasons favored the choice of Venezuela as the main case study for the thesis: first, because the country is a petro state, highly dependent on oil rents. The thesis seeks to explore whether there is a relation between oil rents and foreign policy behavior. If there is such a relation, they should be most visible in a petro state as their oil

98

rents are higher and more volatile than tax and spend or production states. Second, as the debate on petro state characteristics and its alleged relation to foreign policy is still in its infancy it would be unwise to rule out other explanation for foreign policy outcomes (such as neorealist theory or explanations based on domestic economic and institutional variables). It is within this context that Venezuela as a case becomes very interesting. Venezuelas political economy has undergone many changes over the past twenty years. It has had both neoliberal and socialist-oriented regimes and the country has been governed under various institutional arrangement. Last but not least, as oil prices have fluctuated heavily, oil income has varied significantly during the past two decades. At first glance, variation in the aforementioned variables did not seem to take simultaneously but rather sequentially. This makes the Venezuelan case very useful for controlling for these variables. Last but not least, as Venezuela has been an active international player since its transformation into a democratic state, changes in foreign policy are easier to compare than in states that have never shown much interest in participating in the international system.

Main Findings
In order to answer the research question, two important subquestions had to be answered: first, do petro states (like Venezuela) actually soft balance? The case study clearly showed that Venezuela has indeed applied soft balancing since the inception of democracy in 1958, be it in differing intensity, scope and scale. Second, for oil income to actually be related to foreign policy (and soft balancing in particular) one would expect more soft balancing when oil prices are high and the state has more funds to use for foreign policy. The case demonstrated that soft balancing was modest under Prez and Caldera and pre-oil boom Chvez, and heavily increased in both scale, scope and intensity during and post-oil boom Chvez. Yet, for various reasons I cannot conclude that there is a simple causal relation between the level of oil rents and scale, scope and intensity of soft balancing: first, even though oil prices and income were low during Chvez first few years in office, policy documents laid out plans and guidelines for intense soft balancing, striving for the construction of anti-hegemonic blocks to diminish US power and influence over the rest of the world and Latin America in particular. Second, (and this will more extensively be commented on in the next section) the role of the hegemon within this scheme has been left

99

out of the picture: a state like Venezuela may have huge oil income during a boom period, but does not necessarily use it to soft balance when it does not see the hegemon as a threat (as was the case in the 1960s and 1970s in Venezuela). This very point was made by Andrew Hurrell in Chapter 2 and seems to be confirmed by the case study. Third, during the case study, and especially Chapter 2, the relevance of transformations in power positions within Venezuelas political system seems to have made foreign policy options available for the government that hitherto had not been available. Removing various actors with quasi veto points in the foreign policy decision making process, a more aggressive soft balancing approach was a viable policy option for the Chvez government, while it would have been unthinkable for Paz and Prez. Not so much because of their relatively pro-US stance, but because of the weak position of the President within the Venezuelan political system in the 4th Republic. So, to answer the question as to how and to what extent oil rents have given incentives for soft balancing behavior by the Venezuelan petro state, it seems that oil rents have merely facilitated the application of intensive soft balancing. The costs associated with this form of soft balancing could be paid for by the rents proceeding from the post 2004 oil-boom. However, the use of oil rents for this cause seems to have been possible thanks to a specific domestic institutional structure in which traditional actors that were against soft balancing were cut out of the decision making process.

Theoretical implications
Although the reason(s) why states soft balance (apart from the alleged economic incentive in the form of oil rents) was not an explicit part of the subject of this thesis, the topic has been touched upon in the theoretical framework, and surfaced as well in the case study. The idea that aggressive unilateral behavior is a sine qua non for soft balancing behavior as such, as most of the soft balancing proponents argue, cannot simply be confirmed by the case study. Venezuela has been soft balancing when facing a unipolar world power governed by either more moderate or hostile regimes. However, there seems to be a difference in the type of soft balancing initiatives employed by Venezuela during the 1990s and the first Chvez government on the one hand, and post-coup Chvez governments on the other hand. The soft balancing initiatives during the 1990s were limited to ad-hoc initiatives and usually did 100

not involve large sums of money. As stated in the analysis: they seem to have been geared towards blocking very specific US foreign policy goals. Since the US developed a more aggressive, unilateral foreign policy, the Chvez government has increasingly been involved in soft balancing. Since the 2004 oil boom the kind of soft balancing initiatives have become less ad-hoc, more institutionalized an more expensive. This, as I explained eralier, to work towards the construction of (regional) economic and political anti-hegemonic blocks. In assessing how aggressive or unilateral the foreign policy of the hegemon actually is, the worldview dimension to soft balancing behavior as introduced by Andrew Hurrell helps us out: the governments of Prez and Caldera actively sought to maintain the special USVenezuelan relation which they deemed symbiotic: Venezuela as a stable oil provider for the US, and Venezuela as an important democratic partner in the region. Chvez however has typified the relation as one of mutual caution (during the first years in office) and since 2002 one of opposed interests. Within such a context, what constitutes aggressive unilateral foreign policy can be assessed differently depending on the view Hurrell discussed. Nonetheless, the 2002 coup against Chvez which was backed by the US government at the time radically altered Chvez vision on US-Venezuelan relations.

Implications for policymakers


Having assessed the finding of the thesis for theory building, it now is time to shift to policy making. What foreign policy lessons can be drawn from the Venezuelan case by policymakers of the hegemon and policymakers of petro states? The case study seems to confirm the difficult position petro state policy makers face: the very same oil that underpins the survival of the regime also facilitates the maintenance of military and economic supremacy of the unipolar power. Even more so when the petro states most important (and irreplaceable) client is the unipolar power itself, as is the case in Venezuela. This is not to say that policy makers have no options at all. The oil rents can be used to try to diminish the power of the hegemon or greater the influence of the petro state itself. The case seems to demonstrate that choosing these strategies carefully is of utmost importance. In spite of the several billion USD that have been invest by the Chvez regime, 101

Venezuelas military budget pales in comparison to that of the US. By no means has Venezuela been able to better its power-position vis--vis the US. There is little reason to believe other petro states might be able to close the gap (except for development of military nuclear capabilities). Now, the soft balancing strategies that the Venezuelan government has applied over time have produced mixed results and should be a warning to policy makers in other petro states that soft balancing in itself does not guarantee success. Ad-hoc cooperation, offering low-conditional developmental aid and negating access to territories can work on the short term might block concrete foreign policy initiatives by the hegemon. However, the case has not shown convincing evidence that these strategies will facilitate the formation of sustainable anti-hegemonic regimes which are to realize a multipolar world order. In all fairness, this need not surprise us as the majority of these initiatives are relatively recent and only time can tell whether these strategies work out. However, continuous cooperation and funding is necessary to construct these regimes and this is very hard for policy makers in petro states as the policy continuity is threatened by the high volatility of oil income. Given the unpopularity of foreign policy among voters, at least in oil democracies such as Venezuela, this is a challenging task. As access to affordable oil is one of the most important conditions for a unipolar world power to maintain its influence over world affairs, for policy makers it is of the utmost importance to secure this access. Now within a context of oil dependency (besides looking for oil alternatives), oil-consuming country policy makers should ask themselves what the most effective and efficient means to this end are: do they lie in an aggressive foreign policy, not shunning violence to secure access to these resources? Or is a more moderate approach, which gives petro states more room for policy maneuvers that might be against US interests, a more sensible approach? Several proponents of the soft balancing theory had already warned that an aggressive foreign policy seems counterproductive for the maintenance of hegemony in the long term: first, because of the aforementioned mutual dependency on oil, there is little need to secure access to oil through aggressive means. These petro states need to sell oil for their own survival in the international system. Second, this aggressive foreign policy will even if this persuades oil producing nations to sell oil give incentives for (soft) balancing behavior

102

which is ultimately funded by the unipolar power itself. Third, it takes a long time for a state to change its reputation on the international arena when switching back to a more relaxed foreign policy. In the case we have seen all three factors at work: in spite of US hostility towards the Chvez regime, the US continued to be Venezuelas most important client. Second, as the US aggressive policy coincided with radicalization of Chvez (foreign) policy, the very same dollars used to pay for the oil, started being spent on anti-hegemonic initiatives such as the Banco del Sur and PETROCARIBE, diminishing US influence in the region. Finally, in spite of the Obama administrations more moderate tone and seemingly less aggressive foreign policy, the Venezuelan government has been weary of US intentions and will not likely abandon its counter-hegemonic strategies anytime soon. A more moderate, multilateral strategy can reassure petro states like Venezuela that they are not about to fall prey to the empire. This will probably limit their balancing initiatives to acceptable levels (for the hegemon) and lessen the costs of foreign policy whenever the unipolar power feels it needs to act. The other side of the coin is that policy makers will perhaps have to accept less favorable terms when it comes to acquiring oil.

Methodological and theoretical remarks


Despite the merits of the thesis in further exploring the alleged relation between an overdependence on oil income and foreign policy and giving a detailed account of Venezuelan foreign and oil policy of the past twenty years, the thesis has several shortcomings which may have a detrimental effect on both the validity and reliability of the analysis, findings and conclusions. First, because only one single case study has been undertaken it is hard to generalize the findings of the thesis. Since there is no comparison made with other petro states, on the basis of this thesis alone we cannot draw conclusions about the behavior of all petro states or claim that all petro states behave like Venezuela does. Just to name one example: Venezuela is highly dependent on oil exports to the US, while other petro states have a more diversified clientele. So Venezuela is not only dependent on oil rents for its survival, but more specially dependent on the hegemon for its oil income which arguably alters the power relation Venezuela and the US have. Second, the thesis does not offer extensive theory testing. Instead, it compares various perspectives on state behavior in the 103

international system. An attractive method because it can highlight the explanatory power of one theory versus another. However, because the soft balancing argument and theories on the international dimension of the natural resource are still in its infancy, it creates challenges in actually testing the respective theories as its core concept and variables are under debate. In the next section I will pay more attention to this problem as a suggestion for further research. A third problem is the reliability and validity of the data. Official government and private sector data about the same subject often differ greatly in both defining certain concepts (what do they actually measure) and even when they agree in concepts, the actual figures are vastly different. Both the government and private sector actors have an interest in juking the stats.57 Even the data offered by international organizations offer no avail as they often simply use the data provided by governments. And then there is the problem of discontinued time series: one of the most comprehensive and reliable collection of statistics on the Venezuelan (oil) economy, PODE, was discontinued as of 2007. The use of actual data therefore is quite limited in the thesis and no rock-hard conclusions have been based upon this data. Also, it would have been helpful if several interviews with present and former Venezuelan (oil) policy makers could have been conducted. In the first place to verify statements in the literature and second to see what motives policy makers actually had in choosing certain foreign policy options instead of attributing them motives that have been deducted from reality. Lastly, as the thesis progressed it became rather clear that foreign policy options available to the Chvez government hinted that internal decision making procedures can influence the range of policy options a government has which has only been briefly mentioned in the theoretical chapter. Therefore it might appear to be an afterthought, while it is no such thing in any matter, but highly relevant as I explained in the previous chapter.

Suggestions for further research


When discussing the thesis design, I mentioned its explorative character. I see the findings presented after the case study and discussed the challenges that surfaced during the process of writing the thesis as valuable incentives for further research. Given the findings of the
57

Better statistics can be used as propaganda to make the current regime more popular to secure maintenance of power, while the political opposition can deliberately spread misinformation to vilify the government to improve their chances for a (extra-) political victory.

104

thesis I propose a two-track approach to better understand and predict behavior by petro states in the international anarchic system. First, more qualitative research needs to be done on what soft balancing actually entails. I think the umbrella term does not adequately cover the theoretical differences that exist between ad-hoc cooperation to block certain concrete foreign policy initiatives by a hegemon and the construction of non-military anti-hegemonic regimes. A clarification on soft balancing does not only have academic merit. Also for policy makers the differences in time span, costs, risks and rewards involved in the various soft balancing efforts warrant further attention to guide policy makers in both petro states and the hegemon. Second, having a better idea of what soft balancing actually is, one can better compare behavior of petro states vis--vis the hegemon over time in comparative perspective, enabling academics to draw more general conclusions about the relation between oil rents, soft balancing behavior and petro state hegemon relations. This way, researchers can control for outlier cases - an ever present risk when single case studies are undertaken. This seems especially relevant as during the process of writing this theses the institutional configuration seems to have changed the relative influence of various actors in foreign (oil) policy formulation, thus changing the range of policy options available to the executive in the Venezuelan case.

105

Cited Works
1st Summit of the Americas. (1994, December 11). Declaration of Principles. Retrieved from FTAA - ALCA. Adelman, M. A. (1995). The Genie out of the Bottle: World Oil Since 1970. Cambridge: MIT Press. Alconada Mon, H. (2008, January 12). Antonini estuvo en la Casa de Gobierno. La Nacin . Alquist, R., & Arbatli, E. (2010, Spring). Crude Oil Futures: A Crystal Ball? Retrieved July 22, 2010, from Bank of Canada: http://www.bankofcanada.ca/en/review/spring10/alquist.pdf Associated Press. (2009, April 18). Chavez to Obama: I want to be your friend. Retrieved July 24, 2010, from MSNBC: http://www.msnbc.msn.com/id/30271562/ Associated Press. (2010, March 4). Clinton Urges Recognition of Honduras Government. Retrieved June 15, 2010, from ABCNews: http://abcnews.go.com/International/wirestory?id=10012222&page=1 Auty, R. (2001). Introduction and Overview. In R. Auty, Resource Abudance and Economic Development (pp. 3-16). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Aveledo, R. G. (2007). La 4ta Repblica: La Virtud y El Pecado. Caracas: Libros Marcados. Banco Mercantil. (2009). The Economy in Figures: Venezuela 2008. Caracas: Banco Mercantil. Bank Information Center. (2008). Bank of the South: Lending Policies. Retrieved May 1, 2010, from Bank Information Center: http://www.bicusa.org/en/Institution.Lending.21.aspx Baribeau, S. (2005, December 9). Venezuela to Enter MERCOSUR as Full Member. Retrieved January 20, 2010, from VenezuelAnalysis.com: http://www.venezuelanalysis.com/news/1521 Barrett, P., Chvez, D., & Rodrguez-Garavito, C. (2008). The New Latin American Left: Utopia Reborn. London: Pluto Press. Beblawi, H. (1987). The Rentier State in the Arab World. In H. Beblawi, & G. Luciani, The Rentier State (pp. 49-62). London: Croom Helm. Beblawi, H. (1987). The Rentier State in the Arab World. In H. Beblawi, & L. Giacomo, The Rentier State (pp. 49-62). London: Croom Helm. Blair, B., Yali, C., & Hagt, E. (2006). The Oil Weapon: Myth of Chinas Vulnerability. China Security , 32-63.

106

Bloomfield, R. J. (1994). Making the Western Hemisphere Safe for Democracy? The OAS Defense-of-Democracy Regime. The Washington Quarterly (17 (2)), 157-169. Bossi, F. (2009, April 29). 10 Points to understand the ALBA. Retrieved May 3, 2010, from Portal ALBA: http://www.alternativabolivariana.org/modules.php?name=Content&pa=showpage&pid=19 80 Bouzas, R., & Soltz, H. (2000). Institutions and Regional Integration: The Case of Mercosur. London: Brookings Institution. Brooks, S. G., & Wohlfort, W. C. (2005). Hard Times for Soft Balancing. International Security (30 (1)), 72-108. Buxton, J. (2009). Venezuela: the political evolution of Bolivarianism. In G. Lievesley, & S. Ludlam, Reclaiming Latin America: Experiments in Radical Social Democracy (pp. 57-74). London: Zed Books. CAF. (n.d.). CAF. Retrieved May 2, 2010, from Estructura de Capital: http://www.caf.com/view/index.asp?pageMS=34161&ms=17 Catholic New Times. (2004, June 6). Venezuela fires the "School of the Americas". Retrieved June 21, 2010, from BNET: http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m0MKY/is_10_28/ai_n13467190/ CGD Task Force. (2009). Helping Reforms Deliver Growth in Latin America: A Framework for Analysis. In L. Rojas-Suarez (ed), Growing Pains in Latin America: An Economc Growth Framework as Applied to Brazil, Colombia, Costa Rica, Mexico and Peru (pp. 38-67). Washington: Brookings Institution Press. Chalabi, F. J. (1997-1998). OPEC: An Obituary. Foreign Policy , pp. 126-140. Chvez, H. R. (2010, June). BBC Hard Talk. (S. Sackur, Interviewer) CIA. (2009). Country Comparison GDP (Purchasing Power Parity). Retrieved May 3, 2010, from CIA Factbook: https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-worldfactbook/rankorder/2001rank.html Clinton, H. (2009, July 7). Secretary of State. (L. Castillo, Interviewer) CNE. (2004). Boletn Electoral Referendum 15 de Agosto de 2004. Caracas: Consejo Electoral Nacional. CNE. (2006). Eleccin Presidencial - 3 de Diciembre de 2006. Caracas: Consejo Nacional Electoral.

107

CNE. (2000). Elecciones 30 de Julio de 2000 - Presidente de la Nacin. Caracas: Consejo Nacional Electoral. CNE. (2000). Elecciones 30 de Julio de 2000 Votos Diputados Listas a la Asamblea Nacional. Caracas: Consejo Nacional Electoral. CNE. (1998). Elecciones 6 de Diciembre 1998. Caracas: Consejo Nacional Electoral. CNE. (1999). Referendo Aprobatorio Constitucin Nacional Diciembre 1999. Caracas: Consejo Nacional Electoral. Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2000). Greed and Grievance in Civil War. Washington D.C.: World Bank. Constitucin de la Repblica Bolivariana de Venezuela. (1999). Corrales, J. (Forthcoming). Foreign Policy of Venezuela. Corrales, J. (2003). Market Reforms. In J. I. Domnguez, & S. Michael, Constructing democratic governance in Latin America (pp. 74-100). Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press. Corrales, J. (2009). Using Social Power to Balance Soft Power: Venezuela's Foreign Policy. The Washington Quarterly , 32 (4), 97-114. Crow, J. A. (1980). Epic of Latin America. Berkely: University of California Press. Cuban News Agency. (2009, December 17). ALBAs Voice Heard in Summit on Climate Change in Copenhagen. Retrieved June 23, 2010, from Cuban News Agency: http://www.cubanews.ain.cu/2009/1217copenhagen.htm Doyle, M., & Sambanis, N. (2000). International Peacebuilding: A theoretical and Quantative Analysis. American Political Science Review (94(4)), 779-801. Dunne, T., & Schmidt, B. C. (2008). Realism. In J. Baylis, S. Smith, & P. Owens, The Globalization of World Politics: An Introduction to International Relations (4th edition ed., pp. 90-106). New York: Oxford University Press. Economides, M. J., Martnez, A., & Puky, S. (2007, January 17). The History of PDVSA and Venezuela. Energy Tribune . EFE. (2009, July 8). Venezuela Corta el suministro de petrleo a Honduras. ABC . EIA. (2010, April 1). Argentina Energy Profile. Retrieved May 18, 2010, from US Energy Information Administration: http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/country/country_energy_data.cfm?fips=AR

108

EIA. (2010, February 1). Country Analasys Briefs - Venezuela. Retrieved June 26, 2010, from US Energy Information Administration: http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/cabs/Venezuela/Oil.html EIA. (2009). World Crude Oil Production 1960 - 2008. Retrieved June 1, 2010, from Energy Information Agency: http://www.eia.doe.gov/aer/txt/ptb1105.html El Universal. (2009, December 16). Paraguay mantendr negativa para ingreso de Venezuela al Mercosur. El Universal . Ellner, S. (1996). Political Party Factionalism and Democracy in Venezuela. Latin American Perspectives (23 (3)), 87-109. Ellner, S. (2008). Rethinking Venezuelan Politics: Class, Conflict, and the Chvez Phenomenon. Boulder: Lynne Rienner. Embassy of the Bolivarian Republic of Venezuela. (2008). Fact Sheet Venezuela's Military Spending. Ministerio del Poder Popular para Relaciones Exteriores. EU Council. (2006). EU-MERCOSUR Ministerial Meeting Joint Communiqu. Vienna. Faria, H. J. (2008). Hugo Chvez against the Backdrop of Venezuelan Economic and Political History. The Independent (12 (4)), 519-535. Fischer-Hoffman, C. (2005, November 11). Fighting the FTAA and Bush in Argentina. Retrieved June 16, 2010, from VenezuelAnalysis: http://venezuelanalysis.com/analysis/1461 Friedman-Rudovsky, J. (2008, September 11). Bolivia to Expel US Ambassador. TIME Magazine . Gaceta Oficial N. 370076. (2000, November 13). Ley que autoriza al Presidente de la Repblica para dictar Decretos con Fuerza de Ley en las materias que se delegan. Gaceta Oficial de la Repblica Bolivariana de Venezuela . Caracas, Venezuela. Gaceta Oficial N. 37323. (2001, November 13). Gaceta Oficial de La Repblica Bolivariana de Venezuela. N. 37323 . Caracas, Venezuela. Gaceta Oficial N. 38081. (2004, December 7). Gaceta Oficial de la Repblica Bolivariana de Venezuela. Ley Aprobatoria del Protcolo de Kyoto de la Convencin Marco de las Naciones Unidas sobre el Cambio Climtico . Caracas, Venezuela. Gaceta Oficial N. 38443. (2006, May 24). Gaceta Oficial de la Repblica Bolivariana de Venezuela . Caracas, Venezuela. Gaceta Oficial N. 38910. (2008, April 15). Gaceta Oficial de la Repblica Bolivariana de Venezuela . Caracas, Venezuela.

109

Gaceta Oficial N. 39173. (2009, May 7). Gaceta Oficial de la Repblica Bolivariana de Venezuela. N. 39173 . Caracas, Venezuela. Gobierno Bolivariano de Venezuela. (2007). Lneas Generales del Plan de Desarollo Econmico y Social de la Nacin (2007-2013). Caracas: Ministerio del Poder Popular para la Comunicacin y la Informacin. Golinger, E. (2009, May 18). USAID's Silent Invasion in Bolivia. Retrieved May 11, 2010, from Upside Down World: http://upsidedownworld.org/main/bolivia-archives-31/1865-usaidssilent-invasion-in-bolivia?format=pdf Haftendorn, H. (2000). Water and International Conflict. Third World Quarterly (21(1)), 5168. He, K., & Feng, H. (2006). If Not Soft Balancing, Then What? Reconsidering Soft Balancing and U.S. Policy towards China. American Political Science Association Meeting, (pp. 1-38). Philadelphia. Hill, C. (2003). The Changing Politics of Foreign Policy. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Hurrell, A. (2006). Hegemony, liberalism and global order: what space for would-be great powers? International Affairs (82 (1)), 1-19. IISS. (2010). The Military Balance 2010. London: The International Institute for Strategic Studies. IMF. (2010, May 31). Argentina: Transactions with the Fund from May 01, 1984 to May 31, 2010. Retrieved June 18, 2010, from IMF: http://www.imf.org/external/np/fin/tad/extrans1.aspx?memberKey1=30&endDate=201005-31 IMF. (2003). External Debt Statistics: Guide for Compilers and Users. Washington D.C.: IMF. IMF. (2010, May 31). Venezuela: Transactions with the Fund from May 01, 1984 to May 31, 2010. Retrieved June 18, 2010, from IMF: http://www.imf.org/external/np/fin/tad/extrans1.aspx?memberKey1=1050&endDate=2010 -06-18&finposition_flag=YES INE. (2010). Cuadro Comercio Exterior. Retrieved May 18, 2010, from Instituto Nacional de Estadstica: http://www.ine.gov.ve/comercio/CuadroComercioImport.asp?Codigo=Importacion_Paises Institutio Nacional de Estadstica. (2010). Resumen de ndicadores Sociales: 1998 - Enero 2010. Caracas: Ministerio del Poder Popular de Planificacin y Finanzas.

110

Ishmael, O. (2005, July 26). The PetroCaribe Agreement: it's more about financing rather than cheap oil. . Guyana Journal . Jacks, D. S., Fraser, S., O'Rourke, K. H., & Williamson, J. G. (2009). Commodity Price Volatility and World Market Integration since 1700 (February 2009 Draft). 1-36. James, I. (2010, June 7). Cuba trains Venezuela in military, communications. Washington Times . Karl, T. L. (1997). The Paradox of Plenty: Oil booms and petro-states. Berkeley: University of California Press. Karl, T. L. (1999). The Perils of the Petro-State: Reflections on the Paradox of Plenty. Journal of International Affairs (53 (1)), 31-48. Katz, M. N. (2006). The Putin-Chvez Partnership. Problems of Post-Communism , 53 (4), 3-9. Kaufmann, R. K., Dees, S., Karadeloglou, P., & Snchez, M. (2004). Does OPEC Matter? An Econometric Analysis of Oil Prices. The Energy Journal (25 (4)), 67-90. Kelly, J., & Romero, C. A. (2002). The United States and Venezuela: Rethinking a Relationship. New York: Routledge. Kelly, J., & Romero, C. A. (2005). Venezuela y Estados Unidos. Coincidencias y Conflictos. Caracas: Instituto de Estudios Superiores de Administracin. King, A. (2010, July 9). Warming Up the Bronx: Citgo Venezuela Heating & Social Development Program. Retrieved July 22, 2010, from VenezuelAnalysis: http://venezuelanalysis.com/analysis/5484 Klare, M. T. (2001). Resource Wars: The New Landscape of Global Conflict. New York: Henry Holt & Company. Klonsky, J., & Hanson, S. (2009, August 20). Mercosur: South America's Fractious Trade Bloc. Retrieved January 21, 2010, from Council on Foreign Relations: http://www.cfr.org/publication/12762/mercosur.html Kohl, W. (2002). OPEC behavior, 19982001. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance (42), 209-233. Korosec, K. (2009, September 8). Russia Exploits OPEC Cuts, Tops Saudi Arabia in Oil Exports. Retrieved May 17, 2010, from BNET: http://industry.bnet.com/energy/10001997/russiaexploits-opec-cuts-tops-saudi-arabia-in-oil-exports/ Levitsky, S. (2001). Organization and Labor-Based Party Adaptation: The Transformation of Argentine Peronism in Comparative Perspective. World Politics (54 (1)), 27-56.

111

Licklider. (1988). The Power of Oil: The Arab Oil Weapon and the Netherlands, the United Kingdom, Canada, Japan and the United States. International Studies Quarterly (32 (2)), 205226. Lieber, K. A., & Alexander, G. (2005). Waiting for Balancing: Why the world is not pushing Back. International Security (30 (1)), 109-139. Lievesley, G., & Ludlam, S. (2009). Introduction: a pink tide? In G. Lievesley, & S. Ludlam, Reclaiming Latin America: Experiments in Radical Social Democracy (pp. 1-20). London: Zed Books. Livingstone, G. (2009). America's Backyard: The US and Latin America from the Monroe Doctrine to the War on Terror. London: Zed Books. Lombardi, J. V. (1982). Venezuela: The Search for Order, the Dream of Progress. New York: Oxford University Press. Luciani, G. (1987). Allocation vs. Production States: A Theoretical Framework. In G. Luciani, & H. Bablawi, The Rentier State (pp. 63-82). Ludlam, S. (2009). Cuban Socialism: recovery and change. In G. Lievesley, & S. Ludlam, Reclaiming Latin America: Experiments in Radical Social Democracy (pp. 123-139). London: Zed Books. Lupia, A., & McCubbins, M. D. (1998). Political Credibility and Economic Reform: A Report for the World Bank. Mahdavy, H. (1970). The Pattern and Problems of Economic Development in Rentier States: The Case of Iran. In M. A. Cook, Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ministerio de Finanzas. (2005, October 7). Radio Nacional de Venezuela. Retrieved June 26, 2010, from Ministerio del Poder Popular para la Comunicacin y la Informacin: http://www.rnv.gov.ve/noticias/?act=ST&f=4&t=24524 Ministerio del Poder Popular para La Comunicacin y la Informacin. (2007). Lneas Generales del Plan de Desarollo Econmico y Social de la Nacin 2007-2013. Caracas: Gobierno de la Repblica Bolivariana de Venezuela. Ministerio del Poder Popular para la Comunicacin y la Informacin. (2006, January 1). Plan Siembra Petrolera: Visin de Petrleo y Gas hasta el 2030. Retrieved April 16, 2010, from Gobierno Bolivariano de Venezuela: Ministerio del Poder Popular para la Comunicacin y la Informacin: http://www.minci.gob.ve/noticias/1/4057/plan_%E2%80%9Csiembra_petrolera%E2%80%9 Dvision.html 112

Molchanov, P. (2003, April). A statistical analysis of OPEC quota violations. Durham, North Carolina, United States. Mommer, B. (1996). Integrating the Oil: A Structural Analysis of Petroleum in the Venezuelan Economy. Latin American Perspectives , 132-158. Monaldi, F., & Penfold, M. (2006). The Rise and Decline of Democractic Governance in Venezuela. In R. Hausmann, & R. F, Venezuela: Anatomy of a Collapse (pp. 1-32). Forthcoming. Naim, M. (2005). Eplogo: La internacionalizacin de Hugo Chvez. In J. Kelly, & C. A. Romero, Venezuela y Estados Unidos: Coincidencias y Conflictos (pp. 200-212). Caracas: Instituto de Estudios Superiores de Administracin. National Archives and Records Administration. (2006). Bureau of Political-Military Affairs: Revocation of Defense Export Licenses to Venezuela. Federal Register (71 (159)), 47554. Non-Aligned Movement. (2010, June 11). Key Objectives of the Non-Aligned Movement. Retrieved July 15, 2010, from Non Aligned: http://www.nonaligned.org/2010/06/11/keyobjectives-of-the-non-aligned-movement/ Novoa Monreal, E. (1979). La Nacionalizacin del Petrleo en Venezuela: Sus aspectos Jurdicos. Mxico, D.F.: Universidad Nacional Autnoma de Mxico. Nueva Mayoria. (2008). Adelanto del Balance Militar de Amrica del Sur 2008. Buenos Aires: Nueva Mayoria. OAS. (2010). Who We Are. Retrieved May 31, 2010, from Organization of American States: http://www.oas.org/en/about/who_we_are.asp Obiko Pearson, N., & James, I. (2007, August 28). Venezuela Offers Billions to Countries in Latin America. Retrieved May 18, 2010, from VenezuelAnalysis.com: http://venezuelanalysis.com/news/2571 OPEC. (2008). Annual Statistics Bulletin. Vienna: Organisation of Oil Exporting Countries. OPEC. (1961, January). OPEC Statute. Retrieved May 14, 2010, from Organization of Petroleum Exporting Coutnries: http://www.opec.org/opec_web/static_files_project/media/downloads/publications/OS.pdf Panizza, F. (2009). Contemporary Latin America: Development and Democracy beyond the Washington Consensus. London: Zed Books. Pape, R. A. (2005). Soft Balancing against the United States. International Security , 7-45. Paul, T. V. (2005). Soft Balancing in the Age of US Primacy. International Security , 46-71.

113

Paust, J. J., & Blaustein, A. P. (1974). The Arab Oil Weapon - A Threat to International Peace. The American Journal of International Law (68 (3)), 410-439. PDVSA. (2006). La Apertura Petrolera: Reprivatizacin del negocio. Retrieved April 18, 2010, from PDVSA.com: http://www.pdvsa.com/index.php?tpl=interface.sp/design/readmenuhist.tpl.html&newsid_ obj_id=111&newsid_temas=13 PDVSA. (2005). Oil Concessions: Sovereignty Concessions. Retrieved April 12, 2010, from Petrloes de Venezuela, SA: http://www.pdvsa.com/index.php?tpl=interface.en/design/readmenuhist.tpl.html&newsid_ obj_id=1942&newsid_temas=13 Prez, C. A. (1990). OAS Opportunities. Foreign Policy , pp. 52-55. Peters, S. (2005). Coercive Western Energy Security Strategies: Resource Wars as a New Threat to Global Security. In P. Le Billon, Resource Wars: Resource Dependence, Governance and Violence (pp. 187-213). London: Frank Cass. PETROCARIBE. (2005). Acuerdo de Cooperacin Energtica PETROCARIBE. Puerto La Cruz: Petrocaribe. PETROCARIBE. (2005). Estatutos PETROCARIBE. Caracas. Philip, G. (1999). When Oil Prices were Low: Petroleos de Venezuela and Economic Policymaking in Venezuela since 1989. Bulletin of Latin American Research (18 (3)), 361-375. Philips, T. (2008, September 30). The Bolivian Crisis, the OAS and UNASUR. Retrieved May 11, 2010, from Americas Program: http://americas.irc-online.org/am/5567 Quixote Center. (2007, August 27). Venezuela provides 4 times the assistance of the US in Latin America. Retrieved 07 15, 2010, from Quixote Center: http://quixote.org/venezuelaprovides-4-times-assistance-us-latin-america Radio Netherlands Worldwide. (2010, July 31). Colombia denies war launch as Chvez dispatches troops. Retrieved July 31, 2010, from Radio Netherlands Worldwide: http://www.rnw.nl/africa/bulletin/venezuela-sends-troops-colombian-border-chavez Randall, L. (1987). The Political Economy of Venezuelan Oil. New York: Praeger. Rodrguez, F. (2008, March/April). An Empty Revolution. Foreign Affairs . Ross, M. (2004). How Do Natural Resources Influence Civil War? Evidence from 13 Cases. International Organisation (58(1)), 35-68. Ross, M. (2003). How does Mineral Wealth affect the Poor. Unpublished Paper , 1-34.

114

Rosser, A. (2006). Working Paper 268: The Political Economy of the Resource Curse: A Literature Survey. Brighton: Institute of Development Studies. Sachs, J. D., & Warner, A. M. (2001). The Curse of Natural Resources. European Economic Review (45 (4-6)), 827-838. Snchez, A. (2009, May 13). Separating Fact from Fiction: An Analysis of Venezuelas Military Power. Retrieved May 1, 2010, from Council of Hemispheric Affairs: http://www.coha.org/separating-fact-from-fiction-an-analysis-of-venezuela%E2%80%99smilitary-power/ Santos, M. . (2009, May 5). Venezuela: Perspectivas Econmicas. (R. Lehmann, Interviewer) Caracas. Schiff, J., & Clements, B. J. (1996). IMF Working Paper World Wide Military Spending 19901995. Washington: International Monetary Fund. Segura, R., & Bellamy, C. (2009). Conflict Prevention in Bolivia and Ecuador: the Role of the International Community. New York: Center on International Cooperation. SIPRI. (2010, June 2). SIPRI Yearbook 2010 - Military Expenditure. Retrieved June 21, 2010, from Stockholm International Peace Research Institute: http://www.sipri.org/media/pressreleases/100602yearbooklaunch Solano, G. (2009, September 19). As U.S. Closes Military Post, Ecuador Hails Restoration of 'Sovereignty'. Retrieved April 8, 2010, from The Washington Post: http://www.washingtonpost.com/wpdyn/content/article/2009/09/18/AR2009091803407.html SOUTHCOM. (2009, July 16). Fact Sheet: Forward Operating Locations. Retrieved May 11, 2010, from United States Southern Command: http://www.southcom.mil/AppsSC/factfiles.php?id=63 Stern, R. (2006). Oil Market Power and United States National Security. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America (103 (5)), 1650-1655. Stockholm International Peace Research Institute. (2009). SIPRI Yearbook Summary Booklet 2009: Armaments, Disarmament and International Security. Oxford University Press. The Australian. (2009, April 7). China and Russia block Security Council sanctions over North Korean launch. Retrieved March 10, 2010, from The Australian: http://www.theaustralian.com.au/news/china-and-russia-block-un-sanctions/storye6frg6t6-1225696957931 Tran, M. (2007, May 1). Venezuela Quits IMF and World Bank. Retrieved June 18, 2010, from The Guardian: http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2007/may/01/venezuela.imf 115

Trinkunas, H. A. (2002). The Crisis in Venezuelan Civil-Military Relations: From Punto Fijo to the Fifth Republic. Latin American Research Review (37 (1)), 41-76. Trinkunas, H. (2009). Venezuelan Strategic Culture. Miami: Florida International University. Tugwell, F. (1975). The Politics of Oil in Venezuela. Stanford University Press. UNASUR. (2008). Declaracin de la Moneda. Santiago de Chile: Ministerio de Relaciones Exteriores de Chile. UNASUR. (2009). Proyecto de Decisin. San Carlos de Bariloche. US Department of State. (2009, August 18). U.S.- Colombia Defense Cooperation Agreement. Retrieved May 10, 2010, from US Department of State: http://www.state.gov/r/pa/prs/ps/2009/aug/128021.htm US Navy. (2008, April 4). Navy Reestablishes U.S. 4th Fleet. Retrieved July 26, 2010, from US Navy: http://www.navy.mil/search/display.asp?story_id=36606 USGAO. (2009). Drug Control: US Counternarcotics Cooperation with Venezuela has declined. Washington DC: Government Accountability Office. USGAO. (2006). Energy Security: Issues Related to Potential Reductions in Venezuelan Oil Production. Washington DC: United States Government Accountability Office. Venezuela Information Office. (2009). The GAO Report on U.S.-Venezuela Drug Cooperation: Revisiting the Bush Policy of Politicization. Washington DC: Venezuela Information Office. Vivas-Eugui, D. (2003). Regional and Bilateral agreements and a TRIPS-plus world: the Free Trade Area of the Americas. Geneva: International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development. Waltz, K. (1979). Theory of International Politics. Reading: Addison-Wesley. Wilpert, G. (2003, August 30). The Economics, Culture, and Politics of Oil in Venezuela. Retrieved April 11, 2010, from Venezuelanalysis.com: http://venezuelanalysis.com/analysis/74# World Bank. (2010, May 31). Country Lending Summaries - Venezuela. Retrieved June 18, 2010, from The World Bank: http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/PROJECTS/0,,countrycode:VE~menuPK:64820 000~pagePK:64392398~piPK:64392037~subTitle:Lending+Summary~theSitePK:40941~eop_d ate:31-May-2010,00.html

116

World Bank. (2009). Venezuela Country Brief. Retrieved June 18, 2010, from The World Bank: http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/COUNTRIES/LACEXT/VENEZUELAEXTN/0,,cont entMDK:20214769~pagePK:141137~piPK:141127~theSitePK:331767,00.html#wbsupport World Bank. (2010). World Bank Data Catalog. Retrieved April 26, 2010, from World Bank: http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog Yates, D. A. (1996). The Rentier State in Africa: Oil Rent Dependency and Neo-colonialism in the Republic of Gabon. Africa Research & Publications.

117

You might also like