Financial Alchemy in Crisis

Financial Alchemy in Crisis
The Great Liquidity Illusion
AnAstAsiA nesvetAilovA

175 Fifth Avenue.First published 2010 by Pluto Press 345 Archway Road. eX10 9JB. sidmouth. Martin’s Press llC. london n6 5AA and 175 Fifth Avenue.com Distributed in the United states of America exclusively by Palgrave Macmillan. Conclusion Anastasia nesvetailova 2010 Copyright © Chapter 2 Anastasia nesvetailova and Ronen Palan 2010 the rights of Anastasia nesvetailova and Ronen Palen to be identified as the authors of this work has been asserted by them in accordance with the Copyright. Chippenham and eastbourne . Designs and Patents Act 1988.plutobooks. a division of st. British library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British library isBn isBn 978 0 7453 2878 2 978 0 7453 2877 5 Hardback Paperback library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data applied for this book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully managed and sustained forest sources. pulping and manufacturing processes are expected to conform to the environmental standards of the country of origin. england typeset from disk by stanford DtP services. nY 10010 Copyright © introduction. Chapters 2. 3–6. northampton. 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Designed and produced for Pluto Press by Chase Publishing services ltd. 33 livonia Road. new York. england Printed and bound in the european Union by CPi Antony Rowe. nY 10010 www. logging. new York.

For Alexandre Gennady Palan .

.

the tale of northern Rock: Between Financial Innovation and Fraud (Anastasia nesvetailova and Ronen Palan) the controversy over financial innovation offshore: the uses and abuses of sPvs northern Rock and Granite 3. How the Crisis has been Understood Ex-ante and ex-post visions of the credit crunch structural theories of the credit crunch Cyclical theories of the crisis 4. the stages of the Meltdown the prelude: the American sub-prime crisis From sub-prime crisis to the global credit crunch From global credit crunch to global recession 2. some Uncomfortable Puzzles of the Credit Crunch Dismissed: the warning signs and the whistleblowers Ponzi capitalism: a crisis of fraud? ix x 1 4 17 24 24 28 33 40 43 48 51 62 62 71 80 90 91 100 .Contents Abbreviations Acknowledgements Introduction: the end of a Great Illusion ‘liquidity’ and the crisis of invented money liquidity illusion and the global credit crunch 1.

liquidity as a ‘state of mind’ the alchemists: turning bad debts into ‘money’ 6. After the Meltdown: Rewriting the Rules of Global Finance? the three stages of the policy response the crisis and geopolitics: a new special relationship? Conceptual dilemmas and traps Conclusion: A Very Mundane Crisis Notes Bibliography Index 113 113 121 131 143 144 149 156 172 177 184 197 .viii fI nanc IaL a Lchemy In cr Is Is 5. 2002–7: the three Pillars of the Liquidity Illusion liquidity and the paradigm of self-regulating credit Playing with debt – together.

Abbreviations ABss Bis CDos Ceo CRA eCB FsA FsF FsB GDP iMF MBAs MBss niFA oFC oRD otC siv snB sPe sPv vAR Asset-backed securities Bank for international settlements Collateralised debt obligations Chief executive officer Credit rating agencies european Central Bank Financial services Authority (UK) Financial stability Forum Financial stability Board Gross domestic product international Monetary Fund Mortgage-backed assets Mortgage-backed securities new international financial architecture offshore financial centre originate and distribute (model of banking) over-the-counter (trade) special investment vehicle swiss national Bank special purpose entity special purpose vehicle value at risk (model) ix .

Roy Keitner. Michael Zakim and many others for constructive comments and feedback on earlier versions of the text. Dick Bryan. Duncan Wigan. Randall Germain. london. Angus Cameron. Most of all. and elsewhere. Jan toporowski. summarising my own attempts to learn from the financial meltdown. i am particularly indebted to Rory Brown. Assaf likhovski. victoria Chick. Randall Wray. encouragement and patience of Roger van Zwanenberg and the editorial team at Pluto Press.Acknowledgements the booming industry of credit crunch analysis is a tough competition for anyone trying to draw out systematic lessons from the global financial meltdown. Robert Wade. Gary Dymski. Christine Desan. would not have been possible without the generous assistance. Kees van der Pijl. i am also grateful to my students and colleagues at City University. this book. i thank Ronen Palan for everything. x . Paul Davies. Bruce Carruthers. Jakob vestergaard. Giselle Datz.

not to be outdone by their sixteenth-century brethren. as purged as crystal. and Water of the Wood. Alchemical gold is made of three pure souls. new monks. take one part motor car debt. add two parts credit card debt and three parts house mortgage debt. Pierce the Black Monk. this is to be cast on Mercury and it shall become most worthy gold. Fire of earth. invented a new formula. these are to lie together and then be parted. When it falls to the ground. soul. ask him to throw the Bond in the air. a man versed in mathematics. . and spirit grow into a stone. wherein there is no corruption. leave for six days. today’s experts have become as adept as their sixteenth-century forebears in the dark arts of wealth-creation. Call in the Wizard. earth’s Mother (Water of earth). Bond. then sell to a bank. Body. and mix well together. ask for an AAA rating. and call the whole. sometime in sixteenth-century europe sometime in the twenty-first century. Alchemy makes gold from base materials.take earth of earth.

.

Indeed. was now fully in reverse. The turmoil that engulfed an unsuspecting world one Tuesday in early August 2007 has paralysed the 1 . once considered a buttress of the high plateau and a built-in defense against collapse were really a profound source of weakness. ‘those who cannot learn from history are doomed to repeat it’. With remarkable celerity it removed all of the value from the common stock of a trust. of which people only a fortnight earlier had spoken so knowledgeably and even affectionately. The general opinion among financial experts had been rather reassuring: ‘innovative techniques of corporate finance have led to more careful evaluation of corporate wealth and more effective allocation of capital’ (Bernstein 2005: 2). Few thought that his classic study on economic history would be applicable to a crisis of advanced twenty-first-century capitalism. The leverage. (Galbraith 1955) Sounds familiar? John Kenneth Galbraith wrote these words in 1955 in his celebrated text on the 1929 Wall Street Crash. as is argued in this book. it is the illunderstood process of modern financial alchemy that has become the real cause of the global credit crunch. as George Santayana famously wrote.IntroductIon the end of a Great IllusIon By now it was also evident that the investment trusts. Yet.

In fact. Complex in its nature and origins. How was it. some had been warning against super-inflated asset and housing markets. Yet there were some who had been writing about the possibility of such a collapse for years. did not foresee the crisis in the first place. then. on a par with. criticising the traditional vector of monetary policies (Toporowski 2000). and the reason why it was inevitable though not widely anticipated. incidentally. the major cause of the global financial meltdown. since then. Some had warned about the historically unprecedented debt burden in Anglo-Saxon countries and predicted a crisis of debt-driven consumption (Pettifor 2003). . the crisis has spurred a myriad of reflections. even decades. still appears to escape the vast majority of observers – observers who. 9/11 or the fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989. So why another book on the global credit crunch? Because despite the plethora of theories and approaches. The crisis that began in a seemingly isolated segment of the so-called sub-prime mortgage market in the United States soon engulfed the international banking system and was transformed into a deep global recession. others had even detailed the imminent banking crisis in the ‘advanced’ financial systems (Persaud 2002).2 f inancial alchemy in crisis world of finance and. the entire global economy. There is little doubt that the meltdown will be remembered as an historical watershed. the only industry to have done well out of the credit crunch appears to be the booming business of crisis commentary and theorisations. if not of greater significance than.

why listen to the killjoys who want to spoil it? This book offers an analysis of the credit crunch from the same perspective that warned about the dangers of the financial system in the first place. they are rarely invited to air their views in the pages of glossy business periodicals or high-profile policy forums. or critical. If the party is so good. Detecting historical parallels with previous socio-economic and financial crises and warning against history repeating itself. and their concerned voices were simply muffled amidst the general sense of a credit bonanza in 2002–7. As a result. not ‘mainstream’ economists. many of them come from the same school as John Maynard Keynes. as a rule. Hyman Minsky and other scholars who form the tradition of heterodox. Intellectually. a few economist celebrities like Paul Krugman. these scholars prefer critical historical inquiry into the dynamics of financialised capitalism. Joseph Stiglitz and Nouriel Roubini aside.inT roducT i on: T h e end of a Gr e aT i l l u s i o n 3 that these people were not heeded? And why did the global credit crunch come as a massive shock to the world of finance? The trouble is that the sceptics who had been asking awkward questions and voicing concerns about debt levels and asset bubbles during the credit boom were. There . they often sound like unenlightened sceptics of finance-led economic progress. Still others ventured their prognoses on the basis of intuition and gut feeling. political economy. Suspicious of purely econometric techniques and abstract models in their analyses.

They have yet to reach an agreement. it remains current in the wake of the credit crunch. economic. social. was concealed by one great myth of today’s finance: the illusion of liquidity. Keynes famously described the financial market as a ‘beauty . for instance. rational and calculative. the global credit crunch has shown this idea to be a dangerous – and costly – fallacy. strict. Although apparently precise. but for centuries scholars of political economy have been arguing among themselves about how best to define the concept of ‘value’. As will be argued below. During the boom years of 2002–7 this fallacy. strikingly. Yet as the following pages contend.4 f inanci al alchemy in crisis is no doubt that complex sets of factors – historical. including its major casualties. We all know. the key cause of the global credit crunch can be traced back to one pervasive and dangerous myth. apparent to many in the aftermath of the crisis. technical. today’s financiers create money and wealth. what ‘price’ is. a substantial part of the discipline operates with concepts that are better described as metaphors rather than as a coherent conceptual grounding or a set of definitions. ‘liquidity’ and the crisis of invented money There is a certain oddity about the realm of finance and economics. Specifically. even cultural – have shaped the preconditions for the global malaise. it is the idea that by inventing novel credit instruments and opening up new financial markets. This belief had been shared by many participants of the crisis. geopolitical.

In this sense. Most commonly the global financial meltdown has been defined as a ‘credit crunch’ or crisis of liquidity: liquidity simply melted away from the world markets in the space of just a few days. is that economists and finance professionals would probably never agree on what liquidity actually is. Most people. As one official put it: ‘liquidity clearly ain’t what it used to be. however. rather than as a clear. would intuitively prefer to be in a position that is liquid rather than one that is illiquid. still less whether that is a “good” or a “bad” thing’ (Smout 2001). but a major transplant. leading policymakers were concerned with what they believed was a structural ‘liquidity glut’. these worries turned into the fear of a global liquidity meltdown. But it is much less clear what such a statement means. . Just weeks before the crisis erupted. Yet within a matter of days. The problem is that ‘liquidity’ is precisely one such category in contemporary finance that seems to be easier understood by means of metaphors and allusions.in T roducT i on: T h e end of a Gr e aT i l l u s i o n 5 contest’1 and the metaphor stuck – albeit we know that things in this beauty contest often turn rather ugly. even those outside finance. the world economy may require not just a facelift. agreed definition or framework. after the financial wreckage of 2007–9. The irony. That fear soon materialised in a very real financial and economic crisis. Everyone knows that liquidity is the lifeblood of any financial market and that it is essential for general economic activity.

Liquidity is a very fluid. complex. Liquidity also denotes a quantity – most often associated with the pool of money or credit available in a system at any given time. a market. Liquidity can literally vanish overnight. To make things more complicated still. illiquid debt when confidence and optimism evaporate. Or. Liquidity is also about depth – of a market for a particular class of assets – and speed – with which a certain transaction can be completed. Liquidity is also an intertemporal category: liquidity in good economic times is not the same as liquidity in bad times. national economy and finally. the liquidity of an individual bank. . It describes a quality – of an asset. Liquidity is also a probability – a calculated chance of a transaction being completed in time without inflicting a major disruption on the prevailing trends in the market. portfolio. The liquidity that was widely assumed to be abundant during the pre-crisis period was not the same liquidity that melted away during the crisis.6 f inancial alchemy in crisis The problem is conceptual. Assets that are easy to sell when investors are confident about their profitability and risk profiles often turn out to be unwanted and expensive bundles of poor quality. a segment of the market. as economists like to stress. multidimensional notion. an institution or even an economic system as a whole. liquidity can also comprise all these things and describe several layers of economic activity at the same time – for instance. the global financial system as a whole. liquidity to sell is not always the same as liquidity to buy.

financial institutions employed armies of young MBAs. The new generation of finance professionals turned out to be nothing but a highly motivated sales force. these and many other puzzles of the credit crunch centre on the problem of liquidity and its metamorphoses in the modern financial system. As will be argued below.500bn of loans were securitised in the US. When the boom came to a halt. took the trouble to learn about the nature of these instruments in depth. importantly. liquidity drainage from the markets. synthetic financial products were exposed for what they actually were – parcels of toxic debt – and their market liquidity evaporated. or at least started as. gave them fancy job titles and paid them handsomely. Bankers could confidently sell highly complex instruments in bulk to clients around the world. in 2008 almost none were sold to private sector buyers (Tett and van Duyn 2009). bent on persuading even the most sceptical clients to part with their cash for bundles of securitised loans.inT roducT i on: T h e end of a G r e aT i l l u s i o n 7 This is exactly what happened to trillions of dollars of securitised loans and a plethora of highly sophisticated and opaque financial instruments during 2007–9. it now transpires. There is no clear . Most chronicles of the crisis concur that the global meltdown centred on. their competitors – were making money. as did the markets for these products: whereas in 2007 $2. All they seemed to care about was that the market for these products appeared highly liquid and that they – and. At the height of the 2002–7 liquidity boom. Not many buyers.

the diversity of views becomes ever more apparent. but crucially it is intimately related to the notion of money: liquidity is ‘an asset’s capability over time of being realised in the form of funds available for immediate consumption or reinvestment – proximately in the form of money’ (Hirchleifer 1986: 43). however. an intermediary between lenders and investors. In parallel. As the field of credit crunch studies expands. the postwar system of fixed exchange rates and financial controls was dismantled. most students of finance at the time would concur that liquidity is a property of an asset. As a result of the financial innovations that led to this collapse. In the brief age of Keynesian economic stability.8 f inancial alchemy in crisis consensus. into an industry of trading and optimising risk. the concept of liquidity has undergone its own series of mutations. the state lost its monopoly over the process of credit-creation. In 1971. And even though the concept of ‘money’ remains probably the most controversial aspect of economics and finance. But then the real life of the financial markets complicated matters. on what the concept of liquidity actually implies today. The financial sector has been transformed from being part of the service economy. it is conditioned by the market context. As such. . ‘liquidity’ was generally assumed to describe a quality of an asset and ultimately was related to the notion of money. Not that long ago things were somewhat simpler.

the Eurocurrency market became the global engine of liquidity-creation and debt-financing. widen . the notion of liquidity. financial institutions attach a price to these assets. has been gravitating towards the realm of the financial markets themselves. and later in the era of the Gold Standard and even the fixed exchange rates of the Bretton Woods system.in T roduc Ti on: T he end of a G re aT i l l u s i o n 9 First. Created by commercial banks to avoid national regulations. liquidity was closely associated primarily with state-generated credit money and. the banking system’s ability to extend credit. securitisation is a technique used to create securities by reshuffling the cash flows produced by a diversified pool of assets with common characteristics. this trend manifested itself in the global debt crisis of the 1980s (Guttman 2003: 32). A key factor in this trend was the emergence in the late 1960s of the unregulated financial space. The idea behind this principle is economic flexibility: by securitising previously non-traded products and putting them on the market. the Euromarket. both functionally and conceptually. one can design several securities (tranches) with different risk-reward profiles which appeal to different investors (Cifuentes 2008). the transformation of liquidity has paralleled the rise of private financial markets. Most dramatically. By doing so. and became prone to overextension of credit. The second mutation of liquidity has been the so-called securitisation revolution. During the centuries of metal-based money. second. Theoretically. With the collapse of the Bretton Woods regime and the rise of private financial markets.

therefore. the securitisation of credit has greatly increased the variety and volume of trade in the global financial markets. In theory. The explanation for this . the notion of liquidity as tied to the pure credit intermediation mechanism or a state-administered monetary pool began to fade away. With banks rapidly becoming major players in this global financial market. Boosted by the resolution of the debt crisis of the 1980s. Facilitated by technological and scientific advances. have viewed liquidity as necessarily a twofold concept. and with their greater reliance on securitisation techniques in managing their portfolios. Indeed. obscure loans have been transformed into securities and traded in the financial markets. the securitisation of credit became a process through which often poor quality.10 f inancial alchemy in crisis their ownership and hence. by expanding the web of economic transactions. the earlier political-economic conceptualisations of liquidity. More recent examinations of liquidity as a category of finance have moved away from associating it with notions of money or cash. strengthen the robustness of the economy as a whole.: 40–1). stressing instead the link between market liquidity and risk (Allen and Gale 2000). securitisation is supposed to enhance liquidity and economic stability. while emphasising its evasive and multidimensional character (Keynes 1936). as well as the spread of the derivatives markets. The business of securitisation has been assumed to bring many benefits to the economy. creating the sense of much greater liquidity of these markets and the depth of the credit pool (ibid.

liquidity describes ‘a high level of trading activity. the privatisation of financial and economic risks and the denationalisation of money have shifted the process of liquidity-creation away from the public sphere of political economy and into the realm of private financial markets (Holmstrong and Tirole 1998: 1).in TroducT i on: T h e end of a Gr e aT i l l u s i o n 11 change in the analytical approaches is to be found in the financial developments of the post-1971 era. As a result. high-powered or state-backed money. The outcome of this chain of mutations – both analytical and market-based – is that in most contemporary readings the connection between ‘money’ and ‘liquidity’ has waned. the global financial system is based on credit and a multitude of economic transactions. a market characterised by the ability to buy and sell with relative ease’ (Farlex Free Dictionary). The policies of financial deregulation and liberalisation reinforced this trend. but rather an indicator of the general condition and vitality of a financial market. over the past few decades. Instead. analyses of finance in the macro-economy have assumed that liquidity is no longer primarily a property of assets. Specifically. With money itself becoming increasingly dematerialised. allowing buying and selling with minimum price disturbance. thereby institutionalising liquidity firmly as a category and instrument of the market and its pricing mechanism. After all. As one web-based financial dictionary suggests. liquidity has been presumed to relate . Also. it may seem odd to link liquidity to categories of cash.

12 f ina nci al alchemy in crisis to the complex mechanism of financial transactions taking place in the markets and confronting a variety of risks. In terms of understanding what liquidity is and how it behaves. the deepening of the financial sector and the growing role of finance-based relations in shaping the nature of socio-political developments today. real economic . therefore have been progressively abstracted from the dynamics of productivity. It encapsulates two intertwined tendencies in contemporary capitalism: first. trade. an important assumption correlated with this trend. liquidity has increasingly assumed the features of a private device of the financial markets in the sense that it is created by agents seeking to benefit individually from that privilege (Guttman 2003: 23). This in turn has produced several interrelated assumptions that have shaped finance theory and policy in the run-up to the global credit crunch. The expansion of the credit system and the accumulation of financial wealth. liquidity has progressively lost its public good component. reaping profits in the process. marked by the inherent contradiction between money as a public good and as a private commodity. centred on financial institutions’ ability to transform illiquid loans into tradable securities. or what social scientists understand as financialisation. both spatially and intertemporally. and second. therefore. the process of securitisation (depicted above). The first trend concerns the expansion of the global credit system and can be described as a process of demonetised financialisation. or financialisation. As financialisation advanced. Just as money itself is.

as happened with many highly risky securitisation products) (e. Toporowski 2009). often institutions specialising in trading these particular products. and (iii) by redistributing the risk to those who are deemed most able and willing to hold risk (i. Second. for instance. by pooling a bunch of sub-prime mortgages from several mortgage lenders). or placing them off the balance sheet. riskoptimising and market-creating financial innovations have been seen as key to enhancing social welfare more generally: . developments in the sphere of state-backed or high-powered money. In the context of the sub-prime market. by selling it on to third and fourth parties. Rather. mainstream finance theory and practice supported and guided these trends by embedding the new credit system in a paradigm of scientific finance.e. In this view. crucially. the ultimate aim of the financial system today is to manage and optimise risk in three steps: (i) by identifying and pricing risks (for instance. (ii) by parcelling them into specific financial vehicles (such as tranches of mortgages or structured financial products).in T roduc Ti on: Th e end of a G re aT i l l u s i o n 13 growth and. the key function of the financial system as a whole is no longer the intermediation between savers and borrowers as such. analytically. that role has been assigned to just one sector of the financial system – commercial banking.g. This complex chain of financial innovation is known in mainstream finance theory as market completion.

even to applicants able to qualify in a prime-only market. securitisation. prime lenders can target some applicants who otherwise might not be qualified … The prime mortgage market allows all borrowers meeting a particular threshold to be qualified … adding a subprime market provides a welfare gain. for instance. car or student loans and sub-prime mortgages. by relying on scientific approaches to risk management and calculative practices. Financial innovation. this process – extending far beyond the sub-prime market – symbolised ‘a new paradigm of active credit management’ (cited in Morris 2008: 61). transforms previously unpriced and typically illiquid assets. (chinloy and macdonald 2005: 163–4) Ultimately. such as real estate. ‘financial innovation will slow as we approach the world in which financial markets are complete in the sense that all financial risks can be effectively transferred to those most willing to bear them’ (2003. Those applicants obtain a welfare gain by having more choices and flexibility. as Alan Greenspan foresaw. thereby optimising risks and enhancing the liquidity of the financial system as a whole (Cifuentes 2008). By pricing the risks of different types of credit quality. therefore. . is believed to create new facilities for risk optimisation and thus complete the system of markets. into tradable and liquid financial securities. cited in Wigan 2009). According to Greenspan. As the theory holds.14 financi al alchemy in crisis The subprime market provides a market-opening and -completing opportunity … The subprime market allows funding to those who would otherwise not be homeowners.

no less than $450bn worth of ‘collateralised debt obligations of asset-backed securities’ (CDOs of ABSs) were created. Indeed. in 2006 and early 2007. she argues. the spiral of demonetised financialisation has been underpinned by institutional and operational advances in financial innovation. the growing sophistication and specialisation of offshore financial centres and techniques (Palan 2003). Generally. all leading to the extraordinary growth of variety and complexity of financial products themselves. In addition to the structural shift towards the ‘originate and distribute’ (ORD) banking model. in ways almost nobody understood. a set of innovations that were supposed to create freer markets and complete the system of risk optimisation actually produced an opaque world in which risk became highly concentrated – worryingly. most were sold to banks’ off-balance-sheet entities. such as value-at-risk (VAR) models. the expansion of the so-called shadow banking industry. there has been a remarkable rise in the number of hedge funds. and the spread of new methods of risk management and trade. such as structured investment vehicles (SIVs). as Gillian Tett writes. as the principle of active credit risk management would imply. Yet instead of being traded.inT roducT i on: T h e end of a Gr e aT i l l u s i o n 15 Third. or simply left on the books. What is striking about the wave of financial innovation that defined the last two decades of the global financial system is that many newly created products of risk management became so specialised and tailor-made that they were never traded in free markets. .

by 2006. they conceive liquidity fundamentally as a property of the market or an institution. more accurately. And although some recent analyses have drawn a distinction between market and systemic liquidity (Large 2005). it could take a whole weekend for computers to carry out the calculations needed to assess the risks of complex CDOs (Tett 2009).16 fina nci al alchemy in crisis Officials at Standard & Poor’s admit that. This conceptualisation of liquidity in turn has produced a sequence of analytical fallacies which have . or between search and funding liquidity (ECB 2006). debt – has resulted in the now mainstream notion of liquidity that is divorced from any attribute of assets per se. At the level of financial institutions themselves. the axiom that financial innovation and engineering have the capacity to liquefy any type of asset – or. What does the combination of the three trends imply for the analysis of the crisis offered in this book? It appears that most analytical and policy frameworks of the global financial system have been based on a strong and relatively straightforward assumption. able and willing to trade at a given point in time at a prevailing price level (Warsh 2007). Namely. rather than as a quality of assets as such. in the Anglo-Saxon economies it is the concept of market liquidity – describing the depth of markets for the sale or loan of assets or the hedging of risks that underlie those assets – that has come to inform most recent frameworks of financial governance (Crockett 2008: 13–17). liquidity is most commonly understood as ‘confidence’ of the markets. Here.

in T roducT i on: Th e end of a G re aT i l l u s i o n 17 contributed to the illusion that this is the real cause of the global credit crunch. it is . price and trade new financial products that creates and distributes liquidity in the markets. originates in a hollow notion of liquidity itself and. Hyman Minsky famously stated in his financial instability hypothesis. in the flawed vision – academic as well as political – of the dynamics of the relationship between private financial innovation and the liquidity and resilience of the financial system generally. Therefore. Amidst the ostensible rehabilitation of his name. consequently. Second is the view that general market trade and turnover are synonymous with market liquidity. This misunderstanding. I believe. liquidity illusion and the Global credit crunch ‘Stability is always destabilizing’. the hollow notion of liquidity lies at the heart of the great illusion of wealth and the belief in financial markets’ capacity to invent money that are the real causes of the global meltdown. this line of reasoning has been underpinned by the notion that financial innovation in its various forms ultimately enhances the liquidity of the financial system as a whole. Altogether. The third and corresponding fallacy is the notion that market liquidity itself – when multiplied across many markets – ultimately is synonymous with the liquidity (and financial robustness) of the economic system as a whole. The first fallacy is the assumption that it is the market-making capacity of financial intermediaries to identify.

economic prosperity and optimistic forecasts that pervaded North Atlantic economies and financial markets. things will be complicated. of risk by financial agents. in terms of liquidity. as stated famously by Citi’s Chuck Prince in July 2007: ‘When the music stops. Indeed.18 f inancial alchemy in crisis this message that seems to attract most commentaries on the credit crunch.. But as long as the music is playing. you’ve got to get up and dance’ (cited in Soros 2008: 84). The trend towards the ‘originate and distribute model’ … ultimately led to a decline in lending standards. exuberance and optimism about one’s position in the market and lead to greater reliance on leverage and underestimation of risks. regardless of their intellectual and policy affiliations. most commentators on the credit crunch recognise the tendency to underestimate the risks in a bearish market or bubble. According to Minsky. based in turn on the general sense of stability. financial . Many American observers continue to believe that the root cause of this problem was the liquidity glut coming from the emerging markets. ‘good’ times breed complacency. Economists analysing the crisis do recognise the role of a liquidity crunch in the first stage of the crisis (August 2007–September 2008). or misunderstanding. Indeed. notably again identifying the link between the supply of capital from abroad and the housing bubble in North America: The creation of new securities facilitated the large capital inflows from abroad . Most observers concur that the major factor in the global credit crisis was the progressive underestimation..

as now commonplace references to a ‘Minsky moment’ in finance or the crisis of Ponzi finance suggest. it appears that only a fragmented and highly selective version of Minsky’s theory resonates in current readings of the global meltdown. this phenomenon constitutes an illusion of liquidity. In this sense. Very few indeed cast a critical . many emergent theories of the global credit crunch appear to have strong Minskyan undertones. Yet once we consider the contentious place of ‘liquidity’ in the crisis. the illusion of liquidity is understood as a false sense of optimism a financial actor (be that a company. or a situation in which markets under-price liquidity and financial institutions underestimate liquidity risks (CGFS 2001: 2). economic and political consequences. (Brunnermeir 2009: 78) The BIS arguably went furthest in analysing the repercussions of this collective underestimation of risks for liquidity and admitted that. fund manager or a government) has about the safety and resilience of a portfolio and/or market as a whole. most mainstream analysts of the crisis overlook the core of Minsky’s framework. this illusion can have very real – and destructive – social. In other words. While noting the risk effects of the general macroeconomic environment and investor expectations. As the credit crunch revealed. essentially.in T roducT i on: T h e end of a G re aT i l l u s i o n 19 innovation that had supposedly made the banking system more stable by transferring risk to those most able to bear it led to an unprecedented credit expansion that helped feed the boom in housing prices.

in fact has driven the financial system into a structurally illiquid. According to Minsky. propelled by the belief that clever techniques of parcelling debts. create additional and plentiful liquidity. Although the firm’s securitisation strategy had been based on the assumption that collateralised mortgage obligations (CMOs) would be more liquid than their underlying collateral – the properties – he warned that this assumption was far too . on the other.20 f ina nci al alchemy in crisis eye on the very ability of private financial intermediaries to extend the frontier of private liquidity. Just as the securitisation bubble was beginning to inflate. as financial innovations gain ground. At the level of the financial system. the velocity of money increases. What is astonishing is that some market players seemed to be aware of this danger. one of the big investors warned about specific liquidity risks faced by his company. ‘every institutional innovation which results in both new ways to finance business and new substitutes for cash decreases the liquidity of the economy’ (1984 [1982]: 173). securitisation has produced an incredibly complex and opaque hierarchy of credit instruments. creating new products and opening up new markets. ultimately accentuating financial fragility in the system and thus accelerating the scope for a structural financial collapse and economic crisis. as Minsky warned. On the one hand. Yet. the web of debt-driven financial innovations has a dual effect on the system’s liquidity. crisis-prone state. The latest round of securitisation. whose liquidity was assumed but in fact was never guaranteed.

diagnose the evaporation of liquidity as a result of market failure rather than as a systemic tendency. during more benign periods. 9 August 2008).in T roducT i on: T h e end of a Gr e aT i l l u s i o n 21 short-sighted and over-reliant on the market’s shared sentiments: ‘as a guide to market discipline. in October 2008. some banks sought to reduce the opportunity cost of holding liquid assets by substituting traditional liquid assets such as highly rated government bonds with highly rated structured credit products. stating that: The ongoing turmoil has revealed that. This has been part of a longer-term decline in banks’ holdings of liquid . the Bank of England documented a depletion of sterling liquid assets relative to total asset holdings in the UK banking sector. indeed. makes the connection between the excesses of private financial innovation and its liquidity-decreasing effects.. we like the expression.2 However. unless you actually have to sell them!”’ (Kochen 2000: 112). A notable outcome of the credit crunch is that it seems to have raised the importance of liquidity in the hierarchy of concerns of some policymaking bodies. most discussions of liquidity in the crisis. as one risk manager admitted in the wake of the crisis: ‘The possibility that liquidity could suddenly dry up was always a topic high on our list but we could only see more liquidity coming into the market – not going out of it . by focusing on the problem of valuations and risk mis-pricing. Yet the evidence is abundant. or. For instance. None of the studies. “sure they’re liquid.’ (The Economist..

as is explained in the following chapters. which has been replicated in other countries.22 f inanci al alchemy in crisis assets in the united Kingdom. an important question about the credit crunch remains unanswered. this book tells the story of the global credit crunch as a crisis brought about by a pervasive and multifaceted illusion of wealth. In what follows. Together. therefore. which thrives in a climate of deregulated credit and robust financial innovation. and if a whole body of scholarship in heterodox political economy can explain the dangers of financial euphoria and innovations. these three elements helped sustain the illusion of infinite liquidity during 2002–7. illusion of liquidity. leading people like Greenspan to celebrate ‘the new era in credit risk management’? The answer. or more concretely. If the participants of the credit boom themselves did admit that some of the foundations of their innovative techniques were shaky. why is it that the illusion of liquidity and wealth was sustained over a prolonged period. and a structure of authority able to legitimise the newly created financial products and thus assure their marketability (the credit rating agencies in the case of the current crisis). Such a narrow subject matter may seem far too technical and specific. can be found in three political-economic pillars of the liquidity illusion: the paradigm of a self-regulating financial system. (2008: 39–40) In this instance. Ponzi-type finance. yet it serves an important purpose in unpacking the political .

While any economic crisis is in a sense a crisis of belief and confidence – be it in a national currency.inT roducT i on: T h e end of a G r e aT i l l u s i o n 23 economy of the credit crunch. a bank or a whole industry – the concept of liquidity has played a crucial. Not only does the idea of liquidity capture a range of axioms and assumptions that shaped the architecture of the unravelling global financial system. role in the political economy of the credit crunch. . and ultimately destructive. it also encapsulates the politics of financial alchemy today. or what is widely celebrated as a process of financial innovation.

the meltdown turned into a cross-border banking crisis which threatened the very viability of the financial services in key economies. the financial malaise spread to the real economy. the credit crunch has had no lack of chronologies: every major media outlet and financial institution updates the timeline of key events and figures. the meltdown goes back earlier 24 . It began with paralysis in the international financial markets. Gradually. To date.1 the staGes of the Meltdown Since it began in the summer of 2007. By the summer of 2009. causing a chain of bankruptcies and job losses in manufacturing and the services sector. this chapter uses the records of the crisis and traces the evolution of the global meltdown through its three distinct stages. commonly dubbed a ‘liquidity crunch’. the global credit crunch has gone through three distinct stages. the financial meltdown had matured into one of the deepest recessions recorded in the postwar history of capitalism. The Prelude: The american sub-Prime crisis Most records of the global credit crunch start at 9 August 2007. However. Rather than replicate these detailed records. A year later.

sub-prime loans made up just 5.6 per cent of mortgage dollars. American MBSs became the largest component of the global fixed income market. Yet it was as early as 2006 that the price increases in the American housing market slowed down. these clients were now granted access to credit and could own a house on what appeared – initially at least – to be favourable and affordable rates. the US sub-prime market was worth $600bn.1 The expansion of the mortgagebacked securities (MBSs) market drew investors into some of the more risky tranches of MBS debt. In the United States. accounting for a fifth of its value. and the first . housing markets in the Anglo-Saxon economies were booming at unprecedented levels.T he s TaGes of T he me lTdoWn 25 than that.2 In 2001. In the US in particular a whole new segment of housing finance – sub-prime mortgages – provided a major motor for the credit boom and the expanding financial system. which has been the epicentre of the global malaise. the prelude to the global financial meltdown unfolded in late 2006/early 2007. But in the booming housing market. In global terms. supported by opportunities to manage the high risks that the new financial system offered. In 2006. ‘Sub-prime’ designates a category of borrowers who otherwise would be considered ‘high-risk’ clients: they had poor or no credit histories. Between 2002 and 2007. It all started with a boom. or 20 per cent of the $3 trillion mortgage market. The great housing boom was supported by cheap and plentiful credit and the widely held belief that house prices would continue to rise.

came from the architect of mortgage-backed finance himself. thereby increasing the interest payment on the loans.26 financi al alchemy in crisis wave of mortgage delinquencies started to spread. sub-prime delinquencies more than 60 days late jumped to almost 13 per cent. from 1 per cent in 2004. Commentators explained this by the fact that in 2006 . According to the structure of sub-prime loans. who said: ‘I think [the risk] is containable … I don’t think this is going to be a cataclysm’ (in Kratz 2007). which climbed to 5. By the end of 2006. Also. began to default on their mortgages and defaults on sub-prime loans rose to record levels.35 per cent in 2006. The trigger to the rising number of defaults was the increase in the interest rate. Observers offered different readings of this trend: some argued that despite the notable increase in bankruptcies. in 2006 the structure of US sub-prime mortgages shifted many borrowers out of their initial (presumably favourable) fixed-rate terms. their repayments were due to rise in a year or two. compared to 8 per cent in 2005. for those who needed them. many of whom could barely afford their mortgage payments when interest rates were low. the trend historically was insignificant (IMF 2007: 5). The sceptics were proven right. Homeowners. crucially. Lewie Ranieri. The words of reassurance. Others began to anticipate a bigger wave of defaults and bankruptcies: most 2006 borrowers were still in the ‘teaser rate’ period of their mortgages. Some sceptics warned that against this background a default of one or two financial companies could well spark a worldwide financial crisis.

a giant like HSBC could write off the $10bn loss and escape relatively unscathed from the mounting market distress. the largest sub-prime lender in the US and a leading investment bank globally. On 22 February 2007 HSBC. most notably New Century . This fuelled fears of bankruptcy in several sub-prime lenders. Many smaller sub-prime lenders were already facing bankruptcy. Smaller sub-prime lenders operating on the American markets were in a less healthy position. compared to 2. Market sceptics immediately read this as a sign of a greater trouble ahead: HSBC’s total annual profits were around $15bn. the housing boom stalled and. In March 2007. and higher.2 per cent for a similar type of loan originated in 2004. news of heavy losses from the ailing sub-prime market hit American building companies. interest rate. HSBC Finance.4 At the time. in 2006 it reached almost 4 per cent.5bn loss in its mortgage finance subsidiary. The number of bankruptcies and foreclosures also rose: according to Moody’s. The impact of these defaults was felt throughout the financial system as many of the mortgages had been bundled up and sold on to banks and investors (BBC 2009). and borrowers could no longer afford to pay the mortgage on a new. The winter of 2006–7 brought the first signs of the real magnitude of the coming meltdown. started to affect the financial and banking system more generally.3 announced a $10. through the complex web of mortgage-backed finance.T he sTaG es of T he me lT doWn 27 some of the more neglected sub-prime loans had reached their refinancing limits. Eventually.

at the time the largest American independent sub-prime mortgage lender. for instance. Specifically. New Century Financial Corporation filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy. The fall of the company marks the point when tensions in the sub-prime mortgage markets started to affect Wall Street directly. According to the BIS. announced write-downs. In July 2007. over the following few months the sub-prime crisis escalated as more and more high-ranking companies. this reflected a ‘seemingly orderly re-pricing of credit risk’. Bear Stearns told investors . the weaker mortgage collateral was partly associated with adverse trends in employment and income in specific American states rather than with escalating housing markets (IMF 2007: 7). on 2 April 2007. explained the downturn as a combination of regional economic factors and a shift in the US mortgage market. In just a few weeks. rather than as a systemic breakdown in finance and the economy. from sub-Prime crisis to the Global credit crunch Notwithstanding the optimism in the markets.28 f inanci al alchemy in crisis Finance Corporation. conditioned by changing economic and policy factors in the US economy (Borio 2008: 5). Interestingly. including UBS and the investment bank Bear Stearns. The IMF. even as the prospects for the housing market and financial boom darkened. commentary at the time viewed the unfolding downturn as no more than a cyclical adjustment to the otherwise normal trend of rising house prices.

On 9 August 2007. if any. By early August 2007. On that day. the world’s financial indices went into free-fall and pretty much remained there over the following months. the largest French bank. BNP Paribas. Central banks around the world immediately offered liquidity support in an attempt to stem the panic. subprime-backed bonds and collateralised debt obligations (CDOs). announced that it was unable to value three investment funds in the volatile market context and informed investors that they could no longer withdraw money from these facilities. the European Central Bank (ECB) injected €95bn into the overnight markets and the Federal Reserve injected $38bn.T he sTaG es of T he me lT doWn 29 they would get little. Countrywide Financial.5 and the German bank IKB. As large financial houses were calculating their losses from sub-prime loans. the world’s . American Home Mortgage Investment Corporation. of the money invested in two of its hedge funds after rival banks refused to help it bail them out. the list of casualties of the implosion included the hedge fund run by Bear Stearns. Reacting to the news. Federal Reserve chairman Ben Bernanke estimated that the sub-prime crisis could cost up to $100bn. In the space of just a few days in mid-August 2007. the credit ratings agencies were downgrading asset-backed securities (ABSs). other central banks followed with similar actions over the following weeks. a US home loan lender.6 The fateful date 9 August 2007 became the official anniversary of the global credit crunch.

might be facing a liquidity crisis. Northern Rock.7 Despite these collective and unprecedented efforts to restore optimism in the markets. Aside from liquidity injections. other emergency policy measures employed over the next few months included repeated cuts in interest rates and coordinated international monetary interventions in the credit markets. in particular. Northern Rock Just days into the unfolding malaise in the financial markets. the first run on a bank in the UK for a century. the Financial Services Authority (FSA). . on 13 August 2007. which went bankrupt in August–September 2007 and had to be nationalised. With this. the first stage of the global meltdown – the sub-prime crisis in the US – had not been brought under control. by harming those financial institutions that relied heavily on wholesale credit markets. Through its effects on the financial markets worldwide and. started to unfold. was reportedly informed that the country’s fifth largest mortgage lender. and a subsequent political scandal. it was transformed from a crisis in one segment of the market into an international banking crisis and global credit crunch.30 financi al alchemy in crisis central banks pumped an extraordinary $240bn into the ailing markets. The best known of the casualties during this second phase was the British bank Northern Rock. the UK financial watchdog.

Northern Rock had a portfolio of loans and assets of £113bn. but it would later emerge that the UK authorities spent around £50bn of taxpayers’ money rescuing the bank. Granting the cash. and cash support from the Bank of England guaranteed by the government (ibid. the amount of money used to save the bank was not disclosed. During the years of the credit boom. three scenarios of crisis management were discussed: a market solution (Northern Rock would try to obtain the necessary funding by itself). On 13 September 2007. Between 10 August and mid-September 2007.T he s TaGes of T he me lTdoWn 31 In 2006–early 2007. it could no longer tap the international financial markets for financing. As Wood and Milne document. At the time. a takeover by another major bank. the Financial Services Authority and the Treasury) debated how best to extricate the bank from its difficulties. Northern Rock and the UK tripartite authorities (the Bank of England.). But fortunes turned against the bank in the summer of 2007. the Bank of England provided Northern Rock with emergency liquidity support. As the crisis in the international financial markets deepened and credit flows froze up. this ‘aggressive’ business strategy had paid off handsomely. As credit dried up. linked to the exceptional market . while the deposits it had on its books were simply not sufficient to cover its outstanding obligations. but a small customer deposit pool of only £24bn (Wood and Milne 2008). the first two options became unfeasible. the authorities also commented that funding problems at Northern Rock were of a temporary (liquidity) nature.

Despite these measures. As banks were increasingly reluctant to lend to each other. In the midst of gloomy macroeconomic data now coming from economies around the world and debates about the imminent recession and. . Sceptics warned that the true costs would be much higher still. On 17 March 2008. however. potentially. for $240m in a deal backed by $30bn of central bank loans. Bear Stearns. customers launched an old-fashioned run on Northern Rock – on Friday 14 September they withdrew £1bn in what was the biggest run on a British bank for more than a century. This continued until the government stepped in to guarantee depositors’ savings (BBC 2009). By March 2008 things had become darker still. Despite government support.8 The collapse of the bank and general market downturn prompted the authorities in the US and the EU to draft the first regulatory policy responses reflecting the unfolding malaise. JP Morgan Chase. Meanwhile the crisis intensified. rather than a serious structural problem. entering the year 2008 in the gloom of foundering housing markets. After a failed attempt by the Virgin group to buy Northern Rock. credit markets remained frozen. depression. panic in the financial markets and more losses being revealed by banks and other companies. Wall Street’s fifth largest bank. the IMF estimated that total losses from the sub-prime crisis could reach $1 trillion.32 financi al alchemy in crisis conditions. was acquired by its larger rival. the bank was nationalised in February 2008.

9 Although the Chinese government made no official comment at the time. signs of recession were becoming more visible. the largest holder of US debt. it was clear that the fall of the two institutions would harm the value of the dollar and thus affect all holdings of US debt held by foreign creditors around the world. Alistair Darling. They had been the drivers of the mortgage securities markets. On the other side of the Atlantic. according to market consensus and common sense. The pressure. warned that the economy was facing its worst crisis in 60 years and added that the downturn would be more ‘profound and long-lasting’ than most had feared.Th e sTaGe s of Th e me lTd oWn 33 the crisis continued to accelerate into the summer and autumn of 2008. The next dark moment in the crisis chain came in mid-summer 2008. came from China. . On 7 September. the UK Chancellor. or nearly half of the US’s $12 trillion mortgage market. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were taken over by the US government in one of the largest bailouts in US financial history. On 14 July. owning or guaranteeing $5 trillion worth of home loans. from Global credit crunch to Global recession The week of 7–15 September 2008 was the darkest to date in the history of the credit crunch. In late August 2008. the two largest lenders in the US – Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac – appealed for help from the US government.

in return for an 80 per cent stake in the company.34 f inancial alchemy in crisis Three days later. Merrill Lynch.9bn for the three months to August 2008. AIG paid out hundreds of millions of dollars in bonuses to its senior executives. representing the biggest erosion of financial wealth since the 1930s. it would emerge that having received the bailout. Alan Greenspan described the fall of Lehmans as ‘probably a once in a century type of event’. The collapse of the global bank was a major shock to the international financial system and marked the transformation of a market liquidity crunch into an international banking and credit meltdown. These included top US firms Goldman Sachs . Markets went into free-fall for weeks in a row. agreed to be taken over by Bank of America for $50bn (BBC 2009). Under pressure from an angry Congress. the Federal Reserve authorised an $85bn rescue package for the country’s biggest insurance firm. AIG. On 15 September 2008. AIG eventually had to list the firms to which the money was actually paid. Direct comparisons with the 1930s crisis and projections of a global depression became commonplace. Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy protection under Chapter 11. The second half of September 2008 witnessed several attempts by governments to tame the panic in the markets and save individual institutions from bankruptcy. after several futile attempts to find a buyer or secure governmental rescue. In the US.10 Several months later. The situation worsened as another high-profile US bank. Lehman Brothers – one of the largest Wall Street banks – posted a loss of $3.

11 Merrill Lynch ($6. In total. policymakers in the US drafted a massive $700bn rescue package for the American financial system. Bank of America ($5. The UK’s Bradford & Bingley – the largest provider of ‘buy to let’ mortgages in the country (controlling around £50bn of mortgages) – was part-nationalised. Lloyds TSB took over the ailing bank in what would soon prove to be an unwise £12bn deal. Towards the end of September.T he sTaG es of T he me lT doWn 35 ($12.5bn). Barclays ($8. On 25 September. the country’s biggest mortgage lender. 12 In the UK at around that time. Citigroup ($2. US mortgage lender Washington Mutual (whose assets were valued at $307bn). the credit crunch spread further into the European banking systems.2bn).8bn). AIG named nearly 80 companies and municipalities that benefited most from the Fed rescue. was nationalised. though many more receiving smaller payments were unnamed (Williams Walsh 2009).3bn) and Wachovia ($1. was facing bankruptcy. was closed down and sold off to JP Morgan Chase.9bn). Meanwhile. It was the biggest public intervention in the markets since the Great Depression and would take weeks to be approved by Congress. part-sold to the Spanish bank . The deal allowed the Treasury to buy up ‘toxic debt’ from ailing banks. a banking and insurance giant. The major foreign banks included Société Générale and Deutsche Bank (nearly $12bn each).5bn) and UBS ($5bn). Fortis. HBOS. Political disagreements and uncertainties over the nature of the deal continued to send shockwaves through the global financial system.

On 11 October. as governments around the world drafted recapitalisation plans for the financial systems. The government also offered up to £200bn ($350bn) in short-term lending support. Eventually. companies and non-bank financial institutions accelerated their withdrawal from even short-term funding of banks. the G7 nations issued a five-point plan of ‘decisive action’ to unfreeze credit markets. as carefully described by Mervyn King. Glitnir. the UK authorities announced details of a rescue package for the banking system worth at least £50bn ($88bn). The Icelandic government took control of the country’s third largest bank. On 8 October. Iceland would approach the IMF for a rescue loan. central banks in the US. Meanwhile. Canada. funding costs rose sharply and for . Iceland was on the brink of complete financial meltdown. after the company faced short-term funding problems. Over the following days.36 f ina ncial alchemy in crisis Santander. Governor of the Bank of England: in the second half of september. Governments throughout Europe announced multi-billion support packages for their economies. Finance ministers from the leading industrialised nations announced action to tackle the financial crisis. EU. Sweden and Switzerland cut interest rates. facing a currency attack and a systemic banking crisis. When another major UK bank – RBS – required a public rescue the UK financial system came to a standstill. All these events spurred action. and banks increasingly lost confidence in the safety of lending to each other.

affecting economic growth in the emerging markets. recession trends set in and spread globally. By early November 2008. despite interest rate cuts and other state efforts to restore confidence in the economy. with the major European countries following the UK in authorising massive recapitalisation plans for their financial system. similar action was adopted by most countries affected by the credit crunch. credit to the real economy almost stopped flowing … eventually. (King 2008: 2) The possibility of an imminent breakdown in the UK’s payment system prompted the government to set up a COBRA13-style committee on the economic crisis (Winnett and Simpson 2008). these extraordinary policy efforts appeared ineffective. reacting to weakening economic data and ever more tangible signs of economic recession on both sides of the Atlantic. on 6 and 7 october even overnight funding started to dry up. the committee drafted a rescue plan (later known as the Brown-Darling bank recapitalisation plan).14 The continuing crisis and deepening recession prompted multi-level attempts to form a coordinated global policy plan to reform international financial architecture. as markets and economies continued to stumble. Over the weekend of 4–5 October 2008.T he sTaG es of T he me lT doWn 37 many institutions it was possible to borrow only overnight. The US government unveiled a $250bn (£143bn) plan to purchase a stake in a number of banks in an effort to restore confidence in the sector. and over the course of the following weeks. yet as Chapter . Nevertheless.

At the end of 2008. disagreements over the appropriate course and tone of regulatory action opened up at the transatlantic level. In March 2009. South . Official institutions adjusted their estimates of total losses to much higher levels. over the course of its two-year history. world manufactured output and world trade in manufactures had fallen off a cliff: Germany’s industrial output was down 19. Diagnoses and projections of the nature and duration of the meltdown became more and more pessimistic.38 financi al alchemy in crisis 6 below shows. or just over one year’s GDP – suffering more than other regions of the emerging markets.16 The loss of stock market wealth alone amounts to $25 trillion. the global credit crunch has transformed from a seemingly isolated sectoral crisis in the US sub-prime mortgage market into a cross-border banking and financial collapse.15 Overall. demand for manufactures.2 per cent year-on-year in January. with developing Asia – where losses totalled $9. Data reflecting real economic losses globally are sobering. the global financial crisis had been transformed into a global recession. the Asian Development Bank (ADB) reported that the crisis had precipitated a total loss of worldwide market wealth of $50 trillion.6 trillion. with some believing that the financial markets would not recover their pre-crisis levels until 2012. but is close to a year’s world output. and eventually into a global credit crunch which has directly led to a global recession. This figure not only exceeds all previous estimates of sub-prime-related losses. By 2009.

But before delving into the emergent schools of thought. as well as uncertainties over its potential effects on the economic activity and politics globally. as argued in this book. epitomises the politics and economics of the credit crunch: the fiasco of Northern Rock. let us take a closer look at one particular event that.8 per cent (in Wolf 2009). The sheer severity and scale of the global meltdown. have spawned a rash of explanations and theories of the credit crisis and its major lessons.6 per cent and Japan down 30. .T he sTaGes of T he me lT doWn 39 Korea was down 25.

congratulated Whinstone Capital Management fund – a part of the British bank Northern Rock – on winning the award for the best securitisation deal of 2005. was the first European securitisation programme to transfer ‘first-loss risk’ through a credit default swap contract. it allowed Northern Rock to offload more risk from its balance sheet. one of the financial industry’s glossy periodicals.2 the tale of northern rock: Between fInancIal InnovatIon and fraud Anastasia Nesvetailova and Ronen Palan In January 2006. explained that the Whinstone transaction allowed the fifth largest UK mortgage lender to reference the reserve funds of 13 Granite transactions. operational director for securitisation at Northern Rock. In technical terms. London’s Credit Magazine. three of which were stand-alone issues and the other ten under the Master Trust programme. ‘The beauty 40 .4 million – and one of the largest subordinated debt issuances ever in the European market. the transaction represented the largest public placement of double-B risk – £117. The deal. it was reported. David Johnson. Essentially.

Northern Rock. greed and fraud. became victims of a convoluted chain of securitisation techniques that centred on the sub-prime mortgage industry in the US. along with other high-profile financial collapses. observers on the left and right started to argue. the UK government announced a controversial decision to nationalise the bank. In the winter of 2007. reducing the value of the company to £380 million. Fortis in Belgium and most of the Icelandic banks. the bank’s shares had dropped to 90p per share. parcelling the reserve funds and writing a credit default swap thereby transferring the majority of Northern Rock’s first-loss risk to the international capital markets’ (Credit Magazine. such as Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers in the US. January 2006). * * * It is disconcerting how quickly a widely shared belief in new and better ways of managing risk has unravelled and been revealed to have been no more than a grandiose scheme of exuberance. Bradford & Bingley in the UK. he declared. that securitisation techniques had never discovered new ways of managing or optimising risk.T he Tale of norT he r n ro cK 41 of it’. they merely disguised or . quite persuasively. ‘is in its simplicity. but soon paralysed the world financial system. As the securitisation boom of the decade ground to a halt in the summer of 2007. Northern Rock was valued at £5bn. On 18 February 2008. by February 2008.

Jersey-based special purpose vehicle (SPV). how was the securitisation boom sustained for those five years? Why and how were so many dubious debts transformed into liquid assets? We believe that there were three factors supporting the boom of what Claudio Borio. driven by financial innovation. The following chapters delve deeper into the analysis of the dynamics driving this complex process. Here. second. But if the real foundations of financial health in the 2002–7 credit boom never existed. Granite. chief economist of BIS. and third. as many analysts now seem to agree. these three sets of factors can be summed up as market exuberance. 2008): first. the global expansion of the private risk management industry.42 f inancial alchemy in crisis reparcelled it. we focus on one emblematic example of the effects of this process: the fall of the Northern Rock and its offshore. a collective belief that debt – of whatever kind – can be bought and sold endlessly. has called ‘artificial liquidity’ (Borio 2000. it illustrates the extent to which the political and legislative environment set the conditions for the global crisis. regulatory evasion masquerading as innovation and sheer fraud. . The story of the fall of this bank is significant in the analysis of the political economy of the credit crunch. see also Nesvetailova 2007. Encapsulating many wider trends of the global meltdown. a regulatory environment that occluded the build-up of bad debts and dubious investment practices. 2004. Together.

The orthodox view holds that innovations in instruments and institutions improve the ability to bear risk. Hu et al. or product inventions like the myriad of new asset-backed securities and their derivatives – are in fact a reaction. channels and financial institutions was facilitated by the deregulation of global capital markets and national financial systems starting in the late 1960s (Helleiner 1994. at least within financial orthodoxy. whether direct or overt. Most theoretical interpretations of financial innovation also concur on the relationship between official regulation and the progress of private financial innovation. ultimately brings social and economic benefits and increases social welfare. 2005). Structurally. most financial innovations – be they institutional changes. rules or regulations. Although actors in the public domain tend to lag far behind advances in financial engineering. Most accounts of financial innovation explain it as a market-driven process that. . of the financial industry to official restrictions.Th e Ta le of norT h e r n ro cK 43 The controversy over financial innovation For the past three decades.g. financial innovation has been theorised and understood. Burn 1999). much like any other technological innovation in the economy. Chinloy and Macdonald 2005. lower transaction costs and circumvent outmoded regulation (Silber 1983: 93). such as the rise of the hedge fund industry. the invention of new credit products. as a technologically-driven process of ‘market completion’ (e.

respectively.g.44 fin anci al alchemy in crisis Not surprisingly. as history suggests. accounting. reflective and to a large extent cyclical. financial derivatives or mortgage securitisation (e. What is apparent at this stage is that there is no straightforward dynamic between regulation and financial innovation. Indeed. Rather. On the one hand. introduced and established in the markets in reaction to changes in official rules on taxation. as many scholars have pointed out. in light of the global crisis. Kane 1988). financial innovations are often designed. as we noted in Chapter 1. the Swiss National Bank (SNB) and the Federal Reserve (the Fed) – entered into mutual currency swap arrangements. The scheme allowed the SNB and ECB to conduct repo operations1 in US dollars against the usual collateral of the SNB and ECB. compliance and other regulatory norms (Chick 2008). tend to involve some type of new financial practice. the precise nature of the relationship between private financial innovation and public control of the financial markets has become the subject of debate in academia and the policymaking community. on the other. which. be that cross-border trade. the relationship is reciprocal. Although . in December 2007 the world’s leading central banks – the European Central Bank (ECB). But. public monetary authorities and even many analysts have lost track of the essence and purpose of many of today’s sophisticated financial products and techniques. It is also worth noting that public authorities often tend to ‘innovate’ in their own techniques and methods when reacting to financial crises.

American banks not only failed to repatriate their investments. economic and structural changes that prompt a wave of financial innovation include: (i) volatile inflation rates and interest rates. Generally. Any new product or practice needs a motive and a context in which to thrive. In fact. rather than structured or revolutionary. this example of international regulatory innovation was one of the few of its kind. Commonly.) Generally. an outcome of the complex interplay of incentives and governmental controls over finance. For instance. is. according to many critics. the interaction between regulation and innovation tends to bring out the evolutionary. and attract American funds back into the US economy. the notorious Tax Equalisation Act of 1963 was an official US response to the tendency of American banks to invest money in the highly profitable Eurocurrency markets. dating back to the late 1960s. or financialisation.T he Tale of norT he r n ro cK 45 critics at the time said that the measure was neither well coordinated nor justified by the market’s need (Buiter 2007). The Act was designed to compensate banks for the difference in interest rates between the European and the US financial systems. (The only previous example of such coordinated effort dates back to the policy response to the 9/11 attacks. therefore. the most recent wave of financial globalisation. (ii) regulatory changes and the circumvention of . but opted not to leave the Euromarket altogether (Palan 2003). character of financial globalisation. Financial innovations rarely emerge ab initio.

van Horne 1985. (iv) technological advances. (iii) tax changes. The rules of the level playing-field themselves become obstacles to some but not all.46 financial alchemy in crisis regulations. (v) the level of economic activity. and (vi). Shah’s investigation of the workings of regulatory arbitrage in the convertible bond market confirmed that companies are able to design sophisticated schemes of regulatory avoidance with . cited in shah 1997: 86) At the time. the scant literature on financial innovation observed that a great impetus to innovation in finance comes from regulatory arbitrage – ‘a desire to circumvent existing regulations in taxation and accounting. the ability to avoid regulation may provide competitive advantage to firms in the deregulated market: a legally based level playing-field opens up new sources of competitive advantage. Some 20 years ago. (mcBarnet and Whelan 1992. Both factors have been at the epicentre of the global credit meltdown generally and of the fiasco of Northern Rock in particular. cited in Shah 1997). regulation … becomes a further stimulus for innovative use of law both to defeat unwelcome regulation and to secure advantage over competitors. with some more able than others to creatively escape even harmonised regulatory restrictions. interestingly. Specifically. without necessarily breaking the law’ (Miller 1986. Two of these structural elements are pertinent to our focus on Northern Rock: the circumvention of the regulation and rules of taxation. academic work on market efficiency and inefficiencies (van Horne 1985: 622).

These elements.T he Tale of norT he r n ro cK 47 the help of investment bankers and lawyers. often. When interest rates are low and the traditional function of financial intermediation – taking deposits and lending – is no longer appealing. financial innovation has produced a skewed structure in the financial system itself. . they are also representative of more general trends in the financial industry. Thriving in this zone. In turn. were at the heart of the Northern Rock fiasco. financiers look for alternative ways to make money through commission fees. the regulators. outright fraud. Worryingly. particularly in common law countries – created a grey zone for competitive financial innovation. the media and analysts were unable to expose these practices publicly and restrain such creativity: ‘practising creative accounting is not that difficult. tax avoidance and evasion. owing to the significant grey area that exists between compliance with the rules and non-compliance or evasion … The collusion between management. The nexus between these two elements – selfregulation of the financial industry itself and the ambiguity that exists at the juncture between law and new financial practices. bankers. ‘creative accounting’ and. obscured by the general euphoria of the 2002–7 credit boom and disguised by the sophisticated techniques of modern finance. lawyers and auditors suggests that there is an avoidance industry out there which is capable of undermining the spirit behind accounting regulations’ (Shah 1997: 99).

Parmalat and. . The function of both SPVs and SPEs raises severe prudential problems. The small investor is. ‘the smarter men in the room’. Enron. at least the one least equipped to handle complex and rapidly changing information. Tax havens have made it exceedingly easy to set up offshore SPVs. but more often than not it is ‘a ghost corporation with no people or furniture and no assets either until a deal is struck’ (Lowenstein 2008). more recently. by definition. at least in part. they leave many workers without pensions and jobs. including those in East Asia and Russia. The offshore entities that seem to have caused most of the problems are the special purpose vehicles (SPVs). and have a contagious effect on the entire economy. The term SPV covers a broad range of entities. which ultimately has to bear the resulting risk without enjoying the risk premium that created it. WorldCom. Refco. have been blamed. entities (SPEs) or investment vehicles (SIVs). as one of the directors of Enron reputedly quipped. Northern Rock and the 2007–9 credit crunch. The argument is that opacity benefits those who are. But these crises revealed a more critical dimension: scandals and frauds not only cheat investors. as well as the scandals associated with the dot. on the opacity of current accounting practices and the use of affiliate entities based in tax havens either for fraudulent purposes or in pursuit of opacity (Picciotto 2009).com bubble.48 fina ncial alchemy in crisis offshore: The uses and abuses of sPVs Most financial crises in the past two decades. if not the stupidest in the room.

A report by the UK’s National Audit Office clearly suggested that they do not (NAO 2007). Ireland.3 Unsurprisingly. We have no way of knowing.2 to perform appropriate due diligence on what are very sophisticated financial vehicles. however. Murphy and Chavagneux 2010).T he Tale of norT he r n ro cK 49 yet crucially they do not have the resources. especially in terms of people. exactly how many of the world’s SPVs are based in these tax havens. Yet considering that they are competing with better equipped but almost equally unregulated centres such as London and New York. It seems pertinent to ask whether such small jurisdictions can allocate sufficient resources to monitor and regulate such colossal sums of money. Luxembourg and Jersey are attracting much of the world’s SPVs. We . The most recent data on external liabilities in all currencies suggest that about 28 per cent of cross-border lending is conducted through such jurisdictions. Most of the financial regulations introduced in the past decade are aimed more at placating the Financial Stability Forum (FSF)4 and other such organisations than at ensuring regulation (Palan. the Cayman banking system holds assets of over 500 times its GDP and Jersey holds resources of over 80 times its GDP. The only reliable indicative data can be gleaned from the BIS locational statistics. they have few incentives to ensure that appropriate due diligence and regulation are undertaken. executives of financial companies do not like to see their names mentioned in the context of scandals or fraud. There is a broad consensus that the Caymans. For example.

reported that the company created complex financial arrangements.691. that we do not see the two as being the same thing.1 The share of ofcs in international financial flows.000 .7 0. 2008. 2007 All countries Caymans Switzerland Netherlands Ireland Singapore Luxembourg Bahamas Jersey Guernsey Bahrain Isle of Man Total $29.1 0.5 1.5 326. partnerships and SPVs in order to shift debt around and make illicit payments to its directors.3 1. not to achieve bona fide economic objectives or to transfer risk’ (Powers. Table 2.164.5 761.0 % share 5. Troubb and Winokur 2002: 4). International Financial Statistics.413.8 4.3 28.8 4. Enron’s fraud was organised through 3.7bn 1.0 71.334.5 Source: BIS.8 773.9 8.2 2. The Powers Committee.1 205. The report states that ‘[m]any of the most significant transactions [of Enron] apparently were designed to accomplish favorable financial statement results.226.6 2.6 1.218.50 f inancial alchemy in crisis would like to stress. which investigated Enron’s collapse.0 1.7 0.5 436. though.2 4. SPVs hit the headlines following the collapse of Enron.3 1.3 210.

can get ready access to larger sums from the money markets. the fifth largest mortgage lender in the UK in early 2007. on the other hand. despite headline reports. that Enron’s offshore SPVs were set up primarily for tax avoidance purposes. In this context. rather. Northern Rock was different from conventional commercial banks in that it had a small deposit base and relied heavily on wholesale money markets for its funds. In 1997. Banks. began life as a building society in 1965. after the wave of demutualisations of the 1990s. northern rock and Granite Northern Rock. It appears. the fall of Northern Rock in 2007–8 raises interesting questions about the role of offshore SPVs in the global meltdown and the nature of financial innovation today more generally. Northern Rock became a public limited company. Building societies typically raise the money they lend conventionally.T he Tale of norT he r n ro cK 51 SPVs ‘with over 800 organised in well known offshore jurisdictions. Nevertheless. and about 600 using the same post office box in the Cayman Islands’ (US Senate 2002: 23). including about 120 in the Turks and Caicos. by attracting it from depositors. neither the Powers Report nor the congressional hearings demonstrated that offshore structures were palpably more poisonous that the onshore ones in the Enron case. This was an aggressive expansion technique: the audit of Northern Rock’s accounts in 2006 showed that it raised just 22 .

52

f ina nci al alchemy in crisis

per cent of its funds from retail depositors and at least 46 per cent from bonds. It was this risky financing technique that gained Northern Rock its award for the best securitisation deal of the year in January 2006. Crucially, the bonds that were so instrumental in Northern Rock’s financial success were not issued by the bank itself but by what became known as its ‘shadow company’. This was Granite Master Issuer plc and its associates, an entity formally owned not by Northern Rock but by a charitable trust established by Northern Rock. After the bank failed it transpired that the trust had never paid anything to the charity; the charity in turn was not even aware that the scheme existed. The sole purpose of Granite was, in fact, to form a part of Northern Rock’s financial engineering that guaranteed that Northern Rock was legally independent of Granite, and that the latter was, therefore, solely responsible for the debt it issued. This was plainly a masquerade and one that was helped by the fact that the trustees of the Granite structure were, at least in part, based in St Helier, Jersey. When journalists tried to locate these employees they found none could be found in Jersey. In fact, an investigation of Granite’s accounts showed it had no employees at all, despite having nearly £50bn of debt. The entire structure was acknowledged to be managed by Northern Rock and, unusually, was treated as being ‘on balance sheet’ of Northern Rock and thus included in its consolidated accounts.

Th e Ta le of norT h e r n ro cK

53

As the credit boom unravelled, Northern Rock faced a dilemma. Granite was used to securitise parcels of mortgages on the money market through bond issues. When in August 2007 the money market lost its appetite for that debt, Northern Rock’s business model malfunctioned: it could no longer refinance the debt. Consequently, it had to support Granite in meeting the obligations it had entered into with its bondholders, even though the company was notionally independent. A similar confusion arose as to whether the company was onshore or offshore. In practice it included elements of both. When Northern Rock was eventually nationalised, debates in the House of Commons ran late into the night: MPs aimed to establish whether the nationalisation of the bank meant that Granite was also nationalised. Yvette Cooper, chief secretary to the UK Treasury, stated that ‘Granite is not owned by Northern Rock; nor will it pass into the hands of the public sector’ (Hansard 2008: col. 277). Alistair Darling reiterated this in a letter to Vince Cable, Liberal Democrat shadow chancellor, on 20 February 2008: ‘Granite is an independent legal entity owned by its shareholders … Northern Rock owns no shares in Granite’ (Accounting Web 2008). In the very same parliamentary debate, however, Cooper also confirmed that ‘Granite is part of the funding mechanism for Northern Rock and it is on the bank’s balance sheet’ (ibid.). So how could Granite be part of the Northern Rock’s funding mechanism and yet be a separate entity? The precise ownership structure of Granite companies

54

financi al alchemy in crisis

and its financial relationship with Northern Rock are murky. Because Granite is a Jersey-incorporated vehicle and protected under the secrecy laws of Jersey (generally considered an offshore financial centre), there is no way of knowing who really is the trustee of Granite. Consequently, the issue was never resolved. No one seemed to know whether a company wholly managed by a state-owned enterprise but notionally owned by a charitable trust was under state control or not. Despite that, the government had little choice but to extend its guarantee to the Granite bondholders. The consensus is that the Jersey-based offshore structure was used as a securitisation vehicle for mortgages issued by Northern Rock. It is suspected that Granite served as an equivalent of a price transfer channel for the bank, a means by which it could transfer profits earned in the UK to Jersey’s near-zero tax regime. In February 2008, an anonymous source close to Granite admitted that ‘the obligations on Northern Rock as an originator of mortgages continue to exist … It is a financial reality’ (cited in Accounting Web 2008). According to this source, in the event of Northern Rock not supplying Granite with mortgages, it would have to repay the £49bn owed to its investors. In the worst-case scenario, therefore, British taxpayers were to pay twice for Northern Rock: first to nationalise it, and then to honour the bank’s obligations to Granite, which in turn, may be owned by Northern Rock. In the winter of 2008 some MPs raised questions about the precise links between Northern Rock and Granite, but no clear

T he Tale of norT he r n ro cK

55

answers have been forthcoming. In the meantime, the unfolding financial malaise shifted political concerns to the UK’s increasingly shaky financial system. The confusion created by Granite’s structure is indicative of the larger-scale problem that the use of SPVs, often ‘orphaned’ from their parent through the artificial use of charitable trusts to break nominal control, can create. Yet such structures are commonplace throughout the offshore world and have been widely used for the securitisation of sub-prime mortgages. Curiously, Northern Rock was a relatively ‘clean’ case compared to many; yet when it failed, it exposed the great uncertainty as to how to deal with the resulting situation on the part of almost every regulator who approached the scene. This ambiguity lingered even after Northern Rock had been nationalised and received additional rescue funds from the public. While the government may have settled the issue at Northern Rock, despite the unresolved nature of its relationship with Granite, the existence of so many orphaned SPVs, holding billion upon billion of debts, yet legally separated from their parents, has unnerved banks and investors, contributing in turn to paralysis in wholesale financial markets. In this instance, the fall of Northern Rock is also emblematic of the wider impact of the regulatory background to the credit crunch. Specifically, the way the bank’s failure was handled by the tripartite structure of financial governance in the UK highlights

the information-gathering body. According to this ‘tripartite’ arrangement. In Northern Rock’s case. As Willem Buiter argues. formalised a division of labour between the Treasury. the arrangement failed in a number of ways. the separation of the function of information-gathering and processing and the organisational resource capacity simply does not work: ‘the main problem with the arrangement is that it puts the information about individual banks in a different agency (FSA) from the agency with the liquid financial resources to provide short-term assistance to a troubled bank (BoE)’ (Buiter 2008: 17–18). then Chancellor of the Exchequer. In 1997. This division of labour was supposed to make the overall maintenance of financial stability more efficient by facilitating a clear distinction between the micro. and the Treasury for the overall institutional structure of financial regulation and the legislation which governs it. First. the Bank of England and the newly established Financial Services Authority (FSA). Gordon Brown. the FSA for prudential supervision of financial institutions and market segments.56 fina nci al alchemy in crisis several fundamental problems that financial regulators encounter in the age of thriving financial innovation. the FSA. failed to compile an accurate picture of the financial .and macro-approaches to financial regulation and became ‘a result of the Bank’s efforts to ensure that oversight of the financial system did not fall between the gaps in the new institutional structure of supervision’ (Ryback 2006: 7). the Bank of England is responsible for monetary policy and systemic financial stability.

Second. The fact that Northern Rock – which held approximately 20 per cent of the mortgage market – raised three-quarters of its funds through short-term borrowings did not alert the supervisors. other parties to the tripartite arrangement are blamed for the Northern Rock fiasco as well.000 staff working at the FSA. only three were reportedly dealing with Northern Rock. the FSA’s implementation of the few rules on liquidity risk also raised concerns. Probing questions about the bank’s finance model (relying on wholesale markets for funds) and its liquidity position were never asked. Of the 3. and of Northern Rock in particular.T he Tale of norT he r n ro cK 57 health of the bank. The Treasury has been . which was clearly not adequate to form an accurate picture of risk exposures in an environment where most risks are ‘marked to market’ and are therefore extremely volatile. The supervisory reviews of the bank’s books were only conducted every three years.5 Third. It transpires that the FSA had neither the knowledge nor the resources to oversee and make sense of the growing complexity of securitised portfolios of individual banks. which drained much-needed cash from a bank tightly dependent on the ailing sub-prime market in the US. The Bank of England and its Governor have been criticised for acting too slowly or simply being out of touch with the developments in the markets and the risks involved in the securitisation process. Northern Rock was allowed to pay out large dividends to its shareholders. In the midst of the unravelling crisis (July 2007).

Why nothing was done in the years that followed and why the bank was encouraged to continue with its aggressive and dubious financial strategy remains. as is maintained in this book. the Treasury was told that Northern Rock might run out of money. Applegarth reportedly was paid a $1. by taking the initiative in the Northern Rock case. In the midst of the collapse. When he resigned. imposing a political solution to nationalise the bank (Lascelles 2007). he cashed in shares worth more than £2 million. The Northern Rock crisis has raised many issues about how private financial gains and socialised losses are addressed by political leaders. On 14 August 2007. was paid $1.5 million bonus. on 14 September 2007. (In 2006. the Treasury did nothing to prevent the collapse (Moulton 2008).58 financial alchemy in crisis faulted for overriding the terms of the agreement and. the tripartite arrangement as a whole failed in the task of passing information from the FSA to the Treasury.36 million. Most scandalously of all. in the summer of 2009 the Financial Times would reveal that a special simulation test conducted by the Bank of England in 2004 had detected a strong likelihood that Northern Rock and other UK banks would go into crisis. is one of the many uncomfortable puzzles of the credit crunch. During 2007. Northern Rock’s former CEO. Adam Applegarth. the bank’s senior management were . Fourth. In the period between those dates. a month later. the bank did just that.

vehicle of financial innovation. sweeping under the carpet the complex legal situation . Rather. Merrill Lynch and UBS. the tale of Northern Rock raises concerns about how many other companies might be benefiting from similar schemes through the use of structured finance and complex investment pyramids. The scheme that Northern Rock set up with its Jersey SPV illustrates one of the problems the financial markets face. The list which links the names of the world’s largest investment banks with an obscure offshore financial scheme suggests that bad debts. a regime that has made the pyramid (or Ponzi) principle a legitimate. The secrecy and lack of transparency offered by offshore financial centres facilitate outright scams. JP Morgan and Morgan Stanley. and prominent. underwriters were Barclays Capital. preventing public authorities from adjudicating in cases when private financial manipulation leads to systemic risks and public losses (Palan 2003). quasi-legal Ponzi schemes or regulatory avoidance techniques.) But apart from this. The UK government was prepared to accept the arrangement.T he Tale of norT he r n ro cK 59 offered £100. Citigroup.000 in compensation pay. the crisis is the outcome of a political and legal regime which has facilitated the privatisation of gains from financial risks at the cost of socialising their losses – in other words. sub-prime lending and hence the current crisis are not the outcome of one malfunctioning institution. market segment or even a financial model. Lead underwriters on the Granite programme were Lehman Brothers.

60 fina nci al alchemy in crisis it found itself in. banks and other financial intermediaries have no recourse but to rely on each other’s goodwill. but in times of crisis it proves extremely damaging. Ambiguity of this sort may be ignored in good times. with its use of an obscure finance scheme and. a Ponzi investment principle. and hence stability. Specifically. As is argued in the following chapters. Private investors are not as forgiving. the crisis was brought about by the multifaceted illusion of liquidity that. as the following chapters show. while temporarily . The web of offshore entities. The fall of Northern Rock. why so many dubious debts were regarded as safe investment vehicles for so long. of the economic system that precipitated the global meltdown. In other words. one answer to this puzzle (and some others) of the credit crunch centres on the contentious notion of liquidity in finance today. knowing full well that most if not all of their counterparties holding accounts and SPVs offshore are beyond the scrutiny of any regulatory authority. namely. orphaned and legally separated yet holding massive amounts of debts. essentially. plays a crucial role in perpetrating mistrust – and for good reasons. it was a flawed understanding of the effects of financial innovations on the liquidity. raises another concern about the systemic role of financial innovation today. In contemporary finance. where at least half of all international lending is conducted through offshore jurisdictions and such ambiguous arrangements.

But before we turn to this part of the story.T he Tale of norT he r n ro cK 61 profitable. it is worth examining how the crisis has been understood so far and what questions about the global credit crunch remain unanswered. in the end proved to be a dangerous and destructive myth. .

broadly there are two ways to differentiate and classify the rapidly evolving theorisations of the credit crunch: on the basis of time and on their theoretical grounding. are those that warned about the possibility of such a collapse – and eventually predicted it – before the events of 2007 engulfed world markets. as the term suggests. 62 . These range from popular commentary. blogs on crisis-related issues and journalistic investigations. Whilst readings of the crisis do overlap. this chapter aims to systematise the spectrum of emerging views on the nature and implications of the financial meltdown. to high-profile policy discussions commissioned by official bodies and academic analyses. Ex-Ante and Ex-Post Visions of the credit crunch At first cut. The ex-ante theories. Ex-post explanations were put forward once the crisis started to engulf world markets. Focusing mainly on the latter. credit crunch theories can be divided into ex-ante and ex-post explanations.3 how the crIsIs has Been understood The continuing economic malaise has produced a whole industry of credit crunch analytics.

the sheer sense that the Anglo-Saxon economies were overheating and asset and financial bubbles would soon burst. conflicts of interest and profound structural dislocations). and deeper scholarly analyses of the credit system that detected profound abnormalities and tensions accumulating in the economies of ‘advanced’ Anglo-Saxon capitalism. as well as globalising trends across markets. Apart from the timing. Here.hoW T he crisis has B een un de r s Too d 63 Within this rather broad classification. and to what extent one can talk about a distinctly ‘new’ type of political economy in the twenty-first century (as defined by revolutions in technology. the basic difference between these two schools of thought is their reading of the place of finance in the evolution of capitalism more broadly. communications and finance. the distinction focuses on what is ‘normal’ and what is ‘abnormal’ in the structure and functioning of the economic system. The ex-post theories can in turn be classified into those that view the credit crunch as a cyclical event and those that see it as a structural crisis. the ex-ante theories originated both in a simple ‘gut-feeling’ understanding of what was happening in the financial markets. as opposed to ‘capitalism as usual’ (a system marked by periodic crises. polities and cultures). Whereas more pessimistic predictions of the imminent collapse of US debt-driven consumption . Specifically. an important element shaping the different opinions is the role that consumption and debt have come to play in the countries of Anglo-Saxon capitalism.

the dominant mood in the markets during 2002–7 is probably best expressed in the admission of a risk manager of a global bank. The Global Credit Crunch as an Exogenous Shock Within this ex-post group of analyses. who preferred to remain anonymous: We were paid to think about the downsides but it was hard to see where the problems would come from. low interest rates. during the credit boom such ideas were at best taken as purely hypothetical and remote possibilities. penalised.64 financial alchemy in crisis emphasised the destructive role of unprecedented levels of debt in the US and the global economy. making the economy more flexible. market regulators. four years of falling credit spreads. Ultimately. they were simply dismissed or. the deregulation of the financial system has popularised access to credit and finance. one interpretation of the crisis stands out: the reading of the global credit crunch as a ‘surprise’ event – a shock that took most financiers. as argued from these perspectives. worse. efficient and diversified. And although in the wake of the crisis many market traders have confessed that they understood full well that the bubble could not continue to expand indefinitely. virtually no defaults in our loan portfolio . political leaders and observers totally by surprise. In most cases. Instead. many ex-post theories of the credit crunch interpret the rise of debt and consumption as sustainable and constructive features of the new type of economy.

The fact that such a ‘correction’ spilled over into a global financial meltdown came as a shock that ruptured the workings of most financial systems around the world. In this sense. reflecting a price correction in one isolated sector of the global economy – the US sub-prime mortgage sector (Dymski 2009). In hindsight. they comment that complacency and collective reliance on fashionable techniques of trade and risk valuation have taken the markets into the crisis. the crisis should have been a relatively minor event in finance. crisis or painful recession. 7 august 2008) As a result. whether small or large. this logic seems rather odd. We said then: ‘Well hell. and that some events in the markets in 2006 had implied that the credit boom might unravel. All booms. the air of general optimism translated into pervasive short-termism and lack of basic foresight and accountability among market players: … things go in cycles. even if risk managers did acknowledge that the history of finance offers unsettling lessons about bubbles and crises.’ (in Gimson 2008) Moreover. (The Economist. taking the real economy into recession. it doesn’t matter if i’m running up the money on my credit cards because next year i’m going to earn more. typically with a crash. according to his colleague at Barings. anyone who believes things are going to go on up forever is a fool. everyone borrowing up to their eyeballs.hoW Th e crisis has B e en un de r s To o d 65 and historically low volatility levels: it was the most benign risk environment we had seen in 20 years. eventually come to an end. The fact that house prices and the . we went through this in the eighties and early nineties.

Williams et al. Academically. as we shall see in Chapter 4). finance and credit are only one facet – albeit a defining one – of the general short-termism of contemporary society as a whole. Yet there are also reasons why long-term historical regularities and warning signs were ignored or dismissed. 2002). Langley 2008. They concern a peculiar anthropology. Second. Seabrooke 2006. brand or logo capitalism. the financial system itself has come to be defined by the paradigm and practice of scientific finance (Greenspan 2001. typically with excellent and highly specialised training in mathematics and physics. the changed character of work and. The many other dimensions of such short-termism include changing patterns of production. To begin with. Blackburn 2006. as a culmination. these professionals have no . the rise of the digital economy. The major engine of financial innovation today is in the hands of a class of young and narrowly educated geeks. Having embarked on a career in finance or banking in the past 10–20 years. the unprecedented rise of the financial sector to a dominant position in the economy. Montgomerie 2009). yet often having minimal understanding of the ways the economic system works as a whole. demography and the political economy of today’s financial industry. this process has been viewed as the financialisation of everyday life (Martin 2003.66 financi al alchemy in crisis financial sector’s profits grew exponentially in a decade to historically unprecedented levels in all Anglo-Saxon economies should have alerted many people (as in fact it did. 2008.

. their role was to make the sophisticated and complex financial markets work more efficiently. as one insurance broker noted: We did the south sea Bubble at school. as far as this new generation was concerned. Criticised for his direct role in creating the bubble of easy credit during the 1990s/early 2000s. they would tend to interpret these as dark episodes in the ‘older’ type of capitalism (and hence irrelevant to the ‘new economy’ of the twenty-first century) or as isolated collapses of companies that miscalculated in their investment strategies and thus do not represent any of the main trends in finance. and many might remember the collapse of Barings in 1995 or the 1998 LTCM fiasco. therefore. so we know how it works … it was clear that the property bubble was going to burst but it would have been nice if it had deflated slowly rather than popped. The fact that this wonderful system could unravel so quickly and with such disastrous consequences came as a shock – a nasty one – to many of them. Interestingly. While most of them would be familiar with the story of the 1929 Crash. (in Gimson 2008) During the boom years of 2002–7. Indeed.hoW T he crisis has B een un de r s Too d 67 memory of earlier recessions or even structural financial crises. by applying scientific approaches to managing risk and various quantitative methods of valuing the balance of risks and rewards for a particular company or class of assets. the ‘shock’ vision of the global crisis has also been common in courtrooms and on news screens.

one of the Bear Stearns executives charged with a nine-count indictment of conspiracy and securities and wire fraud. But sometimes the reality is that defining moments of history come suddenly and without warning … an economic hurricane has swept the world. Lord Turner. The British prime minister. the risks unleashed and accentuated by the . Indeed. regulators and policymakers also tend to emphasise the extraordinary character of the crisis and the fact that it took most people by surprise. (Brown. it simply does not make sense to view the crisis as a surprise or shock. Gordon Brown. noted: ‘In April of this year everybody knew that something pretty big had happened to the world’s financial system. his lawyer argued: ‘the credit crisis took everyone by surprise. including the Fed and the Treasury. creating a crisis of credit and of confidence. In October 2008. however. was how extreme it was going to be …’ (Financial Times. Baffled and incapacitated by the scope of the meltdown. bluntly. What we had no idea. Defending Ralf Cioffi. 17 October 2008). Dozens of the largest financial institutions in the world have lost over $300 billion to date on the same investments’ (Kelly 2008). 4 march 2009) Outside the courtroom. followed the same line: We tend to think of the sweep of destiny as stretching across many months and years before culminating in decisive moments we call history. a newly appointed boss of the FSA.68 financi al alchemy in crisis Alan Greenspan called the crisis a ‘once-in-a-century phenomenon’ (Greenspan 2008b).

or – in the case of the crises of the LTCM. and increases the likelihood of operational problems. certainly a once-in-a-career.hoW T he crisis has B een un de r s Too d 69 securitisation process. Parmalat. as well as the fragility of the US mortgage market and the economy as a whole. the global financial system seemed to have worked smoothly and efficiently for several decades. Either way. When it did experience breakdowns (in 1982. 1987. event. 1994–5. they were easily dismissed as problems specific to the financial structure of the emerging market economies. (White 2006: 5–6) So what should one make of ‘shock’ explanations of the credit crunch? On the one hand. the reliance of banks in many countries on revenues from dealing with the household sector. it is understandable why many market practitioners and politicians view the global crisis as a once-in-a-lifetime. had been noted repeatedly by many commentators long before the boom started to unravel in the summer of 2007. already heavily indebted. more broadly. 1997–8 and 2000). etc. – as isolated episodes reflecting troubles in individual firms. could in the future prove a source of financial vulnerability … [T]hese exposures might also have increased over time in response to successive episodes of monetary easing and associated credit expansion. According to the philosophy of self-regulating and self-correcting markets. To take just one example. none of the financial crises of the past 30 years was understood . William White of BIS observed in 2006: … the opacity and complexity of the financial system today shrouds in secrecy who finally bears the risks. Enron.

16 March 2008). as the term suggests. the gloomy autumn of 2007. both intellectually and politically. sustainable and historically unprecedented levels of development and growth. In this light. On the other hand. and policy in the future will be informed by these lessons. Greenspan. Every crisis. essentially because it did not reflect systemic flaws in the financial systems of the core. Thus the ‘shock’ theory of the crisis has some superficial plausibility. Yet characterising the global crisis as an extraordinary episode. ‘advanced’ capitalism – until. and involves an element of a shock. these explanations are simply unhelpful: stressing its immediate effects. these theories make it impossible to draw any long-term lessons about the nature of the crisis in its historical context. reflects a lack of anticipation and foresight. believes that it is impossible to draw any lessons about the financial system in the future: ‘In the current crisis. as in past crises. it is telling that the thesis about the ‘shock’ of . while recognising the crisis as potentially ‘the worst since World War II’. we can learn much.70 f inanci al alchemy in crisis to require a global response. that is. explains nothing in terms of its real causes. for instance. while emphasising the scale of the disaster. But we cannot hope to anticipate the specifics of future crises with any degree of confidence’ (Greenspan. or a once-in-a-lifetime event. Moreover. The sheer scale of the global meltdown certainly came as a shock to all of those who thought that financial capitalism had reached new. the ‘exogenous shock’ interpretations of the crisis are problematic.

At the same time. they tend to see the credit crunch as a crisis of Anglo-Saxon capitalism more generally: while it is in finance that the crisis has been most apparent. social. cultural and ideological foundations of market-based capitalism. Thus emphasising the historical origins of the current crisis. structural theorists view it as a specific. but largely predictable result of the operation of a type of economy that had replaced the Keynesian welfare state of the . the emergent theories of the credit crunch have incorporated deeper scholarly inquiries into the nature of finance today. these views can be classified as structural or cyclical explanations of the global meltdown. Broadly.hoW T h e crisis has B e en un de r s To o d 71 the global meltdown has become one of the dominant theories of the credit crunch in policymaking circles in both the UK and US. overlapping the political. As such. The ‘exogenous shock’ readings of the global meltdown therefore appear opportune to those who are reluctant to question the underlying belief in the selfcorrecting forces of the market and interpret all major disruptions – however frequent – as extraordinary events. in reality the meltdown is more pervasive. economic. structural Theories of the credit crunch The Crisis of Anglo-Saxon Capitalism Theories that come under this heading aim to inquire into the long-term causes of the financial meltdown.

individuals in the UK held over £1. Gamble 2009. the consumer-driven pattern of recovery from previous crises and a general hedonistic basis of socioeconomic relationships that have come to define the culture of American-style capitalism (Altvater 1997. Shiller 2008.374. and total private sector debt had risen from 133. higher than in any other major industrialised economy. have been growing much faster than incomes and wages in the Anglo-Saxon economies. Wade 2008. And according to Turner (2008). The levels of borrowings. In the US over the course of the decade. debt-financed consumption. minimal savings. and its role in the overall economic organisation. In 2007. is the key structural cause of the meltdown. 2002.5 trillion in debt. deregulated capital markets.5 per cent of GDP to 227. The financial meltdown of 2007–9 is thus only a reflection of many other deep-seated crisis tendencies brewing in the structure of this model – a crisis brought about by a combination of short-term policy targets. etc. Debt.5bn. the growth of debt-financed consumption and business activity has been more pronounced in the UK. Pettifor 2003. Turner 2008.4 per cent during the first ten years of the New Labour government.1bn to $14. Tily 2007. The ratio of debt . The debt-driven culture has produced its own category of ‘new poor’ – the middle classes – who now account for the bulk of personal debt (Pettifor 2003).).72 f inanci al alchemy in crisis 1950s–1960s with a neoliberal model of capitalism. both private and corporate. personal debt jumped from $5. leaving the country more vulnerable to the effects of the credit crunch.547.

as an inevitable result of the Anglo-Saxon mode of capitalist organisation. and thus unravelled. This vast growth of debt was evolving into what George Soros (2008) has called a ‘super-bubble’ – a concoction of a housing bubble. both the credit super-bubble and debt-financed consumerism were unsustainable. or what Greenspan called ‘active credit management’ (in Morris 2008: 61). In this instance. Emphasising the role of key features of such a model. sparked by the fiasco of the sub-prime industry in the US. Many historically-oriented and systemic visions see the crisis. therefore. it is interesting that another group of structural theories of the credit crunch takes . In the long run.hoW T he crisis has B een un de r s To o d 73 to disposable income went up from 93. these economies have been affected by the credit meltdown not through their own role in the credit super-bubble but through the externalisation of the crisis from the US financial system to the global level. therefore. an explosion of leveraged buyouts and other financial excesses. they also point out that economies that have followed a different trajectory – such as the ‘welfare’ capitalism of continental European states or the Asian developmental economies – have escaped the excesses of financial speculation and debt-dependent growth.4 per cent to a post-1945 record of 139 per cent (Turner 2008: 26–7). Essentially. These in turn were unleashed by a regime of historically cheap and easy credit which was made possible in the era of low consumer price inflation and aggressive competition among financial institutions for new profits.

Essentially. effectively blaming the crisis on the role of emerging markets – mainly East Asian exporters – in skewing the balance in the world macro-economy. The abnormality has been noted by many. International Imbalances: Naughty Asian Exporters This school of thought views the credit crunch as a result of a structural discrepancy at the international level. channeling domestic saving away from local uses and into international capital markets. the crisis is the unwitting outcome of an abnormal state of affairs in world financial flows. Trying to rebuild their economies in the wake of the 1990s crises. so the argument goes.74 financial alchemy in crisis a diametrically opposite view. a shift that has transformed those economies from borrowers on international capital markets to large net lenders’ (Bernanke 2005). not least by the economist Ben Bernanke. with the funds coming from a combination of reduced fiscal deficits and increased domestic . the governments of these countries have acted as financial intermediaries. He then elaborated on why the Asian countries and other raw material exporters chose to transfer their savings to the mature markets. who in 2005 explained the huge increase of US current account deficit by ‘a remarkable reversal in the flows of credit to developing and emerging-market economies. a related strategy has focused on reducing the burden of external debt by attempting to pay down those obligations.

hoW T he crisis has B een un de r s Too d 75 debt issuance. Within the US. resulted in a ‘global savings glut’. Overall.1 current account imbalances as a Percentage of GdP (1975 Q1–2006 Q4) source: Bracke and fidora 2008. reducing US national savings and contributing to the nation’s rising current account deficit. Bernanke argued. this strategy also pushed emergingmarket economies toward current account surpluses.) 6 4 2 0 –2 –4 –6 –8 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 6 4 2 0 –2 –4 –6 –8 Emerging Asia United States 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 Figure 3. together with the high saving propensities of Germany. and to diffuse it efficiently through the advanced system of financial intermediation to those who were assumed to be best placed to bear it: . (ibid. Japan and some of the other major industrial nations. widening homeownership was supported and facilitated by securitisation – the ability of financiers to price the risk in mortgages and other loans. This glut boosted US equity values during the stock market boom and helped to increase US home values during the more recent period as a consequence. of necessity. this shift by developing nations.

the secondary market helped stimulate widespread competition in the mortgage business. Within this unique arrangement. reflected ‘the exceptional depth and liquidity of the US financial markets. The mortgagebacked security helped create a national and even an international market for mortgages … This led to securitisation of a variety of other consumer loan products. By reducing the risk of making long-term. Dollar reserves. fixed-rate loans and ensuring liquidity for mortgage lenders. 1 The bank commented that ‘conditions in the major financial markets remained calm and accommodative for much of 2005 and early 2006. in turn. a similar understanding of the global liquidity glut was of fered by the BIS. reflecting the surprisingly strong performance of the world economy and still abundant liquidity’ (BIS 2006: 98). the new financial relationship between the emerging markets and advanced capitalist economies became so paramount to world economic stability that it was even named a ‘Bretton Woods 2 system’. such as auto and credit card loans. (Greenspan 2005) At the time. However ‘abnormal’ though.76 financial alchemy in crisis The development of a broad-based secondary market for mortgage loans also greatly expanded consumer access to credit. it was argued. the US could run massive trade deficits without seeing the dollar fall against the currencies of the ‘periphery’ because the latter were anxious to accumulate dollars and maintain their position in the American market. which makes it attractive for .

2 –30. 41.5 205.0 11.3 –30.9 29.0 148.5 Statistical discrepancy Source: Bernanke 2005.3 –10.3 45.5 20.6 25.7 –23.2 Middle East and Africa 5.0 3.1 –20.2 88.7 47.8 –13.1 137.5 55.2 –342.9 –87.9 4.1 Global current account Balances.8 5.9 17.8 7.5 24.4 –39.hoW T he crisis has Be en un de r s To o d 77 Table 3.1 –6.4 17.5 –15.1 10.4 12.9 –14. 1996 and 2003 (billions of us dollars) Countries Industrial United States Japan Euro Area France Germany Italy Spain Other Australia Canada Switzerland United Kingdom Developing Asia China Hong Kong Korea Taiwan Thailand Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico 1996 2003 46.5 –40.8 –23.0 –8.6 0.4 4.2 –530.8 3.3 –120.4 138.1 42.9 Eastern Europe and former Soviet Union –13.3 .4 21.3 8.8 7.4 39.2 –2.6 –23.2 –2.7 65.

78

financi al alchemy in crisis

other countries to hold assets in this form’ (Eichengreen 2007: 2–4). In the meantime, the Asian exporting countries were criticised for keeping their debt markets underdeveloped and shallow: ‘Large Asian holdings of U.S. debt are usually attributed to the region’s penchant for undervalued home currencies, which lead to chronic trade surpluses and a buildup of foreign reserves.’ Such excess liquidity, or savings glut, according to observers, was stunting their growth.2 The explanation was found to be in the nature of market openness and competition: according to market commentators, Asian savings tend to sit in savings accounts, creating vast pools of liquidity that enable banks to offer mortgages and loans at rates with which the originators of securitised loans cannot compete. Analysts at the time concluded that ‘a liquidity glut is mitigating against Asia’s capacity to generate an adequate supply of financial assets that will allow it to keep its savings at home’ (Mukherjee 2007). As the securitisation boom imploded, proponents of the ‘liquidity glut’ were quick to identify the root cause of the credit crunch. It was not so much the debt embedded in the structure of the economies, but the global savings glut coming from the Asian exporters. Barry Eichengreen, for instance, while recognising the role of the ideology of deregulation and self-governed finance, commented that the crisis was produced by ‘the change in the global financial landscape [that] is the rise of China and the emerging-market savings glut that flooded U.S. markets with cheap funds’ (Eichengreen

hoW Th e crisis has B e en un de r s To o d

79

2009: 2). At about the same time, Hank Paulson, outgoing US Treasury Secretary, diagnosed the causes of the crisis in his own way:
superabundant savings from fast-growing emerging nations … put downward pressure on risks and yield spreads everywhere … This laid the seeds of the credit bubble that extends far beyond the us sub-prime mortgage market and now has burst with devastating consequences … (Paulson, in Guha 2009)

As can be seen, the credit crunch has long-term causes, those specific to the countries of Anglo-Saxon capitalism and those reflecting the international scene, as reflected in the ‘global liquidity glut’ theses. Politically, these diagnoses may be quite uncomfortable. While the emphasis on the role of debt-driven consumption places the blame for the crisis on the political institutions and ideology of market-led capitalism, theories based on the argument about international imbalances effectively tell the story of the crisis as precipitated by naughty Asian exporters, thus absolving the agents and institutions of finance in supposedly advanced economies of their share of responsibility for the global meltdown. Arguments between the two camps will surely linger in the wake of the global meltdown. What is important to note is that while reflecting the broader historical and geopolitical context of the credit crunch, these views rarely delve into the trends that defined the specific character of the 2002–7 financial bubble. In order to understand such trends and their role in the crisis, we turn next to the cyclical explanations of the credit crunch.

80

f inancial alchemy in crisis

cyclical Theories of the crisis
The End of the 2002–7 Credit Boom Chronologically, the global credit crunch came as the end of the preceding housing and credit boom centred on the North Atlantic economies. This ‘boom-and-bust’ sequence led to a common reading of the crisis that has its origins in the business cycle theory of finance and economy. At its core, the theory derives from the Austrian school of political economy and is based on the assumption that in the long run any economic system necessarily goes through periods of boom and bust, expansion and contraction. Crises therefore are cyclical – or transient – events, marking the natural ‘bottoming out’ points of economic activity between the two major phases of the cycle – expansion (boom) and contraction (bust). In this view, any crisis is caused by, and reflects, the dynamics specific to the expansionary period in question, as opposed to being the outcome of a more inherent – structural – disruption to the political-economic system as whole. This vision, therefore, makes crises appear natural, normalising events in the course of the economic cycle. In the context of the global credit crunch, the business cycle approach to crisis is built on the argument that the crisis originates in a problem specific to the 2002–7 expansion of the credit system. At its heart lies the problem of pricing risk. According to cyclical explanations, the underlying cause of the continuing malaise is the markets’ increasing tendency

hoW T he crisis has B een un de r s To o d

81

to under-price financial risks during the boom years of 2002–7. Thus the booming housing market, low inflationary monetary policy, constant competitive drive among banks and financial houses for commissions and aggressive techniques of investment, underpinned by expectations of unbroken increases in housing values, have blunted the financial sector’s ability to value risks and rewards accurately. This in turn pushed investors into more risky assets and techniques of trade:
… although the sub-prime debacle triggered the crisis, the developments in the u.s. mortgage market were only one aspect of a much larger and more encompassing credit boom … aspects of this broader credit boom included widespread declines in underwriting standards, breakdowns in lending oversight by investors and rating agencies, increased reliance on complex and opaque credit instruments that proved fragile under stress, and unusually low compensation for risk-taking. (Bernanke, 13 January 2009)

Many factors contributed to the problem of mispricing risk. These include permissive monetary policy, a conflict of interest in credit rating agencies, some more technical problems with models and techniques of pricing risks commonly used by financial institutions, such as value-at-risk (VAR) models, as well as a lack of effective regulatory oversight over the markets:
regulation, or the alleged lack thereof, was indirectly to blame for the crisis through providing the illusion of control and involving banks and the fsa in endless detailed matters that distracted them from the big picture. furthermore, regulation of conventional financial services drove banks into unknown areas, notably the use of financial

the crisis was the result of long-run efforts by Anglo-Saxon governments to encourage low-income people to become homeowners. one strand of interpretation stands out in particular. behavioural and market-specific – that together diverted the markets away from a correct strategy and attitude to pricing risks. the cyclical theory stands in stark contrast to those views which emphasise that the sheer magnitude of the crisis calls for an overhaul of the entire edifice of finance. importantly. This socially motivated policy has relaxed lending criteria in the financial industry and pushed financial institutions into risky and opaque areas. Also. cyclical views of the credit crunch accommodate another crucial aspect of financial volatility: the human factor. which ultimately proved unsafe. securitisation and complex derivatives. the crisis was caused by a combination of factors – policy-related. it is argued.82 f inanci al alchemy in crisis packages. Altogether. As such. the cyclical theory of the credit crunch holds that the credit boom of 2002–7 and it subsequent bust in 2007–9 did not reflect structural or systemic flaws in the financial system as such. (ambler 2008: 8) Generally. therefore. Incompetence and Exuberance Within the range of cyclical theories of the crisis. . The Human Factor: Greed. including the paradigm of financial regulation and governance. Rather.

as well as a lack of transparency or. which became the defining feature of the most recent bout of securitisation. What makes these analyses distinct is that their advocates. and second.hoW Th e crisis has B e en un de r s To o d 83 Broadly. supervisors and policymakers). The focus of these theories tends to be twofold: first. The two problems. while intertwined. opacity of financial practice. These include the erosion of incentives for financial dealers to be prudent when taking on risks and the lack of proper incentives (such as pay) for regulators to attract and retain personnel sufficiently competent to keep up with the latest innovations in the financial markets. it is the problem of the knowledge or expertise gap associated with the process of financial innovation. while viewing the crisis as the inevitable end of the preceding credit boom. stress different aspects of financial transformation. it can be called the ‘greed. The ‘skewed incentive structure’ argument captures managerial and institutional problems associated with the changes in banking and financial systems generally. it is the so-called skewed structure of incentives affecting both the agents of financial innovation (market actors) and those who are tasked with overseeing the process (financial regulators. The ‘expertise gap’ thesis relates to the dilemma of asymmetric information that financial agents and market regulators tend to encounter. . place greater emphasis on some of the implications of the process of financial innovation and competition. incompetence and exuberance’ school. simply.

’ In the 1940s. before they got to a position of responsibility. have no sense of responsibility. There was always someone overseeing someone to see things didn’t go too far. years of it. One anonymous 78-year-old accountant. they entered straight from university and were allowed to take extraordinary risks: ‘They’ve been doing it for years but it’s been hidden …’ A 43-year-old fiduciary risk manager at Barings agreed: ‘Everyone borrowing up to their eyeballs. They’ve been lending out money on securities that are worthless. it doesn’t matter if I’m running up the money on my credit cards because next year I’m going to earn more”’ (in Gimson 2008). ‘The trouble today is that the people . bank manager became an anachronism – hence the list of faults attributed to the geeky culture of Americanised finance centres on the issue of unaccountability and greed.84 fina ncial alchemy in crisis With increasingly fierce competition in the markets generally and growing specialisation within financial firms themselves. We said then: “Well hell.. blamed young. he said. when he started. it was the younger generation of employees – and institutions more broadly – who came to shape the face of global finance. we went through this in the eighties and early nineties. In the sea of new. The problem of unaccountability and lack of ethical standards in finance goes beyond financial dealers and . who spent 60 years working in the City. inexperienced traders for adopting aggressive practices from the US. ‘scientific’ finance the traditional. recruits were regulated: ‘They had experience. and typically more conservative..’ Now.

their sluggish reactions to the unfolding crisis and simply not being up to the task or . The tendency of the private market to bypass any set of regulations that circumvent its profit-making potential is well known and has been noted among others by economic and financial historians (Kindleberger 1978). On the one hand. on the other. the rise of institutional investors and the development of the ‘shadow banking system’. proper insight into the state of the financial sector. the failure of regulatory and supervisory bodies to read market developments accurately has come to light on many occasions. and the corresponding transformations within financial institutions themselves. now increasingly oriented towards taking and passing on risks.hoW T he crisis has Be en un de r s To o d 85 institutions. as well as on the role of managerial practice and business conduct within the financial industry itself. It also has important implications for various segments of financial practice and control. it describes the institutional transformations of banking and finance that have paralleled the erosion of the function of traditional banking. In the wake of the global crisis. rather than taking on and managing the risks themselves. where the two institutions responsible for financial stability – the Bank of England and the FSA – have been exposed for their lack of vision. As such. Some of the most staggering examples come from the UK. these schools of thought place greater emphasis on the role of policymakers and regulators in creating the crisis. it captures the inherent conflict between financial market developments and the reach of the regulatory oversight.

there are those critics who argue that it was not the lack of regulation but rather the plethora of financial . but the Bank produced an inflation report that did not mention the word. David Blanchflower. Nor did it try to anticipate the kind of shock that the collapse of Lehmans in September 2008 would deliver to the British financial system (in Hutton 2009). Chris Rexworthy. admitted that he considered resigning in August 2008 at the point when the UK economy was sliding into recession. freely admits that the regulator did not understand the risks banks and building societies which had grown so reliant on the money markets for their funding were taking. As is being argued. placed a large chunk of bad debt in the hands of people who are least able to hold it. a member of the Monetary Policy Committee at the Bank of England. Anecdotes about the breathtaking incompetence of regulators and supervisors abound. and increasingly risky. this policy. Third. But criticisms of the official policy stance are manifold and go beyond those directed at individuals.g. Amery 2008) have pointed out that the main problem of the pre-crisis regulatory system was the classic case of moral hazard. First. ways to manage and redistribute the debt to third and fourth parties.86 financi al alchemy in crisis ‘asleep at the wheel’. thus prompting financial institutions to invent new. Second. the credit crunch was the direct result of a long-standing political aim of the Anglo-Saxon governments to encourage wider homeownership and access to credit. driven by social motives. according to many analysts. a former director of the FSA. many commentators (e.

critics argue that it was the inadequate implementation of financial policy as much as its flawed theoretical assumptions that precipitated the crisis. where senior managers often had no idea about the composition. with deal-chasing ability. There also emerged a peculiar state of affairs within financial companies themselves. unseen by. and not understood by the FSA or UK Treasury’ (Ambler 2008). sales. in this instance financial engineers themselves were keen to focus blame on the decision-making processes within banks and financial companies: as we have learned [in 2008]. outside the traditional set of requirements imposed by regulations) and that they generated positive earnings. (carmona and sircar 2009) Fourth. Interestingly. this problem was apparent .hoW T h e crisis has B e en un de r s To o d 87 norms and regulations that encouraged financiers to seek ways of bypassing the official regulatory system and exploit regulatory arbitrage: ‘The over-regulation of traditional financial services shifted enterprise towards the complex financial engineering of packages unknown to. As Willem Buiter (2008) writes. They were mostly concerned that the company’s trading techniques provided legitimate means of raising funds off balance sheet (i. far too often. those responsible for the grossly irresponsible credit derivatives trading and the ensuing risk exposure were not people who had been quantitatively trained. and other attention-deficit-promoting activities ranking high.e. they rose to their positions on other criteria. purpose or even the name of the products their company was trading in.

the Bank of England (the lender of last resort) claims not to have had any individual institution-specific information and never considered market liquidity. A product of the many vices of the age of ‘scientific finance’. near-banks and financial markets. The FSA (the market regulator) focused almost exclusively on capital adequacy and solvency.88 f ina nci al alchemy in crisis in all major geographical corners of the credit crunch. On the one hand. more and more critical voices have observed that lack of due oversight and diligence reflects a much . In the US. The UK financial systems have suffered from a flawed tripartite arrangement between the bodies responsible for financial stability. likewise. while the Treasury was simply too slow to act. as the crisis continued. the crisis was aggravated by the chaotic and extremely convoluted regulatory structure for banks. the meltdown has underscored the extent to which the technical and mathematical sophistication of modern financial techniques has outpaced the options available to financial regulators. it fell victim to regulatory capture by Wall Street (ibid. the central bank did not play a supervisory and regulatory role for the banking system. In the Euro area. On the other hand. therefore. which led to a paucity of information about the financial circumstances of individual banks and other systemically important financial institutions.). cyclical visions of the credit crunch emphasise that the crisis reflected a classic problem of the knowledge gap between policymakers and the financial markets.3 And while the Fed did have better access to institution-specific information.

considering the many grey zones of finance today and the sheer obscurity that finance had reached.hoW T he crisis has B een un de r s Too d 89 bigger trend in Anglo-Saxon financial capitalism – namely. Altogether. What. operation and governance of the financial system today. the emergent schools of thought on the global meltdown. Yet while analysing the many tentacles of the highly complex crisis. wasn’t the securitisation bubble one giant fraudulent scheme? In what follows. but convinced others that the boom would continue indefinitely? What was it that the financial markets invented and traded so aggressively? And. politics. . raise many important questions about the structure. for instance. the paradigm of soft-touch (or light-touch) regulation advocated by the political regimes on both sides of the Atlantic for the past three decades. individually and collectively. they leave a host of concerns about the crisis unaddressed. made some people anticipate the crisis almost to the letter. this book addresses these questions.

and the credit crunch has its share of both. Yet it is they. demographic 90 . it has shown that those supposedly tasked with financial supervision and stability often have very little idea of what financial institutions actually do. and their children. Their governments will then owe about $50.000 for every citizen. on average. it has revealed that greed can be very blinding.4 soMe uncoMfortaBle Puzzles of the credIt crunch Any financial crisis has its villains and fools. Most painfully. the crisis impinged on the ordinary person in the street: the majority of people in crisis-hit countries have had little contact with the brave new world of financial engineering. The IMF also estimated that the present value of the fiscal cost of an ageing population is. If unchecked. Data released in the summer 2009 suggest that the public debt of the ten leading rich countries will rise from 78 per cent of GDP in 2007 to 114 per cent by 2014. who have rescued private financial firms through massive injections of taxpayers’ money into individual banks and financial markets. The meltdown has exposed the ineptness of many people – in high places and elsewhere. of course. ten times that of the financial meltdown.

Generations of taxpayers. But the crisis has also posed somewhat smaller. . are destined to pay for the vagaries of the credit boom. therefore. many market players.uncomf orTaB l e P uzzles of Th e cre di T c r u n c h 91 pressures will increase the combined public debt of the wealthy economies to 200 per cent of GDP by 2030 (The Economist. and banking crises were widely assumed to have been the ills of the immature capitalism of the nineteenth century and not a problem of today’s financialised. remain unanswered. These are just some of the long-term concerns raised by the burst of the credit bubble. baffled by the scale of the unfolding turmoil. As the markets imploded. Indeed. analysts and brokers. dismissed: The Warning signs and the Whistleblowers The first puzzle is the timing and the apparent unpredictability of the meltdown. so far. 11 June 2009). eroding the values of many companies and individuals. the West has been enjoying a decade of unprecedented prosperity. including traders in big investment banks. questions about today’s finance which. They centre on the ethics of financial industry and the question of social justice in financial capitalism. yet important. have admitted that nobody anticipated that a devastating collapse could take place in the twenty-first century. globalised economy. despite occasional corrections to the markets.

In fact. in some cases. HBOS was lending too much by relying on wholesale financial markets. fired. It was the freezing up of these markets that pushed the bank into insolvency. In other words. unfortunately. who had warned management about the excessive risks in its loan portfolios. At the level of individual companies. But in 2004 and 2005. an internal risk compliance manager. as in any major financial scandal. the UK’s best known case is the Royal Bank of Scotland (RBS). these whistleblowers were routinely ignored or. neither HBOS nor the FSA believed that it was appropriate to assess the riskiness of its rate of growth . they were not heard even though. warnings about the possibility of a structural financial collapse had been voiced at different levels of financial and economic analysis. To date.1 it emerged that the then chief executive of HBOS had fired Paul Moore. as we learned in the wake of the crisis. this simply does not make sense. As two member banks of the group – RBS and HBOS – came close to bankruptcy and public money was put to their rescue. ABM Amro. The bank reached the brink owing to an extremely aggressive financial strategy during 2000–8 and what turned out to be the very ill-advised acquisition of a Dutch bank. Just like Northern Rock.92 f ina nci al alchemy in crisis Yet in light of the arguments outlined in Chapter 3. the global credit crunch has its own whistleblowers. many people knew and warned that the end was imminent. Moore had said that this was very risky because borrowers would have difficulty repaying (though not because funding could dry up).

was obliged to resign in February 2009 following allegations that in his previous job as chief executive of HBOS he had fired the whistleblower and dismissed warnings about excessive risk (Kennedy 2009). In a subsequent development.uncomforTaB le Pu zzles of T he cre di T c r u n c h 93 on the grounds that funds from wholesale sources could dry up (Peston. The scandal surrounding the fiasco of HBOS-RBS was further fuelled by the revelation that Sir Fred Goodwin. Northern Rock and HBOS were at the centre of a 2004 ‘war game’ regulators held to test how banks would cope with sudden turmoil in the mortgage market and the withdrawal of money from foreign banks on which Northern Rock’s business model relied. James Crosby. the UK authorities had been informed about potential trouble at Northern Rock as early as 2004 (Cohen and Giles 2009). served on the official committee that advises the UK Treasury on financial stability until well into the credit crunch (Hope 2009). newly appointed deputy chairman of the FSA. Another embarrassing revelation came in the summer of 2009. . three months after quitting RBS. In a letter. The group included more than a dozen bankers and City grandees. 11 February 2009. thanked him for his good service. Kennedy 2009). on an annual pension of £693. former chief executive of the fallen RBS.000. the Chancellor of the Exchequer. Part of its remit was to examine ‘proposals to reduce administrative burdens of regulation’. Sir Fred was not asked to stand down until 28 January 2009. According to the Financial Times. Alistair Darling.

including $711m in marketable . According to the accounts. though the Bank did warn of the growth in wholesale deposits repeatedly in its financial stability reports. the regulators concluded they could not force the lenders to change their practices.3bn in assets. Madoff Securities had $1. though not to the auditors. The warnings included the fact that Madoff’s books were audited by a three-person accounting firm. According to a number of people well versed in the subject. and in any case banks following that strategy were profitable and growing. In the US we learn that Bernard Madoff’s Ponzi scheme came as a surprise to his clients. conducted by the FSA. spokespeople for the FSA and the Bank of England said that the aim of the exercise was to identify weak regulatory practices rather than predict individual bank failure. Subsequently. hedge fund investment adviser Aksia LLC warned clients not to invest with Madoff after learning of ‘red flags’ at his company.94 f inanci al alchemy in crisis As the Financial Times reported. even though the exercise revealed the banks’ vulnerability. the Bank of England and the Treasury. It was felt that it was too harsh to say Northern Rock’s business model was excessively risky. highlighted the systemic risks posed by Northern Rock’s business model and its potential domino effect on HBOS. 2 which in late 2006 affirmed that the financial statements of Madoff’s securities firm were ‘in conformity with accounting principles generally accepted in the United States’. the risk simulation planning. In late 2006. then the UK’s largest mortgage lender.

an academic and market practitioner advising many policymaking bodies. In circles closer to academic commentary. Members’ equity. Warren Buffet. typically herding in the markets. warnings about the crisis were formulated more systematically. Let us take as an example Financial Reckoning Day. himself a successful market player. were likely to suffer from systemic collapse: large banks with their sophisticated internal risk systems have been caught up in every market cycle. the firm’s net worth. In the winter of 2008. Madoff confessed that his fund was indeed a Ponzi pyramid. published an article in the Financial Times warning that the Basle II accord would be inadequate to prevent a systemic banking failure and that the banks. They may be about to do so again on their syndication of collateralised debt obligations – the next bubble to burst. They lost considerable amounts during the dotcom bubble and on companies with crooked accounting. In the summer of 2009 he was sentenced to 150 years’ imprisonment for financial fraud. In 2002 Avinash Persaud. (Persaud 2002) In the same year. 13 December 2008). Economic historians and those working in the heterodox tradition of economics and political economy had been writing about unsustainable levels of debt in the North Atlantic markets for years. Surviving the Soft Depression of the . famously described derivatives as ‘financial weapons of mass destruction’. was $604m. Such a ratio of debt to equity made Madoff’s company a classic pyramid scheme (Bloomberg News.uncomforTaB l e P uzzles of Th e cre di T c r u n c h 95 securities and $67m in US debt.

In 2006. Ponzi-style era of consumer borrowing and credit excesses in the US with a rather pessimistic prognosis: american consumer capitalism is doomed … The trends that could not last forever seem to be coming to an end. the dominant tone in the official understanding of financial development remained puzzlingly optimistic. in the run-up to the credit meltdown.96 f ina nci al alchemy in crisis 21st Century. foreigners will not continue to finance america’s excess consumption … and fiat paper money will not continue to outperform the real thing – gold – forever. published in 2003. consumers cannot continue to go deeper into debt. noted the dangers of overoptimistic risk assessments in the markets. (Bonner with Wiggin 2003: 276) They continued: ‘America will have to find a new economic model. drawing on Hyman Minsky’s work. several research publications by official financial institutions like the BIS. for instance.: 256). This is not a cyclical change. More interestingly. However. but a structural one that will take a long time’ (ibid. concluded their study of the new. consumption cannot go down much further. The book’s authors. There is also a whole current of academic work in political economy and related disciplines that had been warning about the unsustainability of the credit boom and dangers of over-inflated asset markets and mispriced risks. the BIS pondered: . for it can no longer hope to spend and borrow its way to prosperity.

even if these did arise. This leaves room for a complementary explanation: these phenomena might be linked to there having been such abundant global liquidity over such a long period. has been essential to the longevity of political regimes on both sides of the Atlantic. Another reason is political. unfortunately. could withstand a variety of shocks. while the prevailing mood in the markets and the attitude in policy circles and in everyday life reinforced the notion that the world economy as a whole. that no one seems to have been prepared for the possibility of the financial meltdown on a global scale? One answer is quite simple: when the party is so good. no one wants to be the one who stops the music. concerns about disruptive reversions to more ‘normal’ values have to be qualified to the extent that such deviations can be explained and justified as being of a lasting nature. however. then. The sceptics and whistleblowers were too few to mention.uncomf orTaB l e Puzzles of T he cre diT c r u n c h 97 What grounds are there for believing that ‘imbalances’ pose a threat to the optimistic view looking forward? it is not hard to identify a large number of significant and sustained deviations from historical norms in important macroeconomic variables. strengthened by the forces of globalisation and financial integration. (2006: 141) Why was it. In the UK during 2002–7. supposedly heralding a new era of prosperity. the flourishing . the success of New Labour was founded on the greater availability of credit to the population. The credit and financial boom. recourse to such ‘fundamentals’ does not seem adequate to explain either the extent or the duration of the unusual circumstances currently being observed.

and expand free and fair trade. enhance national energy security.. slow the rate of health care inflation. In the US.s. the economic argument remained one of the few things supporting Labour’s success with voters. as Gordon Brown liked to repeat. economy and pro-growth policies such as tax relief.. As a result. goods and services . restrain government spending.s. in 2007.4 percent during the four quarters of 2006. (2007: 23) . and opening foreign markets to u.98 f ina nci al alchemy in crisis position of London as a financial centre and the new nature of economic growth which. meant ‘the end of the boom-and-bust’ character of the inflation-prone economic cycle with which the Conservative Party was associated. overlooking evidence of the deterioration in the housing market and the growing risks of the debt-driven financial expansion. the signs of growing economic fragility were missed or simply ignored (Galbraith 2006). The administration forecast calls for the economic expansion to continue in 2007. Indeed. with real gross domestic product (GdP) growing at 3. economy continued for the fifth consecutive year in 2006. regulatory restraint.s. on the other hand. it was observed in the Economic Report of the President that: The expansion of the u. the economy was never a priority for President Bush and his administration. economic growth was strong. but we must continue to pursue pro-growth policies such as those designed to keep tax relief in place. With the Labour Party’s position and appeal fatally damaged by the deeply unpopular war in Iraq. This strong economic growth comes in the face of numerous headwinds and resulted from the inherent strengths of the u.

the financial sector provided 40 per cent of jobs in London (Caulkin 2006). At the same time. Under New Labour. Gini coefficients (a measure of income inequality) were rising steadily (Funnel 2009). According to Société Générale. In the UK. financial and business services accounted for 45 per cent of UK corporate tax income. Many scholars maintain that the debt-driven expansion was the only way to maintain the living standards of the majority of the population at a time when wealth was being concentrated in the hands of the very few. while its rivals in New York and Tokyo. London’s model historically had been much more global. the City dominated the economy and emerged as a unique global financial centre. which made it a peculiarly . while it has fallen by more than 10 per cent for the rest. It appears that the Wal-Mart Walton family is wealthier than the bottom third of the US population put together – about 100 million people.a. In both the US and the UK.) pay 25 per cent of all income tax. during the decade of credit frenzy.uncomforTa Bl e Puzzles of T he cre diT c r u n c h 99 So one answer to the question ‘why did politicians choose not to acknowledge the growing pyramid of debt or the risks mushrooming in the financial systems?’ is simple: debt was useful. reliance on finance-led growth produced its own political dynamic. At the peak of the credit boom. according to 2006 data. tended to service domestic economies. for instance.000+ p. The financial sector’s high earners (earning £100.3 Domestically. the inflation-adjusted income of the highest-paid fifth of US earners has risen by 60 per cent since 1970.

ineptness and cynicism that thrive at different levels of the political economy. as the allusion to the original fraudster. implies.com boom of the late 1990s. Ponzi capitalism: a crisis of fraud? From its very start.4 Are we to understand. the credit crunch has unveiled another highly sensitive area of finance today: the very thin line that appears to separate outright fraud from what is commonly taken to be a venture of financial innovation. who seize the . the credit crunch has been described as the crisis of ‘Ponzi’ finance. Palan. are driven by deliberate deceit. trade in money has often been described as a Ponzi game. Carlo Ponzi. But aside from the longer-term contradictions of the mode of economic growth in the advanced capitalist economies and issues of political short-sightedness. that the whole financial system has become one giant Ponzi scheme? Ever since finance was liberalised. Gowan 1999). Murphy and Chavagneux 2010). tend to be a magnet for rogue dealers and outright crooks. offshore financial space where financial innovations flourished (Burn 1999. Is it fair to argue that the whole architecture of the global financial system is centred on the idea of ripping others off? History tells us that all economic bubbles. a giant casino or a global game of fictitious capital (Strange 1997. from the tulip mania in Holland in the seventeenth century to the dot. But Ponzi schemes.100 f inancial alchemy in crisis unregulated. then. Palan 2003.

As the crisis unfolded. such as Bernard Madoff and Allen Stanford. Second. . First. Observing these cases. commentators often talk about the global credit crunch as the collapse of a gigantic Ponzi scheme. Ponzi pyramids were exposed as the particularly nasty practice of some high-profile financiers. venture. captures a more general tendency among financial firms to avoid true disclosure of risks and hide bad debts by using the tools of financial innovation. In essence. scams and pyramid schemes as legitimate investments. the notion of Ponzi finance. they view the credit boom of 2002–7 and the process of securitisation as one massive industry of deceit and fraud. the principle of a pyramid scheme applied to the dynamics of the sub-prime mortgage industry in the US – the epicentre of the crisis. fictitious. it transpires. The securitisation boom of 2002–7 proved to be no exception. corruption and financial machinations hit the headlines. There are at least three levels at which the notions of Ponzi finance and thus fraud are relevant in the analysis of the global credit crunch.uncomforTaB le Pu zzles of T he cred i T c r u n c h 101 opportunity to make a lot of money by deceiving the public by promising high returns from a new. Sophisticated financial means of trading and packaging highly obscure financial instruments employed in securitisation and re-securitisation deals were instrumental in concealing not only bad lending and business practice. more and more cases of fraud. reflecting the element of deceit and fraud. but also. Third. during the securitisation boom.

where cash flows only cover interest payments. In Minsky’s original taxonomy. Ponzi finance is the ultimate phase in the evolution of a financial cycle. which develops after hedge finance.102 f inanci al alchemy in crisis Ponzi Finance and ‘Sub-Crime’ In his financial instability hypothesis. where both interest and principal are repayable. Minsky (1982. where even interest payments have to be financed by new debt. and then into the Ponzi state. The three types of finance mark the transitions starting with a conservative financial strategy and working towards an economic agent taking ever greater risks. particularly during periods of economic optimism. Ee and Xiong 2008. turn into more risky speculative finance. 1986) used the notion of ‘Ponzi finance’ to describe a state of acute financial fragility. Several facts about the structure of sub-prime lending substantiate this assertion. Wray 2008). At the same time. Dorn 2008. Many believe that the epicentre of the continuing credit crunch – the sub-prime mortgage industry in the US – was a giant Ponzi pyramid (Fish and Steil 2007. this progression describes the spiral of financial innovation and the progressive underestimation of risk by financial agents. in which an economic agent can pay debts and interest only by borrowing even more. Broadly speaking. the Ponzi principle implies that fraud and deception are key motives. therefore. ‘Ponzi’ is a method of financing old debt with new debt. For Minsky. . Kregel 2008.

Any Ponzi scheme can thrive only as long as it attracts new participants. they can tumble too. As Black argues. In the US. In 2006 alone. however. one of the first large US mortgage houses to crumble in the global meltdown. sub-prime lending was justified by the belief that the rising value of property would be sufficient to repay the loans and. Yet from the very start it was clear that many of those sub-prime borrowers would be unable to pay their mortgages if. as in any Ponzi scheme. For instance. are notoriously cyclical. Housing markets. was not . specialised in making what are known as ‘liars’ loans’. what is most worrying is that this was happening far beyond the sub-prime mortgage business: liars’ loans were securitised and. According to Jan Kregel (2008). through a complex chain of financial innovations.uncomforTaB l e Puzzles of T he cred iT c r u n c h 10 3 First. this belief proved to be self-fulfilling. no prospects of a higher income and often no jobs with a 100 per cent (or sometimes higher) mortgage was itself a very large-scale deception. it sold $80bn such loans to other companies (Black 2009). the entire US housing market entered a bubble phase. This possibility. along with the actual terms of the sub-prime loans. constituted a web of new markets for exotic financial products. the interest rates on their loans rose. the practice of providing people who have uncertain credit histories. or rather when. IndyMac. and house prices can not only stop rising. once the bottom tier of properties was inflated through the creation of massive demand.

The reasons why the sub-prime industry flourished for so long go beyond economics. enticed by commission fees. was facilitated by the political climate in the Anglo-Saxon economies and. In retrospect.5 In the aftermath of the crisis.104 financi al alchemy in crisis mentioned by the scores of financial advisers who sold the products to their clients. the terms of borrowing and the conditions for repayment appear to have been the key block in the Ponzi pyramid of sub-prime loans. On the one hand. This suggests that the Ponzi pyramid of sub-prime finance. and the related securitisation boom. it also transpired that many lenders. low ‘teaser’ rates that were later reset at much higher rates. knowingly inducing borrowers to accept loan terms they will not be able to meet (Wray 2008: 51). Ponzi-type methods employed by lending institutions included large pre-payment penalties. On the other hand. even when the applicant could have qualified for a ‘prime’ loan. correspondingly. low interest rates were available in many other regions – notably in continental Europe and Japan – which managed to avoid the proliferation of similar Ponzi schemes on the back of their own sub-prime sector. were deliberately diverting clients to more expensive sub-prime products. by the benign and ill-informed view of the financial and monetary authorities of the risks posed . Australia and New Zealand) due to historically low interest rates in the 1990s and 2000s which offered ample opportunities for borrowers. sub-prime lending flourished in the US (and to a lesser extent in other Anglo-Saxon countries such as the UK.

As of June 2008. 406 defendants were charged in 144 cases across the US. The first was put together by Bernard . two major cases of pure Ponzi pyramids have come to light. which brings us to the next terrain of Ponzi finance: the business of securitisation itself. It is in the wake of the sub-prime fiasco that clear evidence of mortgage fraud hit the headlines. insider trading and failures to disclose – with criminal intent – the proper evaluation of securitised loans and derivatives. the housing and securitisation boom was in fact celebrated by many officials on both sides of the Atlantic.uncomforTa B le Pu zzles of T he cred i T c r u n c h 10 5 by the expanding credit bubble. such as Bear Stearns in the US. FBI investigators were homing in on 19 ‘large corporations’ – including investment banks. The Ponzi Business of Securitisation To date. fraud was a ‘contributing factor’ to the overall credit crisis (Kirchgaessner and Weitzman 2008). The majority of the large corporate cases involved accounting fraud. Journalists following the investigations likened the instances of sub-prime fraud to the Enron and WorldCom scandals. Cases range from small-time manipulation of accounting books by brokers and the practice of ‘predatory lending’ to more high-profile cases involving big banks. As noted above. In the summer of 2008.6 According to the Federal authorities. accounting firms and hedge funds – as part of a wide-sweeping probe into mortgage fraud. credit rating agencies.

Madoff admitted to his sons that. rather than demanding money up front. And although. he reassured his clients that they were benefiting from a specialised inside track. In truth. By turning some investors away. a New York-based financier. Although justice seems to have been done as the 70-year-old is likely to spend the rest of his life in prison. as noted above. Madoff was building the steadily increasing flow of money he needed to keep the scheme going (Financial Times. RBS and other financial institutions. As it would emerge later. Essentially. In the winter of 2008–9. In the summer of 2009. Banco Santander. with a wide portfolio of clients who included thousands of individual investors and pensioners. once a Ponzi-style activity is suspected it is relatively easy to uncover the truth. questions mount about how many people knew about the nature of Madoff’s business and why his scheme was not exposed earlier. a laborious and well-choreographed effort to produce accounting books every month and report to clients was nothing more than a confidence trick. Madoff was sentenced to 150 years in prison for fraud. thorough accountants did smell a rat in .106 financi al alchemy in crisis Madoff. 20 February 2009). For several years he had been running what was known as a super-profitable hedge fund. he encouraged investors by suggesting they pour their cash into his funds incrementally. HSBC. his hedge fund was a Ponzi pyramid. According to many financial supervisors. in reality. as well as well-established banks like BNP Paribas.

which sold about $8bn of certificates of deposit to investors by promising improbable and unsubstantiated high interest rates. unlike Madoff. Madoff and Stanford dominated their companies and used peculiarly inconspicuous auditing firms to check them. The second now notorious case of a Ponzi scheme involves Sir Allen Stanford. What is most astonishing is that there were real warning signs about both men. nobody in a senior position in the US regulatory system seems to have suspected the massive pyramid scheme. another well-known financier. Accused of an $8bn fraud. continues to deny any Ponzi element in his business (Ishmael 2009). analysts grew suspicious of the returns the two financiers were offering. Stanford. Regulators allege that Stanford’s pyramid operated primarily through Stanford International.uncomforTaB l e P uzzles of Th e cred i T c r u n c h 10 7 Madoff’s books. an Antigua-based bank. Officials appointed to liquidate the offshore bank at the heart of the purported scam warned that it could take up to five years to locate funds lost by investors in Stanford’s Ponzi scheme (Chung 2009). 20 February 2009). In both cases. If Madoff himself had not confessed. who knows how many more billions of dollars would have disappeared into fictitious books. Stanford ran institutions that are alleged to have misled investors about their exposure to risky illiquid assets (Financial Times. His company went into liquidation after it became apparent that many investors were seeking to withdraw funds from the bank when its cash reserves were insufficient. Yet while they continued . In both cases.

In the wake of the sub-prime crisis.108 financial alchemy in crisis to post astronomic returns. at least twelve complaints involving Ponzi schemes and similar scams have been filed (Chung and Masters 2009). Both schemes came to light only because their architects were unable to continue their financial manipulations in the frozen financial markets and their clients started to demand their money back. For instance. for at least 13 years. What is worrying is that although these two cases are certainly the most well known. they represent a much wider trend of fraudulent financial practices which had been concealed by the credit boom and securitisation industry.). But according to prosecutors and regulators the money simply filled the two men’s personal piggy banks. whereas as we have seen. large and small investors alike invested with Paul Greenwood and Stephen Walsh. It is thus unclear for how long the pyramids would have continued had the international credit markets not seized up. two New York-based money managers. they evaded any serious scrutiny (ibid. Madoff came clean voluntarily (Chung 2009). the most it did was fine them for relatively minor transgressions. in the belief that an ‘enhanced equity index’ strategy was superprofitable. The sheer number of schemes under investigation and their geographic spread – from Alaska to Florida and with a whole raft of overseas investors . They are just the latest in a stream of alleged Ponzi pyramids. Although the SEC investigated both companies. the case against Stanford was brought only after a Venezuela-based analyst made his criticisms public. In the end.

But what does one make of all this? It is contentious to allege that the securitisation industry was in fact one giant Ponzi scheme. According to historians. In Germany. securitisation has . including the regulatory framework in which it flourished. Deutsche Bank and Hypo Real Estate – came under investigation for what prosecutors believe may have been fraudulent or ‘illicit’ profits amounting to €100 million. when Ponzi’s original postage scam flourished. Milan has lost millions on a derivatives deal. The growth of hedge funds and offshore finance made secrecy and high returns seem more common (Picciotto 2009). the last time the US saw anything like this was during the 1920s.uncomforTaB l e P uzzles of Th e cred i T c r u n c h 109 – dwarf what was uncovered in any recent recession.). ‘the beauty of these recent cases is that very little money ever went out.000 registered investment advisers on the other (Chung and Masters 2009). After all. regulators were hampered by political pressure to leave hedge funds alone on the one hand. It was all on paper. It is very likely that in the aftermath of the crisis more such revelations will surface. As many critics argue. In Italy. In the spring of 2009 four big banks – UBS. the institutional foundations of the securitisation industry. JP Morgan Chase.’ At the same time. and a lack of resources to inspect more than 11. According to one former SEC official. have helped entrench fraud as a legitimate practice of financial innovation. as many as 700 local authorities may have lost money on similar deals (ibid. The Ponzi web has spread beyond America’s shores.

to the high-profile scams mentioned above. On the other hand. Theoretically at least. In principle. having gained access. then. rather than just one bank. they set up their businesses with the sole purpose of reaping personal profits by deceiving their clients. even in radical academic circles. could own or claim a portion of a loan portfolio. securitisation has as its aim facilitating wider economic turnover. flexibility and thus economic stability. so far conceptualising the credit crunch as one massive crisis of financial fraud has not gained much popularity. to a variety of options on their mortgages. the process of securitisation widened their ownership structure as several parties. diversity. To claim that the major part of the international financial sector operated under the logic of a massive Ponzi pyramid is highly controversial and requires some substantiation. Consumers and producers in many segments of the world market benefited from securitisation. coupled with widespread expectations that more fraud schemes are bound to be exposed as the recession . thus spreading and diversifying the risks. Indeed. Ponzi and Madoff are convicted crooks. by creating a market for these assets and transforming them into liquid assets.110 financial alchemy in crisis existed for decades and its economic purpose had been to attract previously unpriced (because unmarketable) assets into market circulation. the number of fraud schemes that have surfaced to date – from the case of a rogue trader Jerome Kerviel whose scheme cost Société Générale almost €5bn. for instance.

that outright fraud. it appears that the many parties to this process included financiers (large and small). The credit boom of 2002–7 and the whirlpool of new financial techniques and products made these schemes almost impossible to detect. Notwithstanding various explanations of the long-term . it transpires that the proliferation of scientifically calculated but opaque financial techniques in the self-regulated financial markets has made it easier for individuals and institutions to conceal fraud and deception under the wide umbrella of financial innovation. regulators and. as the booming industry of credit crunch studies suggests. for the most part they were ignored.uncomforTa B le Pu zzles of T he cre diT c r u n c h 11 1 continues – does suggest that something went terribly wrong with the business of securitisation. Third – and much more worryingly – when warnings about the true nature of these schemes were voiced. predatory lending and obscure financial schemes bordering on fraud have been sustained for so long? Why were the warnings about the mounting risks of securitisation and the growing fragility of the financial system unnoticed? How did the sub-prime loan industry. whose very name implied something very rotten. continue to flourish in the US? And why did politicians of various calibres continue to celebrate the advance of the ‘new economy’ and the ‘new paradigm’ of credit risk management? There are many answers to these questions. bankers. How is it. then. Second. politicians. lawyers. as the political connections of both Madoff and Stanford imply. First.

by innovating in credit instruments and techniques.112 financial alchemy in crisis causes and short-term triggers of the global meltdown. Put more simply. economic and theoretical origins. financial markets not only optimise the risks. it is the naïve belief that the financial market today creates wealth and spreads it through the economic system. of one great illusion that has become an axiom of financial innovation over recent decades: the misconceived idea that. . this illusion has complex socio-political. both direct and indirect. thus contributing to greater and wider prosperity. They are the products. they also enhance the liquidity and welfare of the economic system as a whole. this book suggests that most of the riddles brought up by the credit crisis have a common origin. As explained in the next chapter.

it would have played an important yet relatively minor role in sustaining the 2002–7 boom had there not been a broader international politicaleconomic environment that supported. The following pages identify three interconnected forces that. liquid markets and economic prosperity. political and institutional developments. liquidity and the Paradigm of self-regulating credit In narrow terms. emerged as a combination of historical. the global meltdown is a crisis centred on the US sub-prime mortgage industry.5 2002–7: the three PIllars of the lIquIdIty IllusIon Even in purely financial terms. This chapter unpacks the role that ideas. facilitated and encouraged a particular market-based approach to managing risks in finance. in its broader 113 . in turn. helped disguise the deepening fragility of the North Atlantic economies. This environment. having reified the myth of efficient finance. the sub-prime lending industry was a time-bomb waiting to explode (Wray 2008). Even so. behaviour and the institutional organisation of financial regulation played in constructing and sustaining the illusion of liquidity. analytical.

securitised and transferred to others in the market (Shiller 2008). but also. yet not necessarily warranted. liquidity is about desire for and ownership and transferability of one’s claims on wealth (Berle and Pederson 1934). The way liquidity has been understood in this framework is representative of many other important assumptions underlying the paradigm of self-correcting financial markets. innovation in finance has always been driven by the desire for quicker and greater profits.114 f inanci al alchemy in crisis international dimension. Liquidity is the absolute essence of all market exchanges and is paramount to the functioning of any financial system. In the era of highly financialised capitalism. Some scholars even suggest that liquidity is synonymous with the wider meaning of capitalism itself: ultimately. and defined by the notion that every eventuality can be priced. it is a crisis of securitisation. efficient finance which has constituted mainstream thinking on finance and financial regulation for the past decades. dominated by sophisticated trading techniques and products. by the search for greater liquidity. as the preceding . As in any other area of economic activity. It is important to realise in this instance that securitisation itself has become a functional form of the paradigm of self-regulating. crucially. it is argued. On the one hand. The key reason lies in the ideology of perfect markets and the theory of market-completing financial innovation. liquidity of financial markets has often been assumed. Yet precisely what this greater liquidity implies remained a somewhat fuzzy notion.

The process of inventing. from Minsky onwards. financial engineers and traders have expanded the reach of the financial markets. It ‘enhances the liquidity of underlying receivables by transforming them into tradable securities. securitisation has been understood to be . On the other hand. rely on the liquidity of the underlying assets. in popular terminology. Securitisation has had its own controversial effects on the idea and functioning of liquidity in the markets. liquidity. for instance – the latest wave of financial engineering – both relies on and enhances liquidity. by pricing them and then transferring them to new. Securitisation. have argued that the relationship between new financial products and the liquidity of the economic system as a whole is far less straightforward. thereby increasing market turnover and. new financial instruments. most financial innovations have for a long time been perceived to be liquidity-enhancing: by pooling a greater variety of assets in the market exchange. the funding of a large number of market participants involved in the securitisation process depends crucially on market liquidity being permanently sustained’ (Banque de France 2008: 11). willing and able owners. At the same time.T he T hree Pi llars of T he li Qu idi T y i l l u s i o n 11 5 chapters have noted. markets and institutions has been driven by the search for greater liquidity across the global financial markets. Theoretically. critics of the financial orthodoxy. while adding to a sense of greater liquidity in the markets. valuing and introducing new credit instruments. On the other hand.

This idea did not emerge out of the blue. the Basle requirements made it unprofitable for banks to hold safe and liquid assets on their balance sheets (Wigan 2009). much like other important financial segments (say. securitisation was believed to increase liquidity across the financial system and the economy as a whole (ibid.116 f inancial alchemy in crisis a technique to create securities by reshuffling the cash flows produced by a diversified pool of assets with some common characteristics. securitisation has been the banking sector’s reaction to the introduction of the Basle II accord of financial regulation. thus allowing them to make more loans. (cifuentes 2008) Advocates of the technique argue that the key economic functions of securitisation have been to provide an alternative form of financing for companies with predictable cash flows and to help lending institutions manage the credit exposure more efficiently. the Eurodollar market which emerged almost by accident but later become widely established). In simple terms. In practical terms. banks reacted to the new regulations by accelerating debt origination on the basis of the capacity to move assets off balance sheet by selling them. . securitisation meant that risky (but profitable) assets were moved from the banks’ balance sheets into the unregulated financial system. one can design several securities (tranches) with different risk-reward profiles which appeal to different investors. By doing so. by creating securities out of illiquid assets. therefore. Unsurprisingly. Generally.). Historically.

As a result of the introduction of the Basle rules. At the heart of this process lay the transformation of the US banking system (Kregel 2007. securitisation reflects the way risk has been modelled. but on such a scale as to change the whole manner in which banks operate (Chick 2008). This shift in turn has become a major institutional transformation of the global financial system. Regulations intended to strengthen the balance sheets of banks by weighting their assets on the basis of their riskiness and thus rewarding the holding of safe assets actually drove risky assets off the balance sheet. securitisation was undertaken not just as a small part of bank operations when banks needed liquidity. it was transmitted through its impact on liquidity. ultimately destructive repercussions for the stability of the financial system as a whole. valued and traded by banks and financial houses since liberalisation reforms were introduced in the 1980s .T he Th ree Pi llars of T h e liQ u idi Ty i l l u s i o n 117 This trend has had its own. financialised economy the ability to lengthen the debt chain leads to increasing illiquidity in the financial system as a whole: ‘to the extent that either the most liquid assets leave the banking system for the portfolios of other financial institutions or the debts of the newly grown and developed financial institutions enter the portfolios of banks. in a deregulated. In this regard. according to Victoria Chick. Chiefly. As noted above. 2008). As Minsky foresaw. the liquidity of the banking system declines’ (Minsky 1982: 174). the experience of the first Basle accord illustrates the law of unintended consequences.

and servicing them. The incentive to be a prudent lender has been replaced by an overarching drive to maximise commissions. The adoption of the ORD model has underpinned a phenomenal rise in commission fees and income from banks’ capital market-related activities. the banker today has no motivation to conduct proper credit evaluation. In recent years.1 These reforms led to the introduction of a new type of banking. now known as the ‘originate and distribute’ (ORD) model. according to Robert Wade.118 financial alchemy in crisis in the US and elsewhere. banks and hedge funds became careless because they were acting as intermediaries. in which the bank is no longer an institution whose principal purpose is to take deposits and grant loans. not as principals (Wade 2008: 32–3). According to one estimate. Lenders have become progressively indifferent to risk and obsessed by reward (Credit Magazine 2008). Crucially from the point of view of financial fragility. managing those assets in off balance sheet affiliate structures such as special investment vehicles (SIVs). the gap between a bank’s capital and its managers has widened. between 2004 and 2006 earnings from . but to the final buyers of the collateralised assets. bonuses and profits. underwriting the primary distribution of securities collateralised with those assets. Thus. it is a competitive financier seeking to maximise fee and commission income from originating assets. and thus spread moral hazard around the financial system. Instead. simply because the interest and principal on the loans will be repaid not to the bank itself.

The concern with creating new markets for their products prompted financial institutions – both in the official. but also assuming a greater share of the investment banks’ revenues (over 90 per cent for the Americas. profits from sales and trading operations had not only been growing. of abundant liquidity in the sub-primerelated financial markets and of financial wealth being created and spread. Middle East and Africa. The resulting series of financial innovations created a sense. the Bank of England. over 80 per cent for Europe. from $55bn in 2004 to $90bn in 2006.T he Th ree P i llars of T h e liQ u idi Ty i l l u s i o n 119 trading in derivatives and capital market-related activities at the top ten global investment banks rose by almost two-thirds. though not a guarantee. it seems naïve and short-sighted to draw a straightforward. visible banking sector and in the so-called shadow banking system – to embark on a spate of financial engineering which was unprecedented in its scope and sophistication.2 Reflecting these changes. it promises to ‘improve systemic stability if risk is held by those with the greatest capacity to absorb losses’ (Bank of England 2006. linear link between securitisation and systemic stability. In the wake of the global meltdown. and just over 40 per cent for Asia Pacific). for instance. In 2006. Politically. cited in Langley 2009). At . noted that while the ORD model ‘does not alter the financial sector’s aggregate credit exposure to the non-financial sector’. this trend has been commonly viewed as an indication of a more efficient financial system and foundation for economic stability.

With the assumption of an infinitely liquid market there was no need to install a systemic provision to guarantee its liquidity. a particular emphasis in the Basle II accord proved fatal in the lead-up to the global credit crunch. Basle II has been built on the assumption that a well-functioning financial market is always liquid. however. liquidity that disguised many fallacies – both conceptual and political – at the time. such representations of finance meant that a ‘liquid’ market became an object that investors increasingly regarded as a given fact. (langley 2009) With regard to how liquidity has been approached within the regulatory architecture. things were much murkier. The key concern for . Specifically. the central parameters of international financial governance were founded on regulatory developments in the private sector: when the first Basle accord proved ineffective. or more accurately the illusion of. external to them. the solution was sought in private risk management tools (Wigan 2009).120 f inanci al alchemy in crisis the peak of the credit boom. the mainstream political discourse that paralleled the expanding credit boom invariably represented the markets as efficient … and liquid. there was little to suggest that markets for assets named ‘liquid’ would be any different from the norm. the accord established a system of regulatory principles that delegated to the individual institutions themselves the management of their portfolio of risks. As a result. Here again it is the idea of. As Paul Langley writes. since the sub-prime industry seemed to exemplify what was possible in an era of liquid finance.

Th e T h ree P i llars of T h e liQ u idiT y i l l u s i o n 121 policymakers at the time was market efficiency and the efficiency of individual banks (Davies 2009). Put simply. Warburton 2000). this assumption itself is a . while the market as a whole – founded on financial innovation and competition – was made liquid. or market turnover. although seemingly only an analytical fallacy. the idea of ‘liquidity’ has come to describe the liquidity of the market. in both practical and analytical terms. has meant that the very idea of liquidity has become progressively detached from its older associations with the liquidity of assets and proximity to instruments of payment. Paralleling the rise and spread of financial markets. in popular terms liquidity has increasingly come to describe the volume and speed of financial transactions. The advance of financial engineering. Playing with debt – Together. Through the alchemy of financial engineering. liquidity as a ‘state of mind’ The popularisation of finance has had its own impact on the way liquidity is understood. As contended in this book. It is this reliance on private regulatory techniques and risk-optimising tools that has produced the other two pillars of the 2002–7 liquidity myth: the Ponzi mode of finance and an authority structure for validating the products of financial innovation. the banks were assumed to optimise their own risk strategies.g. rather that the content of those transactions (e.

In narrow technical terms.122 f inanci al alchemy in crisis key reason why many destabilising trends and risks in the credit bubble had been overlooked. And building a whole system of theories and regulatory principles on these two assumptions borders on something much more serious. Believing that market turnover is infinitely sustainable and hence synonymous with liquidity is a dangerous illusion. and it is important to understand how social and behavioural factors shape liquidity. market fluidity. perceptions. unfounded conceptual assumptions and beliefs constitute only one side of the liquidity illusion. made possible when a crowd of knowledgeable buyers meets a crowd of knowledgeable sellers. Continuity of trade. But market activity is always a social process and thus constitutes a complex interactive process of information flows. market liquidity is about prevailing price trends and the ability to execute transactions reasonably swiftly. The other important element of the illusion in the run-up to the global credit crunch lies in the dynamics of market liquidity itself. Therefore. According to Carruthers and Stinchcombe (1999). attitudes and expectations. . in the realm of the financial markets three basic mechanisms underpin the creation of liquidity: 1. is a social construction. At the same time. or market liquidity in a more narrow sense. Assuming that anything can be bought and sold in the financial market is simply wrong.

3. either on organised market platforms or. on an over-the-counter (OTC) basis. seemed to ensure that these products contain accurate information about their underlying risks and values. market-makers and sellers all have to hold a deep conviction that the ‘equivalent’ commodities in a large flow of financial instruments really are all the same. As the boom expanded. For a while during the credit boom this conviction appeared to function well. are willing to risk transferring large quantities and thus maintaining a continuous price. comprises the spatial. manufacturing standard products or by creating legal instruments with equal claims on an income stream. as the authors argue in their original study. for a small margin. Homogenisation and standardisation of commodities. This standardisation in turn. the belief in and reliance on the capacity of securitisation to optimise risks became ever greater. in turn. Financial geeks were extending the range of financial products and services. spawning theories about . Market liquidity. more typically. therefore.: 353–4). Standardisation of products and financial techniques is absolutely central to sustaining market liquidity (ibid. is a collective and cognitive achievement: buyers. The magic of securitisation. The existence of market-makers who. cognitive and social processes of valuing risks. offering them to a host of seemingly willing buyers. by grading natural products. intertemporal.T he T hree Pi llars of T he li Qu idi T y i l l u s i o n 12 3 2.

this was generally considered to be a healthy development supporting owner-occupied housing. (Bis 2007: 7–8) Optimism during the global credit boom had its own. credit was both cheap and commonly available with weaker conditionality than had previously been the case. not least in the area of credit to households. the BIS observed: the prevailing view that the world was awash with liquidity – that is. for instance. until quite late in the period under review. examples of new practices abound. peculiar impact on the construction of liquidity. speculation. both mortgage and consumer credit became available to many who previously would not have had access at all. liquidity was no longer about the available pool of money or even credit more generally. in the united states and a number of other countries. But institutional developments within the financial sector also contributed to both the perception and the reality of the greater availability of credit: changes in regulation and technology altered what could be done. According to one market player. only in recent months … has the downside to these new practices become more apparent. it is ‘the result of the appetite of investors to underwrite risk and the appetite . Stripped of its relation to the underlying assets. indeed. thanks both to deregulation in many countries and to the global extension of the mortgage scoring techniques pioneered in the united states.124 financi al alchemy in crisis ‘abundant market liquidity’ and a ‘global liquidity glut’. mortgage credit has become available on easier terms to borrowers almost everywhere. Rather. and changes in attitude altered what people wanted to do. market liquidity was increasingly taken to be synonymous with the shared appetite for financial trading – or put bluntly. In June 2007.

was absolutely pivotal both to sustaining the investment boom and to preserving the notion of a liquid market. a tendency . The greater the risk appetite. the new derivative products had become so obscure that it could take days for computer programs to value them. proved to be dangerous. From the point of view of markets as social institutions. the greater the liquidity. But here is one of the many paradoxes of liquidity. the other side is the ability to sell. First of all. Most people understand this as ‘market confidence’. crucially. it was increasingly difficult to shift them in the markets. While one side of liquidity is about finding a willing buyer and exercising one’s ability to transfer claims. so central to the sense of market liquidity. Confidence in turn depends on a level of transparency in the markets and knowledge about the new securities being traded. this twofold function became ever more difficult to maintain at a systemic level. Standardising these securities and making them transferable in the market. as noted above. In fact. As Gillian Tett (2008) notes.Th e T h ree P i llars of T h e liQ u idiT y i l l u s i o n 125 of savers to provide leverage to investors who want to underwrite risk. a liquidity boom can only be sustained as long as a collective belief in the tradability of assets persists. As the techniques of securitisation became ever more complex and opaque. the idea that collective reliance on financial innovation and sophistication automatically creates ‘the market’ proved to be an illusion. Tett argues. Standardisation. and vice versa’ (McCulley 2008: 1). more and more of these newly minted securities were left on banks’ balance sheets.

trading practices and pricing methods is essential for ensuring a certain level of transparency in the market. liquidity. Financial commentators call this problem the ‘concentration level’. ultimately.126 financi al alchemy in crisis that was overlooked by most financial supervisors and regulators at the time. other buzzwords include ‘herding’ . market exchange is essentially about the double coincidence of two diametrically opposed desires: a transaction will only take place if a seller finds a willing and able buyer. As the ensuing crisis showed. After all. standardisation has given rise to its own dangerous dynamic in the market. and the actions of buyers and sellers taken together. but also on the diversity of opinions and positions of the market-makers. It is the erosion of this diversity. its fluidity and thus. In this sense. liquidity is contingent not only on the standardisation of products and market trends. that contributed to the misinterpretation of market liquidity trends and. Yet. With the spread of financial innovation this crucial component of heterogeneity of the market context gradually eroded during 2002–7. The success of credit derivatives markets and the profits they offered attracted many investors who used broadly similar market positions and pricing models. constitute an important aspect of market turnover. Second. as Persaud and Nugée (2006) explain. this proved to be fatal to the idea of a liquid financial system. Knowledge about markets and products. precipitated the liquidity crunch. in common terms. the standardisation of techniques and products.

the aggressive expansion of new borrowings. especially liquidity risk. while during a boom similar attitudes and shared positions create a sense of greater vibrancy and liquidity in the market. Whatever the term chosen. There were simply too many speculators operating in one market segment. they magnify it. herding and the concentration of risks . Instead. similar investor positions are unable to diffuse the shock. the use of quasi-legal investment techniques and outright swindles. proved the point. In this herd-driven process of financial innovation. As the first waves of the crisis combined with a spate of downgrades and uncertainty over valuations. the major risk posed by the growing homogeneity of market behaviour is that when distress strikes the market. The global credit crunch. hordes of investors were left holding similar positions in a falling market (Madigan 2008). At the same time. Therefore. in many cases. One of the most telling signs was that credit spreads had been tightening virtually uninterrupted from 2003 to early 2007 as investors piled into the collateralised debt obligations (CDOs) market. it is noteworthy that while speculation. much like any other systemic financial collapse.T he T hree Pi llars of Th e liQ u idi T y i l l u s i o n 12 7 and ‘crowded trades’. and. warnings were voiced about the dangers of what looked like herding in the derivatives markets. in stressful periods and crises these common practices erode more values than a more diversified market would allow. During the later years of the credit boom. the conventional trends of a bubble and Minsky’s Ponzi finance prevail: the undervaluation of risks.

2m derivatives contracts with a total notional value of $6 trillion. As with Northern Rock. Lehmans is estimated to have held 1. blurring the valuation basis of the original . as the preceding chapters have shown.128 financi al alchemy in crisis tend to be generic features of any financial crisis. like many other banks. As the spiral of financial innovation progressed. The post-crisis investigation of the fallen bank revealed that globally. reiterates the scale of the problem of obscure debt and financial manipulation. both in relation to supervisory bodies and also. often registered in unregulated spaces of offshore finance and associated primarily with the strategy of financial deregulation. then moved the resulting assets overseas. at the time of collapse.2 trillion of open positions spread across almost every market counterparty. such as synthetic financial structures. ‘sliced and diced’ them with other MBSs. all of whom were looking to minimise their exposure to Lehmans. The tale of the biggest casualty of the credit meltdown so far. the credit boom of 2000–7 had been defined by a specific element within the underlying regulatory paradigm: the sophistication of new products. Lehmans. Lehman Brothers. importantly. it eroded the transparency of the markets. at the level of counterparties – those at the other end of a transaction. it has blurred the line between financial innovation and financial fraud. It held over $1. accumulated mortgage-backed assets (MBAs) in one country. Also crucially. securitised them. offshore facilities helped conceal the risks of the transactions.

T he Th ree Pi llars of Th e liQ u idi T y i l l u s i o n

129

security (Thomson 2009: 9–11). This not only triggered a liquidity crunch at the bank, but also made bankruptcy procedures very difficult to instigate. Instructively in this instance, in May 2007 Bernanke warned: ‘substantial market risk may be associated with holdings of illiquid instruments – tranches of bespoke collateralised debt obligations illustrate this well. A pattern of crowded trades may lead to market illiquidity, sometimes in surprising locations, when risk aversion heightens’ (in Madigan 2008). And while it is the banking sector that has suffered the bulk of losses and remains the focus of attention in the wake of the credit crunch, some observers doubt whether commercial banks have increased their leverage too much. According to Willem Buiter, most of the increased leverage in the financial sector took place outside the commercial banks – in investment banks, hedge funds, private equity firms and a whole range of new financial institutions relying on the new securitisation-based financial instruments (Buiter 2008). Other analysts and regulators confirm that it is the spread of the hedge fund industry and, in particular, its involvement in the securitisation industry that aggravated the problem of risk concentration and market illiquidity. This process has been twofold. First, the expansion of the hedge fund sector led to more investors chasing the same opportunities. When this happens, profits start to decline. Declining profits in turn encourage investors to increase leverage, so that a Minsky-type Ponzi pyramid emerges. Second, hedge

130

f inanci al alchemy in crisis

funds appear to have been using increasingly similar trading strategies, thus eroding the diversity of the market. According to the ECB, since 2001 hedge fund returns have become less widely dispersed, indicating that their positioning was becoming increasingly similar. In 2005, the ECB stated that ‘under stressed conditions, hedge funds, because they simply cannot afford to wait when leveraged positions begin to lose money, would probably be among the first to rush for the exit’ (in Madigan 2008). It is also telling that not only did regulators note the potential dangers of risk concentration and crowding, but risk managers themselves admitted that problems in the credit sector were not really unexpected. In 2007, Madelyn Antoncic, New York-based chief risk officer at Lehman Brothers, admitted that there was too much complacency in the markets at the height of the boom: ‘People didn’t realise that one of the main factors that contributed to this period’s recent stress was the crowded trade and the lack of liquidity for a particular trade once everyone gets out of the same strategy, especially when the trading models are the same’ (ibid.). The liquidity of the new financial system, therefore, was a somewhat artificial construction, created by the rarely questioned theorems of self-regulating, efficient and optimising market strategies and the collective behaviour of investors, or simply, herding: the sustainability of market turnover depended crucially on the collective actions and expectations of financial players.

T he T hree Pi llars of T he li Q uidi T y i l l u s i o n

131

In the end, both pillars of the so-called liquidity boom proved illusory. The idea of risk-optimising financial engineering has turned out to be flawed at its core: it proved impossible to eliminate risk from the financial system since, in Buiter’s (2008) words, the world of finance does not have a hole in it through which risks simply fly away. The creation and maintenance of liquid markets by financial practices, or what scholars call the ‘performativity’ of various calculative practices, also proved to be a fiction: the crowd of buyers and sellers can shuffle debts around for a while, yet insofar as the assets themselves were never truly liquid, these actions could only be sustained temporarily. And it is here that we encounter the third pillar of the liquidity illusion of 2002–7: the role of a singular structure of private authority in the financial markets which was pivotal to creating and sustaining the illusion of a liquid financial system during 2002–7: the credit rating institutions.

The alchemists: Turning Bad debts into ‘money’
No matter how exuberant, canny or short-sighted financial strategists might be, illusions of prosperity, including the liquidity illusion, can only be sustained while there is some credibility to newly invented instruments. Following Carruthers and Stinchombe (1999), one can understand this issue in terms of a liquidity-maker’s presence in the market. At the heart of the function of a liquidity-maker lies the dilemma

132

f inanci al alchemy in crisis

of transferring very specific, idiosyncratic knowledge about a given product into standardised and more transparent, common knowledge that would render underlying products knowable, valuable and tradable. In a national economic system, for instance, the state typically performs this function when issuing its own currency. In the private sphere of the securities markets there are other institutional arrangements designed to serve this role. According to Carruthers and Stinchombe, in postwar America, by pooling together large numbers of home mortgages and guaranteeing the income stream from them, Fannie Mae made them into more liquid securities, first, by making the task of discerning their market price easier and, second, by reducing the amount of information needed to understand their value. As Carruthers and Stinchcombe explain, instead of compiling information about each individual home and borrower on a case-by-case basis, a lender need only use aggregate information about means and variances in the pool of mortgages. By pooling mortgages the function of Fannie Mae was to increase market liquidity by transforming a future flow of payments to the issuing bank into a financial instrument to sell on the secondary mortgage market by using a short-run guaranteed price for mortgages that banks originate (ibid.: 359). More recently, in the ‘new economy’ of the late 1990s it was financial analysts, accounting and audit firms that, by endorsing the financial reports of dot. com companies – real and fictitious – created market

the accounting violations at Enron included revenue overstatement. somehow failed to see what they were doing (Kadlec 2002). cost understatement. involving special purpose entities (SPEs) and financial manipulations. corporations whose executives have been convicted of serious financial fraud. The two most notorious scandals of that particular bubble were WorldCom and Enron. The method of market-to-market accounting allowed the company instantly to book future earnings it forecast on energy deals.3 Enron employed a much more elaborate scheme of financial innovation.Th e T h re e P illars of T h e liQ u idiT y i l l u s i o n 133 liquidity for the shares of those companies. WorldCom’s auditor. Arthur Andersen. Enron’s financial engineers also structured several of its partnerships to make the parent company appear to be generating cash from operations rather than from its financial activities (Guttman 2003: 208). In the case of WorldCom. the company seems to have relied on old-fashioned cooking of the books: by treating routine expenses as capital investments. masking of risk and overvaluation of assets. The combined effect was to overstate earnings per share. Using its exemption from brokerage regulations and oversight by the Commodities Futures Trading Commission. with the corollary of bolstering Enron’s potential return on investment and . Enron recorded as revenue the total amount of its energy trades rather than just the profits made on each trade – the standard practice at brokerage firms. Overall. The basic idea was to represent losses as profits.

and individual accounting firms like Arthur Andersen for lack of due diligence. The inevitable implosion of the dot. and the general culture and political ideology of efficient markets (Lowenstein 2004). a giant Ponzi scheme. Vivendi and many other firms for cooking the books and deceiving their shareholders. WorldCom. dominated by the five largest accounting firms in the US. the Financial Standards Accounting Board. Lowenstein 2004). Importantly. Guttman 2003.com euphoria made things much less clear-cut. the dot. In essence. analysts note that this trend was supported by the standards of the private regulatory body. in reality.134 f inancial alchemy in crisis diminishing the firm’s cost of capital (Tinker and Carter 2003).com crash . accounting representations set the competitive conditions for others to match if they were to survive in the marketplace (Tinker and Carter 2003: 580–1. the financial frauds.com bubble and the competition for markets set a general trend across the new economy: while appearing temporarily profitable and highly liquid. however. Yet both facts and the controversial role of financial innovation suggest that the speculative drive of the dot. both of whom have since been imprisoned for fraud.com boom was.com bubble must have been painful to the CEOs at Enron and WorldCom. For the financial industry. During the boom. Enron was a typical Ponzi scheme. In both these high-profile cases the companies’ auditors chose to overlook. Yet the dot. It is tempting to blame individual executives at Enron. the dot. or helped disguise (Grey 2003).

In 1909. or something. in the words of Timothy Sinclair (2005). and make the complex structures of IOUs ‘worth – or seem to be worth – more than the sum of its parts’. when information is key to managing risks and structures of knowledge are essential for market turnover and. starting with US railroad bonds (Cantor and Packer 1994). That something was the credit rating agency (Lowenstein 2008). in essence. The first mercantile ratings guide was established in 1841 in the wake of the financial crisis of 1837 in order to rate merchants’ ability to meet their financial obligations. The rather feeble regulatory reforms that were introduced in the wake of the Enron scandal did nothing to stop the escalation of the new profitable niche – residential mortgage markets and the wider securitisation. John Moody extended the practice to rating securities. bundles of toxic debts. In the age of ‘scientific’ finance and securitisation. Today’s CRAs are the products of their time. much as in the bubbles of the 1980s and late 1990s. During 2002–7.T he Th re e Pillars of T h e liQ u idi Ty i l l u s i o n 135 seems to have been no more than a blip in the larger trend of speculation and expansion. Credit rating agencies (CRAs) have been with us for a long time. in order to turn sub-prime loans into liquid securities someone. became the ‘new masters of capital’. in . was needed to act as market-maker on a large scale and sustain collective belief in the liquidity of what were. But it is with the rise of today’s self-regulating finance that CRAs have assumed a new niche of private authority in the markets and.

ratings have increasingly become the norm of the price mechanism of the market (ibid. the easier it is to sell the asset to a final buyer. And they were paid for their ratings by the banks. the liberalisation of the financial markets and the general transformation of finance into the business of risk optimisation have increased the importance of investigation. analytical mechanisms and calculative practices in finance. and as the valuation mechanisms and trust implicit in the older system of bank intermediation have broken down. and the like have been required to buy investment-grade securities as rated by one of the nationally recognised rating agencies. by and large. Institutional investors. The higher the credit rating of a security. At the same time. it suffered no penalty (Wade 2008: 30–1). The role CRAs played in turning toxic securities into tradable assets and subsequently in making the bubble implode4 is one of the least disputed aspects of the global meltdown. insurance companies. the rating agency in question bore no responsibility for its rating: if it made a mistake. Opinions do diverge. market liquidity. The functioning of the market and the tradability (synonymous for many with liquidity) of mortgage-based securities fundamentally depended on the ratings they acquired. As capital markets have displaced bank lending. As Sinclair explains.). crucially. ratings agencies have acquired unprecedented power. as to precisely what aspect of their operation was so detrimental to the financial economy. trusts.136 f inancial alchemy in crisis some readings. such as pension funds. however. Some argue that. .

the rating business has shifted from providing information to selling ‘regulatory licences’ – or keys to ‘unlocking financial markets’. the crisis made it clear that CRAs have . they face a conflict of interest between their objective to make profits and their role as independent risk assessors (Wade 2008). predicting valuations of future risks based on narrow historical records – that were flawed (Boorer 2008). but because these higher ratings permitted investors to buy something triple A-rated which paid 20 times the spread of other triple A-rated instruments. the financial Frankensteins that the CRAs’ mathematical models said were low-risk. Others note that the CRAs themselves are not the villains. issuers and ratings agencies to create complex financial instruments that received higher ratings than they deserved. but it is the methodological assumptions of the models they used – for instance. In principle. the real problem lies with the rules and regulations that govern them.T he Th re e Pillars of Th e liQ u idi T y i l l u s i o n 1 37 CRAs performed well. they cannot serve as an effective assessor of value for the financial market. the AAA ratings of these instruments were granted not because of the underlying information. In the case of Constant Proportion Debt Obligations. Partnoy (2008) argues. ratings-based rules precipitated the crisis by creating perverse incentives for arrangers. Being regulated under the Basle accord. As Partnoy (2008) insists. Still others argue that the core problem with CRAs is structural: as private companies. therefore. Notwithstanding the nuances of this continuing debate.

138

f inanci al alchemy in crisis

aggravated the securitisation bubble by creating the illusion of liquidity in the markets and wider political-economic systems. Functionally, as noted above, they have been trapped by the basic conflict of interest between being private, profit-seeking companies and their function of providing an independent assessment of risks to the market. This trap has affected their performance in three ways. First, each rating agency had an incentive to overrate the products in order to attract more deals. Second, CRAs run a parallel line of business, giving advice on how to structure financial products. Just as in the case of financial analysts and crooked accounting firms in the 1990s dot.com boom, the CRAs’ advice was skewed by the hope that the products on which they advised would also come to them for rating, giving them a double stream of revenue and a double incentive to overrate. The third conflict, the most egregious of all according to Wade, also parallels the privately defined regulatory context of the dot.com boom. Under US securities law, ratings agencies were not obliged to undertake their own due diligence about the risk characteristics of the products they were rating. Legally, they were entitled to take the information provided by the seller more or less at face value. This, Wade (2008: 33) argues, gave the seller an even stronger incentive to deceive. Another crucial aspect of the CRAs’ role in precipitating the meltdown concerns the methods they relied on when rating the newly minted securities. Here, again in intriguing parallel to the ‘new economy’ boom,

T he T hree Pi llars of T he li Qu idi T y i l l u s i o n

13 9

a complex process of financial innovation has been at work: first, formal separation of ownership, driven by regulatory avoidance, manipulation of legal ownership of assets and creative accounting; and second, the technique of layering securitisation structures. Credit rating agencies have been pivotal to both. From the very beginning of the securitisation boom, a central objective in ensuring the marketability of securitised debt has been to enable the rating agencies to grade the credit risk of the assets in isolation from the credit risk of the entity that originated the assets. Rating agencies demanded legal opinion that the securitised assets represented a so-called ‘true sale’ and were outside the estate of the originator in the event the originator went bankrupt (Baron 2000: 87). Such separation was essential for the approval stamp that the risk was redistributed and removed from the originator’s books. This role was played by scores of offshore SPVs, which were set up specifically as sham operations to isolate the originators from the product they sold. Once the assets had been isolated from the insolvency risk of the originator, no further credit risk analysis was required from the purchaser. Risk analysis, however, was required from credit rating agencies, and it is here that they failed most miserably. According to Lowenstein (2008), in the euphoria of 2006, a Moody’s analyst had, on average, a day to process the credit data from the bank. The analyst was not evaluating the mortgages but rather the bonds issued by the SPV. The SPV would purchase

140

financi al alchemy in crisis

the mortgages. Thereafter, monthly payments from the homeowners would go to the SPV. The SPV would finance itself by selling bonds. The question for Moody’s was whether the inflow of mortgage payments would cover the outgoing payments to bondholders. For the bank, the key to the deal was obtaining an AAA rating, without which the deal would not be profitable. The secret to turning a sub-prime loan into a triple-A asset lay in the innovative technique of layering various types of assets according to their seniority. The highest-rated bonds would have priority on the cash received from mortgage holders until they were paid in full, followed by the next tier of bonds, then the next, and so on. The bonds at the bottom of the pile – the ‘equity’ tranche – got the highest interest rate, but would absorb the first losses in the event of defaults (IMF 2007b; Lowenstein 2008). Thus in another worrying parallel to the financial fraud of the dot.com era, the private agencies of the self-regulating market were now heavily implicated in facilitating dubious financial practices and outright fraud. The similarities between the ‘true sale’ idea of using SPVs in the securitisation process and the legal manipulation through the use of special purpose entities (SPEs) in the dot.com era are hard to ignore. In the case of Enron, for instance, SPEs – most infamous among them was something called Raptor – provided hedging insurance to Enron for any losses the latter might suffer from its volatile investments. To achieve this, Raptor needed to be a legal entity independent and separate

T he T hree Pi llars of T he li Qu idi T y i l l u s i o n

14 1

from Enron (Tinker and Carter 2003: 579). Being in full compliance with Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP) requirements as to its independence, Raptor was in a position to offer Enron a hedge contract on any of the latter’s investments, whereby Raptor guaranteed Enron that it would absorb any loss in value should the value of Enron’s asset portfolio decline. No recompense for the hedge was needed, as Raptor would be allowed to reap any profits in the (unlikely) event that the investment appreciated in value. Mirroring the experience of the Granite fund and Northern Rock discussed in Chapter 2, the scheme unravelled when Enron’s own stock declined in value amidst rumours about the firm’s economic viability. Raptor was first hit through its balance sheet. In order to compensate for the losses on its books, Raptor, along with several other SPEs, was consolidated into Enron’s accounts, registering an immediate loss in excess of $500m (ibid.: 580). Eventually, the firm sank. So we can see that the securitisation boom of 2002–7 was built on one great illusion – liquidity. Financial agents and engineers, relying on the techniques of scientific finance, ‘created’ the markets for what were essentially bundles of toxic debt. The regulatory paradigm supported this practice in two major ways. Analytically, the regulatory principles of most financial supervisory bodies assumed the markets to be always liquid, prioritising not only the risk of market or systemic illiquidity, but also individual and specific risks that financial institutions might face while

142 financial alchemy in crisis operating in such a system. . Mainstream finance theory. in turn. Institutionally. Like most illusions. Politicians reaped the benefits. a whole set of regulatory norms produced the specific pillars of the illusion of liquidity during 2002–7: the markets’ view that liquidity is synonymous with confidence and thus is self-fulfilling. the global financial architecture reflected the idea of liquidityenhancing financial innovation. and the financial trade based on credit ratings. however. has guided this trend. the illusion of liquidity eventually came to a destructive end. ‘democratised’ finance. arguing that this new approach to managing risks enhances market liquidity and the financial robustness of the economy. as a result. partly by capitalising on the contribution of the financial sector to the economy. and partly by advocating the social welfare gains of new.

financial institutions and traders enhance the liquidity – and thus the stability – of the financial system as a whole. crucially. by the structure of financial regulation founded within the private realm of finance. It has been argued in earlier chapters that the great illusion of liquidity that lies at the heart of the credit crunch 143 . As the credit boom of 2002–7 illustrated. yet the idea of ultimate benefits brought by private financial innovation – social. Scholars and analysts had long pointed out the flaws in such reasoning. the global credit crunch became the crisis of the latest bout of financial alchemy. the illusion of liquidity was supported by the political and theoretical edifice of global financial governance. economic and political – became an axiom of modern finance.6 after the Meltdown: rewrItInG the rules of GloBal fInance? Essentially. the social institutions of the financial markets today and. The dangerous illusion of wealth which became an article of faith during 2002–7 was centred on the idea of infinite market liquidity and the notion that through continuous innovation in new financial techniques and instruments.

with this move. high-powered . central banks rushed to put out the fire with massive injections of cash. Effectively. quite a lot: the policy response to the global meltdown has evolved through three distinct stages. several central banks agreed to offer their guarantees in exchange for toxic assets from financial institutions. Essentially. unblocking credit lines through monetary injections that were quite unprecedented in their scale. the answer is. the first phase was about pumping money into the frozen markets and was defined by the efforts of the national monetary authorities. Now that the global credit meltdown has passed its second anniversary. As the crisis progressed. The Three stages of the Policy response Ad hoc Crisis Management (10 August 2007–9 October 2008) In the first days of the unfolding turmoil. Hence the efforts of the regulators centred on opening up the markets.144 f inanci al alchemy in crisis was built on these three pillars of modern finance. cutting interest rates and trying to make the financial institutions lend to each other. often coordinated internationally. governments validated the experiments of private financiers by offering state-backed. The amounts set the tone for how the crisis would be handled for the year ahead. to restore confidence (understood as liquidity) in the financial markets. one question naturally arises: What has been done? At first glance.

This decision remains one of the most controversial policies of the global credit meltdown. Panics require urgent. In the midst of the panic that paralysed the global markets in the late summer of 2007. National Recapitalisation Schemes (9 October 2008–2009) Following the government takeover of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and the collapse of Lehman Brothers. the immediacy of political reaction was understandable.af T er T he me lT doW n 14 5 liquidity to individual institutions which could no longer shift their junk paper in the markets. decisive action. however. Not only does it go against the golden rule of monetary theory and the principle of a lender-of-last-resort action. whether governmentsupported or not. the ad hoc measures proved to be insufficient. Neither the exorbitant size of cash injections nor the central banks’ attempts at transatlantic regulatory coordination helped quell the turmoil.2 Even this radical response to the crisis brought feeble results. the world entered the second phase of crisis management: . allowing little time for deep analysis or musings about the actual causes or lessons to be learnt from the crisis.1 it is also unclear what will happen to the billions of dollars of toxic debts now being held by the banks. Yet as the crisis intensified and transformed into deeper problems in the national and international credit systems.

A Troubled Assets Relief Programme (TARP) gave the Treasury. The British solution to the problem of de facto insolvent banks was drafted over the first weekend of October 2008. In a quite extraordinary turn against the principle of the free market. governments in the US and Europe followed the example set by the UK in launching recapitalisation or bailout plans for the troubled banks. In the US. authority to buy or insure up to £700bn of illiquid assets from private financial institutions (Wigan 2010 forthcoming). The so-called Brown-Darling £500bn bailout aimed to transform the way these institutions are run by using public funds.146 f inancial alchemy in crisis national recapitalisation programmes. The conditions attached to the use of taxpayers’ money included curbs on executive pay. via the Office of Financial Stability (OFS). With the election of Barack Obama as president in November 2008. suspending payment of dividends to shareholders and maintaining lending to small businesses and homebuyers at 2007 levels. . a similar scheme was launched. In parallel. an additional $787bn fiscal stimulus was launched. The UK rescue plan therefore contained a vital element of conditionality within the new liquidity provisions to the banking system. a special term asset-backed securities loan facility (Talf) gave investment groups access to cheap leverage so that they could buy securitised bonds. where since April 2008 the Fed had been expanding its lending facilities (and its balance sheet). The government’s goal was to restore the credit circulation not only within the financial system but also in the ‘real’ economy.

since the latter’s acquisition of the stricken HBOS. The banks in turn. since the funding plan effectively recognised that the insurance giant had transformed itself into a de facto investment bank through its subsidiary. toxic asset purchases. the mood in the world of finance was far from optimistic. In November 2008.42 trillion – made up of capital injections. although publicly shamed by various governmental committees for their experiments during . Oxfam (2009) estimates that governments have pumped $8. subsidised loans and debt guarantees – into the failed financial institutions. the rescue plan for AIG is of particular significance. Overall. Financial Products AIG. As Wigan (2010 forthcoming) writes.3 In total. The reaction from the financial markets was half-hearted: although market indices stopped falling uncontrollably. The bailout plans met with little success. Cavanagh and Redman 2008). the US and European bailouts taken together were 41 times more than their commitment to development aid and 313 times more than the funding pledged to climate change control (Handerson. In the US. the UK government is now the majority shareholder in both RBS and Lloyds TSB. starting with Northern Rock. several big banks in the US and the UK have come – either partly or totally – under state ownership.afT e r T h e me lTd oWn 147 As a result of these bailouts. he notes. the majority of the failed institutions had to agree – extremely reluctantly – to become part of the scheme in which their share of toxic securities was acquired by the state in exchange for public control.

fuelling public and media fury. and the chain of bankruptcies expanded into the real economy. Its inception can be dated to 15 November 2008. were slow and reluctant to accept state help. The G20 summit. It did not help when it emerged that executives in the key financial institutions. was a central forum in . it did mark the beginning of a series of efforts at the global level to reform world finance. Lending levels remained low. Although the summit did not bring any tangible results. which reconvened in September 2009. have received vast amounts in bonus payments. the world financial crisis descended into a global recession.148 financi al alchemy in crisis 2002–7. two key events have spurred progress on these efforts: the election of Barack Obama and the G20 London summit in April 2009. albeit rather too hastily. such as AIG and Goldman Sachs in the US and RBS-HBOS in the UK. other than public commitments to bolster the global financial system and rethink existing approaches to financial governance. DC for a summit that was dubbed ‘Bretton Woods 2’. even claiming that ‘they are not charity’ cases. International Financial Reform (15 November 2008–?) The deterioration of economic conditions worldwide has moved crisis management into its third phase: an international regulatory response. In the meantime. when world leaders gathered in Washington. To date. The Obama administration has been behind a radical plan for financial reform announced in June 2009.

at various levels. if any. it is difficult to comment on the proposals that are being debated. And while it is difficult to predict which form the world financial architecture will assume.af T er T he me lT doWn 14 9 which pre-existing differences of opinion and politics had to be renegotiated in order to produce a plan for financial reform which all could agree to. The crisis and Geopolitics: a new special relationship? The first visible crack in the seemingly global reaction to the crisis is geopolitical. this book concludes its analysis of the global meltdown by charting the key lines of the debate that appear to be informing the new vision for global finance. finally. the chapter delves into some of the key rifts that have surfaced to date. So. therefore. plans for a new architecture of global finance are still being negotiated. and simply impossible to foresee which version. as it seems likely that both political and analytical differences will affect the course of action. all three stages of the policy response to the meltdown have been marked by divisions and conflict. to coordination at the international level. is likely to be implemented as policy action. in the evolution of the policy reaction to the crisis. it is clear that these differences are determining the path of financial reform. both analytical and geopolitical. In what follows. Put in somewhat crude terms. Instead. from localised injection of money to national bailout schemes and. As this book goes to press (winter 2009). Indeed. it can be understood as a reflection of the .

Here. one important conceptual detail of the US bailout plan stands out. in the US until the nationalisation of Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae and the collapse of Lehman Brothers. where there is a sharp divide between the UK and other EU members. within the EU itself.150 financial alchemy in crisis long-running differences between the Anglo-Saxon and continental models of capitalism. Originally. the UK has built its economic strength on the power of the City of London as the world centre for financial innovation. the official reflection on the . the political response to the credit crunch was simply an attempt to restore confidence by pumping liquidity into the markets. In the context of the global credit crunch. Whereas the EU has traditionally been more in favour of closer regulation of the financial industry. for its part. these political differences have centred on the way politicians at different levels of the decision-making hierarchy chose to interpret the nature of the crisis and its major lessons. the line cuts in two ways: between London and Wall Street on the one hand and Brussels on the other. has been opposed to the idea of preventing market progress by administrative or political interference since the 1970s. Both sides of the conflict centre on how national (and supranational) authorities view the process of financial liberalisation. In the age of financial capitalism. most notably France and Germany. The United States As noted above. The US.

protects consumers and investors. The proposal targets financial regulation at four key levels: 1. installing. or ‘objectives-based’ plan. the blueprint. Oversight and close supervision of financial firms. Specifically. was designed to address individual market and business failures rather than question the core principles of the functioning of the financial system. in particular. The version of the reform proposal launched by the Obama administration in early summer 2009 takes things much further. Stronger regulatory potential by the government. Comprehensive supervision of the financial markets. as articulated by the US Treasury Secretary in the March 2008 blueprint for a new system of regulation (Paulson. new requirements for regulation of the financial products that previously were traded in unregulated exchanges. rewards innovation and is able to adapt and evolve in line with changes in the financial markets (US Treasury 2009: 2). 2. 3.afT e r T h e me lTd oWn 1 51 lessons from the crisis. Steel and Nason 2008). The plan aims to build ‘a new foundation’ for financial regulation and supervision that is simpler and more effectively enforced. stressed that innovation and market competition remain the priority for the US economy. including the establishment of several new institutions that would undertake the task at the federal level. extending the scope of regulation to non-banks .

by raising international regulatory standards and levels of coordination.5 Moreover. nationally and internationally.4 At first glance. As noted above.152 financi al alchemy in crisis and adding to the apparatus of existing financial supervisory authorities at the Federal level. At the same time. lack of clarity associated with the division of powers and responsibilities between the monetary authorities and financial supervisors has been a major factor in aggravating the crisis. In its call for a system-wide overhaul of financial supervision. and that existing market-friendly standards of governance have been unable to address them. critics have pointed out that the apparent comprehensiveness of the plan is illusory. and as many analysts continue to reiterate. there is a risk that the reform will only complicate the already cumbersome structure of financial governance in the US. In this respect. the proposal is thin on concrete initiatives and fails to address many important issues. Obama’s vision for a new financial system stands in stark contrast to a much more muted and light approach of the blueprint drafted by Paulson’s team in spring 2008. a more . Although full of good intentions. 4. calling for more regulatory bodies and extended powers in the US network of financial regulators. The plan also commits the US to taking a lead in strengthening international financial reform. it is a long-needed and welcome step towards public acknowledgement that financial excesses have disastrous consequences for society and the state.

the EU followed the US in acknowledging the need for international policy coordination. they centre on the differences between American and European officials in drawing lessons about the risks and benefits of financial innovation and liberalisation. if any. significant divisions. To complicate matters. Europe Things in Europe have been somewhat different. the EU’s initial regulatory response to the crisis echoed the themes of the US March 2008 blueprint. not least because the risk of a cross-border banking crisis was deemed high. Yet. between the US and Europe gradually surfaced. On the face of it. Fundamentally. of the proposals is likely to make it to the final policy act. In spring 2008. which has been a key problem in the global meltdown (Crook 2009). both conceptual and policyrelated. the plan has yet to gain congressional approval and it is unclear which version. Therefore. the Obama administration’s proposals for a better governed financial system have left many questions about the credit crisis unanswered.afT e r Th e me lTd oWn 153 effective mechanism of crisis resolution would need to be much more transparent and simple. . A more complicated domestic regulatory framework would also undermine the effectiveness of any international coordination in terms of cross-border supervision. rather than complex. notwithstanding its radical tone. though not decisively so.

upgrading valuation standards.154 f inanci al alchemy in crisis The European ‘roadmap’ for a new regulatory structure is built on four conceptual areas: improving qualitative information and transparency for investors. including the European divisions of US banks. in Europe arguments have centred on the split between the UK and continental Europe. these distinctions became ever more apparent. and reviewing the role and use of credit rating agencies in the financial markets. Over the course of 2008–9. the EU’s stronger preference for tighter financial regulation and calls for a pan-European committee of financial supervisors have been the major stumbling blocks to discussion in the November 2008 and April 2009 summits. the Financial Times reported that ‘fears are rising in the City [of London] that strict new European regulation could hit the financial services . These measures would make it more expensive to package and sell obscure products such as mortgage-backed securities (MBSs) in Europe and thus erect a barrier in the way of the further evolution of securitisation. Specific regulatory norms proposed by the EU include higher and tighter capital and liquidity requirements for all banks operating in Europe. As proposals for regulatory reforms matured from initial discussions to the level of procedural planning and implementation. While the voice of American delegations in these summits has been muted due to the political changes in the US. strengthening prudential frameworks and risk management in financial institutions. In June 2008.

But the devil. as they say. Such a body would also be able to bully reluctant regulators elsewhere in the EU into demonstrating that their banks hold sufficient risk capital (Financial Times. such as credit ratings agencies and central clearing houses. is in the detail. All these proposals have unnerved . • The proposal that supervision of entities with a pan-European reach. for tighter regulation of hedge funds and private equity. Financial institutions would also have to meet increased minimum capital requirements and limits on borrowing. • The proposal that EU supervisors be empowered to demand that national governments bail out banks. • The idea that an EU ‘systemic risk council’ (a new supervisory body) would be chaired by the president of the ECB. Specific European proposals that trouble Britain include: • The proposal. A European institution setting minimum standards would fetter the competitive drive to deregulate between countries. The EU directive would also require many hedge funds and private equity firms to register with regulators and disclose more about themselves and their investments. set out in an EC paper.af T er T he me lT doWn 15 5 sector as a weakened Prime Minister confronts the leaders of France and Germany buoyed by their success in the European elections’ (Masters and Barber 2009: 3). should be at the EU level. 11 June 2009).

156 f inanci al alchemy in crisis the City. In July 2009. Lord Myners. en route to a new architecture of financial governance. technical and political. The plans for a new financial architecture are also riddled with opacities and conflicts at a deeper. conceptual level. At the level of global geopolitics. the post-crisis regulatory fallout can broadly be divided into two . therefore. the real danger is that despite the severity of the crisis and ostensible determination of a number of policymakers to rewrite the rules of global finance. As some commentators and politicians began talking about the ‘green shoots of recovery’ in the second half of 2009. But the problems with the crisis response unfortunately do not stop here. conceptual dilemmas and Traps In terms of its theoretical underpinnings. claimed that the plans to regulate the hedge fund industry are motivated by political gains and are ‘bordering on a weak form of protectionism’ (Jones 2009). amidst reports that delegates from the City of London Corporation had been sent to Washington to seek American support in drafting a resistance to the EU initiative. Considering the politics of financial regulation on both sides of the Atlantic. the post-credit crunch financial system may not be so different from its predecessor. Financial Services Secretary to the UK Treasury. as well as the poor record of previous efforts to design a global financial architecture. there are serious stumbling blocks. the efforts will be too vague and hesitant.

is a search for comprehensive..afT e r T h e me lTd oWn 157 distinct paradigms of finance. . but the timing and strength of the recovery are highly uncertain . The first. Stressing the benefits that the era of new. or the structure and principles of the economic organisation as a whole: ‘[T]he global economy will recover. more up-to-date and competent approach to financial regulation and governance. I believe that the Fed still has powerful tools at its disposal to fight the financial crisis and the economic downturn …’ (Bernanke 2009). Their emphasis in challenging the basic paradigm of finance today could be called the ‘traditionalist’ approach to financial reform. these theories tend to be built on structural explanations of the crisis. more mainstream set of opinions and plans come under the rubric of ‘making financial innovation work’. The second.. diagnosing it as a major breakdown in the very foundations of Anglo-Saxon capitalist organisation. Rarely do these views question the logic of existing economic and policy frameworks. these proposals call for a better. democratised finance and financial innovation has brought to society. quite radical range of views is framed by disillusionment with the performance of the financial industry over the past few decades more broadly. This school of thought diagnoses the credit crunch as a cyclical event and strives to find policy solutions to the crisis within the existing range of tools available to governments and markets. In essence. systemic solutions to the crisis. therefore. The resulting reform agenda.

trading. specialists in academic finance theory. valuation and supervision techniques. The Traditionalist School: Return to Prudence and Old Values you have forgotten the basics of what finance and banking are for. Intellectually. The banker. on occasion. you have carried your institutions into abyss. on the contrary. The audience – comprising mostly young finance geeks – was clearly not impressed. These were the key words of a plenary address given by a senior bank executive to a credit risk summit held in London in October 2008. are couched in the specialised financial language of today and are formulated by a range of financial practitioners. the ‘traditionalists’ frequently draw their insights from history and non-economic academic disciplines and they often appeal to a wider audience. who started his career in the 1950s at a desk in a provincial bank.158 financial alchemy in crisis A notable distinction between the two groups lies in their intellectual origins. in your financial experiments. the second is mostly built on the idea of improving the current practice of investment. observers and. are dominated by expert forums. private financiers. The latter approaches. it is time to return to some old-fashioned banking. While the first school of thought is informed by considerations of the place of finance and money in society. at the expense of all of us. was asked only one question from the audience at the end of his address: ‘So has .

Therefore. and made aggressive greed the code of practice in the financial industry. supported by unanimous understanding in the markets that things will be fine ‘as long as the music is playing’. the views of some politicians and a few financiers – most prominently Warren Buffet and George Soros. Innovation and speculation. encouraged herding. the advocates of this group call for a rethink of the very structure and purpose of the financial system today. the use of common analytical and trading techniques. ‘liquidity’. underpinned by the desire for quick profits and market-making opportunities. The markets’ appetite for apparent efficiency. have gone too far. corrupt and unaccountable financial industry. Blaming the crisis not merely on specific investment and speculation techniques. it emerged that the bank in question is the only British bank that has got through the credit crunch with minimal losses. has made finance a very brittle system. amidst calls to overhaul this dangerous and obscure financial industry. It accommodates the many angry voices of civil society groups. senior managers and analysts.af T er T he me lT doWn 15 9 your bank avoided all the losses then?’ Later. the anti-greed . they argue. exuberance and short-termism. As the traditionalists argue. but rather on the whole culture that has bred irresponsible. but ultimately came at the high cost of the public good of financial stability. This anecdote captures the essence of the ‘traditionalist’ school on the lessons of the credit crunch. flexibility and profits has not only bred pervasive unaccountability on behalf of individual traders.

hierarchies of power and coordination rather than horizontal .160 financi al alchemy in crisis and ‘pro-prudence’ regulatory camp calls for the return of old-fashioned. based on a culture of thrift rather than spending. We have a very conservative business model not by luck but by design. Accordingly. one that is more prudent and long-term in its orientation. our goal is not to maximise earnings in any given year but to have a profitable business for centuries. ‘We see ourselves as retailers. the vision of a better capitalist system of finance tends to be charted either along Keynesian lines of the regulatory state or. boring banking and conservative finance – in terms of both size and aspirations: ‘The market will reward you for safe. Specifically. speculative investment banking. long-term profits even though they happen to be lower than your rivals’ in any given year’. the traditionalists argue.) Crucially. would also require restoring the state to the centre of power vis-à-vis the City and Wall Street and warrant severe punishment for the convicted fraudsters who have made their fortunes in the bubble. at some extreme.’ says an executive of a medium-size bank commenting on the role of the culture of big-bank aggressive competition in the crisis. a new financial order. by drawing on the virtues of a more ‘Asian’ type of capitalism. at the expense of us all. as an executive of a medium-sized lender argued (in Guerrera 2009). to ensure a better financial system in the future. (ibid. the world needs to make a clear distinction between socially useful banking (retail and commercial) and the more parasitic.

for instance. has designed new tools of ‘smart securitisation’. such as ATM machines and internet banking.6 Within hours of being published. on the other hand. such proposals prove to be far too threatening for the financial industry and hence too sensitive for political authorities. paternalistic loyalty rather than aggressive competition and flexibility. in July 2009. and maintain that without the massive investments poured into the industry by competitive lenders. the UK itself was vehemently resisting EU pressure for a pan-European system of tighter financial supervision and regulation. for example. while analysts and critics argued that the plan is far too anaemic and not radical enough in challenging the culture of greed and unaccountability. are typically caught between electoral priorities and pressures from the financial industry. are keen to find ways to recycle their old. Barclays Capital. Predictably. representatives of big financial firms defend the culture of competition and innovation. etc. The financial markets. consumers and the real economy would have been deprived of now mundane services. The technique enables clients to reduce the amount of capital they must hold.af T er T he me lT doWn 161 networks. as noted above. the UK authorities drafted a White Paper proposing changes to the existing system of bank regulation. toxic products. Indeed. On the one hand. Meanwhile. in the meantime. It works by . the plan came under fire from two sides: bankers accused it of being politically motivated and even incompetent. especially in Anglo-Saxon capitalism. Politicians.

that needs to be addressed by the new regulatory paradigm in the post-crisis environment. much wider group of post-crisis reflections encompasses policy discussion at various levels and is unfolding along with the dialogue with private financial actors. doesn’t it? Making Financial Innovation Work The second. ‘securitisations have become ridiculously complex. With some variation. director-general of market operations at the ECB. plain-vanilla deals’ (in Tett and van Duyn 2009). but also creating opacity within the financial markets. and the obscurity of finance. what defines these views is their critical examination of some of the new financial practices and products that became the defining features of the latest round of securitisation and ‘re-securitisation’. Highlighted by the G20 statement on financial architecture in April 2009 as well as several high-profile . To these ends. Structures should become simpler. it is argued. have made the system as a whole less transparent and more obscure. such a vehicle would require a lower level of capital to be held against it (Tett and van Duyn 2009). With a decent rating. various improvements to the current self-regulating financial system are being proposed. It is this gap. According to Francesco Papadia. Sounds familiar.162 financi al alchemy in crisis pooling their assets with those of other clients into a securitisation vehicle large enough to be rated by a credit rating agency. not only widening the gap between the regulators and financiers. These practices.

and on regulating what is being understood as ‘systemic risk’ in finance. Measures being proposed include: • A ‘Basle III’ accord on capital and liquidity norms that would be counter-cyclical and require financial firms to hold more liquid assets. they are based on the idea of rebalancing private gains and social losses. • The need to license and control credit rating agencies that have disgraced themselves by assigning AAA ratings to toxic and illiquid securities. whereas regulatory structures like the FSA should offer better pay to their personnel in order to attract and retain employees who actually understand what they are charged with regulating. This proposal concerns financiers themselves: CEOs should not receive excessive pay and bonuses. thereby making financial trades more transparent and hence accountable. especially when these are funded by the taxpayer.) • The need to set up organised and centralised trading platforms for products that were traded off market until recently (like OTC derivatives). • National plans to re-empower and strengthen the mandates of existing monetary and financial . (These controls are mainly advocated by the EU.afT e r T h e me lTd oWn 163 reviews of the lessons of the global credit crunch. • The need to change the structure of incentives.

‘scientific’ risk management and financial sophistication. it is difficult to predict which version of the proposals will be incorporated into concrete policy. therefore. The G20 plan for strengthening the . the process at the core of the crisis – the ability of financial engineers to transform obscure debts into ‘liquid’ assets – is not being questioned. there are also proposals to set up a pan-European body with a similar agenda. regulators and home buyers to believe that global capitalism had entered a new era of resilience and prosperity based on deregulated credit. though these ideas remain riddled with political conflicts. This illusion led politicians. that in the current discussions of the future of finance.164 f inancial alchemy in crisis institutions. the major lesson of the global credit crunch has been the fact that the meltdown came as a result of a long tradition of financial innovation and the belief that financial engineering creates money and wealth. It is particularly disappointing. (The most recent negotiations have charged the IMF with this task.) Again. In essence. • The need to set up some sort of system of international coordination to detect the warning signs of financial trouble ahead which would respond efficiently to the emerging crisis. the credit boom of 2002–7 was based on a pervasive illusion of liquidity that blinded financiers into taking on multi-billion dollar parcels of debt. In terms of the analysis of the crisis presented in this book. as mentioned above.

2009: 10) Generally. restrictive control of financial intermediation stifles innovation and. avoid adverse impacts on other countries. with appropriate assistance from the state. as stressed in the G20 communiqué: ‘Regulators and supervisors must protect consumers and investors. (Brunnermeier et al.af Te r T he me lT doW n 16 5 global financial system. are even more confident of the ultimately beneficial role of financial innovation: our preference is for light-touch regulation (with one exception on housing loan-to-value ratios …). the mainstream solution to the global crisis is based on the cyclical theory of financial crisis and on the belief that the market mechanism. and keep pace with innovation in the marketplace’ (G20 2009: paragraph 14). is disappointingly reminiscent of its rather impotent predecessor: the brief attempt to erect a New International Financial Architecture (NIFA) in the wake of the late 1990s crises. one of the high-profile policy reports on the crisis. in general. therefore. interferes with the appropriate allocation of capital. indeed crucial. The regulatory and policy adjustments necessary for stabilisation and recovery in turn should not compromise the abiding principles of free competition: ‘It is important. support competition and dynamism. can re-balance itself in the event of failure. for instance. The authors of the Geneva report. Indeed. support market discipline. that . especially if government starts to intervene with direct controls over bank lending. reduce the scope for regulatory arbitrage.

but for reasons specific to 2002–7. without killing the underlying drive for financial innovation. importantly. it has been mispriced and misallocated. A better approach to financial regulation in the future should therefore compensate for these flaws. no one within the emergent mainstream of post-crisis policy debate is seriously challenging the idea that private financial innovation and complexity have become such a destabilising factor that it has moved many segments of the financial system – the regulation of liquidity being one of them – beyond the reach of regulators. confidence itself is not synonymous with liquidity. The logic underpinning these proposals is that. few seem to understand that. appearances notwithstanding. As a result. At the same time. without undermining the key benefits of innovative. Moreover. . as a principle. risk-taking is a healthy and positive part of economic activity.166 f inanci al alchemy in crisis any reforms in. and adjustments to. privatised finance. As a result. the emerging debate over an appropriate regulatory response concerns the fine-tuning of existing principles of financial policy and governance. competition and liberalisation of markets. Thus the key lesson that cyclical interpretations of the crisis draw from the global crisis is the idea that the real problem of the global credit crunch is its sheer magnitude. the structure of markets and regulation not inhibit our most reliable and effective safeguards against cumulative economic failure: market flexibility and open competition’ (Greenspan 2008a).

Since the late 1970s. has firmly shaped the ‘constitution of global capitalism’ (Gill 2002. the paradigm of market-driven progress has not been seriously challenged and. while more recently. Despite the waves of financial disasters and growing tensions within the economies of advanced capitalism. the wave of financial crises of the late 1990s has given rise to what has been dubbed a New International Financial Architecture (NIFA). It is thus likely to lead us into another one in the not-too-distant future. and the very meaning of what ‘liquidity’ is. few heed their warnings once the financial cycle and market ‘liquidity’ are restored.afT e r T h e me lT d oWn 167 however. the past few decades of the evolution of financial architecture suggest that despite the radical tones and ostensibly far reach of some of the post-credit crunch proposals for reform. NIFA was briefly in vogue from . every crisis – economic and financial – almost invariably rekindled the calls for a ‘new Bretton Woods’ system. the injustices of globalising markets fuelled anti-globalisation movements across the world. the nature of assets being created and traded. Even if critics like Minsky appear to be taken seriously during crises. history is a useful indicator of how effective. up to now. attempts to re-regulate finance can aim to be. Vestergaard 2009). Moreover. has led the financial system into the gigantic hole it finds itself in today. very few of the ideas being put forward are essentially new. Indeed. restoring market liquidity without questioning the essence of financial trade today. and stringent. In this instance.

financialised capitalism. now fashionably called a macro-prudential approach to financial governance. liberalisation and competition further. The bodies and committees that were set up under the NIFA umbrella remained poorly coordinated and impotent in terms of their juridical status. Apart from a plethora of forums and committees set up in the wake of the 1997–9 crises (the G20 forum.168 f inanci al alchemy in crisis 1999 until the 9/11 attacks diverted the attention of policymakers from finance-related problems to other areas. various Basle-centred groups. policymakers tend to search for the same weapon.). etc. Recent history also suggests that in another important parallel to earlier attempts to deal with the legacy of the financial crises. NIFA targeted mainly the emerging markets – places notorious for their financial and economic woes – and hence completely overlooked the possibility that a devastating financial malaise might engulf the economies of highly sophisticated. it targets qualitative parameters of financial risk – the macro-prudential approach is in a fact a big elephant in a very dark room. With regard to its focus. . macro-prudential regulation risks becoming to finance what ‘good governance’ has become to politics: instinctively. Financial Stability Forum. Ambitious yet vague on concrete detail. Apparently radical in its tone – unlike conventional quantitative. microeconomic indicators of financial stability. NIFA remained pro-market-centred and aimed to facilitate financial innovation. everyone senses it should be a good thing.

derives from the assumption that. Second. has moved economies far . national-based statistics and the assumptions of monetarism. Yet again. measure or control it. there is currently very little understanding. It certainly has not. how it evolves (Davies 2009). aside from an intuitive understanding that ‘systemic risk’ is widespread. One positive thing about calls for a closer macroprudential focus is that they are based on the apparently serious realisation that the micro-prudential institutionby-institution supervision undertaken by the FSA has not been sufficient. crucially. First. contagious and quite dangerous for the system. least so at the international level. politically and economically.af T er T he me lT doWn 16 9 but no one knows precisely how best to define. as John Plender (2009) argues. however. the macro-prudential approach. had macroeconomic analysis played a larger role in governing finance during the bubble. current proposals are) – is not a panacea which will necessarily save us from financial instability and crises. But macro-prudential regulation – whatever form it might eventually take (and there are serious doubts as to how feasible. The world of finance. There are several reasons for saying this. at the core of the macro-prudential approach is the idea of better management of ‘systemic risk’ in finance. macroeconomic governance has been based on obsolete. as to what ‘systemic’ risk might be and. this argument appears quite naïve: for a while now. Under closer scrutiny. the crisis might have been averted.

the foundations of financial reform continue to prioritise the benefits of financial competition and innovation. as the argument of this book has implied.7 In the wake of the 1990s crises. including John Eatwell and Charles Goodhart. After all. but how best to implement it today remains a very open question. congressional approval. the IMF published proposals for a new macro-prudential approach. and finally. Despite appearances. Third. and several prominent scholars. The City of London is becoming increasingly uneasy about EU-based initiatives for a stronger and wider system of financial regulation. History in turn . policymakers did not pursue it seriously and the idea remained purely academic. Yet lacking a current crisis. To incorporate qualitative indicators of risk in the framework of governance is a good idea. making macroeconomic targeting and even analysis somewhat old-fashioned in an age of obscure financial engineering. while Obama’s radical programme to re-regulate finance still needs more concrete detail on the parameters of national regulatory framework and crucially. in the excitement about post-credit crunch reform people tend to forget that the idea of macro-prudential regulation has a long history. As the political rifts underlying the post-credit crunch reforms outlined above suggest. the global meltdown.170 f inanci al alchemy in crisis beyond national boundaries. very little has changed. analysed in detail the pros and cons of a new paradigm. is a crisis of economics as a profession as much as it is the crisis of finance.

It has exposed financiers as villains. it is revelations of this type – diagnosing the crisis as caused by individual failures rather than a systemic tendency – that will end up being the summary of the legacy of the global meltdown. hence. the pressure from the financial industry and the anaemic nature of the reform proposals noted above render the plan incomplete. including the pillar of macro-prudential regulation. made banking a dirty word. ‘advanced capitalism’ – has come to collapse since the Depression of the 1930s. aside from installing new jargon in the world of finance. While some less controversial and technical proposals for re-regulation may eventually materialise. more accurately. policymakers as laggards and. As the recession lessens and the conflicts within the post-crisis policy debate deepen. is likely to bear little fruit: the global meltdown simply was not painful enough. to the 1999 US Priorities for a Global Financial System. the global credit crunch is the closest the world – or. briefly. and even various Basle-centred initiatives for international financial cooperation in the late 1990s. This is what happened to the 1988 Brady Report. On the other hand. . On the one hand. slow and. financial reform.afT e r T h e me lTd oWn 171 suggests that. That is probably the most tragic paradox of the current crisis. the momentum for a comprehensive financial reform is fading away. ultimately inefficient in preventing another global crisis in the future.

more accurately. 172 . Like other crises. The recession that has subsequently engulfed international markets is the closest the world has come to a global depression since the 1930s. in early October 2008. following the sinking of Lehman Brothers. the credit crunch was brought about by the strategy of financial deregulation. ‘expert’ opinions about a ‘new economy’.conclusIon: a very Mundane crIsIs The global financial meltdown wrought havoc in the countries of ‘advanced’ capitalism. it came at the end of an unsustainable economic boom and a bear market. it was preceded by optimistic. Critically. And yet aside from its geography. or ‘boom-and-bust’ pattern of growth. Like any other crisis. competition for quick and easy profits and lack of oversight of – or. what is most extraordinary about the global meltdown is that in the history of financial capitalism it has been a rather mundane event. the global payment system was on the verge of total breakdown. full of enthusiasm about the extraordinary sophistication of finance in handling risk and widely celebrated political victory over economic cycles. Like most of the crises of the past two decades. In September 2008. the international financial system teetered on the brink of a collapse. after a year of credit paralysis.

As the preceding chapters have shown. the global credit crunch showed that the fashionable enterprise of ‘financial innovation’ only helped disguise the buoyant trade in toxic products. debt structures and the myth of prosperity. Although ostensibly nothing more than a technical term. is still with us. today’s financial alchemy and. The global meltdown revealed ‘liquidity’ as a dangerous beast of modern finance. the availability of easy leverage. strengthen economic stability. despite the severity of the crisis. this book has argued that at the heart of the crisis has been the great illusion that the financial markets actually create liquidity and wealth and thus enhance social and economic well-being and stimulate growth. Built on the theory that by creating a market for a new financial product or technique. And just like every other financial crisis. the paradigm of modern finance – has created the most dangerous of all myths: the liquidity illusion that precipitated the crisis. murky speculative practices and the outright frauds of some financiers and bankers. Like every other bubble. the peculiar and complex relationship between three factors – herd behaviour on the part of financiers. Contrary to mainstream views that the credit crunch was caused by the problem of risk valuation. the credit crunch has been driven by the interplay of market psychology.conclusion: a Ve ry munda n e c r i s i s 173 insight into – the nature of ‘investment’ today. the illusion. the concept of liquidity encapsulates crucial socio-economic and . crucially. therefore. financial engineers enhance the liquidity of the financial system and.

the Ponzi pyramid of bad quality. crises normally affect emerging economies or perhaps individual companies who mismanage their financial affairs. all of these trends and processes can easily be traced back to any of the outbreaks of financial volatility and crisis during the past few decades. Predicated on the confusion between market confidence and systemic liquidity. transparent and advanced financial systems of the West and. not only by scholars of financial history and capitalism. not in kind but in it geographical spread. the widespread belief in the infinite and abundant liquidity of the global market has fuelled the latest bout of securitisation. The sophisticated. and the notion of wealth-enhancing financial engineering. but also by market analysts and participants.174 f inancial alchemy in crisis political dynamics of the modern financial system. According to financial orthodoxy. Yet the debt that was the foundation of the securitisation industry could only be shuffled around temporarily. and did just that. In the end. their pessimistic messages were seen as sour grapes on the part of the financial markets and were unpopular politically. as Minsky and many of his intellectual successors warned. In the midst of the economic boom. illiquid loans was bound to collapse. is unique. The global meltdown. Sadly. The trouble is. The global meltdown has been anticipated and even foreseen. Sceptical voices were mostly heard from the heterodox schools of economics and political economy. . then. those opinions were heresy vis-à-vis the dominant ‘religion’ of efficient finance theory. long banished to the sidelines. specifically.

Minsky and Galbraith – suggest. it also inevitably drives the system towards the brink of a crisis. seems to have been rehabilitated by the economic and financial mainstream. That is perhaps the greatest paradox of the global financial meltdown. however. At the same time. Unfortunately. There are some proposals that aim to eliminate and control . It has erupted as an historical shock to the world of advanced capitalism. It has been unable. this rehabilitation is only partial. however. one odd outcome of the global meltdown is that Minsky. efficient and democratic. Minsky’s most profound message concerned the role of financial innovation in socio-economic stability. along with Keynes and Irving Fisher. Some of the post-crisis moves towards a new architecture of global financial governance do touch on various problems exposed by the credit crunch. the shock seems to be both shallow and short-lived. as references to both the Great Depression and its classic analysts – Keynes. The global credit meltdown has shown this idea to be a dangerous and costly myth. In this respect.conclusion: a V ery munda n e c r i s i s 175 of Anglo-Saxon capitalism had been assumed to be robust. The mechanism that produces such a tendency centres on the myth of liquidity-creating and wealth-enhancing financial innovation. Those who argued that financial fragility is inherent in the economies based on self-regulating capital markets were dismissed as sceptics whose theories lacked a robust technical foundation. He argued that while financial innovation marks any period of economic optimism and tranquillity. to shake the orthodox view of financial innovation.

it was the ability of today’s financial alchemists to build a giant Ponzi pyramid of debt and conceal it with the great illusion of liquidity and wealth that is the real cause of the global financial meltdown. Watch out for comments about ‘abundant liquidity’ and new frontiers of financial innovation and engineering. or even a profound rethink. It also means that such a crisis can.176 f inancial alchemy in crisis greed. and is likely to. All this suggests that despite the emergent buzz of reform. . After all. recur. the global credit meltdown has been neither deep nor painful enough to initiate a radical overhaul. and even challenge the place of offshore financial centres and tax havens. of the rules of global finance. unaccountability and lack of transparency. the notion of ultimately beneficial financial innovation seems to be too sensitive – or perhaps too complex – to be confronted openly. At the same time.

in 2006 13. IKB had to be rescued with a $3. the BIS. It filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy on 6 August 2007. 2. 4.5 per cent of mortgages originating in the US were sub-prime. 6. 3.5bn rescue package put together by a group of public and private sector banks on 1 August 2007. In 2004. Most notably. Occasional studies of liquidity have been published by other central banks in the wake of the crisis. Forbes ranked HSBC as the seventh largest company in the world. Voters evaluated contestants not on the basis of any objective criteria. According to Inside Mortgage Finance. 5. 2. According to the Mortgage Bankers Association. in 2007 HSBC was the world’s seventh largest bank in terms of shareholders’ equity (data from Euromoney). the ECB.notes introduction 1. Keynes likened finance to a beauty contest run by a newspaper.6 per cent in 2000. chapter 1 1. but according to what others might consider to be ‘beautiful’. The Bank of England. noted in October 2008 that liquidity regulation ‘can play an important role in requiring banks to build larger defences against crystallisation of rollover risk’ (2008: 39). 177 . FSF and the IMF. for instance. compared to 2. ResMae Mortgage filed for bankruptcy and Nova Star Financial reported a loss that analysts had not foreseen.

according to Brad Setser. 14 July 2008). (a type of insurance intended to protect buyers should their investments turn sour). A year earlier. China’s biggest banks own large chunks of agency debt. JP Morgan and Merrill Lynch. then US Treasury Secretary. analysts put the total exposure of the six biggest Chinese banks at $30bn (data from Bloomberg News). Also. the two states hold at least $925bn in US agency debt. the AIG bailout would balloon to around $150bn. Analysts estimated that. 11. On 13 December 2007. According to official US data. In the autumn of 2007. is more likely to be about $1 trillion. The second largest holder is Russia. China held $376bn of long-term US agency debt. According to 2008 data. including the Treasuries. including bonds sold by Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae. who actually authorised the AIG bailout. such as Goldman Sachs. The actual amount. Interestingly. seven central banks around the world continued to slash interest rates and provide additional emerging liquidity support to the markets. or a fifth of outstanding agency debt (Bloomberg News.178 f inanci al alchemy in crisis 7. the largest recipient of the AIG debt. A few months later. reacting to falling market indices and more and more bad news coming from individual companies. in the past had repeatedly claimed that derivatives were valuable risk -management tools which did not need . 12. 8. Commentators note an odd coincidence here. that sunk AIG when the sub-prime market turned sour. China controls more than $1 trillion of US debt. It was credit derivatives. was the ‘home’ institution of Hank Paulson. Bear Sterns had been worth £18bn. while the bulk of China’s holdings of US debt is in the hands of the government. 9. the Federal Reserve led an internationally coordinated monetary injection which involved swap facilities and a multi-billion support package between five leading central banks (BBC 2009). the key beneficiaries of the Fed rescue. Goldman Sachs. 10. In July 2008.

Ireland and Luxembourg. chapter 2 1. Latvia and Ukraine suffered the most. threatening in turn the stability of European banking generally. The figures include the Netherlands. 2. Interestingly. South Korea down 25. In the wake of the credit crunch.n oT es 17 9 13. the IMF predicted that the total expected losses by banks and other financial institutions were in the range of $2. Germany’s industrial output was down 19. or more than 50 per cent from the peak reached in summer 2007 (Papademos 2009). 3.8 per cent (in Wolf 2009). Among the emerging markets affected. 14. 16. repo transactions allow banks to post unwanted securitised bonds as collateral to borrow funds from central banks (Tett and van Duyn 2009). In the EU.2 trillion (IMF 2009: 2).6 per cent and Japan down 30. the rest. Yet the banking systems in Eastern Europe – mostly controlled by European banking giants – are at a major risk of collapse. AIG officials also dismissed those who questioned its derivatives operation. Granite had no employees whatsoever. it has also emerged that European banks have incurred higher losses than their US counterparts.2 per cent year-on-year in January. Sale and repurchase agreements. saying that losses were out of the question (Williams Walsh 2009). In March 2009. 15. At the end of 2008. the value of equity has fallen by €6 trillion. We are grateful to Victoria Chick for highlighting this key detail. Until the liquidity squeeze of autumn 2008. which may be controversial. clearly attract these SPVs due . COBRA (Cabinet Office Briefing Rooms) is the UK government’s crisis response committee which deals with national crises such as pandemics and floods. world manufactured output and world trade in manufactures shrank dramatically. including Singapore. Switzerland. to be regulated.

while in Japan and Malaysia the ratio was between 5 and 6 per cent. Based on interviews and analysis by Jon Moulton. .25 trillion. Channel 4. ‘How the Banks Bet Your Money’. in Hong Kong. As of April 2007. According to the BIS. India and South Korea. Renamed the Financial Stability Board in the wake of the global credit crunch. which played a key role in the crisis through the credit risk insurance industry. This compared with 68 per cent in the US. chapter 3 1. The European market is 12 times as large. Investment banks fall under the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). the Federal Reserve Board and the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. 4. Financial markets are supervised by the SEC or by the Commodity Futures Trading Commission. 3. from just over $800bn at end of 2004 (2006: 103–4). The data for the state of the markets for securitised debt also suggested that the financial systems in the Asian economies were ‘too shallow’. the Asian sovereign bond market (valued at $830bn) was less than a tenth the size of its US and Japanese counterparts. According to the BIS. As Buiter explains. 5. 18 February 2008. Insurance. Other depositary institutions are supervised at the Federal level by the Office of Thrift Supervision and the National Credit Union Administration. is not supervised at the Federal level at all (Buiter 2008). only 1 per cent of housing loans were securitised. by early 2006 the combined holdings of China and other large emerging markets had increased to an estimated $1. Dispatches.180 financial alchemy in crisis to their very low tax regimes and because they offer a high degree of opacity and secrecy. at the Federal level commercial banks are supervised by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. 2.

In the context of the credit crunch. the term actually commemorates the life of a scandalous crook. an auditor operating out of a 13 × 18 foot location in a business park in New York City’s northern suburbs. In 2006. As a result of the bailout. Employed in analytical terms by Minsky. 4. Often. 6. the scandals of pyramid schemes run by Madoff and Stanford made the notion ever more widespread. and that their interest repayments after the initial ‘teaser’ periods would be up to 6 per cent (600 basis points) higher than the market average: in other words. who made millions of dollars by fleecing Americans during the 1920s economic boom. financial services incurred £19bn in trade surplus. the City of London was global No.n oT e s 181 chapter 4 1. 3. 5. cross-border bank lending and as a secondary market for international bonds. but was ultimately caught and died in poverty. borrowers were persuaded to take a mortgage without being told that they would be unable to pay it off early or change the terms. they were ensnared in the sub-prime net (Kregel 2008). It was the fastest-growing hedge fund market. lenders and lawyers. and has been the leading hub of financial innovation globally. derivatives and foreign exchange trading. from estate agents and appraisers to underwriters. 2. 68 per cent of the bank is currently owned by the state. targeted anyone involved in fraudulent mortgage loans. Bernard L. . In 2004. Carlo Ponzi. Madoff Investment Securities LLC used Friehling & Horowitz. up 9 per cent from 2003 (Caulkin 2006. The 144 cases. 1 in foreign equity. IFSL 2007). developers. which involved roughly $1bn (£510m) in losses.

At least 22 smaller banks have been allowed to repay some or all of their taxpayer money. $6. As Crook (2009) writes. By issuing ratings downgrades. Data from The Economist. Kregel (2008) notes. Observers agree that the institutions are mainly motivated by the desire to ‘get out from under US government thumb’ (Reuters 2009). 4. US Bancorp and BB&T repaid billions of dollars ($10bn. According to the classic doctrine of Walter Bagehot (2006 [1877]).182 financi al alchemy in crisis chapter 5 1. In this regard.6bn and $3. which was paid $4. The accountancy firm Arthur Andersen. claims that WorldCom’s finance chief Scott Sullivan never handed over the material Andersen asked for (Kadlec 2002).4 million a year to certify that WorldCom’s books were honest. chapter 6 1. 3. supervision of internationally active financial firms. oversight of global financial markets. the plan notes that ‘We will focus on reaching international consensus on four core issues: regulatory capital standards. 4. By the summer of 2009. there is vagueness about how . several financial institutions started repaying the taxpayer funds. 17 May 2007. 2. Here. the lender of last resort should only offer financial help to viable but temporarily illiquid financial institutions under a range of stringent conditions and at a penalty rate. Accepting toxic debt as central bank collateral did not give the central banks a clear ‘way out’.’ 5. Morgan Stanley. and crisis prevention and management.1bn. respectively) in June 2009. 2. the ongoing financial crisis differs from the context Minsky identified. 3. such loose ends concern technical aspects of regulatory capital and leverage ratios for financial institutions.

7. . 6. The paper includes tighter capital and leverage requirements.n oTe s 18 3 Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac – central to the mortgage securities bubble – will be regulated under the new rules. and new norms of consumer protection in the country. I thank Victoria Chick for highlighting this important point to me.

T. London and Cambridge. D.co. 11 March. F. Financial Stability Report. July. Financial Stability Report. 2008. Bank of England 2008. E. http://www.cgi?id=180124&d=103 2&h=1024&f=1026. 2006 [1877]. New York: Macmillan. Financial Stability Report. Baron. W. 184 . eds. 1997. London: Adam Smith Institute. Liquid Claims and National Wealth.bbc.uk/cgi-bin/item. Bagehot. ‘Heavy Financial Regulation Has Created Danger’. 2002. Gloucester: Dodo Press. Fishman. Paris: February.stm. Socialist Register. V. Liquidity Special Issue. A Description of the Money Market. ‘The Growth Obsession’. accountingweb. 29 February. A Primer on Securitization. Financial Times. Bank of England 2006. Ambler. Banque de France 2008. 1934. Feature. Accessed 23 July 2009. Issue 20. in L.co.uk/1/hi/business/7521250. London: October. The Lombard Street. 2008. Timeline: Credit Crunch to Downturn. BBC 2009. ‘Rock Bottom: How Granite Reflects on Financial Reporting’. Socialist Register. MA: MIT Press. Allen. ‘Financial Crises at the Threshold of the 21st Century’. Amery. ‘The Financial Crisis: Is Regulation Cure or Cause?’ Briefing Paper. 110 (January). ‘The Role of Rating Agencies in the Securitization Process’. and Gale. N.BIBlIoGraPhy Accounting Web 2008. Altvater. ‘Bubbles and Crises’. http:// news. E. 2000. Altvater. P. Randall and M. Economic Journal. 2000. Berle. London: Bank of England. A. Accessed 29 July 2009. and Pederson.

C. 2003. Financial Reckoning Day. ‘Market Liquidity and Stress: Selected Issues and Policy Implications’. W. Credit Magazine. ‘The Global Saving Glut and the U. Bonner. Bloomberg News 2008. Surviving the Soft Depression of the 21st Century. C. ‘CSI Bailout’. Remarks at the Sandridge Lecture. BIS Working Paper no. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons. R. 158. Accessed 26 July 2009. Boorer. 13 January. 10 March. Basle: Bank for International Settlements. Stamp Lecture. BIS 2007. 2008. 2009. 13 December.html. Basle: Bank for International Settlements. ‘Chaos Theory – Why a Little Instability Might Be No Bad Thing for the Future of the Credit Market’.Bi B li oG r aPh y 185 Bernanke. Borio. Bernanke. 2009. 3 April. October. Basle: Bank for International Settlements. 2000. BIS Working Paper no. Basle: Bank for International Settlements. A. BIS 2006. July.org/ moyers/journal/04032009/profile. W.pbs.S. D. ‘Finance and the Fourth Dimension’. 2005. C. ‘The Crisis and the Policy Response’. 2004. http://www. . B. Blackburn. 2006. ‘The Financial Turmoil of 2007–?: A Preliminary Assessment and Some Policy Considerations’. 2008. Borio. B. VA. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons. Basle: Bank for International Settlements. ‘Market Distress and Vanishing Liquidity: Anatomy and Policy Options’. 39. 77 Annual Report. 25. London: London School of Economics. Borio. BIS Quarterly Review. November. New Left Review. Current Account Deficit’. Bernstein. Black. Capital Ideas. P. ‘Investment Adviser Aksia Warned Clients of Madoff “Red Flags”’. Virginia Association of Economics. 76 Annual Report. Richmond. May–June. 2005. with Wiggin.

2 April. Quarterly Review (Summer–Fall). Ft. B. and Fidora. June. 2009. 2005. Journal of Economic Perspectives. and Sircar. ‘The Social Structure of Liquidity: Flexibility. SIAM News. Buiter. ‘The State. M. Burn. paper prepared for presentation at the conference ‘The Role of Money Markets’ jointly organised by Columbia Business School and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. and MacDonald. 2008. 28:1. F. 2008. ‘Could the Crisis at Northern Rock Have Been Predicted? An Evolutionary Approach’. CGFS Discussion Paper. 2006. 30:2. Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics (SIAM). Brown. ‘Lessons from the North Atlantic Financial Crisis’. and Stinchcombe. Carmona. V. and States’. 1999. Review of International Political Economy. R. Caulkin. June. 28. ‘Financial Mathematics ’08: Mathematics and the Financial Crisis’. R. ECB Working Paper no. ‘Deciphering the 2007–2008 Liquidity and Credit Crunch’. May. W. Markets. Speech to US Congress. ‘The Coordinated Central Bank Action that Wasn’t’. Federal Reserve Bank of New York. G. N. the City and the Euromarkets’. A. 13 December. . M. 1994. Chick. ‘Subprime Lenders and Mortgage Market Completion’. 29–30 May. Chinloy. 2007. 2008. P. and Packer. R.186 f inanci al alchemy in crisis Bracke. ‘Structural Aspects of Market Liquidity from a Financial Stability Perspective’. Buiter. ‘City Calls the Tune – But Can it Remain Lord of the Dance?’ Observer. 23:1. CGFS 2001. 1999. Theory and Society. G. Cantor.com. S. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics. 6:2. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. BIS: Committee on the Global Financial System. Brunnermeier. T. 10 January. ‘Global Liquidity Glut or Global Savings Glut? A Structural VAR Approach’. 911. 4 March. W. 2009. Contributions to Political Economy. 2009. Carruthers.

16 April. Crockett. C. 28 July. Davies. 45:2. ‘Just Where Does the Locus of Corruption Lie?’ Financial Times. 2008. Keynote Address to the Workshop on Securitisation. Finance and Development. ‘The Biggest Bill in History’. Paris: Banque de France. 2009 ‘Age of Excess Fuelled Rise of Ponzis’. Cohen.B iB li o Gr a Phy 187 Chung. 11 June. . A. The Economist 2009. R. C. and Masters. J. 10 November. 5 March. January. 2009. ‘A Thin Outline of Regulatory Reform’. Credit Magazine 2006. Cifuentes. ‘Deals of the Year. ‘Insight: Securitisation Isn’t the Villain’. K. ECB 2006. Washington. Dymski. and Xiong. P. Financial Times. K. 6–7 May. H. ‘Confessions of a Risk Manager’. Occasional Paper Series no. Economic Report of the President 2007. mimeo. ‘Banking Goes Bananas – Efficiency and Brittleness in Finance’. ‘Implications for Liquidity from Innovation and Transparency in the European Corporate Bond Market’. 2009. 2008. Financial Stability Review (Special Issue on Liquidity). ‘Talking Point – Are We Facing a Global Economic Slowdown?’ June. G. 2009. Financial Times. Financial Times. DC: US Government Printing Office. and Giles. 50. Dorn. 2008. 33:2. Winner: Whinstone Capital Management’. 30 May. ‘Afterword: Mortgage Markets and the Urban Problematic in the Global Transition’. 2008. The Economist 2008. Washington. Crook. Securitization. 9 August. Risk and Governance. Chung. ‘Locating Stanford Billions Will Take Five Years’. J. DC: International Monetary Fund. 2009. ‘Chilling Plausibility of Bank’s “War Game”’. 2009. ‘Market Liquidity and Financial Stability’. B. February. A. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research. Financial Times. Ee. Financial Times. N. ‘Asia: A Perspective on the Subprime Crisis’. N. 23 June. London: City University. Credit Magazine 2008.

Galbraith. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. J. 4:2. Berkeley. Galbraith. and Steil. P. Financial Times 2009a. 2006. 2007. 20 February. London: Verso. Gamble. Gill. B. ‘Why Doesn’t Asia Have Bigger Bond Markets?’ NBER Working Paper no. London: Hamilton. 2002. Daily Telegraph. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. The Spectre at the Feast: Capitalist Crisis and the Politics of Recession. A. The Great Crash of 1929. 2009. B. 2004. 1999.188 financial alchemy in crisis Eichengreen. M. Funnel. Working Paper. Final Communiqué of the G20 Summit. J. 2009. Cambridge. Financial Times. Fish. K. thefreedictionary. Global Imbalances and the Lessons of Bretton Woods. 2009. ‘Turf Warriors Head for Washington’. London. Gimson.com/liquidity. 2008. Editorial. 10576. 7 October. 11 June. . Greenspan and the Economics of Empire. Unbearable Cost: Bush. Editorial. 21 December. G20. The Cairoli Lectures. ‘Root out Bad Debt or More Pain Will Follow’. B. ‘Constitutionalizing Inequality and the Clash of Globalizations’. B. 2007. B. Financial Times. 1955. CA: University of California. ‘Roots of Our Depression’. Farlex Free Dictionary. http://financial-dictionary. 2009. ‘Debt is Capitalism’s Dirty Little Secret’. Eichengreen. ‘Financial Crisis: Fear Stalks the City’. S. MA: MIT Press. Gowan. Financial Times. Eichengreen. 10 March. 2 April. The Global Plan for Recovery and Reform. ‘Stanford Caught Out – at Long Last’. 2009b. International Studies Review. 30 June. The Global Gamble: Washington’s Faustian Bid for World Dominance. A.

Remarks at the Conference of State Banking Supervisors. Holmstrong. Accessed 26 July 2009. J. 2009. ‘International Financial Risk Management’. Helleiner. http:// www. Chicago. Guha. 6810. Conference on Bank Structure and Competition. A. A. 16 March. Greenspan. ‘Liquidity. Greenspan. Hansard 2008. E. A. 2008a.co. MI. Greenspan. S. Organization. IL. Financial Times.htm. and Tirole.uk/pa/cm200708/ cmhansrd/cm080219/debtext/80219–0022. Guttman. Greenspan. 19 November. 24 November. Greenspan. 2003. 18 May. 2001. Financial Times. Cybercash. 1994. Guerrera. Washington. 1 January. 2008. J. F. Remarks to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. 5 May. ‘Paulson Says Crisis Sown by Imbalance’. J. ‘We Will Never Have a Perfect Model of Risk’. Traverse City. CORE Discussion Paper no. Remarks before the Council on Foreign Relations. ‘Old Bank Axioms Gain New Currency’. 1986. Interview to CNBC.. The Coming Era of Electronic Money. 19 February. Journal of Political Economy. ‘How the Bailouts Dwarf Other Global Crisis Spending’. 7 July. Ithaca. K. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.B iB li o Gr a Phy 189 Greenspan. B. A. Chicago. 31 July. and Redman. Financial Times. 8 May. C. ‘Private and Public Supply of Liquidity’.the-stationery-office. A. 2009. ‘Issues for Bank Regulators’. 1998. IL. Hirschleifer. 2008b. ‘Corporate Governance’. 2005. Uncertainty and the Accumulation of Assets’. DC. States and the Re-emergence of Global Finance. 2003. R. DC: Institute for Policy Studies. NY and London: Cornell University Press. 10:3. Washington. Grey. Cavanagh. ‘The Real World of Enron’s Auditors’. . 106:1. A. ‘Risk Transfer and Financial Stability’. Parliamentary debates. J. Handerson.parliament. 2003. 2002.

Market update. Panics and Crashes. London: Macmillan. 2005. 8 July. Kindleberger. Leeds: Leeds Chamber of Commerce and Yorkshire Forward at the Royal Armouries. C. November. Interest and Money. 3 March.uk/research. IMF 2007a. ‘US Prosecutors to Focus on Bear Managers’ Email’. 2008. M. DC. S.3 Trillion and Do They Thank You? Do They Hell’. ‘International Financial Markets in the UK’.ifsl. 28 January. 2008. S. Y. Kennedy. ‘Revealed: Sir Fred Goodwin Was Still Advising the Treasury until Five Weeks Ago’. ‘UK Slams EU Hedge Fund Rules’. Washington. Washington. C. DC. 2009. Global Financial Stability Report. Ishmael. 1978. Kadlec. J. Kelly. June. Jones. MarketWatch. Manias. Hutton. Imkeller. Institute of Directors. 21 October. Washington. P.190 f inancial alchemy in crisis Hope. K. DC. M. 11 February. Kane. King. Daily Telegraph. IMF 2009. Wall Street Journal Europe. ‘Stanford Denies Ponzi Scheme’. IFSL 2007. London: Macmillan. Keynes.. October. ‘UK Regulator Quits after Whistleblower’s Allegations’. April. S. ‘WorldCom’. Global Financial Stability Report. 2009.org. Global Financial Stability Report. 1983. Hu. 19 April. 73:2. Financial Times. W. ‘Monetary Policy Developments’. Speech to the CBI. The General Theory of Employment. 8:4. 2009 ‘You Give Bankers £1. 7 April. Observer. and Muller. E. M. 2002. 20–22 June. 1936. 2009. . 2009. ‘Partial Equilibrium and Market Completion’. Financial Times. ‘Policy Implications of Structural Changes in Financial Markets’. AEA Papers and Proceedings. IMF 2007b. http://www. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance. 7 July. Time. D.

Financial Regulator. 18 March. ‘Minsky’s Cushions of Safety. 2007. New York: Penguin. MA: MIT Press. February. Credit Magazine. Financial Times. Risk and Governance: Understanding Uncertainty in the Age of Finance. in L. E. H. J. 26 April. J. Kregel. 2008. ‘FBI Eyes Big Business in Mortgage Fraud Probe’. 6–7 May. 2003. ‘Herd Mentality’. J. Speech at the International Conference on Financial Stability and Implications of Basle II. Origins of the Crash: The Great Bubble and its Undoing. 2005. paper presented at the workshop on Securitisation. N. R. A Primer on Securitization.org. 46:1. 93. P. ‘A Framework for Financial Stability’. ‘Financialization of Daily Life’. 2000. London: City University. Kratz. Lowenstein. ‘The Performance of Liquidity in the Sub-Prime Mortgage Crisis’. Madigan. London and Cambridge. 30. ‘The Risk in Subprime’. 2008. Lippman. Langley. 1 March. New York Times. Public Policy Brief no. Large. ‘Rocked to the Core’. Systemic Risk and the Crisis in the U. 2008. eds. Istanbul. S. and McCall. ‘The Natural Instability of Financial Markets’.B iB li o Gr aP hy 191 Kirchgaessner. 2008. 523 (December). R. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 2004. Lascelles. Randall and M. P. Subprime Mortgage Market’. . 2008.levy. Levy Institute Working Paper no. ‘Triple A Failure’. R. Lowenstein. New York: Levy Economic Institute of Bard College. Fishman. D. American Economic Review. The Everyday Life of Global Finance. A. New York: Levy Economic Institute of Bard College. 1986. 12:3. 2007. Kregel. Journal of Sociology & Social Welfare. 2009. 2007. P. Kochen. ‘An Operational Measure of Liquidity’. Langley. S. ‘Securitization from the Investor View: Meeting Investor Needs with Products and Price’.S. Martin. Fortune. 19 June. Vol. Available at http://www. and Weitzman.

2007. and Whelan. ‘How the Banks Bet Your Money’. Moulton. and Barber. McCulley. Minsky. New Haven. Mukherjee. Nesvetailova. Speculation and Crisis in the Age of Global Credit. T. Channel 4. Nesvetailova. ‘Three Facets of Liquidity Illusions: Financial Innovation and the Credit Crunch’. ‘Financial Innovation: the Last Twenty Years and the Next’. London: The Stationery Office. 1992. CT: Yale University Press. 2009. C. ed. McBarnet. Bloomberg News. New Political Economy. 21:4. 2008. Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. Morris. Financial Times. ‘The Pursuit of (Past) Happiness? Middle-class Indebtedness and American Financialisation’. C. B. 1986. ‘The Liquidity Conundrum’. H. 2008. Montgomerie. Fragile Finance.. Dispatches. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. D. Fingleton. March. HC 4 Session 2007–2008. 2009. National Audit Office 2007. ‘International Corporate Finance and the Challenge of Creative Compliance’. Foreign and Commonwealth Office. 14:1. Miller. CFA Institute Conference Proceedings Quarterly. 11 June. 4:3. .192 f inanci al alchemy in crisis Masters. J. December. German Policy Studies. 9 April. 16 November. 18 February. London: Graham & Trotman. Debt. 2008. The Internationalization of Capital Markets and the Regulatory Response. in J. P. 2008. A. Sharpe. 2007. A. ‘Managing Risk in the Overseas Territories’. 1982. 1986. Can ‘It’ Happen Again? New York: M. H. ‘Asia or Excess Savings Keep the Region’s Debt Markets Shallow’. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. E. The Trillion Dollar Meltdown. A. M. Minsky. ‘City Fears UK is Too Weak to Defend Finance Industry’. New York: Public Affairs. report by the Comptroller and Auditor General. J.

Murphy. NY and London: Cornell University Press. March. .. Picciotto.. Assassi. and Nason. ‘Bank Bailout Could End Poverty for 50 years – Oxfam Tells G20’. 1 February. ‘Why Sir James Crosby Resigned’. Brussels: European Business Forum. Nesvetailova and D.bbc. 2003. J. 11 February. A. and Chavagneux. TX. R. H. ‘Insight: Re-regulation Won’t Curb Worst Excesses’. 26 March. and Winokur. 2002. Peston. C. A. Plender. R. Pettifor. J. 2008. ‘Banks Put Themselves at Risk in Basle’. DC: Department of the Treasury. R. Persaud. Persaud. Global Finance in the New Century. ‘Do away with Ratings Based Rules’. S. ‘Coming Soon: the New Poor’. 2009. 2002. 2007. Powers. 2010. 2009. (The Powers Report). ‘How to Deal with the Global Financial Crisis and Promote the Economy’s Recovery and Sustained Growth’. A. 9 July. 2009. Ithaca. S. New Statesman. press briefing. L. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. 6 May.. Blueprint for a Modernized Financial Regulatory Structure. Papademos. A. S. 1 September. Wigan.uk/blogs/thereporters/ robertpeston/2009/02/why_crosby_resigned. Accessed 27 July 2009. and Nugée. H. D. Speech at the 7th European Business Summit. Ithaca. Troubb.Bi B li oG r aPh y 193 Oxfam 2009. R. http://www. R. in L. Tax Havens: How Globalization Really Works.html. 26 May. R. BBC. Paulson. Financial Times. Financial Times. ‘How Tax Havens Helped to Create a Crisis’. 2003. F. Steel.co. 2009. 2008. The Offshore World. Financial Times. Palan. 1 April. ‘Redesigning Financial Regulation’. Palan. NY: Cornell University Press. Report of Investigation by the Special Investigative Committee of the Board of Directors of Enron Corp. 17 October. Financial Times. eds. Washington. Deregulation and Beyond. Austin. Partnoy. C. W.

1997 (1986). Thomson. ‘The Mysterious Balance Sheet’. ‘Foreign Exchange as a Business in the 21st Century’. ‘The Process of Financial Innovation’. The Subprime Solution. 7 July. T. G. 2008. Manchester: Manchester University Press. A.194 financi al alchemy in crisis Reuters 2009. Sinclair. Domestic Legitimacy and International Financial Orders. Casino Capitalism. ‘Unravelling Lehman’. London: Demos. G. Audit and Accountability Journal. Seoul. May. Silber. D. 2009. G. L. Seabrooke. AEA Papers and Proceedings. Tett. London: Lyonsdown. and van Duyn. The Social Sources of Financial Power. Lessons from the Global Financial Crisis. W. 16 May. ‘Under Restraint’. 2008. Financial Times. ‘Macro Prudential Policy: A New Name for Some Old Ways of Thinking?’ Speech to the Korean Financial Supervisory Commission/Financial Supervisory Service International Monetary Fund Macro Prudential Supervision Conference: Challenges for Financial Supervisors. Strange. Accounting. Shiller. 2005. 2008. ‘3 Large Banks Pay Back US Bailout Funds’. 10:1. . Tett. The New Masters of Capital. Business (Turnaround). NY: Cornell University Press. 2006. S. R. The New Paradigm for Financial Markets. NJ: Princeton University Press. Financial Times. 1983. International Herald Tribune. 2009. Tett. 1997. 1 March. Ryback. G. in After the Apocalypse. Soros. 2009. 2001. Princeton. ‘Regulatory Arbitrage through Financial Innovation’. 73:2. C. Ithaca. ‘Lost through Destructive Creation’. Shah. A. New York: Public Affairs. 18 June. Smout. Ithaca. NY: Cornell University Press. W. Speech at the ‘Euromoney’ Forex Forum. May. 2006.

17 October. . XL:3. Journal of Finance. G. ‘The First World Debt Crisis of 2007–2010 in Global Perspective’. Washington. 2000. Discipline in the Global Economy? International Finance and the End of Liberalism. Interview with the Financial Times. US Senate 2002.B iB li o Gr aP hy 195 Tily. 2nd Session. Copenhagen: Danish Institute for International Studies. Turner. Warsh. P. 2007. Washington. 2008. London and New York: Routledge. J. Debt and Delusion. July–August. Warburton. Toporowski. Wade. 1985. 2007. van Horne. The Rate of Interest and Keynesian Economics. C. T. 10:3. 2008. Lord. and Carter. Tinker. Keynes’s General Theory. United States Senate. ‘Of Financial Innovations and Excesses’. Vestergaard. R. A New Foundation: Rebuilding Financial Supervision and Regulation. The Theory of Capital Market Inflation. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. 2008. ‘Spectres of Accounting: Contradictions or Conflicts of Interest?’ Organization. K. Financial Derivatives and Pension Fund Capitalism. 5 March. London: Pluto Press. London: Routledge. J. Challenge. The End of Finance. G. DIIS Working Paper 2009:08. ‘The Role of the Board of Directors in Enron’s Collapse’. Report Prepared by the Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations of the Committee on Governmental Affairs. The Credit Crunch. It’s not about Regulation …. 2009. J. J. ‘Market Liquidity – Definitions and Implications’. Financial Regulatory Reform. Report 107–70. 2003. Turner. US Treasury 2009. Toporowski. 2009. 107th Congress. DC: Department for the Treasury. 2000. Remarks at the Institute of International Bankers Annual Washington Conference. Washington. DC: US Senate. DC. London: Penguin.

2009. I. M. 2008. Basle: Bank for International Settlements. D. ‘Lessons from the Subprime Meltdown’. 1 April. Challenge. 3:2. and Milne. April. D. ‘Credit Risk Transfer and Crunches: Global Finance Victorious or Vanquished?’ New Political Economy. Williams. 1 April. 2008. W. J. 205. 6 October. Working Paper. 2009. ‘AIG Lists the Banks to Which it Paid Rescue Funds’. London: Routledge.. 51:2. S. 2009.196 financi al alchemy in crisis White. and Johal. March–April. . Winnett. Competition and Change. ‘Is Price Stability Enough?’ BIS Working paper no. ‘Shattered on the Rock? British Financial Stability from 1866 to 2007’. Financial Times. 2010 forthcoming. New York Times. with Erturk. London: Cass Business School. M. and Simpson. R. Wolf. Wray. Froud. Leaver. 2006. 15 March. G. Wigan. 2008. Wigan. A. ‘US Foreign Policy and the Global Financial Crisis’. A. A. ‘Financialisation and Derivatives: Constructing an Artifice of Indifference’.. Williams Walsh. Wood. 2008. R. K. Financialization at Work. Daily Telegraph. ‘Financial Crisis: Gordon Brown’s Economic Committee Meets as Parliament Returns’.

30. 139 and securitisation 9. 29. 94 Tripartite Agreement 31. 88. 153 Bank of England and credit crunch 21. 146. 94. 96. 141 Agency debt (USA). 57. 106. 34. 38. 124. 117. 131. 147 and capital 31. 136. 141. 79. 177n. 116. 161. 58. 78. 178n. 3. 160 investment. 194 Asia – 38. 129. 42. 139–40. 119. 115. 158.9 Agencies. 74 ‘Naughty Asian exporters’. see also Ponzi capitalism 66 ORD model 15. 167 and risk 67. 87. 118 shadow 15. 36. 77–8. 117. 78. 146 system 2. 73. 107. 128 asset inflation 2. 119 Banking crisis 2. 144. 118. 162 Banking and liquidity. see ratings agencies Arbitrage. 116. 110. 120–1. 49. 19. Ponzi. 43.14 commercial (traditional) 13. 134 Accounting standards: 135–8. 171. 21–2. 31. 139 and fraud 94–5. 85. 21. 9. 125. 88 197 . 117. 85.2 and Northern Rock. 163 and liquidity (also liquid assets) 6. 35. 179n. offshore.2 ADB 38 Asian capitalism 160 Asset(s) Asset-backed securities (ABS) xxx. 83.index Accounting. 48. 56. 86. 91. 105. 81. 133. 85. 119. 180n. 132 creative accounting 47. 63. 16. 44–8. 49. 95. 24. see also fraud. 36. 11. 35. 48. 8. 77. 88. 88. 74–5. 164. 115–16. 165. 110. 133 toxic. 14–15. regulatory arbitrage 46. new economy. 95. 27.

144. 124. 161–3. 133–4. 164 Credit derivatives 87. 129. 171 Bernanke. 100. 74. 160–1 Anglo-Saxon 63. 74–5. 28. 44. 18. 43. 179n1. 114. 124. 30. 88. 157. 108. 122. 91. 111. 103. 175 Ponzi. 44. 175 Capitalism 1. 22. 154–5. 69. 26. 123. 183n. 71–4. 136 dot. 136. 169. 143. 180n. 99. 43. 79. 116–17. 68. 42. 89. 63. 72. 27. 35. 35. 44. 41. 32. see also Ponzi 100–12 Central bank(s) 29. 148. 91–2. 31. 177n.6 Capital markets 41.4 Basle Accord 95. 162.1.2 on liquidity 19. 53. 29. 120. 174–5 financialised 3. 130. 170. 120. 183n. 156. 177n2 Federal Reserve (the Fed) 29. 157 BIS 19. 146. 36. 88. 145. 139. 114. 69 Credit rating 142 . 80–3. 71–4. 181n3 Credit boom 3. 66. 65. 25. 95. 42. 50. 167 crisis of 24. 127. 138. 134 securitisation 20. 96. 157. 101. 137. 165 Capital adequacy (also norms) 88. 160. 92.2. 177n2.com 48. 96. 127–8. 168. 76 Bretton Woods system 9 ‘Bretton Woods-2’ 76. 34. 135.198   financial  alchemy  in  c risis Bankruptcy 24. 178n7. Ben 29. 133. 178n12 Credit expansion 19. 171–2.4. 76. 96. 182n2 ECB 16. 79. 64. 91.5. 164. 81. 80 Capital see also recapitalisation: 1. 172 varieties of 150. 135. 163 committees and groups 168. 172n. 67. 91–2. 89. 172n. 49. 129. 180n. 47. 105. 178n12 City of London 150. 70. 161. 12. 160. 34. 18. 167 Bubble 3. 126. 28. 178n7. 63–7. 177n. 155. 148. 100. 114.5 ‘super-bubble’ 73 Business cycle theory of. 30. 173.

64.2 mortgage-backed. 164 EU 32. 43. 40. 170 theories of. 178n. 6. 162 regulation of. 178–9n. 141.14 response to crisis 153–6. 183n. see also crisis of the 1930s. dot. 178n. 173–4. 178n. 172 Depression. 121.index  199 Credit rating agencies (CRAs) 22. 104. 171. 3. 134. 146 Eastern Europe. 145. 175 Dot. 183n. 32. 128. 101–2. 163.5 Freddie Mac 33. 44. see central bank Fannie Mae 33. 156. 33. 95. 116 Enron 48. 95. 72–5. 164. see central banks Financial expansion 98 . 154. 150. 133–5. 145. 37.5 Federal Reserve (Fed). 179n. 138. 98. 20. 45. 119. 25. 77. 176. 78–9. 153–4. 95. 178n. 63–4. 55. 126–8. 116. 29 public 90–1 US debt 33. 35. 178n. 167. 124. 95–6. 42.2 toxic 7. 32. 128. 87. 40. 150. 102 Derivatives 10. 119. 135 role in the crisis 135–9. 50. 109. 179n. also Eurocurrency. 144–9 Debt 2. 81. 77. 172 of the 1990s. 163. 36. 171 Great Depression 35. 171. 50. 100. 74. 105. 45. 78. 60.11. 42. 99. 86. 69.9. 95–6 Global 34.com crisis. 95.9 Debt culture 9–10. 140–1 European Central Bank (ECB). eurodollar market 9. 165.15 Euromarket. 16. 181n.com bubble 48. 163 Crisis of the 1930s. 82. 140 Europe 36.9. 132. 180n. 139. 105. 170. 43.3 Deregulation 11.9. 145. 52–3. 161.12. 59. 135. 161. 73. 62–89 structural theories 71–9 cyclical theories 80–9 policy responses to. 131. 117. 34–5. 51. 132. 182n. 150. 69.

103 Human factor. 89. 33. 95. 28. see also NIFA.200   financial alchemy  i n crisis Financial fragility 20. 181n. 56. 158 Geopolitics 149. 22. 20–3.2 Great Depression. 155–6. 130. 118. 141. 89. 159 Heterodox (economics. 160. investor 95. 166. 175 Geeks. 146. 59. 157. 118. 116. 166 Hedging 16. 47–9 and Ponzi. 45. 142. 34. 109. 175 Granite. 156–7. 153. in crisis 82–9 Iceland 36. 156 Global recession. 51. JK 1. 109. 128. 163 institutions 182n. 168. finance 66. 65. 42–3. 42. 82. 167 Financialisation 12. 52–5. 100. 28. 175 and liquidity 20 and ORD model. 111 Galbraith. 176 Greenspan. 13–17. 29.6 and offshore. 120. 162. 148 Global savings glut see also savings and liquidity glut 78 Gold (standard) 9.1 . 118 Financial innovation 8. 150. 501. 73. 47. 179n. 165. 140 Hedge fund(s) 15. 175–6 controversy over. 96 Governance. 25. 43. 15. 107. 68. 59. 159–61. see also depression and crisis. 173. 66. 168–70. 84. 109–20 Financial liberalisation 150 Financial architecture. 181n. 38. 82. 81. 22. 152. 2. 66 Fraud 40–2. 102. 103 Housing market(s) 2. 70. see crises Greed 41. 43–7 role in crisis. 140. 164–6. 41 Illiquid asset 14. 32. 133–4. 100–3. 143. Alan 14. 100–9. see also Northern Rock and Offshore 40. 174 House prices 25. 126–7. 173.3 Herding. 162. 76. 55. 37. 105–6. 90. 83. 83. 68. 129–30. 123. 156. 60.3 and liquidity 129–42 crisis lessons. 84. political economy) 3. 94–5. 181n. 148. financial 16. 98. 149.

36. 141. 140. 182n. 6. 124–5.12 illusion of 4. 173. 32. see also toxic debt Keynes. 10–12. 81. 29. 16–17. 90. 30. 78. 183n. 176 defined. 64. 129 Systemic 141 IMF 26.15 Inflation. see also savings glut 7. 73. 112.2 crisis. 18. 121. 154. 47. 177n. 113. 129–30. 34. 115–17. 88. 178n.7 and subprime 103–6 Japan 39. 176 Liquidity support in crisis 30–1. 145.1 Keynesian welfare state 71 Kindleberger. also crunch. 126. 146. 136. 175. 140. 125.6 Liquidity artificial 42 concept. 137–9. Charles 85 Lender of last resort 88. 180n. 76. 16–17. 177n. 91. 126–7. John Maynard 3–4. 136. 173–6 and regulation 57. 146. 164. 182n.16. 164. 86. 177n. 159. 115. 167 and system 14. 126.5. 60. 141 Illiquidity 117. 20. 145 and assets 8. 174 system 20. 115–16. 6) Leverage 1. 166. 12. 10. 113–42 paradox of. 150. 107. 173–4 and financial innovation 9–10. 60. 34. 173. 142. also liquidity boom. 98–9 Innovation. 77. 7–8. 121–4. 45.1 (ch. 125 risk 19. also meltdown 5. 119. 132. 179n. 143. 73. 79. 178n. 57.2 Junk (securities) 145. 10–11. 11. 179n. 167. 112.7 . 174. 30. 114. 170. 36–7.2 liquidity glut. also debt 6. 104–5. 128–31. 104. 5–6. 179n. 159. 121. see also asset price inflation 45. 24. 17–23 pillars of. 17. 12. see financial innovation Interest rate 26–7. 144. 28. 76. 135 and markets 7.index  201 loans. 173. 97.2. 161. 143. 163. 144. 143. 141–2. 177n. 127 types of. 8. 75.

see also Granite and offshore 30–2. 32. 86. also Ponzi scheme 19. 163. 41. 105. 48. 178n. 180n. 69 Mania. 59. 65. 92–4. 112. 57. see also Ponzi 96. 102–3. liars’ 103 LTCM 67. 100. 25. 128. 51. 28. 129. see also Granite and Northern Rock 15. 18–19. 127.1 taxonomy of finance. see also Minsky. 145 Ponzi. 26. 100–4. 121. 53–5. 56. 174 Ponzi. 144–5.202   financi al alchemy  in  c risis Loans. 174 Ponzi principle 59–60. 182n.2 Loans. 59. 69. 163 Panic 29. 134. 113 Residential 135 Neoliberal. 102–3. 104. 128. entities 48. 104–5. capitalism 72 New economy 67. 55. 22. 127. 96. 44. 103. 78. 42. 102. 134. 181n. 101. Hyman Ponzi capitalism 100–2.4 on financial innovation 115–17 Monetarism 169 Monetary policy 2. 176 and securitisation 106–10. 134. 138. 105. 166 . 14. Hyman 3. securitised 7. 152. 114. tulip 100 Minsky. 181n. 146. 81.4 Ponzi era 96 Ponzi finance. 128. 30. 128. 167. 34. 39. 179n. 105. 174. 20. 147 and Granite 40–2. 172 New International Financial Architecture (NIFA) 165. 13. 174–5. Carlo 100. 103. 176 Offshore.4. 17. 38. sub-prime 2. 141.1. 181n. 167. 107. 95. 139.7 Mortgages. 102 and Ponzi finance. 51–61 Offshore finance. 127 Privatisation of financial risk 11. 60. 129. 109. 139 Over-the-counter (OTC) 123. 79. 168 Northern Rock. 132. 59. 106.

85. 121–5. 163. 112. 67. 117. 65. 18. 75. see also liquidity glut 75. 172. 118 .12 optimisation of. 124. 136. 135. 86. 92–3. 25–6. 64. 55. 28. 37. 111–12.2 in the political-economic system. 141–2. 120. 94. 172 global 2. 85. 41–2. 137 and innovation. 50. 38. 177n. 14–15. 94. 155. 11. 78 Speculation 73. 107. 65. 33. 38. 49. 9. 109. 83. 43–7. 166. 131. 178n. 6. 59. 40. 16. see also NIFA.2 macroprudential 168–71 light-touch 89. 121. 81. 82. 179n. 161. 173 systemic 59. 105. 138. see credit ratings agencies Real economy 12. 68–9. 81–2. 18. 124. 172 management of. 143. 179n. 170. 110. 86.3 Savings. 180n. 155. 148 Regulation. 148. 169. 24. 102. 128–30. 165–6 Risk and liquidity 10. 165–6 and Basle 116–17. 130. 92–3. 6. 24. 150–7. 56. 171. 11–12. 84. 15. 118. 139–40. 65. 152. governance 9. 42–3. 25. 32. 67. 133. 155. 78. 96. 48. 48–51.3 SIV 15. 153. 86–7. 154. 87. 145. 135. 13. 142. 128. 37. 111. 95. 147 Recession 2. 64. 146. 65. 59–60. 119. 65.14 underestimation (also misunderstanding) of. 164 pricing of. 81. 82. 8. 19. 165 paradigm of. 82. 112. 114 in wake of the crisis. 172. 127. global glut. 59 SPV 42. 33. 64. 161 Real estate 14 Recapitalisation: 36. 133. 93–4. 48. also valuation. 177n. 146.index  203 Rating. 43. 78. 138–9. 116. 113. 65. 21. 79–80. 137. 19–22. 19. 98–9. 57. 113. 89. 168. 127. 102. 52. 13–15. 76. 159 Structured finance 13.

71–2. 150 Wall Street 1. 124. 7. 58. ch. 119. 2. 88. see debt True sale 139–40 United Kingdom 21. 164. 95. 133–4. 43.3 . 182. 32. 99. 173–6 Welfare 13–14. 71. 30. 51. 97–100. 28. 86–8.204   financial  a lchemy  i n  c risis Toxic debt. 154. 146–8. 143. 142 WorldCom 48. 73. 25. 105. 35–7. 49. 34. 38. 92–4. 18. 104. 114. 12. 156. 40–1. 17. 59. 33. 34. 77. 112. 53–5. 31. 160 Washington Mutual 35 Wealth. 179n. 112. 150. illusion of 1.13 United States 2. 22. 150. 91. 161. 75. 85.5n.

Sign up to vote on this title
UsefulNot useful