Published in December 2000, in the Journal of Economic History, (Vol. 60, No.4), the article “The First
Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792” was wrote by David J. Cowen,
director at Deutsche Bank and trader in foreign currency. In his paper Dr. Cowen tries to explain why the
security market crash of 1792 happened.
The view generally accepted is to incriminate the investor William Duer for the market crash. Using data
from the balance sheets of the First Bank of the United States (BUS), letters from different major players
and some contemporary press releases, Cowen demonstrates that the security market crash of 1792 was
not the fault of Duer but a miss-management of credit from the BUS and other major banks of this time.
In order to understand perfectly what happened, it’s important to reestablish the situation, the role of
each major player, as well as some basic economic principles.
Historians had considered for a long time that the security market crash of 1792 was William Duer fault.
In December 1791, W. Duer with other investors had borrowed an enormous amount of money in order
to speculate on the U.S. debt security and stock market. Although the amount of money Duer had
borrowed is unknown, it appears that contemporaries considered it has being "beyond all description-the
sums he owes upon notes is unknown the least supposition is half a Million dollars. Last night he went to
[jail] “3 (recall that at this time, $500,000 was an extraordinary large sum of money, The BUS collected
capitalization was just more than 6 times Duer’ debt).
1
Cowen, D. J. (2000). The First Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792. The Journal of Economic
History , 1041
2
Cowen, D. J. (2000). The First Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792. The Journal of Economic
History , 1042
3
Cowen, D. J. (2000). The First Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792. The Journal of Economic
History , 1043
1
Stéphan Laouadi American Economic History 4/15/2009
Because of the security market crash Duer was ruined, and in the impossibility to pay back his debts, he
ended his life in prison. Nevertheless, new evidence brought forward by Cowen tends to exonerate Duer
from responsibility for the crash.
As noted in Cowen’s paper, “Even at this time individuals were aware of the connection between bank
credit and securities prices4”. During a period of credit expansion, investors are more likely to take loans
and invest in security market, but if credits contract rapidly, investors, without cash in hands to pay back
their loans are obliged to sell their securities. As lots of securities are sold in the same time on the
market, prices fall (Supply and Demand), and if they fall sharply, it’s consider as a “security market
crash”. It’s exactly what happened in the first two quarters of 1792. Security prices had reached a peak in
the late January; start to fall slowly during February, dropped by more than 20% in March. During April
security prices bottomed before recovering slowly in May 1792.
Already in March 1792, Daniel McCormick who was a board member of the Bank of New-York (BONY),
blamed the First Bank of the United States for their credit policy. According to McCormick analysis of the
situation, the BUS had lent too many credits using bank notes during January 17925. Realizing their
errors, the BUS curtailed loans by calling them back and not renewing them6.
In order to assess McCormick’ theory, Cowen first analyzed if the BUS had really flooded the market with
too many bank notes (1st claim of the McCormick’ theory) and if the bank curtailed its loans too rapidly
and too sharply (2nd claim of the McCormick’ theory). In a second part, Cowen tried to understand why
the BUS has changed its credit policy so rapidly .Then in a last part, the author tried to establish if the
BUS was the only responsible, if it has acted in relation with other major banks and who was the one to
blame, if someone has to be blamed.
4
Cowen, D. J. (2000). The First Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792. The Journal of Economic
History , 1044
5
At this time, the lending process involved the creation of Bank notes.
6
At this time, bank loans were issued for 30 days.
2
Stéphan Laouadi American Economic History 4/15/2009
Already in January 1792, some contemporaries, other than McCormick reported to the First Bank of the
United States that the amount of notes outstanding was too important. In mid-January 1792, the Boston
Port Collector in a letter from Benjamin Lincoln, informed Alexander Hamilton of the current situation in
Boston. “There are such a flood of them [BUS notes] now here that they are bought up at a depreciated
value by the Gentlemen indebted to us for the payment of their bonds.8”
In late January, it is the director of the Boston branch of the BUS (Not yet opened but in process) who
wrote to the parent bank in Philadelphia, that due to the amount of BUS notes, some Bostonians don’t
accept them anymore.
The same situation was taking place in New-York; the cashier of the Bank of New-York reported to
Hamilton that the BONY was “engulfed” with approximately $100,000 of BUS notes and that, because
speculators were coming to exchange them for specie, the BONY decided to no longer accept BUS notes.
7
Cowen, D. J. (2000). The First Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792. The Journal of Economic
History , 1046
8
Cowen, D. J. (2000). The First Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792. The Journal of Economic
History , 1047
3
Stéphan Laouadi American Economic History 4/15/2009
As noted at this time by the broker John Pintard, the BUS loans were for “legitimate business” but were
also accommodating speculators. As explained by Cowen “It is therefore probable that some Bank
borrowers bought debt securities with their loans in order to pay for the debt portion of their
subscriptions to the stock of the Bank, thereby pushing securities market prices higher in January9”
Cowen analysis of the BUS balance sheets let us understand that loans were not paid back with bank
notes; in fact between February and March 1792, bank notes increased by $5,000. Cowen analysis states
that a small portion of the loans were reimbursed thru deposit account (Individual deposit account fall
from $811,863 in end January to $569,550 in early March). Nevertheless, money in deposit accounts was
not enough to cover the amount of loan called in or not renewed.
In order to pay back their loans, investors had no other choices to sell their securities. Because of the
large amount of stocks sold in the same time, security prices fall, leading to what is known as the security
Market Crash of 1792.
As Cowen shows on his paper, prices fall more rapidly in Philadelphia then spread out to other cities11.
Between January and February, the U.S. 3% bonds fall from by $4.16 in Philadelphia, $1.25 in New-York
and did not moved in Boston. In March nevertheless, this same bonds were trading for more or less the
same prices in all 3 cities.
By this analysis Cowen proved McCormick assumption that the important credit expansion followed by
the rapid credit contraction from the First Bank of the United States had led to the Security Market Crash
of 1792.
9
Cowen, D. J. (2000). The First Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792. The Journal of Economic
History , 1048
10
Cowen, D. J. (2000). The First Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792. The Journal of Economic
History , 1049
11
At this time, communication between Philadelphia, New-York and Boston was not instantaneous, but could have
taken 1 week.
4
Stéphan Laouadi American Economic History 4/15/2009
All these information create evidence that the credit contraction was not just happening in Philadelphia
but in the entire banking system. The only person who would have been in power to coordinate all banks
was Alexander Hamilton, the Treasury Secretary. Nevertheless, evidences exists that state that the BUS
did not contracted its loans gradually, as required by Hamilton, but sharply as we have seen before. Due
to its dominant position, the action took by the BUS had been followed by all the other banks creating a
shortage of money. Borrowers like Duer who have taken loans in order to buy stocks were not able to
contract other loans, and were asked to pay back their debt (recall that loans were running for 30 days).
The only solution was to sell their stocks leading to an excess in supply and creating the Security Market
Crash of 1792. Investors like Duer were ruined.
5
Stéphan Laouadi American Economic History 4/15/2009
The article ends with some comparisons of the security market crash of 1792 with some other important
market crashes.
The one from 1792 differs from 1819 and 1929 by the fact that in 1792 no recession neither depression
had followed the crash. But the market crash of 1792 was similar to the one of October 1987 because of
their rapid declined, and rapid recovery. In both cases, authorities reacted by injected liquidities in the
market.
The last sentence of Cowen’s article states that “History in 1987 was in some form, therefore, repeating
events from 195 years earlier at the beginning of our financial markets.12”
12
Cowen, D. J. (2000). The First Bank of the United States and the Securities Market Crash of 1792. The Journal of Economic
History , 1058
6