Page 1

The Evolution of Citizenship Economic and Institutional Determinants ∗
Page 2

ABSTRACT We investigate the evolution of the legal institution of citizenship from a political economy perspective. We first present a median voter model of citizenship laws determination. Next we test the implications of the model on a new dataset on citizenship laws across countries of the world. We show that citizenship laws have responded endogenously to economic and institutional determinants. When facing increasing immigration, countries with a jus soli tradition tend to restrict their legislation, while jus sanguinis countries resist innovation. The welfare burden proves not to be an obstacle for jus soli legislation, while demographic stagnation encourages it. A high degree of democracy promotes the adoption of jus soli elements, while the instability of state borders determined by decolonization impedes it. Religion and ethnic diversity have no residual impact. .Key Words: citizenship laws, international migration, legal origins, democracy, borders. 1
Page 3

1. Introduction Each country of the world has established a complex system of rules that govern the attribution of citizenship. As a consequence of the increasing pressure of international migration, citizenship laws have moved to center stage on policy agendas, since citizenship laws not only affect the design of immigration policy, but also interact with the workings of labor markets, affect welfare programs, and influence demographic trends. Citizenship is the legal institution that designates full membership in a state and the associated rights and duties. It provides benefits such as the right to vote, better employment opportunities, and the ability to travel without restrictions, legal protection in case of criminal charges, and the possibility to obtain a visa for a relative. There are also costs to citizenship, such as the military draft, renunciation of the original citizenship, and the pecuniary and non-pecuniary costs that may be required for naturalization and for recognition at the age of majority. Examples are language and culture tests, waiting periods, and a commitment to avoid activities leading to disqualification. There are several ways to acquire citizenship: at birth, by naturalization, by marriage.

The regulation of citizenship at birth, which determines citizenship acquisition by second- generation immigrants, is rooted in the well-defined bodies of common and civil law. The former traditionally applies the jus soli principle, according to which citizenship is attributed by birthplace: this implies that the child of an immigrant is a citizen, as long as he is born in the country of immigration. The latter applies the jus sanguinis principle, which attributes citizenship by descent, so that a child inherits citizenship from his parents, independently of where he is born. Despite being rooted in these principles, during the 20th century - and especially after World War II - in many countries citizenship laws have gone through a process of continuous adaptation, in conjunction with the decolonization phase, the collapse of the socialist system, and the mounting pressure of international migration. In this paper we investigate the determinants and evolution of citizenship laws in the postwar period from a political economy perspective. To pursue this goal, we assemble a new dataset which codifies citizenship laws across the countries of the world, with a specific focus on the provisions that regulate the access to citizenship at birth. The dataset is then used to study the dynamic adaptation of these laws, by relating the observed patterns to a
Page 4

number of potential determinants, including economic factors as well as other political and cultural factors which have been found relevant in related research on institutions. Modern sociopolitical theories have advanced several hypotheses concerning the determinants of citizenship laws dynamics, on the basis of case studies and nonquantitative cross country comparisons. The legal tradition established in a given country is generally believed to exert a persistent impact on current legislation. The relevance of migration has also been investigated. In particular, pressure from a large stock of migrants is perceived as a factor that shapes a country's attitude toward citizenship policy. On the one hand, it could push toward a legislation that allows automatic citizenship granting for all newborn. On the other, migration could also drive toward restrictions of the same principle in countries where it was originally applied. According to some sociopolitical theories, the combination of these forces tends to induce convergence toward a mix of jus soli and sanguinis provisions for countries coming from different legal traditions (Weil 2001). For the case of Europe, Baubock et al. (2006) instead stress the presence of divergent trends, towards liberalization in some countries and toward restriction of access to citizenship in others. The influence of other economic forces is also recognized. Since citizenship rights determine the ability to enjoy welfare benefits, the shaping of nationality laws has been linked with the nature of the welfare state, with a large government representing a potential obstacle to the retention of jus soli (Joppke 1998). This argument, however, has to be weighted against the potential gain coming from the acquisition of relatively young new citizens for countries with expensive

pension systems and in the midst of a demographic crisis. Political factors have also been found relevant. The presence of a consolidated democracy is expected to lead to the adoption of jus soli, viewed as a more equal treatment of aliens. Stabilization of state borders should reduce the pressure to preserve a national identity through jus sanguinis. Finally, an additional factor that has been the subject of debate is the influence of national character and culture. The theory advanced by Brubaker (1992) focuses on France and Germany as two antagonistic kinds of nationhood, the former more assimilationists, and the latter more ethnocentric, which also differ in their definitions of citizenship. In this paper we formalize the above hypotheses within a simple median voter model which can guide our empirical investigation by generating testable implications and by offering an interpretation of the resulting evidence.
Page 5

The model is based on the assumption that the laws regulating citizenship acquisition can be viewed as the outcome of the decision problem faced by a native median voter, in a context where citizenship confers the right to vote over policy variables. In making this decision, the native median voter takes into account the associated benefits and costs, which depend on the share of migrants over population and the other factors suggested by the literature. The model indicates that the share of migrants has a potentially ambiguous impact on the decision to grant citizenship and voting rights to migrants, since it increases the loss, for the native median voter, of letting migrants vote, but it also increases the cost associated with their exclusion. Moreover, the natives' decision is positively influenced by a relatively high income level of the migrants, a small welfare state, a relatively old native population, a high level of democracy, a stable national border, and an inclusive national culture. We test the above empirical implications and find that in the postwar period citizenship laws have responded endogenously and systematically, through a slow but steady process of adaptation, to economic and institutional factors. Overall, our results suggest that migration pushes national legislations in the direction of jus sanguinis, not jus soli. In particular, when we take into account the legal tradition established in the matter of citizenship, we find that countries with a jus soli origin react to increasing migration by adding jus sanguinis elements. On the other hand, in jus sanguinis countries the impact of migration has been negligible. Therefore, the evidence does not support the hypothesis of convergence toward a mixed regime, since migration tends to induce restrictions, but not extensions. Other economic factors also matter. While the welfare burden proves not to be an obstacle for a jus soli legislation, demographic stagnation encourages the adoption of mixed and jus soli regimes.

Turning to institutional factors, we find that a high degree of democracy is significantly associated with a jus soli legislation while border instability, in particular following the decolonization phase, decreases its likelihood. Cultural characteristics captured by religion and ethic fractionalization are not found to play a significant role. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 introduces the related literature. Section 3 reviews the historical and legal background for the issues we address. Section 4 presents our model of citizenship laws determination. Section 5 describes our dataset on citizenship laws around the world 4

Page 6

Section 6 investigates empirically the determinants of current citizenship laws and presents our main results, together with a set of robustness checks. Section 7 develops an alternative empirical strategy that highlights the determinants of change in citizenship laws. Section 8 concludes and indicates directions for future research. The Data Appendix collects information about the data employed. 2. Related Literature Our work is related with several branches of the economic literature. First of all, this paper adds to research on international migration and migration policy. Timmer and Williamson (1998), Hatton and Williamson (2006) and Bertocchi and Strozzi (2008) empirically analyze immigration policies enacted at the end of the 19th century during the mass migration era, while O'Rourke and Sinnott (2006) and Mayda (2006) estimate voters' attitudes toward immigration in the postwar period. The political economy of migration has been modeled, among others, by Benhabib (1996), Gradstein and Schiff (2006), and DeVoretz (2006). More specifically, the role of citizenship policy has been discussed by DeVoretz and Pivnenko (2006), who investigate the economic costs and benefits derived from citizenship, by Pritchett (2006), who evaluates citizenship policy within a broader discussion on labor mobility and

Johnson. . our work contributes to the research program which has focused on the historical determinants of institutions. but with a focus on the conflict between rich and poor. the issue of franchise extension has recently received considerable attention within the literature. On the other hand. and Robinson (2001) contribute to the understanding of how institutions evolve by using historical variables as instruments for contemporary measures of the quality of institutions. and by Chiswick and Miller (2008). (1998). Acemoglu. Bertocchi and Spagat (2001). who compare the impact of migration on the welfare state with or without voting rights for the migrants. More broadly. The basic premise of this research line is the recognition that laws in different countries are adopted or transplanted from a few legal traditions and that the resulting legislative bodies reflect both the influence of the legal origin and the subsequent revision specific to individual countries. with contributions by Acemoglu and Robinson (2000).. (2008) specifically analyze the evolution of an index of formalism of legal procedure. Engerman and Sokoloff (2002) highlight the relevance of wealth inequality and political factors in accounting for how fundamental economic 5 Page 7 institutions developed over time. We add to this stream by focusing on the determinants of the dynamic adaptation of nationality rules. who evaluate the determinants of the decision to naturalize. Sadka. while Bertocchi (2007) concentrates on the conflict between men and women. they do not examine the determinants of these alternative regimes. and Swagel (2002) and Dolmas and Huffman (2004). Balas et al. our work is also related to Razin. However. Since our theory emphasizes that citizenship rights imply the right to vote. This paper also relates to the comparative legal approach initiated by La Porta et al.immigration policies.

citizenship laws reforms tend to be the outcome of long-term processes of adaptation often involving constitutional amendments. is also relevant to our approach.Finally. By imitation. Citizenship Laws in Historical Perspective Citizenship policy can be viewed as part of broader migration policy. and also because borders play an important role on the determination of citizenship rules. However. By the end of the 19th century. that are typically adjusted to the business cycle and to the current government orientation. On the other hand. following feudal traditions which linked human beings to the lord who held the land where they were born. contrary to other migration policy measures such as quotas and visa requirements. recent work by Alesina and Spolaore (1997) and Bolton and Roland (1997) on the optimal determination of the size of nations. both because country size in this literature is the same as population size and is potentially influenced by migration and by the legal status of immigrants. During the 19th century the jus sanguinis principle was adopted throughout Europe and then transplanted to its colonies. 3. In 18th century Europe jus soli was the dominant criterion. Continental modern citizenship law was subsequently built on these premises. The French Revolution broke with this heritage and with the 1804 civil code reintroduced the ancient Roman custom of jus sanguinis. the British preserved their jus soli tradition and spread it through their own colonies. At the same time. starting with the United States where it was later encoded in 6 Page 8 the Constitution. the process of nation-state formation and the associated codification effort were completed in Continental Europe. and thus state borders. Japan also adopted jus sanguinis in this phase. .

2001) and Brubaker (1992). The United States Jus soli was encoded in the US Constitution through the 1868 Fourteenth Amendment. ranging from immigration policy to naturalization requirements. Debate about possible restrictions did arise recently. Therefore. and jus sanguinis regulating citizenship law in most civil law countries. Below are some specific cases. the next century witnessed a continuous process of transformation of citizenship laws across the world. had by then already moved toward a mixed regime. 2 Australia Current citizenship law in Australia differs considerably from that of the United . 1 In particular. while civil law France. with the specific purpose to protect the birthrights of black slaves. drawing mostly from Joppke (1998). the US approach is still remarkably consistent with its original attitude in all its aspects. civil law Latin America had embraced jus soli early on. despite important exceptions. A relatively young and thin welfare state contributes to the fiscal sustainability of jus soli in this country. Aleinikoff and Klusmeyer (2000.the revolutionary phase was over in those countries that had been the subject of the earlier colonization era. and with a general positive attitude toward economic liberalism. Consistently with its history as a country of immigrants. most countries of the world had established specific provisions regarding citizenship acquisition within a relatively well-developed legal system. but never led to actual change. jus soli came under attack in the 1980s regarding its applicability to the children of illegal immigrants. by that stage. For instance. with jus soli being the norm in common law countries. However. and 19th century colonization had extended the process of transplantation of legal tradition to the rest of the world. with its colonies.

Jus soli had also been introduced in Australia by the colonists. most of Latin America was already a jus soli country before the 19th century immigration waves began. 7 Page 9 States. even if it is no longer attracting immigrants. most of the incipient states chose jus soli as a way to break with the colonial political order and to prevent the metropoles from making legitimate claims on citizens born in the new countries. At independence. 2 The relative thickness of the concept itself of citizenship. from the perspective of poor countries. of Venezuela in 1830. despite the common origin as countries of immigration. Jus soli survived until 1986. in the sense that it confers few additional benefits if compared with residency. while afterwards a person born in Australia must have at least one parent who is either an Australian citizen or a permanent resident in order to acquire citizenship. is a related. for instance. if compared to residency. Jus soli was encoded in the Constitution of Brazil in 1824. potentially relevant consideration: in the US.1 In his analysis of Mexican immigration. Jus soli is still the prevalent rule in the area. Huntington (2004) has criticized current nationality regulations on the grounds that they represent a “devaluation of citizenship”. Pritchett (2006) discusses the possible advantages of guest-worker programs which do not contemplate citizenship. this area has followed a rather peculiar pattern. the country went through numerous legislative and administrative reforms. citizenship is relatively thin. Therefore. Latin America In the face of a civil law tradition which had been transplanted by the European powers. Mexico represents a special case where jus soli was also . In the postwar period. of Argentina in 1853.

After World War II. making the experience of this country a unique one. qualifies for British citizenship only if at least one parents is a British citizen or resident. since the 1980s. even though military consideration introduced early on elements of jus soli. in 1889 double jus soli became automatic. especially from North Africa. only to come back to stay with a Constitutional Amendment in 1937. but was then abandoned in 1836. Because of its colonial history. The 1948 Nationality Act created the status of Citizen of the United Kingdom and Colonies for people with a close connection to the UK and its colonies. the concept of nationality in the UK was. particularly extensive.adopted in the 1814 insurgent Constitution. Following a postwar wave of colonial immigration. large-scale immigration. The United Kingdom British nationality law has been deeply affected by the imperial experience. this open-door policy was progressively restricted. where jus sanguinis was first introduced with the 1804 Civil Code and maintained 8 Page 10 for the entire course of the 19th century. Citizenship issues and the rights of immigrants became the object . K. as a form of selective immigration policy. France The emergence of the nation-state in Continental Europe was the main factor that shaped citizenship law in this area. The 1984 British Nationality Act restricts jus soli by establishing that a child born in the U. In order to secure immigrants' children born in France to the draft. even though special status is still attributed to citizens of the British Commonwealth. Redefinitions of national citizenship have been effectively employed. The revolutionary experience was particularly important for France. since all subjects of the British Empire had equal access to British citizenship simply by establishing residence in the UK. raised concern regarding assimilation. up to World War II.

With the foundation of the GDR and the consolidation of the Eastern Block. with France sticking to its tradition of assimilationist nation. that required a formal citizenship request from second-generation immigrants. had started to put under strong pressure. the massive guest-worker immigration of the postwar period. A first step in this direction was the new Foreigner Law in 1990. Prior to that. these restrictions were considerably revised. but to no avail. The case of France is frequently compared with Germany. however. and at the same time with millions of ethnic Germans living behind the Iron Curtain. was finally approved in . mostly from Turkey but also from Southern Europe. which turned naturalization from the discretionary exception into the rule. the original Wilhelminian citizenship law of 1913. A major overhaul of the legislation. nor declined it. Germany found itself in the paradoxical situation of having to live with a large population of disenfranchised foreigners born on its soil at home. Germany The single most relevant event in the history of German citizenship law is certainly the fall of the Berlin wall. which had established strong sanguinis ties with German overseas emigrants. Brubaker (2002) has influentially argued that the different path followed by these countries has been shaped by their cultural difference. with the automatic assignment of citizenship at age 18 to those immigrants' children born in France who had neither requested. which paved the way for the achievement of stable national borders. Achieving border stability was a decisive factor in pushing Germany toward the longdelayed adoption of jus soli elements. In 1993 Chirac introduced a restrictive revision to the legislation.of heated debate in French politics. and Germany to its ethnic identity. following an intense political struggle. With the Left regaining political power in 1997.

In particular. The latter aspect may have played a role in shaping the evolution of citizenship policies in several other European countries and especially the Scandinavian ones. by now.1999. which recently adapted their legislation to the globalization of international migration and its increasing impact on Europe. and the thick nature of the 9 Page 11 German welfare state. In the evaluation of the German experience. . where jus sanguinis was functional to the large past emigration flows. many former British and Portuguese colonies rejected the jus soli tradition and switched to an often strongly ethnically-tinged version of jus sanguinis. As documented by Weil (2001). especially for high-immigration Sweden. but had recently to adapt to the quickly changing conditions. other factors that may have delayed the introduction of jus soli are. the strong ethnic character of German national identity. as mentioned in the introduction. restricted forms of double jus soli are de facto applied. in the entire EU. On the other hand. Greece and Luxembourg. Jus soli is now the norm in Germany (under the mild requirement that one parent has lived in the country for eight years). The vast majority of the African colonies that were subject to civil law countries practicing jus sanguinis stuck to this principle after independence. Decolonization Postwar decolonization had a major impact on citizenship rules applied around the world. For instance. in the vast majority of European countries. with the exceptions of Austria. and not only through the indirect impact on the metropolitan countries we previously examined. access to citizenship by second and third generation is facilitated.

In situations where instability was pushed to an extreme degree by the young age and the arbitrary borders of these countries. however. sizeable minorities . there had been considerable migration within. recognized citizenship only for persons whose parents were members of one of the tribes established within the territory by 1908. and was compounded with deep ethnic division. During the following decades millions of Russians were encouraged to settle in Latvia and Estonia (less so in Lithuania) in order to Russify them. in an effort to exclude Rwandan immigrants. the associated exclusive notion of ethnic and tribal identity caused enormous problems in countries where colonial rule had left shaky democratic institutions. To these days. large Russian-speaking. At the same time. In 1981 Mobutu signed a new law on nationality requiring an ancestral connection to the population residing in the territory as far back as 1885. The Soviet Union had occupied Estonia. To these days. Latvia and Lithuania in 1940. Marginalization and de facto statelessness of significant strata of the population is the unavoidable outcome of these policies. as for all empires.Sierra Leone's 1961 Constitution established that citizenship is transmitted only by descent and only to children whose father and a grandfather were Sierra Leoneans of AfricanNegro descent. The 1964 Congolese Constitution. 10 Page 12 The disintegration of the USSR Another major wave of citizenship law codification followed the disintegration of the USSR. The area had been sealed toward international migration but. ethnic conflict lies at the roots of a chronic manipulation of citizenship rules in favor of one ethnic group over others. stateless. jus sanguinis tended to prevail as a way to control more easily the formation of national entities.

and a commitment to democratic values with respect to the rights of minorities. this perception as a country of emigrants pushes toward the persistence of jus sanguinis as the main principle. The hostile attitude toward ethnic Russians was especially strong in Latvia. Estonian and Latvian laws were sharply criticized by international organizations on the grounds of human rights. The Model This section develops a simple theoretical model which formalizes the hypotheses that a widely interdisciplinary literature has advanced with respect to the determinants of citizenship laws. while Lithuania. the new citizenship laws of these three states reflected this heritage with an emphasis on jus sanguinis as the basis for acquiring citizenship. these recommendations were indeed fulfilled in the more recent legislation of the Baltics. By contrast.are still present. for the case of the Russian Federation. in a context where citizenship confers the right to vote . In the anticipation of EU integration. We can view the laws regulating citizenship acquisition as the outcome of the decision problem faced by a median voter. even though small concessions to jus soli have been made. The issue for these states was how to balance a need to reconstitute their national identity around an ethnic model. Again. 4. the salient fact in shaping current citizenship policy is the perception that many of its citizens are outside its borders. showed a more open approach. After independence. which was less affected by Soviet immigration policy. The aim of the model is also to generate testable implications that can guide our interpretation of the empirical evidence. spread around the former regions of the USSR. while most other countries of the area still persist with discriminatory policies.

the same approach could be extended to consider alternative agenda. and y = N P y . respectively. while in practice citizenship acquisition implies a larger set of rights. A few warnings are in order. therefore the model's predictions can be applied to the laws concerning both citizenship at birth and naturalization. Second. Finally. where y N and y M denote average income for natives and migrants. economic and social goals. our focus on the right to vote as the main benefit of citizenship is easily justified. and also implies some duties. where M + N = P and M < N. when considering the decision to grant citizenship. even if the model concentrates on voting on a specific policy.over policy variables. before we present the model's details. First. y N >y>y M . since political rights can be viewed as an instrument through which migrants could achieve broader political. and 11 Page 13 thus the right to vote. beside the right to vote. is driven by the benefits and costs associated with this decision. namely. Migrants are poorer than natives since they are relatively unskilled. to migrants. namely. in our oneperiod framework the distinction between different ways to acquire citizenship becomes irrelevant. a redistributive tax scheme which finances a public good. We consider an economy where a population of mass P consists of natives with mass N and migrants with mass M. A native voter.

according to a proportional income tax rate τ. and a public good. and thus for the economy as a whole.N + M P y M is the economy-wide average income. g. Both groups pay taxes. according to u i =c i + λg (1) where λ is a positive preference parameter. c i . median income is lower than average income both for natives and migrants. Tax revenues are used by the government to finance the public good according to the following balanced budget constraint: g = τy − τ 2 2 y (2) where the second term captures tax collection costs. Each enfranchised individual casts a vote on the tax rate. We also assume that income distribution is skewed to the right for each group. Both natives and migrants derive utility from consumption of a private good. namely. as in Meltzer and Richard (1981). The tax rate is set through a political choice under majority voting. such that 0 < τ < 1. Assume initially 12 Page 14 .

for instance. as captured. This cost increases with the share of migrants over population. reflecting the possibility that their disenfranchisement can lead to social unrest and even violence. k could enter directly the utility function. The cost is also affected by factors that determine the degree of inclusiveness of a country's culture. The cost enters the individual budget constraint as follows: c i ≤ (1 − τ)y i −k (4) where y i denotes individual income. Assume also that society bears a cost k for the exclusion of migrants from citizenship.that only natives are citizens and are therefore allowed to vote. The expression for the indirect utility function of a native voter with income y N i is given by v N i = (1 − τ)y N i − k + λ(τ − τ 2 2 . Equivalently. according to k=K+h M P (3) where K reflects the degree of cultural inclusiveness and h > 0. by a jus soli tradition.

The native median voter could avoid the cost k by granting citizenship to the migrants and thus accepting the tax rate that would prevail under universal enfranchisement. which is measured by the ratio of native median income over the economywide average income.)y (5) which is single-peaked with respect to the tax rate. according to which the equilibrium tax rate is the preferred tax rate of the native median voter with income y N ∗ . To be noticed is that under our assumptions about income distribution it is not necessarily the case that y N∗ y < 1. since migrants also pay taxes. according to τ N ∗ =1− 1 λ y N ∗ y (6) The level of the tax rate increases with the intensity of the preference for public goods and with inequality.which implies that the tax rate is going to be positive only if y N∗ y < λ. which is given by . We can therefore apply the median voter theorem.

The native median voter faces a simple set of costs and benefits when considering the decision to grant citizenship. but can enjoy a smaller tax. In particular. It follows that the native median voter decides to grant citizenship to migrants if and only if . given our assumptions on income distribution. it follows that τ N ∗ <τ ∗ .τ ∗ =1− 1 λ y ∗ y (7) 13 Page 15 where y ∗ is the economy-wide median income. the tax rate chosen by the native median voter is lower than the tax that applies under universal suffrage. If migrants cannot vote. If migrants vote. he has to pay more taxes but k is avoided. Since y N ∗ >y ∗ . he has to face the cost k. The difference between τ N ∗ and τ ∗ increases with the income gap between natives and migrants and with the share of migrants over population. namely. the latter is certainly positive.

(1 − τ N ∗ )y N ∗ − k + λ(τ N ∗ − τ N ∗ 2 2 )y ≤ (1 − τ ∗ )y N ∗ + λ(τ ∗ − τ ∗2 2 )y (8) where following (5) we find on the left hand side his indirect utility function when migrants cannot vote and on the right hand side his indirect utility function when migrants can vote. Even if the model is static. we can think of its dynamic implications in terms of a sequence . while the cost increases with the degree of inclusiveness K of the country's culture. Besides. Both the disenfranchisement cost and the fiscal gain associated with the no-franchise status quo increase in the share of migrants over the population. the fiscal gain also increases with the income gap between natives and migrants.

they will decide whether or not restricting the current regulation taking into account the incoming waves of immigrants and following the simple logic previously illustrated. since a higher share increases 14 Page 16 both the cost and the fiscal gain of disenfranchisement. following a sequence of stationary decisions. the median voter will respond taking into considerations all the channels involved and this may result in an adaptation of the regulation. migrants who are already in the country and have thus become citizens are simply to be considered as natives themselves. To be noticed is that a given stock of migrants has a stronger impact on countries with a relatively small native population. since it is the share of migrants over population that matters. When the status quo is a jus soli regulation. . Finally. The net effect will depend on which factor is stronger. or equivalently a particularly generous naturalization policy. While the present formulation of the model is designed to establish conditions for extension of citizenship rights to migrants. The predictions so far obtained from the model indicate that a decision to extend citizenship and the associated voting rights is facilitated by a smaller income gap between natives and migrants and by a larger degree of inclusiveness of a country's culture. the effect of an increase in the share of migrants is potentially ambiguous. Together with the ethnic natives. it can also encompass restriction. due to a large inflow. it follows that jus sanguinis countries will be more reluctant to change.of repeated decisions. the economy is shocked by an increase of the migrants share. If. generating a trade off. If we interpret a jus sanguinis tradition as a low degree of inclusiveness and thus a low cost of exclusion.

demographic aspects could be considered by assuming that the migrants' younger average age implies a larger ability to contribute to the welfare state. 15 Page 17 . the level of democracy can influence the outcome since it implies a constraint on the political rights of the natives themselves. Thus a relatively large government size. While our one-period model cannot explicitly reflect these aspects. and thus the population share of migrants. is subject to uncertainty. thus amplifying the tax cost which follows the decision to allow migrants to vote. border instability could be captured in a version of the model where the size of the native population. Third. If only rich natives are allowed to vote. which can be modelled with an income franchise requirement. as captured by λ. Fourth. the impact of the size of government on citizenship laws can be captured by assuming that different countries exhibit different preference parameters toward government. we can interpret our tax as a life-long contribution. we should therefore expect a negative impact of the size of government on the degree of inclusiveness of citizenship laws. could make an open citizenship policy more costly. the associated tax rate will be higher than otherwise. The testable implication is that the decision to grant citizenship is positively influenced by the domestic level of democracy. Second. This should facilitate the decision to grant them citizenship and implies that countries with a relatively old native population should be particularly sensitive to these considerations and thus display a more open attitude. Empirically. by increasing the tax differential.The basic model can be extended to consider several other potentially relevant factors. First. at any given level of income. which is higher for a migrant.

but it also increases the cost associated with their exclusion. even though there were nearly no reforms in citizenship laws during the first half of the century. a relatively old native population. a relatively high income level of the migrants. which provides synopses of the citizenship laws currently practiced in 190 countries. we expect the natives' decision to be positively influenced by an inclusive national culture. The sources for this directory were Embassies. when the national border is unstable. of letting migrants vote. 5. The Data: Citizenship Laws of the World We compile a dataset of citizenship laws across the countries of the world for the postwar period. a stable national border. the Library of Congress. the United Nations High Commission for Refugees (2003). to introduce a random component in the model should affect the voting decision by reducing the tax rate. The principal focus of our codification is citizenship acquisition at birth. the main problem is to establish who can be considered as a native. To summarize. and a large native population. the share of migrants has a potentially ambiguous impact on the natives' decision to extend citizenship and voting right to migrants.1. The principal source for the information we codify is a directory published by the Investigations Service of the United States Office of Personnel Management in 2001. for the native median voter. since it increases the tax disadvantage. and the Department of State. but we also collect information about naturalization requirements. a small welfare state. so that . We supplement this information with additional one from the CIA World Factbook (2002). We take 1948 as the starting point. 1975 and at the beginning of the postwar period. and the survey in Weil (2001). a high level of democracy.Indeed. Moreover. Citizenship at Birth We attribute to each country an appropriate code for citizenship laws in 2001. Under standard risk aversion behavior. 5.

and countries subject to full jus soli (Group 3).most of the legislation in place in 1948 had actually been developed much earlier. we treat the specific legal provisions regulating access to citizenship in 1948 as predetermined. In our classification we focus on the presence of jus soli elements in a country's legislation. (1998). at least relative to the subsequent developments that are the focus of the present investigation. which gained independence from the British and French administration in the 1943-1948 period. we include the postwar decolonization phase with the exemption of the Middle East. countries that apply a mixed regime (Group 2). rather than emigrants. 16 Page 18 the analysis of legal origins in La Porta et al. despite the occurrence of major historical events such as World War I. A mixed regime includes elements of both jus soli and jus sanguinis. Indeed. 3 As in 3 By treating 1948 as the initial year. 4 Our dataset includes those 162 countries for which we were able to collect information on both original . This approach is justified by our primary interest in the potential impact of citizenship laws on immigrants. 1975 and 2001. By coding citizenship laws in the intermediate year 1975. For 1948. we divide countries into three groups: countries subject to jus sanguinis without any jus soli element (Group 1). we divide the postwar period into two subperiods of equal length. while the 19th century witnessed a first wave of adaptation of citizenship legislation from the civil vs. the subsequent half century did not see further evolution. common law tradition.

and current citizenship laws, and for which migration data were available for the postwar period. 5 INSERT TABLE 1 The differential patterns of evolution that citizenship laws generate in 1948, 1975 and 2001 are summarized by the transition matrices in Table 1, which reveals considerable variations both across countries and over time. The table shows that in 1948 jus soli was the rule in about 47% (namely, 76 out of 162) of the countries, while jus sanguinis dominated in 41% (namely, 67 out of 162), and the mixed regime was adopted in the remaining 12% (19 countries). Among the countries that were under jus soli in 1948, we find the United States, Canada, all the Oceanian countries, most of Latin America, within Africa and Asia the British and Portuguese colonies, within Europe the UK, Ireland and Portugal. On the other hand, in 1948 jus sanguinis predominated in most of Europe, including its Eastern part. As explained in Section 3, France was unique in its early choice of a mixed regime. Since we 4 For details on our classification criteria see the Data Appendix, part A. 5 For details on migration data see the Data Appendix, part C. 17
Page 19

treat colonial territories as subject to the metropolitan countries' regime until independence, the group applying the mixed regime in 1948 includes France and its colonies. By 1975, 31% (namely, 50 out of 162) of the countries had jus soli, 62% (101) jus sanguinis, and 7% (11) a mixed regime. The main event justifying this evolution is decolonization, with many former colonies switching to jus sanguinis, from jus soli when the UK and Portugal

were the metropolitan country, and from the mixed regime in the case of France (see Section 3). As of 2001, 24% (namely, 39 out of 162) of the countries apply jus soli, 54% (88) jus sanguinis, and 22% (35) a mixed regime. It has mostly been the adaptation of the legislation of many European countries, relaxing pure jus sanguinis in favor of a mixed regime, that explains the pattern observed for the second subperiod. Among the countries that still adhere to the jus soli principle in 2001 are the United States, Canada, New Zealand, and Ireland (which - however - recently introduced restrictions to jus soli with a June 2004 referendum). The United Kingdom and Australia, on the contrary, no longer adhere to it and now adopt a mixed regime. Overall, jus sanguinis is currently the most common regime, with 69% of the countries in Africa, 83% in Asia, and 41% (down from 88%) in Europe. The growing group where a mix of provisions is applied is particularly well-represented in Europe, with 56% of the European countries including the formerly jus soli United Kingdom. On the other hand, jus soli predominates in the Americas, with 89% of the countries in Latin America, and the entire North America (namely, the U. S. and Canada). Table 1 reveals three different patterns of transitional dynamics: stability, switch, and convergence. Stable countries lie along the diagonal. Looking at the 1948 to 2001 transition, we see that a large fraction (28%, namely, 46 out of 162) have started and ended as jus sanguinis. In other words, it is 69% (namely, 46 out of 67) of the originally jus sanguinis countries that have remained so. By contrast, 22% (36 out of 162) are steadily jus soli countries: this means that only 47% (36 out of 76) of the originally jus soli countries have not changed their policies. Off diagonal, there is a sizeable proportion of countries (19%, or 31 out of 162) that have switched from jus soli to sanguinis, by completely eliminating

birthplace as a criterion: most of them - as mentioned - are former African colonies of the UK and Portugal, which made this radical choice at independence. Looking at the two 18
Page 20

subperiods, we see most of these switches occur between 1948 and 1975. Finally, there is evidence of a process of convergence to a soli/sanguinis mix, which affects 18% of the countries (29 out of 162, of which 20 converge from jus sanguinis by adding jus soli elements, while 9 converge from jus soli by restricting it) and intensifies between 1975 and 2001. INSERT TABLE 2 In Table 2 we present further information on citizenship laws evolution by reporting changes in citizenship laws, organized by original laws. Over the 1948-2001 period, 74 countries (46%) have gone through a change in the laws. Of these, 51 have changed toward jus sanguinis and 23 toward jus soli, while 45 changes have occurred in the first subperiod and 33 in the second. 6 In particular, in the first subperiod, the majority of the countries that went through a change (29, or 64%) were originally jus soli. As mentioned, this pattern is determined largely by the behavior of former colonies. In the second subperiod, the majority of the countries that went through a change (20, or 61%) were originally jus sanguinis, most of which adopting a more open legislation. The above discussion suggests a relevant role of border stability. To investigate this issue, we introduce a set of dummies capturing a country's history of border changes. In particular, we distinguish across three different causes of border instability: decolonization, Berlin wall, other border changes. 7 If we compare the transitional dynamics of the full sample with those

of the subsample of countries that did not go through a border change, we count for the latter a much smaller proportion of switches from jus soli to jus sanguinis. This pattern confirms the relevance of border changes, especially those due to decolonization. INSERT TABLE 3 Summary statistics for our citizenship laws dataset are reported in Table 3. The correlation between 1948 and 2001 citizenship laws is 0.42, which points to some persistence, as confirmed by the even higher correlation between 1948 and 1975 (0.60) and 1975 and 2001 laws (0.81). 6 A few countries went through more than one change. 7 The Data Appendix, part B describes how the three border change dummies are constructed. 19
Page 21

5.2. Citizenship by Naturalization and the Citizenship Policy Index Naturalization policies are also relevant to the issues at hand. Indeed, to facilitate naturalization for immigrant parents may represent a substitute mechanism to attribute citizenship to children born in jus sanguinis countries. Besides, the general attitude revealed by a country's regulation of citizenship at birth may be reflected in its naturalization laws, with jus soli countries traditionally making naturalization much easier, at least for resident aliens. Within jus sanguinis countries, naturalization requirements again tend to be correlated with the revisions introduced for citizenship at birth. Basic rules for naturalization may include a period of residence, renunciation of other citizenship, familiarity with the language and customs of the country, and the availability of adequate means of support. We code naturalization only for 2001, on the basis of the available information on 142 of our 162 countries. We classify countries on the basis of the number of years of residence

which can be considered a relatively open attitude. 10 For European countries only. The corrected Cronbach's alpha of the indicator is 0. by associating jus soli elements with lower number of years of residence required for naturalization. 9 Table 3 reports summary statistics for naturalization and the citizenship policy index.required for naturalization. we treat citizenship laws in 2001 as an ordinal variable. 4 years or fewer). 10 8 We do not consider naturalization by marriage. but we do not use this variable due to limited information.54. since it is heavily dependent on family law. 6 to 14 years. by constructing four classes (more than 14 years. which can be explained by the fact that the correlation between citizenship laws and naturalization is only 0. We construct an index of citizenship policy defined on the 0-1 interval. 5 years. while Baubock et al. To construct the index. the British Council has compiled an index of civic citizenship and inclusion (see British Council Brussels 2005). 44%) require five years of residence. 9 Dual citizenship provisions constitute another potentially relevant aspect of citizenship policy. 8 In our dataset 62 countries (namely. even though data on naturalization are only available for the year 2001 and for a subset of countries. We then combine the information we collected on citizenship at birth and naturalization within a single measure. Alternative ways to define naturalization classes yielded similar conclusions. while 46% require more time and only 10% are more open. 20 Page 22 .37. (2006) collect statistics on acquisition of nationality.

an ordering by increasing inclusiveness toward immigrants. Border stability is measured through our border changes dummies. we select the following variables. Among regressors. in principle those regressors that affect the probability of being a jus soli country may not always have the opposite effect on the probability of being a jus sanguinis country. and jus sanguinis with minimal inclusiveness.6. Moreover. . The Determinants of Citizenship Laws 6. To control for other cultural characteristics. and 3 if the country has a jus soli regime. or else may not have any effect at all (and vice versa). We interpret the presence of a jus soli tradition as an indicator of the degree of inclusiveness of national culture.1. Empirical Specification In bringing our theoretical model to the data. We use a multinomial logit specification to achieve maximum generality. The empirical investigation is performed using a panel sample which includes information on two cross sections of 162 countries: the first cross section refers to the 1950-1975 subperiod. we also consider religion and ethnic diversity. this choice does not impose any ex ante ordering among the three regimes. we employ measures of migration. The dependent variable is citizenship laws. 2 if the country has a mixed regime. Further discussion on this point is postponed to the sub-section on robustness. and the age structure of the population. in order to investigate the determinants of citizenship laws evolution in the postwar period. the size of government. with jus soli being associated with maximal. which is categorical and can take three values: 1 if the country has a jus sanguinis regime. while we cannot gauge the impact of the income gap between natives and migrants due to lack of data. In fact. for example. We also control for countries with a particularly small population size.

L it represents citizenship laws in country i at the end of period t.2 (where t = 1 refers to the 1950-1975 period and t = 2 refers 21 Page 23 to the 1976-2000 period)..the second cross section to the 1976-2000 subperiod..162 and t = 1. In the full specification we present. 11 In specification (9).. S it is a dummy for the presence of jus sanguinis in country i at the beginning of each subperiod.. (9) with i = 1. a is a constant term. the multinomial logit model we run has the following form: L it = a + bM it + cS it + dM it S it + eT t +Z 0 it f+ it . M it is migration stock as a percentage of the population in country i at the beginning of period t. M it S .

proxies for cultural characteristics such as religious affiliation and ethnolinguistic fractionalization. and a measure of democracy. The first group includes dummies capturing the country's geopolitical position. 12 The set of explanatory variables Z it can be divided into two groups. and it is an error term. consistent with the model previously outlined. we will organize our comments in terms of the effects of each of our regressors on the probability of adopting either a mixed or a jus soli regime instead of jus sanguinis. starting with the variables we consider focal to our analysis. where we take jus sanguinis as the reference is the interaction between the previous two variables. Z it is a vector of additional explanatory variables. INSERT TABLE 4 We can now suggest a number of specific hypotheses. T t is a period dummy. Within this group we consider the border changes dummies and dummies for Latin American. The second group of explanatory variables includes the size of government as a share of GDP. regarding the potential role of the above mentioned factors. Table 4 presents their summary statistics. This follows the specification of our multinomial logit estimates. Migration (M . Southern European and small countries. The Data Appendix collects information on the definitions and sources of all variables we employed. the share of young in the population. immigration and legal tradition. Throughout the following. namely.

it ) is measured by the stock of migrants in percent of the population at the beginning of each subperiod. By entering the migrant stock near the beginning of each period. since it is unlikely that stocks evaluated at the beginning of the period can be affected by subsequent changes in citizenship laws. 13 while for the second they refer to the stock in 1980. S i1 = 1 if country i has jus sanguinis in 1948 and S i2 = 1 if country i has jus sanguinis in in 1975. M i1 is migration stock in country i in 1960 and M i2 is migration stock in country i in 1980. 14 A positive coefficient . the available data refer to the stock in 11 We also run multinomial logit models for two types of more parsimonious specifications. L i1 and L i2 are citizenship laws in country i in 1975 and 2001. for comparison purposes. T 1 = 0 and T 2 = 1. we avoid any potential endogeneity problem of migration with respect to citizenship laws. respectively. 12 In particular. For the first subperiod. 22 Page 24 1960.

most of Latin America 13 . the coefficients of the interaction could also turn out to be negative since. A crucial control in our regressions. As explained in Section 3. as suggested by some of the political theories introduced in Section 1. its coefficients would indicate that those jus sanguinis countries facing high migration tend to add jus soli elements.for the mixed regime would indicated that high migration pushes toward it rather than toward jus sanguinis. We introduce the Latin America dummy to capture the peculiarity of this continent's experience. In particular. we should expect negative signs for the coefficients for our border change dummies. Turning to our geopolitical dummies. in the presence of a large stock of migrants. and similarly for the jus soli regime. On the other hand. thus confirming persistence of the original laws. We measure it with a dummy for countries that apply jus sanguinis at the beginning of each subperiod (S it ). as previously discussed. We select this dummy because jus sanguinis is the most persistent of the three regimes. The interaction between the jus sanguinis dummy and migration should reveal additional information: if positive. a positive coefficient for the mixed regime would suggest convergence toward the intermediate group. is the legal tradition in the matter of citizenship. thus suggesting a particularly significant role of this initial legislation. the natives' reaction could be a conservative one. To assess the total impact of migration for jus sanguinis countries we also need to take into account the interaction's coefficients. if border stability really counts as a prerequisite for the introduction of automatic birthrights for the immigrants. A negative value of the dummy's coefficient for a mixed and jus soli regime would imply that jus sanguinis countries are less likely to end up in the mixed and jus soli groups.

we should expect a positive coefficient for the mixed regime since these countries have been experiencing quickly increasing migration during the second subperiod. Finally. For Southern Europe. On the other hand. the endogeneity of our migration measure is ruled out by the fact that such changes had been extremely rare during the first half of the 20th century. if young immigrants could offer a solution to domestic demographic imbalances. since migration data reveal that countries with a small population tend to have large and erratic figures. If indeed the behavior of Latin America differs significantly from the rest of the sample in being associated with a higher probability of adopting jus soli. see the Data Appendix.1. more expensive and more redistributive structure would represent an obstacle to automatic citizenship granting to the children of relatively poor immigrants.3. with a disproportionately small impact on their legislation. part C. The potential endogeneity of migration is further addressed in sub-sub-section 6. we would find that countries with a higher share of young in .Earlier data are not available. 23 Page 25 adopted jus soli long before our sample period. so its current position is not determined by postwar developments and in particular by its postwar migration experience. The size of government is meant to proxy for the nature of the welfare state: if a thicker. 14 Even taking into account the anticipation of future changes of citizenship laws in making migration decisions. we would found negative coefficients. we should expect negative signs for this dummy's coefficients. where alternative measures of migration are introduced. it should exhibit a positive coefficient for this kind of legislation. with most of the revision to the legislation toward mixed regimes occurring in the past 15 years or so.

is highly correlated with the initial citizenship laws as identified by the jus sanguinis dummy (-0.15). thus displaying negative coefficients.35). Current citizenship laws. Overall. Pairwise correlations between all our independent variables are not reported for brevity and can be summarized as follows. while its correlation with the civil law dummy is much lower (-0.31) and Latin America (-0.52). The share of young in population is positively associated with migration stocks ( population would be less prone to adopt jus soli elements.measured by the political rights variable . Citizenship laws are also significantly 24 Page 26 correlated with migration. the dependent variable.36). The Latin America dummy is positively associated with the Catholic share (0. the small country dummy. the Catholic share. these stylized facts are in line with previous research and economic intuition. The establishment of a consolidated democracy .64). we include the share of Catholics in total population and an index of ethnolinguistic fractionalization. The dummy reflecting jus sanguinis as the initial law is negatively correlated with decolonization (-0. political rights.should exert a positive effect on the probability of a jus soli legislation even though even in a democratic country hostility toward the assimilation of outsiders may persist for a protracted period of time.43). In an effort to capture additional dimensions of cultural differences. Political rights tend to be low in countries with high ethnolinguistic fractionalization (-0. . beside legal tradition. INSERT TABLE 5 Pairwise correlations among our dependent and independent variables are presented in Table 5. and ethnolinguistic fractionalization.

Hence. This means that high migration and a jus sanguinis origin decrease the probability of applying a mixed or a jus soli legislation rather than jus sanguinis. while migration 25 Page 27 only remains significantly negative for the probability of applying a mixed regime. the results reported in the table indicate the impact of the explanatory variable on the probability of choosing either the mixed or the jus soli regimes. while both coefficients are positive for the period dummy. Finally. migration and jus sanguinis display negative coefficients for both the mixed regime and jus soli. which includes the dummies. Multinomial logit (b) is an expanded specification. multinomial logit (c) is our full specification. which adds to (b) the other potentially relevant economic and institutional regressors. which adds to (a) the dummies we discussed above. 6. the jus sanguinis origin still exerts a negative impact on the probability of applying a mixed or jus soli regime. Multinomial logit (a) is the core specification. which includes only the core variables. Jus sanguinis is the reference category for all the results shown.It is also clear that several of our independent variables are closely interrelated and that it may be difficult to disentangle their specific effect on the evolution of citizenship laws. In particular. migration and jus sanguinis as initial citizenship law. plus the period dummy. we find that the core variables are all significant. and that in the second subperiod the probability of applying a mixed or jus soli legislation increases.2. The period . In specification (b). Results The results of our multinomial logits are presented in Table 6. relative to jus sanguinis. The table reports three different specifications. namely. INSERT TABLE 6 Starting with the core specification (a).

South Europe has a positive coefficient for the mixed regime. in the full specification (c). uncovering a tendency for countries with a jus sanguinis origin which are exposed to high migration to add jus soli elements. As expected. The role of the Latin America and Southern Europe dummies is confirmed. the total effect of migration becomes negligible. having gone through a decolonization border change negatively affects the probability of applying either a mixed or jus soli regime. namely. a jus sanguinis origin and the period dummy are confirmed. if one evaluates the coefficients of migration and of the interaction together. The small country dummy is not significant in this specification. In this extended version the coefficient for decolonization loses significance. However.dummy is significantly positive only for the probability of a mixed regime. 15 The interaction term between migration and jus sanguinis origin is significant and positive for both the mixed regime and jus soli. since these countries have a higher probability of applying this regime. while the small country dummy now reveals a negative impact on the probability of applying a mixed regime. while the share of young in the population exerts a negative impact. the impact of migration. confirming that Southern European countries have a higher probability of becoming mixed. the decolonization dummy displays two negative coefficients. The size of government has a positive and significant coefficient for the probability of applying a jus soli regime. Latin America has a positive coefficient for jus soli. while a high degree of democracy . The share of Catholics and ethnolinguistic fractionalization are both insignificant. the strength of this tendency is questioned by the fact that. Finally. in support of the hypothesis that countries with a relatively old population are more likely to choose mixed and jus soli regimes.

5%. consistently with the positive coefficients for jus soli and a mixed regime in Table 6. to be evaluated together with the 2. 16 For all three specifications. The marginal effects also allow to quantify the impact of our regressors. inspection of the marginal coefficients in Table 7 confirms that migration increases the probability of jus sanguinis and decreases that of a mixed regime and that the interaction between jus sanguinis and migration is negative. In particular. we verified that our results are not driven by outliers. 17 Moreover.3%.positively affects the probability of applying either a mixed or jus soli regime.7%. an increase in migration of one percentage point for a jus sanguinis country decreases the probability of being jus sanguinis by about 2. and decreases the probability of having a mixed regime by 2. . 17 The estimated marginal effects are calculated by holding all the independent variables at their mean 26 Page 28 decolonization reveals that this regressor retains a significantly negative impact on the probability of jus soli. the marginal effect of 15 For both multinomial logit (a) and (b) we obtain the same results using a balanced sample composed by the 224 countries which constitute the reference sample for the estimation of our full specification. while an increase in migration of one percentage point increases the probability of being a jus sanguinis country by about 2. 16 For the full specification (c). having gone through a decolonization border change decreases the probability of being jus soli by about 14%. Besides.5% increase due to direct effect of migration.

as well as the Berlin wall and the other border changes dummies. we cannot include in the regressions the socialist and oil dummies. demographics and democracy also contribute to their determination. Moreover. Quantitative and qualitative development indicators such as income per capita and inequality could reveal if a richer. so they are unlikely to add independent explanatory power to a regression. A dummy for socialist countries could instead work as an alternative to our Berlin wall border change dummy.We also consider additional covariates that have often been found significant in related research on the determinants of institutions. and that other factors such as government size. the original laws and our geopolitical dummies exert a significant impact on current citizenship laws. In fact they fail to add any further significance to the previous results. and also with democracy and fractionalization. a dummy for oil countries could account for the fact that most of them have been experiencing huge immigration which has had no impact on their still very restrictive legislation (often based on Islamic family law). 18 However. our results indicate that migration. For dichotomous independent variables the marginal effect is the change from 0 to 1 holding all other variables at their means. more equal country is more prone to adopting jus soli elements. both per capita GDP and the Gini index of inequality tend to be associated with migration. 18 The correlation between Berlin wall and socialist is 0. However. In levels. 19 INSERT TABLE 7 Overall.48. . due to the fact that all countries identified by them do not exhibit enough variability with respect to the dependent variable.

The presence of countervailing forces highlighted by the model is therefore confirmed by our findings. In addition. On the other hand. in jus sanguinis countries the impact of migration turns out to be negligible. this correlation covers a more complex pattern which can be revealed once the interaction between migration and the legal tradition in the matter of citizenship is considered. Contrary to the model's implications.19 For example. the welfare burden proves not to be an obstacle for a jus soli legislation. countries affected by Berlin wall have always applied jus sanguinis. 27 Page 29 particular. this could be explained by the fact many of the countries with extended welfare systems may favor immigration because of their demographic crisis. on balance. Overall. because liberal countries tend to restrict while restrictive countries tend to resist innovation. countries with a jus soli origin react to increasing migration by adding jus sanguinis elements. However. demo- . Indeed. we show that the legal tradition tends to affect the current legislation persistently. the legal tradition interacts with the way countries react to migration in a complex way. there is evidence of a tendency toward adding jus soli provisions so that. for countries with a jus sanguinis origin which have experienced more immigration. our results suggest that migration pushes national legislations in the direction of jus sanguinis. On the one hand. as predicted by the model. Therefore. not jus soli. even though the process of transplantation can prove discontinuous in the case of former colonies. the evidence does not the hypothesis of convergence toward a mix of provisions suggested by some political theories (see Section 1). However.

As outlined above.graphic stagnation encourages the adoption of mixed and jus soli regimes. the evidence confirms that a higher degree of democracy is associated with more jus soli elements. This could suggest that migration flows are endogenous with respect to citizenship laws. Finally. our migration measure was chosen to minimize a potential endogeneity bias. Alternative Specifications We experiment our multinomial logit specifications with alternative covariates. 21 In the Table Appendix. while cultural traits captured by religious affiliation and ethnolinguistic fractionalization appears to be irrelevant. When we replace our migrations stocks with average migration flows (computed with reference to each subperiod). . Further tests involve alternative measures of migration stocks. relative open socialdemocracies. Robustness In this section we present a number of alternatives to our benchmark regressions to investigate whether they are robust to different specifications. the impact we observe for the size of government could be explained by the fact that it proxies for European-style. in particular as far as the impact of migration is concerned. our empirical findings match the theoretical insights coming from the model.1.3. 20 the coefficients for migration turns out to be insignificant in all three specifications. 6. we replace our measure of migration with a range of alternative measures. Moreover.3. First. 28 Page 30 6. In sum. and provide a deeper understanding of the forces shaping citizenship laws. samples and estimation techniques.

24 When we replace the jus sanguinis with the civil law dummy (see Table A. as possible alternatives. 21 Namely.1. and the 1960-70 and 1980-90 averages. for the first and the second subperiod we select the years 1970 and 1990.45. To sum up. the latter turns out to be substantially less significant and reduces the 20 Migration stocks and flows show a correlation of 0. and citizenship laws could be viewed as part of migration policy.Table A. .1. respectively. column (2)). the simultaneous determination of citizenship laws and migration does represent a concern when we enter within-the-period data on migration instead of beginning-of-period data. respectively. our beginning-of-period migration stocks prove to be the most adequate measures of the role of migration. 23 If the coefficients of the two alternative dummies were the same. the influence of the legal tradition can also be analyzed through a dummy capturing the presence of a civil law tradition. 22 Since jus sanguinis and jus soli are in principle closely linked to the civil and common systems of laws. with the latter losing significance. 22 We also experiment with a specification entering the migrant stock in 1960 for both subperiods. Results from this instrumented specification are similar to those presented in Table 6. Some differences emerge in the coefficients for migration and its interaction with jus sanguinis. Since in the postwar period migration has been highly regulated by policy in most receiving countries. respectively. column (1) presents the full specification with the 1960-70 and 1980-90 average migration stock. one could conclude that our detailed codification of the original citizenship laws does not add much to what we can already learn from a country’s broader legal tradition.

since it is the quickly increasing second-subperiod immigration which determines the peculiar behavior of this region.2 and A.2. an (unreported) alternative multinomial probit model delivers the same qualitative results. suggesting that civil law is a much weaker predictor of current citizenship laws than the original citizenship laws. namley.35.3. we assume that jus sanguinis corresponds to minimal and jus soli to maximal inclusiveness. 6. These results are reported in Table A.23 The dummy is equal to 1 if a country belongs to the civil law tradition and to 0 if a country belongs to common law. Alternative Estimation Techniques Alternative estimation techniques broadly confirm the same results from Table 6. We also replace our decolonization dummy with a dummy for British or Portuguese colonies (identifying those countries that were characterized by a jus soli legislation during the colonial period). and with the subSaharan Africa dummy. possibly because flows are multicollinear with respect to stocks and endogenous with respect to the dependent variable. We also run ordered logit regressions where current citizenship laws are explicitly treated as an ordinal variable. 25 but both alternatives are associated with insignificant coefficients. 29 Page 31 significance of most other regressors. Our previous conclusions . we find that its coefficient is insignificant. The correlation between civil law and jus sanguinis is 0.3. 24 The correlation between the two dummies is 0.35. In particular. which we assume here to be ordered by increasing inclusiveness. When we replace the Southern Europe dummy with migration flows.

3. 30 Page 32 with the initial laws. 26 6. we run a test for the parallel regression assumption. The test is an approximate likelihood-ratio test of proportionality of odds across response categories. 29 while ordinary least squares regressions with our citizenship policy index in 2001 and an indexed version of .31). with migration and a jus sanguinis origin exerting a negative impact on the application of jus soli. 27 The results for this cross section reveal a much lower level of significance for several covariates. an alternative ordered logit regression also achieves much weaker results than in the panel. 27 Here the dependent variable is citizenship laws in 2001. while migration stock refers to 1960 and jus sanguinis in 1948 is the initial law. Our multinomial logit specification is hence superior to an ordered logit specification. 26 For all specifications. 28 The same applies to alternative variants with a cross section over each subperiod. For the same cross section.30) and for sub-Saharan Africa (0. the test provides evidence that the parallel regression assumption has been violated.are confirmed. namely. In all cases. in particular for migration and for its interaction 25 Decolonization shows a significant correlation with the dummies for British or Portuguese colony (0. Alternative Sample Criteria We also run multinomial logit regressions on a cross-sectional sample composed by country averages over the 1950-2000 period.3. 1950-1975 and 1976-2000.

Empirical Specification In the alternative specification. While specification (9) focuses on current citizenship laws as the dependent variable.4). we developed an alternative specification which is designed to capture more specifically the determinants of a change in the laws.1. Z it contains all the variables previ- . For our panel. 7. 0 if no change occurs.2001 citizenship laws as alternative dependent variables both show an insignificant coefficient for migration (see Table A. and 1 if the country changes its laws toward jus soli. 30 These results may be due to the fact that a single cross section of countries includes less information than our panel. we run a multinomial logit model of the following form for its full specification: V it = α + βM it + γT t +Z 0 it δ+η it . (10) where α is a constant term and η it is an error term. 7. the dependent variable is categorical and can take three values: -1 if the country changes its laws toward jus sanguinis. An Alternative Approach: The Determinants of Change in Citizenship Laws In this section we study citizenship laws evolution using an alternative approach which is able to provide additional insights.

to show that they are not driven by outliers.ously described. its interaction with migration. Hence. showing that migration is again negative correlated with the dependent variable. except for those which present zero-cell problems. The period dummy indicates that the second subperiod witnesses an increase in the probability to expand. The size of government's negative coefficient . Decolonization and Southern Europe exert a positive impact on change in both directions. Pairwise correlations among our new dependent variable. more significantly so for restriction for the case of decolonization. Results Regression results for the multinomial logit model are presented in Table 8. and with average migration flows. jus sanguinis as the initial citizenship law. changes in citizenship laws. where the reference category is no change. 31 Page 33 the independent variables are presented in Table 5. with similar results. the results reported in the table indicate the impact of the explanatory variable on the probability of choosing either restriction toward jus sanguinis (first column) or expansion toward jus soli (second column). Migration has a positive impact on the probability to restrict and a non significant impact on the probability to expand. 29 We apply to the above results the Cook's distance method. and 28 We also experiment with migration stocks in 1970 and 1980. while the opposite holds for Southern Europe. 7. namely.2. and the Latin America dummy. 30 The same qualitative results arise in an unreported regression with naturalization in 2001 as dependent variable.

these results are complementary to those of Section 6 since they highlight which . 31 Moreover. Overall. Ethnic diversity emerges as a significant factor of change toward jus sanguinis. the implications of Table 9 are in line with those of Table 7.for restriction confirms that this factor actually prevents it. INSERT TABLE 8 Table 9 reports the marginal coefficients for the regressions in Table 8 and confirms the restrictive impact of migration emerging from Table 8. Alternative measures of migration confirm an irrelevant impact on change in the laws. The Gini index once again fails to add any significance. The subSaharan Africa dummy is not significant when entered instead of decolonization. When we replace our decolonization dummy with the dummy for British or Portuguese colonies. we perform a full set of robustness checks for (10). 32 Page 34 impact on expansion. while again a relatively young population provokes resistance to extension. meaning that relatively old countries are more likely to liberalize their legislation. due to the removal of the Latin America dummy which comprises several former Portuguese colonies. For instance. it emerges as a factor that facilitates change toward sanguinis. in Table 7 decolonization exerts a significantly negative impact on the probability of having a jus soli legislation. which reports the marginal effects for the multinomial logit specification. which is consistent with the fact that. INSERT TABLE 9 As for specification (9). while per capita GDP reveals a significant 31 The estimated marginal effects are calculated as explained in footnote 17. the alternative dummy is again significant. in Table 9.

In particular. jus soli countries have reacted to increasing migration through restriction. the evidence does not support the hypothesis of convergence toward a mixed regime that includes both jus soli and jus sanguinis elements. while in jus sanguinis countries the impact of migration has been negligible. Border instability emerges as a decisive factor in shaping citizenship laws. for each possible direction of change. Countries with larger welfare systems. on the basis of a new dataset we compiled. we found that indeed citizenship laws have responded endogenously and systematically to a number of economic and institutional factors. Our investigation reveals that migration has had an overall negative impact on liberalization of the legislation and the adoption of jus soli elements. as reflected by the original citizenship legislation. Therefore. particularly in connection with the decolonization phase. older population and more extended political rights tend to be associated with more diffused elements of jus soli.factors have induced the observed evolution of the legislation. migration is confirmed as a factor that favors change toward restriction. In particular. reflecting discontinuities for the transplanting process of legal institutions. . We developed a simple median voter model where citizenship rights are granted by natives to migrants on the basis of the associated benefits and costs. The model predicts that migration has a potentially ambiguous impact on the legislation and that this impact is also affected by cultural factors including a country's degree of inclusiveness. Moreover. the legal tradition has affected the way countries have responded to migration. Conclusion We studied the theoretical and empirical determinants of the legal institution of citizenship in the postwar period. 8. In bringing the model to the data.

we also establish that different institutions are interrelated. regardless of the child's actual country of birth. The endogeneity of institutions to economic factors represents a challenge for research aimed at demonstrating that institutions are crucial determinants of economic performances. and women's rights. In the application of jus sanguinis. by using projections of international migration patterns in combination with the available predictions about the future course of democratization and border changes. This represents another challenge for further research on the process of formation of legal rules and on the impact of institutions on economic outcomes. Further research will study the future evolution of citizenship policy.such as commercial law. labor regulation. such as family law. within a legal system. Finally. but also by other institutions such as the internal system of political rights and the international system of relations as reflected by state borders. since they do adapt both to economic and non-economic factors. between the public and the private sphere of influence.More generally. a clear implication of our investigation is that institutions should not be 33 Page 35 presumed to be exogenous. countries may differ on some . By showing that citizenship laws are shaped not only by the broader legal origins. Data Appendix A. citizenship laws can be viewed as a link. Many issues that fall within the former . and government activities .have already been investigated. rules of inheritance. Citizenship laws are still changing. and where citizenship is not granted due to birth within the country. Our methodology can be extended to the study of other evolving bodies of the law. The Citizenship-at-birth Classification Group 1 (jus sanguinis countries): We include countries where citizenship is passed on to a child based upon at least one of the parents being a citizen of that country.

the existence of a provision that birth in the country matters for naturalization. A common exception to the general principle of jus sanguinis is automatic citizenship attribution to children of unknown parents. Another is the ability. the age of maturity) subject to either residence requirements or application. to acquire citizenship at some later point (for example. albeit in a restrictive form. the requirement of citizenship for one or both parents. automatic citizenship for the children of those immigrants who were also born in the country). that justifies the inclusion of a country within Group 2. a frequent provision that limits jus soli is double jus soli (namely. and the requirement that parents must be citizens other than by descent. our classification does not emphasize how narrowly 34 Page 36 jus sanguinis can be specifically applied to emigrants. residence requirements for parents. Most of these factors depend on the interaction between local family law and citizenship law. for example on the father's vs. Since we focus on the presence of jus soli elements in a country's legislation. Group 2 (countries with a mixed regime): We include those countries where elements of jus soli are recognized. . Examples of restrictions are generational requirements limiting the principle of citizenship by descent to the first or second generations of individuals born and residing abroad. Moreover. For example. mother's right to transmit citizenship by descent.factors. Group 3 (jus soli countries): We include those countries where citizenship is automatically granted due to birth within the country. we interpret as an element of jus soli. regardless of the parents' citizenship or status. for a child born in a country were jus sanguinis prevails. and coexist with varying degrees of jus sanguinis. the relevance of the marital status of the parents.

namely. We refer to Bertocchi and Strozzi (2009) for further detail on the data set on citizenship laws. Even if we set 1948 as the initial date for our citizenship laws analysis. Clearly. East Germany in 1990. plus a few additional observations not linked to these two waves. They include the new countries gaining independence . Examples of the events contained in the Polity IV 35 Page 37 (2002) dataset are the State Disintegration of Yugoslavia in 1991. the State Demise of Germany in the postwar decolonization phase. State Demise. B. West Germany in 1945. and the USSR in 1991. and Russia in 1992). In particular. and Other Border Changes) based on data collected from Polity IV (2002). and State Creation. State Disintegration. there is substantial overlap among the observations recorded in the Polity IV dataset. Decolonization. Berlin Wall. for border changes we include a few earlier events occurred in the 1943-1948 period that fit within the phase of post-colonial independence. from the Polity IV variable CHANGE we record information on four types of events capable of affecting state borders. East Germany in 1945. The Border Change Dummies We construct three border change dummies (namely. We .Normally countries that apply jus soli combine it with jus sanguinis provisions for the children of their citizens born outside of their territory (although limitations to the ability to transmit citizenship acquired in this manner to the next generation usually apply through. State Transformation.and therefore state borders . residence requirements). the new countries formed in Europe after the fall of the Berlin wall. The countries affected by State Creation are the most numerous. West Germany in 1990. for example. the State Transformation of Germany in 1990.

and other border changes (identifying countries which went through other types of boundary changes. the State Transformation of Germany in 1990 and the State Demise of East and West Germany in the same year. the separation of Bangladesh from Pakistan counts for two events. On the other hand. we treat as another single event. was obtained from the CIA (2002). we construct our three border change dummies for each period under consideration: Decolonization (identifying countries which went through a post-colonial redefinition of their borders). The data are taken from United Nations (2003) and are available for 1960. C. the State Transformation of East and West Germany in 1945.adapt these data to our needs by matching them to the 162 countries appearing in our citizenship laws dataset. 1990 and 2000. The data refer 36 Page 38 to incoming international migrants less outgoing international migrants. the absence of border changes. per 1. occurring to Germany. including refugees. Net migration flows: International net migration rate. For instance. Additional information. more than the direction of a change in terms of a country's size. On this basis. and the unification of Vietnam). when necessary. namely. we count as a single event.000 total . 1980. but also the State Demise of Germany in the same year. Berlin wall (identifying countries which went through a post-1989 Berlin wall border change). Likewise. Definitions and Sources of Other Covariates Migration stock: International migration stock (% population). Migration stock is the number of people born in a country other than that in which they live. To be noticed is that the way our variables are coded reflects stability of borders. 1970. of which examples are the split between Pakistan and Bangladesh. occurring again to Germany. because it concerns two countries which are in our sample.

The data are taken from United Nations (2005). The data are available over five year intervals from 1950. without distinguishing. taken from Easterly and Levine (1997). among the French. (1999) introduce a separate class for socialist-law countries. within the broader civil law tradition.population. while La Porta et al. taken from Penn World Tables (2002). Civil law: The source is the legal origin classification in La Porta et al. (1999). Catholic share: Percentage of Catholics in 1980. INSERT TABLE APPENDIX References 37 . Moreover. taken from La Porta et al. Government consumption: Government share of GDP in current prices. British or Portuguese colony: Dummy for countries that were British or Portuguese colonies any time after 1918. since they do not present any significant difference for the issue of citizenship. Oil: Dummy for oil countries (OPEC countries plus Oman. Socialist: Dummy for socialist countries. The classification is from UN (2002). with projections until 2050. Southern Europe and sub-Saharan Africa: Dummies for countries belonging to Latin America. Share of young: Share of young between age 15 and 34 (% population). we assign them to their own class of common or civil law as it prevailed before the communist period. The source is the United Nations (2005). We retain only the two main families of common and civil law. and Scandinavian versions. Gini index: Gini index of inequality. and Brunei). GDP per capita: Logarithm of real GDP per capita at current international prices. (1999). taken from Freedom House (1996). Political rights: Political rights index. (1999). Bahrain. Small country: Dummy for countries with a population size of less than one million over all available years between 1960 and 1995. Angola. Latin America. German. Qatar. taken from Penn World Tables (2002). Southern Europe and subSaharan Africa. as in Easterly and Kraay (2000). taken from Deininger and Squire (1996). Ethnolinguistic fractionalization: Composite index of ethnolinguistic fractionalization. The source is the Correlates of War 2 Project (2004). Information is from La Porta et al.

Citizenship Today: Global Perspectives and Practices. 38 Page 40 . 13809. Graziella. The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation. Why Did the West Extend the Franchise? Democracy. Washington: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Thomas A. Alberto. Benhabib. Mass. On the Number and Size of Nations. Acquisition and Loss of Nationality. American Economic Review 91:1369-1401. and James A. The Politics of Co-optation. Bertocchi. Simon Johnson. and Douglas B. Cambridge. and Andrei Shleifer. and Michael Spagat. Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes. Alesina. Daron. The Enfranchisement of Women and the Welfare State. Aleinikoff. Washington: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. On the Political Economy of Migration. From Migrants to Citizens: Membership in a Changing World. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115:1167-99. 1996. Jess. Thomas A. and Douglas B.. Inequality and Growth in Historical Perspective. Rainer. Centre for Economic Policy Research. Graziella. 2001. London. Eva Ersbøll. and Enrico Spolaore. Aron. 6396. Kees Groenendijk. Daron. The Divergence of Legal Procedures. Klusmeyer (edited by). and Harald Waldrauch (edited by). 2000. 2007. Working Paper no. Robinson.. 2006. Journal of Comparative Economics 29:591-607. Baubock. Bertocchi. National Bureau of Economic Research. 2008.Page 39 Acemoglu. European Economic Review 40:1737-1744. Acemoglu. 2001. 2001. Klusmeyer (edited by). Discussion Paper no. and James A. 2000. 1997. Rafael La Porta. Balas. Aleinikoff. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112:1027-1056. Robinson. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

Miller. 2009.Bertocchi. Small Problems? Income. The Pennsylvania State University. William. Brubaker. International Migration and the Role of Institutions. Citizenship and Nationhood in France and Germany. Klaus. 2006. Huffman. IZA. Immigration Policy: Methods of Economic Assessment. 1996. Citizenship in the United States: The Roles of Immigrant Characteristics and Country of Origin. Bolton. A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality. The Citizenship Laws Dataset. Deininger. DeVoretz. Africa's Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic . and Volatility in Small States. 2008. Small States. 1997. DeVoretz. World Development 28:2013-2027. and Lyn Squire. Barry R. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Jim. and Ross Levine. Discussion Paper no. Central Intelligence Agency. 2004. European Civic Citizenship and Inclusion Index. 2000. Bonn. 2006. Correlates of War 2 Project. Graziella. Growth. William.. Department of Political Science. International Economic Review 45:1129-1168. Patrick. The Economic Causes and Consequences of Canadian Citizenship. and Chiara Strozzi. 1992. Journal of Immigration and Integration 6:435-468. 2008. 2002. The World Bank Economic Review 10:565-91. 1997. http://www. and Gerard Roland. British Council Brussels.. Don J. Public Choice 137:81-102. 2004. 2005.asp. and Sergiy Pivnenko. The World Factbook 2002. 3596. On the Political Economy of Migration and Income Redistribution. The Breakup of Nations: A Political Economy Analysis. Graziella. and Chiara Strozzi. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112:1057-1090. Don J. 39 Page 41 Easterly. and Aart Kraay. Rogers. Brussels: British Council Brussels. and Gregory W. Washington: CIA Chiswick. Bertocchi. Dolmas. and Paul W. International Migration Review 40:390-418.unimore.

1998. Pp. Andrei Shleifer. 2004. Heidelberg: Springer. Rafael. 1996. Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). Stanley L. October. Penn World Table Version 6.1. 2006. and Paths of Development Among New World Economies. 2006. Law and Finance. 9259. Challenge to the Nation-State: Immigration in Western Europe and the United States. and Maurice Schiff. Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes. and Bettina Aten. and Robert W. New York: Simon & Schuster. Journal of Political Economy 106:1113-1155. International Migration in the Long Run: Positive Selection. 2002. Freedom in the World. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Freedom House. Christian (edited by). and Jeffrey G. Cambridge. Vishny. 2006. Robert Summers. 40 Page 42 Mayda. New York: Freedom House. Negative Selection and Policy. Rafael. Inequality. Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes. 1998.Divisions. and Robert W. and Kenneth L. Working Paper no. Sokoloff. Timothy J. Review of Economics and Statistics 88:510- . La Porta. 2002. Factor Endowment. edited by Federico Foders and Rolf J. The Quality of Government. Mark. Andrei Shleifer. Political Rights and Civil Liberties. Who is Against Immigration? A Cross-country Investigation of Individual Attitudes towards Immigration. Journal of Population Economics 19:32744. Joppke. Anna Maria. National Bureau of Economic Research. Hatton. Vishny. La Porta. Journal of Law. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112:1203-1250. Williamson. 1999. Gradstein. Who Are We: The Challenges to America's National Identity. Heston. Economics and Organization 15:222279. Huntington. Engerman. Alan... The Political Economy of Social Exclusion with Implications for Immigration Policy. Langhammer. Samuel P. 1-34 in Labor Mobility and the World Economy. Mass.

Citizenship Laws of the World.530.17-35 in Citizenship Today: Global Perspectives and Practices. University of Maryland. 41 Page 43 Weil. 2003. United Nations. World Population Prospects: Population Estimates and Projections. Thomas A. 2001. Razin. Klusmeyer. The Determinants of Individual Attitudes towards Immigration. Pritchett. Washington: The Brookings Institution Press. Richard. 2002. and Jeffrey G. edited by Aleinikoff. Williamson. and Richard Sinnott. NewYork: United Nations. 1998. Alan H. European Journal of Political Economy 22:838-861. and Douglas B. 1981. and Phillip Swagel. 1800-2002. New York: United Nations. 2006. Population and Development Review 24:739-771. Common Database. Pp. Assaf. Tax Burden and Migration: A Political Economy Theory and Evidence. Ashley S. High Commissioner for Refugees.. Journal of Political Economy 89:914-27. Investigations Service. Geneva: United Nations. Access to Citizenship: A Comparison of Twenty-Five Nationality Laws. New York: United Nations. Country of Origin and Legal Information. Polity IV. A Rational Theory of the Size of Government. and Scott F. United States Office of Personnel Management. 2001. 2003. Kevin H. Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions. 2006.. 2002. United Nations. 42 Page 44 Table 1 C . 2002. Efraim Sadka. 2005. Patrick. Let Their People Come: Breaking the Deadlock in International Labor Mobility. Immigration Policy Prior to the Thirties: Labor Markets. Timmer. Center for International Development and Conflict Management. Journal of Public Economics 85:167-190. United Nations. United Nations.. Policy Interaction. and Globalization Backlash. Trends in Total Migrant Stock: The 2003 Revision. Meltzer. Lant. O'Rourke. Washington: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

ITIZENSHIP L AWS E VOLUTION :T RANSITION M ATRICES Citizenship laws in 2001 Jus sanguinis regime Mixed regime Jus soli regime Total Citizenship laws in 1948: Jus sanguinis regime 46 20 1 67 Mixed regime 11 6 2 19 Jus soli regime 31 9 36 76 Total 88 35 39 162 Citizenship laws in 1975 Jus sanguinis regime Mixed regime Jus soli regime Total Citizenship laws in 1948: .

Jus sanguinis regime 63 3 1 67 Mixed regime 10 7 2 19 Jus soli regime 28 1 47 76 Total 101 11 50 162 Citizenship laws in 2001 Jus sanguinis regime Mixed regime Jus soli regime Total Citizenship laws in 1975: Jus sanguinis regime 81 20 0 101 Mixed regime 2 9 0 11 Jus soli regime 5 6 39 50 .

Total 88 35 39 162 Page 45 Table 2 C HANGES IN C ITIZENSHIP L AWS Changes in citizenship laws (1948 to 2001) No change Toward jus sanguinis Toward jus soli Total Citizenship laws in 1948: Jus sanguinis regime 46 0 21 67 Mixed regime 6 11 2 19 Jus soli regime 36 40 0 76 Total 88 51 23 162 Changes in citizenship laws (1948 to 1975) No change .

Toward jus sanguinis Toward jus soli Total Citizenship laws in 1948: Jus sanguinis regime 63 0 4 67 Mixed regime 7 10 2 19 Jus soli regime 47 29 0 76 Total 117 39 6 162 Changes in citizenship laws (1975 to 2001) No change Toward jus sanguinis Toward jus soli Total Citizenship laws in 1975: Jus sanguinis regime 81 0 20 101 Mixed regime 9 2 0 11 Jus soli regime 39 11 .

685 .0 50 Total 129 13 20 162 Page 46 Table 3 C ITIZENSHIP L AWS D ATA S ET :S UMMARY S TATISTICS Variable Observations Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum Citizenship laws in 2001 162 1.916 1 3 .835 1 3 Citizenship laws in 1975 162 1.698 .

173 .941 1 3 Changes in cit.043 .415 .920 1 4 Citizenship policy index in 2001 142 .451 -1 1 Changes in cit.655 -1 1 Naturalization in 2001 142 2.299 0 1 Page 47 Table 4 S UMMARY .056 . laws (1948 to 2001) 162 -.204 . laws (1975 to 2001) 162 -.458 .Citizenship laws in 1948 162 2. laws (1948 to 1975) 162 .488 -1 1 Changes in cit.

500 0 1 Civil legal origin 324 .691 .646 9.470 0 1 Migration stock 300 5.485 -1 1 Jus sanguinis as initial cit.673 Net migration flows 318 -.875 1 3 Changes in citizenship laws 324 -. law 324 .673 .011 70.713 .S TATISTICS Variable Observations Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum Current citizenship laws 324 1.519 .080 .116 .

160 .173 .551 -47.35 Decolonization 324 .434 0 1 Berlin wall 324 .052 .250 .146 0 1 Latin America 324 .223 0 1 Other border changes 324 .204 0 1 Small country 324 .379 0 1 Southern Europe 324 .95 63.368 0 1 Sub-Saharan Africa 324 .8.043 .022 .

535 35.3 Ethnolinguistic fractionalization 272 ..086 .173 .265 .333 .379 0 1 Oil 324 .349 .281 0 1 Political rights 276 3.472 0 1 Socialist 324 .040 1 7 Catholic share 324 31.442 0 1 British or Portuguese colony 324 .572 0 97.730 2.890 Government consumption .299 0 .

233 Share of young 324 34.36 Page 48 Log GDP per capita 263 7.488 1.263 19. The reference period is 19502000.54 3.249 4.495 63.342 2. Page 49 Table 5 P AIRWISE C ORRELATIONS A .617 11. The first cross section refers to the 1950-1975 subperiod while the second cross section refers to the 1976-2000 subperiod.01 53.492 72.966 20.425 9.180 N OTE .47 27.979 10. For details about the construction of the variables see the text.060 Gini index 155 40. The sample includes two cross sections of 162 countries.

04 Southern Europe -.12* Net migration flows -.12* -.15** .02 Latin America . law -.48** Civil legal origin -.42** Berlin wall -.05 .14* -.07 -.33** Decolonization -.08 .11 + -.60** .64** .10 + Small country .09 -.24** Other border changes -.MONG D EPENDENT AND I NDEPENDENT V ARIABLES Citizenship laws Changes in citizenship laws Migration stock -.06 Jus sanguinis as initial cit.12* .

06 Political rights .13* -.29** .19** British or Portuguese colony .20** Government consumption -.39** .26** Socialist -.06 Share of young -.20** Log GDP per capita . .10 + -.10 + Ethnolinguistic fractionalization -.22** -. The sample includes two cross sections of 162 countries.03 -.05 . The reference period is 1950-2000.25** .24** Page 50 N OTE .18** Catholic share .Sub-Saharan Africa -.03 .12* -.02 -.34** Gini index .14* Oil -.

05.055** . * p < .051 + -. For details about the construction of the variables see the text.The first cross section refers to the 1950-1975 subperiod while the second cross section refers to the 1976-2000 subperiod. Page 51 Table 6 T HE D ETERMINANTS OF C ITIZENSHIP L AWS :M ULTINOMIAL L OGIT E STIMATES Specification (a) Specification (b) Specification (c) Mixed regime Jus soli regime Mixed regime Jus soli regime Mixed regime Jus soli regime Migration stock -.10.01. ** p < . + p < .

87) (-3.79) (-1. law -2.211 (4.045 (-1.409* -.523 (-1.09) (-1.193** 1.53) Jus sang.27) Decolonization -1.90) (-5.887** 1.296 + -2.24) (-4.712** -6.272 2.86) (-2.044** -6.55) .61) (-2.211** -.167* -.41) (-.30) (-1.048** -2.81) (-1.02) (2.-.43) (-4.568** -7.032 -.117** -4.65) (.99) (-4.054 + -.39) (-5.28) (-.38) Period 1.59** (-4.385** . as init.47) (2.084 -1.28) (3. cit.

234 + 1.063** (1.87) Latin America -.187 (2.523 (-1.07) (2.799 2.415 -2.035 .75) Government consumption .70) (3.73) (-.81) (1.03) (-.621 4.153 1.084 + (1.93) Small country -.495** (-.68) .69) (-1. X migration stock .Southern Europe 1.51) (2.156 + .64) Jus san.88) (.224* -.69) (.23) (.14) (1.804 .566 + .866** -.

43) (1.73) (2.397* (-1.09) N 300 300 300 300 .46) (.277 (.426* (2.43) Page 52 Catholic share .Share of young -.05) (2. fractionalization .02) Political rights .03) (2.626* -.716 11.48) (-.023 1.193 + -.70) Ethno.84) (2.46) Constant -1.75) (-2.012 .165* (-2.092** .548** .024 1.01 (1.02) (1.353* 3.

29 .77 -155.71 .53 .68 McFadden's R 2 .64 N OTE . .81 .32 .68 .44 Cragg & Uhler's R 2 .79 Count R 2 .58 . The reference period is 1950-2000. Robust z statistics in brackets. Jus sanguinis is the reference category.32 .24 Maximum Likelihood R 2 .224 224 Log likelihood -195.46 .55 .45 .57 McFadden's Adjusted R 2 .83 Adjusted Count R 2 .94 -95. clustered at country level.4 .

875** -.49) (-2.025* -.34) Jus sanguinis as initial cit.001 (2. law .7) .+ P < .09) (-. Page 53 Table 7 T HE D ETERMINANTS OF C ITIZENSHIP L AWS :M ARGINAL E FFECTS (M ULTINOMIAL L OGIT .193* -.F ULL S PECIFICATION ) Jus sanguinis regime Mixed regime Jus soli regime Migration stock .023* -. ** P < .681** ( * P < .

92) Period -.291 .303 + .194** .59) (-3.123 .016 -.80) (.336** -.203** .77) Southern Europe -.027* .(-2.114 (.51) (1.86) (-.86) Jus sanguinis X migration stock -.170 .121 (-1.44) Decolonization .13) (-1.611** -.15) (-2.088 -.805** (-4.75) Small country .16) (.51) Latin America -.139 + (.034 (-1.56) (-7.95) (2.85) (5.03) (.

037 + (-3.004 .007* (-1.069** .018 -.043* (2.107** .29) (1.96) Political rights -.50) .15) Catholic share -.50) (.56) (-.01) Share of young .001 Page 54 (-1.002 .50) Ethno.124 -.006 (-2.010* .152 (-.021 .16) (.18) (-2.98) (. fractionalization -..061** -.028 .76) (2.001 .14) (.92) Government consumption -.36) (1.65) (-1.

05. + P < .10. clustered at country level.039 + .01.(2.90) N 224 224 224 N OTE . Page 55 Table 8 T HE D ETERMINANTS OF C HANGE IN C ITIZENSHIP L AWS :M ULTINOMINAL L OGIT E STIMATES Toward jus sanguinis Toward jus soli Migration stock . * P < . Robust z statistics in brackets. The reference period is 1950-2000.61) (1. ** P < . The above marginal effects refer to the multinomial logit estimates of our full specification (specification (c) in Table 6).

70) .82) Catholic share -.341 -.001 (.12) Share of young .44) Small country -.736 + (.50) (.95) (1.006 .493** (.94) (3.058 + (2.15) (2.652 1.032 (1.60) Government consumption -.006 (1.155** (1.-.2 + 2.82) (1.02 -.05 + .90) (.593 (.68) Southern Europe 2.73) Decolonization 2.898** 2.12) Period .65) (1.

(.58 Maximum Likelihood R 2 .23) (1.04) N 224 224 Log likelihood -107.508 (2.45 Count R 2 .104 .33 McFadden's R 2 .981* 2.16 .81 Adjusted Count R 2 .96) (2.771* Page 56 (.15 Cragg & Uhler's R 2 .84) (1.52) Political rights .3 McFadden's Adjusted R 2 .364 9.12) Ethnolinguistic fractionalization 1.08) Constant -4.234 (.

003 -.05.26) . ** P < . Robust z statistics in brackets.000 (2.01) (-1. Page 57 Table 9 T HE D ETERMINANTS OF C HANGE IN C ITIZENSHIP L AWS :M ARGINAL E FFECTS (M ULTINOMIAL L OGIT ) Toward jus sanguinis No change Toward jus soli Migration stock . + P < .003* -.01. clustered at country level.10. The reference period is 1950-2000. No change in citizenship laws is the reference category.N OTE . * P < .

004* .19) Period .16) Southern Europe .74) (-.415* .02) (1.003 .299 -.33) (1.102 .069 (2.022 .05) Decolonization .00) (-2.013 -.65) Government consumption -.016** (.10) (-2.42) (1.003 .116 (1.31) (2.28) Share of young .29) .53) (.374* -.(-.001 (-2.06) Small country -.058* (.044 -.442* .27) (1.038 -.015 (-.58) (-1.

Robust z statistics in brackets.74) Catholic share -.19) Ethnolinguistic fractionalization .01.077 + (2.007 -.60) (.(1.1 . * P < .10.75) (-1. The above marginal effects refer to the multinomial logit estimates in Table 8.007 (.10) (1.015 .89) Political rights .223* .000 . Page 59 Table Appendix Table A.000 . The reference period is 1950-2000.39) (1.000 (-. clustered at country level.18) (-2. + P < . ** P < .71) (.12) N 224 224 224 Page 58 N OTE .05.12) (-2.145* -.

052 (-2.12) (-1.62) Jus sanguinis as initial citizenship law -4.A LTERNATIVE C OVARIATES Specification (a) Specification (b) Mixed regime Jus soli regime Mixed regime Jus soli regime Migration stock -.152* -.056 -.36) Average migration stock -.533** -7.T HE D ETERMINANTS OF C ITIZENSHIP L AWS :M ULTINOMIAL L OGIT E STIMATES .81) (-.013 (-.344** .

33) (2.01) Southern Europe 1.22) (.21) (-1.54) (1.908 .046 5.09) (-4.525 1.68) (.003 (-.742 + (1.31) Decolonization -.64) (.76) (1.062 .260 1.941 -1.16) (-1.436** .88) Period 2.42) Latin America -.595 (1.12) Civil legal origin .397** .218 1.834** -.317** -.79) (-.667 4.140 -1.509 + -.(-5.649 (2.84) (-1.

67) (-1.65) (1.61) Civil legal origin X migration stock .140 + .90) (.402* .29) Jus san.(-.73) (-.043 .068** (1.503 + .110 (.59) Share of young -.128 (-1.019 -.063** .040 Page 60 (1.09) (2.23) (-1.560 -1.03) (3.036 .25) (2.64) Small country -2.894 + 1.89) (1. X average migration stock .197 + -.65) (.10) Government consumption .55) (2.

247* (-1.273* -3.950 + (-.527 (1.38) Ethnolinguistic fractionalization -.78) (2.029 1.11) .85) (1.017 (1.006 .-.46) (-1.012 .035 1.567 4.011 .03) (1.096 -.52) (.58) (1.56) Constant 3.290 1.74) Political rights .563* .52) (2.276 (2.436* .03) (.75) (.81) (1.98) Catholic share .16) (-1.539** .08) (2.78) (-2.831 11.

78 . Robust z statistics in brackets. ** P < . The reference period is 1950-2000.(-1.05. Jus sanguinis is the reference category.75 Adjusted Count R 2 .48 N OTE . + P < .74 -132.41 McFadden's Adjusted R 2 .10.68 .01 Maximum Likelihood R 2 .64 .83 .55 McFadden's R 2 .64 Count R 2 .28 Cragg & Uhler's R 2 . * P < . .04) (1. clustered at country level.57 .01.44 .01) N 224 224 224 224 Log likelihood -95.

Page 61 .

Sign up to vote on this title
UsefulNot useful