You are on page 1of 17

World Development Vol. 34, No. 7, pp.

1254–1270, 2006
Ó 2006 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.12.002

The Impact of Collective Action


on Economic Development: Empirical Evidence
from Kerala, India
PATRICIA JUSTINO *
University of Sussex, Falmer, Brighton, UK
Summary. — Public participation is generally assumed to be a necessary if not fundamental con-
dition for development. Most studies do not, however, question the kind and level of collective
action that would be desirable. This paper provides a novel empirical analysis of the impact of
collective action on economic development using data for South India. The paper models collective
action as endogenous to economic development and distinguishes between its static and dynamic
properties. The results show that while excessive activism may harm state income, collective action
in the context of responsible bargaining systems may contribute toward increased economic devel-
opment.
Ó 2006 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — collective action, economic development, time series, panel data, Kerala, India

1. INTRODUCTION level of participation is desirable, and very little


work exists that establishes empirically the
Collective action is typically understood as impact of public participation and collective ac-
a concerted effort by individuals or groups tion on economic development. 1 In particular,
to attain certain objectives (see Tarrow, 2003). there is an absence of empirical evidence on
This is the view adopted in public economics whether that impact is direct or whether it de-
(see Esping-Andersen, 1990; Olson, 1971), pends on specific transmission mechanisms,
work on the action of labor unions (see Free-
man & Medoff, 1984), interest group theories
(Buchanan & Tullock, 1962), research on com-
mon resource management (see Meinzen-Dick
* I wish to thank Rathin Roy, Chris Cramer, Barbara
& Di Gregorio, 2004), work on collective vio-
lence (e.g., McAdam, 1982; Tilly, 1993, 2003), Harriss-White, Ron Herring, Julie Litchfield, Subir
theories of democracy formation (e.g., Prze- Sinha, Manny Teitelbaum, Alan Winters, and three
worski, 1985) and recent research on public anonymous referees for their very useful comments and
action if there is development (Drèze & Sen, discussions, M.D. Asthana, Hiranya Mukhopadhyaya,
1991). In particular, the participation of the B. Narayanan, and G. Omkarnath for inestimable assi-
poor in the process of development is viewed stance during fieldwork in India and S.R. Meena, at the
by many as an essential element of successful National Crime Records Bureau, and V. Parameswa-
development strategies (Ahmad, Drèze, Hills, ram, at the Ministry of Labor, for their assistance and
& Sen, 1991; Drèze, Sen, & Hussain, 1995; permission to access various data records. I am also
World Bank, 2001). Participation in social grateful to Professor Chandan Mukherjee at the Centre
and political decisions provides individuals for Development Studies at Thiruvananthapuram,
with a sense of value and identity and is an Kerala, for his hospitality during the initial stages of
important means to voice the needs of vulnera- this project. This paper has received financial support
ble population groups. However, the develop- from the British Academy (PDF/2002/288). Final revi-
ment literature rarely asks what type or what sion accepted: December 8, 2005.
1254
THE IMPACT OF COLLECTIVE ACTION ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1255

what the static and dynamic properties of those poor as a form of pursuing electoral advantages
mechanisms are and whether collective actions (see Esping-Andersen, 1990). These effects may
act as an external shock to the economy or change with time. Initial negative effects may,
are endogenous to the process of economic in the long term, lead to increases in aggre-
development. This paper addresses these gate national income if collective actions result
gaps in the literature using empirical evidence in considerable economic gains for a signifi-
from South India. The paper compares and cant number of disadvantaged individuals
contrasts two concrete forms of collective (Esping-Andersen, 1990; Gurr, 1970; Tilly,
action (industrial strikes and politically moti- 1993). Similarly, immediate positive effects can
vated riots) used as forms of public activism be offset in the long term if forms of collective
to exert political pressure. The paper revisits action cause excessive turmoil and persistent
the ‘‘development model’’ of the south Indian high levels of socio-economic instability
state of Kerala and asks whether and how col- (see Freeman & Medoff, 1984). We found
lective actions affect the development of poor evidence for divergence between static and dy-
economies. namic effects of collective action in Kerala
The choice of Kerala as a case study was and India.
motivated by the unique characteristics of its The paper is organized as follows. Section 2
development strategy, where thanks to the briefly reviews the main characteristics of Ker-
actions of organized public demands, high lev- ala’s development process over the last three
els of social development coexist with very low decades. Section 3 discusses the role and evol-
incomes. This paper builds on the large litera- ution of organized collective movements in
ture on Kerala’s ‘‘development model’’ (Franke Kerala and their impact on state income since
& Chasin, 1992; Gulati, 1990; Heller, 2000; the early 1970s. In Section 4, we analyze
Kannan, 1995; Oommen, 1993; Pillai, 1994; empirically the relationship between collective
Ramachandran, 1997). In addition, the paper action and Kerala’s economic development,
contributes to the literature on the impact of using time-series analysis techniques. This
collective action and participation on develop- empirical analysis is based on state-level data
ment (e.g., Ahmad et al., 1991; Meinzen-Dick on various types of organized collective actions
& Di Gregorio, 2004; World Bank, 2001), by discussed in Section 2. Collective action is
providing a rigorous empirical analysis of modeled as endogenous to the process of eco-
important endogenous, dynamic characteristics nomic growth in Kerala and the endogeneity
of collective action. assumption is explicitly tested. In Section 5,
Public participation and collective action are the results for Kerala are compared with those
likely to be influenced by the process of eco- for a panel of 14 major Indian states. The re-
nomic development of each given society. At sults of this comparative analysis provide
the same time, forms of collective action will af- important insights into the relationship be-
fect the way governments respond to popula- tween collective action and economic develop-
tion demands which, in turn, will impact on ment in poor economies. They suggest that
the type of development policies implemented in the presence of well functioning and
(see Esping-Andersen, 1990; Olson, 1971; responsible bargaining systems, some forms
Przeworski, 1985; Tarrow, 2003; Tilly, 2003). of collective action may have an important
We have empirically tested this endogeneity endogenous role to play in the reduction of
assumption for Kerala and India with positive poverty and the promotion of economic
results. We also distinguish between static growth. Section 6 summarizes the evidence
and dynamic impacts of collective action. and concludes the paper.
Depending on their intensity, some forms of
collective action may have immediate negative
or positive effects on the economy. Immediate 2. KERALA’S ‘‘MODEL OF
negative effects include, for instance, the DEVELOPMENT’’
destruction of private or public property,
increases in economic uncertainty and in the The state of Kerala, in South India, has occu-
risk of private investment (Alesina & Perotti, pied an eminent position in the development
1996). Immediate positive effects can take place debate since the early 1970s due to its singular
when governments respond to population de- development strategy. Unlike most developing
mands by conceding social subsidies to the economies, Kerala’s policy makers followed a
1256 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 1. Quality of life indicators, poverty and state income in Kerala


Kerala India Low-income countries United States
Birth rate (per 1,000) (1995) 18.0 28.3 39.8 22.8a
Death rate (per 1,000) (1995) 6.0 9.0 9.0 5.9a
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000) (1996) 13.0 72.0 69.0b 6.0b
Life expectancy (1989–93) 72.0 59.4 63.0b 77.0c
Literacy rate (%) (1991)
Male 93.6 64.1 46.0 >95.0
Female 86.2 39.3 35.0 >95.0
Poverty rate (%) (1973–74)
Rural 59.2 55.7 – –
Urban 62.7 48.0 – –
Poverty rate (%) (1999–2000)d
Rural 9.4 26.8 – –
Urban 20.3 24.1 – –
State domestic producte
1970 1,325 1,387f – –
1980 1,508 1,579f – –
1990 1,815 2,112f – –
1999 2,591 2,876f – –
Source: Government of India (1998), Government of Kerala (1996), World Bank (1997, 2001), United Nations
(1997); Government of India, National Accounts Statistics. Poverty rates (headcount indices) from NSSO (various
years).
a
Refers to 1994.
b
Refers to 1997.
c
Refers to 1999.
d
The 1999–2000 poverty estimates refer to the 30-day recall period.
e
Refers to per capita state domestic product at factor cost at 1980–81 constant prices in rupees.
f
Refers to average for 14 major Indian states: Andhra Pradesh, Assam, Bihar Gujarat, Karnataka, Kerala, Madhya
Pradesh, Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh, and West Bengal.

successful ‘‘basic-needs-first’’ strategy that pri- cated population) in the state since the mid-
oritized the improvement of socio-economic 1970s. 2 Economic difficulties have, in turn,
standards of its population (Table 1) and started to have significant negative effects on
implemented extensive land reforms (Herring, the implementation of further social redistribu-
1983). This has resulted in remarkable improve- tive policies (George, 1993).
ments in living standards and sharp decreases Kerala’s disappointing economic perfor-
in poverty in Kerala (Table 1), both in the orga- mance has been largely attributed to the
nized and unorganized sectors (Gulati, 1990; strength of militant movements (George,
Heller, 2000). This development strategy has 1998; Kannan, 1990; Oommen, 1993; Prakash,
been largely accredited to the actions of effec- 1994; Tharamangalam, 1998). At the same time
tive collective movements, both in the orga- that organized forms of collective action have
nized and unorganized sectors, which have resulted in extraordinary social developments,
resulted in a very successful interaction between they have also led to demands for unsustainable
public demand and a pro-active state (Heller, increases in social protection expenditure and
2000; Prakash, 1994). higher wages, 3 and to increased risk of disrup-
Despite these successes, state income in Ker- tion, which have discouraged private invest-
ala is low even in relation to the Indian average ment and have led companies to establish
(Table 1). Low economic growth has been themselves in other Indian states with more sta-
accompanied by weak performances in all the ble labor markets (Nair, 1994; Sankaranaraya-
economic sectors (especially, the agriculture nan & Bhai, 1994). These accounts highlight
and manufacturing sectors), and has been interesting questions concerning the relation-
aggravated by a fiscal crisis and increases in ship between collective action and economic
unemployment (particularly, amongst the edu- development in Kerala.
THE IMPACT OF COLLECTIVE ACTION ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1257

3. COLLECTIVE ACTION AND measures that empowered the lower classes,


DEVELOPMENT IN KERALA including the promotion of significant social
protection measures in the unorganized sector
Forms of collective action often take place in (Gulati, 1990; Heller, 1996). However, after
Kerala via the state’s democratic electoral pro- the split of the Communist Party in 1964, trade
cess (see Heller, 1995). Since the formation of unionism tactics started to rely on intimidating
the state in 1956, the political scene in Kerala actions, go-slow practices, short-duration wild-
has been dominated by two main parties: the cat strikes and unofficial strikes, rather than
Indian National Congress (INC) and the Com- concern with longer term issues such as unem-
munist Party of India (CPI). In 1964, the latter ployment, declining industries or increase in
party split into two parties: CPI and CPI- wage inequalities (Nair, 1994). This was fuelled
Marxist. Left-wing governments dominated by a rapid process of unionization and an in-
Kerala’s politics in the late 1960s and late crease in the number of trade unions, as well
1970s, while the Congress party dominated as the emergence of caste and category-craft
the period during 1970–77. After 1977, no sin- based unions and sectorial pressure groups,
gle party controlled the state’s political arena. which led to unhealthy forms of competition
Since then Kerala’s population has voted alter- between unions, inter-union rivalry and the
natively for left- and right-wing parties every consequent division of the trade union move-
5 years (Electoral Commission of India). This ment in Kerala (Heller, 1995; Nair, 1994). As
process has maintained alive both left- and a result, the number of trade unions in Kerala
right-wing governments’ commitment to the is rather large in comparison to the rest of India
state’s model of development. (Table 2).
This historical electoral process has simulta- Labor market instability in Kerala decreased
neously led to and resulted from structured col- in the late 1970s and throughout the 1980s,
lective movements, both in the organized and thanks to ‘‘politics of class compromise’’
unorganized sectors, in the form of militant (Heller, 1996). 4 This progression is illustrated
peasant associations and labor unions (Heller, in Figure 1. This figure provides a comparison
1995, 1996, 2000; Herring, 1983; Nair, 1994). of the number of strikes and lockouts per
The role of labor unions in Kerala illustrates 1,000 factory workers for every year during
familiar questions about the economic effi- 1973–99 in Kerala and India. Strikes and lock-
ciency of organized labor movements (Freeman outs are defined as work stoppages that involve
& Medoff, 1984). Labor unions have consti- 10 or more workers (in the formal sector),
tuted, in most economies, an important pres- whether directly and/or indirectly, and exclude
sure group in the establishment of labor closures not related with industrial disputes (In-
standards. They have also been used as an dian Labour Statistics, 1994, p. 199). The data
important means for workers to voice their include the number of both strikes nd lock-
demands and needs. However, it has not outs. 5 Figure 1 shows a pronounced decrease
been clearly established whether labor unions in the number of strikes and lockouts per
encourage increases in productivity, promote 1,000 factory workers in Kerala since the early
democracy in the work place and protect the 1990s. Nonetheless, in 1999, Kerala still regis-
interests of the more vulnerable population tered some of the highest numbers of strikes
groups, or whether unions act as rent-seeking and lockouts per 1,000 factory workers in India
institutions that protect their own interests. (see also Table 2). 6
Kerala’s experience with labor movements Although data on strikes provide a good
throughout the last three decades illustrates illustration of the degree of industrial action
both views. in Kerala, the data are likely to underestimate
Until the mid-1960s industrial relations were the true extent of collective action in other sec-
relatively better in Kerala than in most other tors of society. Another way of assessing the ex-
states, thanks to the democratic relations and tent of collective action in Kerala is to examine
industrial culture trade unionism (especially in the extent of politically motivated riots in the
the unorganized sector) which helped to insti- state. The Indian Penal Code defines riots as
tute. At that time, the role of peasant associa- collective acts of violence by an assembly of five
tions and labor unions was central to the or more people directed against government
design and implementation of land reforms, institutions, law and order, other people, and
minimum wage legislation, institutionalized property. 7 This is the definition underlying
bargaining procedures and general welfare the data used in this paper. 8
1258 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 2. Collective action in selected Indian states, 1973 and 1999a


Workers’ unionsb Strikes and Riotsd
lockoutsc
1973 1999 1973 1999 1973 1999
Andhra Pradesh 5.17 27.7 0.46 0.13 0.07 0.04
Assam 3.44 6.94 0.21 0.15 0.23 0.14
Bihar 3.65 3.75 1.16 0.04 0.20 0.11
Gujarat 1.49 2.54 0.34 0.13 0.02 0.04
Karnataka 2.79 3.79 0.34 0.04 0.09 0.15
Kerala 15.0 22.2 1.00 0.14 0.26 0.21
Madhya Pradesh 3.33 0.38 0.61 0.02 0.06 0.04
Maharashtra 3.03 4.48 0.76 0.01 0.04 0.06
Orissa 4.56 2.07 0.56 0.11 0.08 0.04
Punjab 4.95 1.56 0.43 0.04 0.00 0.00
Rajasthan 8.39 7.81 0.51 0.07 0.20 0.31
Tamil Nadu 4.79 4.79 0.71 0.15 0.13 0.09
Uttar Pradesh 4.43 3.49 0.55 0.05 0.15 0.04
West Bengal 7.58 9.90 0.48 0.21 0.21 0.06
Source: Data on strikes and lockouts and workers’ unions from Government of India, Ministry of Labour, Annual
Report (various years), Government of India, Ministry of Labour, Indian Labour Yearbook (various years),
Government of India, Ministry of Labour, Indian Labour Statistics (various years). Data on riots from the Gov-
ernment of India, National Crime Records Bureau, Crime in India (various issues).
a
This table includes descriptive statistics for 1973 and 1999 for illustrative purpose only. The analysis in the paper is
based on a time-series data for every year during 1973–99.
b
Workers unions = no. of workers’ unions per 1,000 factory workers.
c
Strikes and lockouts = volume of strikes and lockouts per 1,000 factory workers.
d
Riots = volume of riots per 1,000 people.

1.2
Kerala
India
1
Strikes per 1000 workers

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0
73

75

77

79

81

83

85

87

89

91

93

95

97

99
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

Figure 1. Number of strikes and lockouts per 1,000 factory workers in India and Kerala, 1973–99. Source: Government
of India, Ministry of Labour, Annual report (various years), Government of India, Ministry of Labour, Indian labour
yearbook (various years), and Government of India, Ministry of Labour, Indian labour statistics (various years).
THE IMPACT OF COLLECTIVE ACTION ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1259

Not all riots need necessarily be politically be a good representative variable of levels of
motivated. However, riots in India (and Kera- collective action.
la) have often been characterized by more or Kerala has some of the highest number of
less violent public manifestations driven by eco- riots per 1,000 people in India (Table 2). This
nomic and social discontent, as well as specific is partly due to the fact that riots are likely to
political agendas by competing political parties be more accurately registered in Kerala than
(Brass, 1997, 2003; Das, 2003; Heller, 1995, in other states, given the state’s higher levels
2000; Joseph, 1999; Prabhash, 2000; Wilkinson, of socio-political development, media interven-
2004). 9 In some of the most influential studies tion and government accountability. However,
of rioting in India, Paul Brass (1997, 2003) has it is also noticeable that the number of riots
shown how the dynamic process of riot produc- per 1,000 people in Kerala has been more or
tion in India resembles well-established theories less constant since 1973 around a mean value
of collective action by Olson (1971), Tarrow of 0.21 (with a small standard deviation of
(2003), Tilly (1993, 2003), and McAdam 0.03). Values after 1988 have been consistently
(1982), in that ‘‘riots have become a common higher than the values during the 1970s and
and even anticipated form of collective action’’ the earlier part of the 1980s (Figure 2). This
(Brass, 2003, p. 12), and the means to pursue suggests that although workers’ unions and
political advantage (see alsoEngineer, 1984, the government have reached important com-
2004). This is very much the case in Kerala promises, forms of organized collective action
(e.g., Heller, 1995; Prabhash, 2000). In recent are still pronounced and are likely to both re-
years, the media has reported increased levels of flect and impact on Kerala’s social and eco-
religion- and caste-based rioting. 10 Although nomic performance.
the data provided by the NCRB do not allow
the disaggregation of riots according to differ-
ent motivations, these are likely to constitute 4. ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS
a small percentage of total rioting in Kerala,
where levels are lower than in other Indian Kerala is typically portrayed as an example
states (see Varshney, 2002, Chapter 4). In the of how poor economies can address impor-
specific context of Kerala (and India), riots as tant individual basic needs without requiring
reported in the NCRB data are thus likely to large budgets. However, as discussed above,

0.3

0.25
Riots per 1000 people

0.2

0.15

0.1

0.05
Kerala
India
0
73

75

77

79

81

83

85

87

89

91

93

95

97

99
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

Figure 2. Number of riots per 1,000 people in India and Kerala, 1973–99. Source: Government of India, National Crime
Records Bureau, Crime in India (various issues).
1260
Table 3. Marginal effects for Keralaa
Dep var: NSDPb Dep var: Dep var: Dep var: Dep var: Dep var: Dep var: Dep var: Hud
[3SLS] (1) NSDPb (2) NSDPb NSDPb (4) NSDPb NSDPb (6) Hrc [3SLS] (7) [3SLS] (8)
[3SLS] (3) [3SLS] (5)
State income 0.644 0.062
Lagged state income 0.019 0.028 0.027 0.025 0.006 0.046** 0.435 0.571
Volume of riots 0.311*** 0.018 0.279*** 0.015 0.165*** 0.016 2.144** 1.082
Lagged volume riots 0.009 0.016 0.014 0.025** 0.946 0.241
Volume of strikes 0.026 0.001 0.030 0.002 0.010 0.006 0.563* 0.219
Lagged volume of strikes 0.009 0.003 0.012** 0.006 0.313** 0.206
Expenditure on 0.067*** 0.022* 0.074*** 0.023* 0.060*** 0.027*** 0.906** 0.262

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
social services
Number of 0.001*** 0.001*** 0.008 0.003
workers’ unions
Change of government 0.001 0.002** 0.064 0.001
*** *** *** ***
Trade openness 0.035 0.026 0.035 0.027 0.042*** 0.032*** 0.142 0.391
Education enrolments 0.021 0.0002 0.020 0.004 0.033* 0.031*** 0.310 0.52
Rural poverty
Urban poverty
Trend variable (year) 0.0002 0.0002 0.0004 0.0002 0.005 0.0003 0.042 0.020*

R-squared 0.929e 0.993 0.949e 0.993 0.973e 0.998 0.949e 0.962e


No. of observations 24 24 24 24 24 24 24 24
a
Refers to the percentage impact of a unit change in independent variable on state income.
b
NSDP = logarithmic function of real per capita net state domestic product at 1980–81 constant prices.
c
Hr = percentage of the population below the poverty line in rural areas.
d
Hu = percentage of the population below the poverty line in urban areas.
e
This is not the ‘‘true’’ R-squared. The R-squared reported in 3SLS models is determined using the actual values of the structural model for LNSDP and not the
instruments of the endogenous variables in the right-hand side of the equation.
*
Significant at the 10%.
**
Significant at the 5%.
***
Significant at the 1%.
THE IMPACT OF COLLECTIVE ACTION ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1261

although this strategy was quite successful in ness of the Indian economy, given by the
the early stages of Kerala’s development, it is all-India ratio of imports and exports over na-
not clear whether it has proved to be a sustain- tional domestic product (per capita at 1980–
able strategy in the long term. In this section, 81 constant prices), to control for the increase
we examine some of the reasons behind this in trade liberalization and national economic
outcome from a collective action perspective. changes that took place in India after the
In particular, we model empirically the rela- mid-1980s. 15 We expect this variable to cap-
tionship between forms of collective action ture the effects of economic changes not related
and economic development in Kerala using a to collective action or redistributive decisions.
time-series model that covers for every year In order to control for the impact of human
the period during 1973–99. 11 We explicitly capital and productivity on economic growth
model collective action as endogenous to Kera- (Barro, 1991), we have added a measure for
la’s economic development, represented by the the level of education in Kerala, given by the
level of state income in each year. The model al- per capita number of individuals enroled in
lows us to also distinguish between short- and primary and secondary education.
long-term effects of collective action on state in- The results for the model are presented in
come. This dynamic process is described by Table 3, columns (1), (3), and (5). For compar-
ison reasons, the specification in column (1) ex-
Y t ¼ a þ uY t1 þ bX t1 þ cZ t þ dW t þ t þ et ; cludes lagged values of collective action. These
ð1Þ have been added to the model in column (3).
Column (5) illustrates yet another specification
where the dependent variable, Yt, represents the of the model. In this specification, we have
logarithmic function of per capita net state added two further collective action variables
domestic product at 1980–81 constant prices. discussed in the previous section. These include
We have allowed current levels of state income the number of trade unions (per 1,000 factory
to depend on past levels of state income. This is workers) in period t. We have also incorporated
a standard assumption in the economic growth into the model a political variable, which takes
literature (Barro, 1991). a is a constant, et is the the value 1 if in that year there has been a gov-
error term, and t is the trend variable. This var- ernment change and 0 if not. 16 This controls
iable is used to correct for the presence of deter- for the influence of individual political parties
ministic trends in the time-series variables. 12 on economic development and collective ac-
Xt1 is a vector of endogenous lagged regres- tion. Columns (2), (4), and (6) include estimates
sors illustrating the dynamic impact of collec- for the same three model specifications where
tive action on the level of state domestic all independent variables are treated as exo-
product. Collective action is represented by genous. We present these results for compara-
the number of riots per 1,000 people and the tive reasons. 17
number of strikes and lockouts per 1,000 fac- We have used a three-stage least-squares mod-
tory workers. 13 We have decided to use the el (3SLS) to estimate model (1). This method
volume of collective action per unit of popula- uses instrumental variables to construct consis-
tion rather than the absolute number of strikes tent estimates that allow for the correlation of
and riots in order to enable, in the next section, the explanatory variables with the disturbance
comparison between Kerala and other Indian term caused by the presence of endogeneity in
states, with very different population sizes. some independent variables. In stage 1, we pre-
Zt is a vector of endogenous independent dicted values for the instrumented variables
variables at time t. It includes the current num- from the regression of each of the endogenous
ber of riots and strikes and lockouts per unit of variables on all exogenous variables in the sys-
population, and a proxy for the redistributive tem, plus three other variables in order to guar-
social development program in place in Kerala. antee the system of equations to be identified.
This is given by the level of public expenditure These were rural and urban poverty, 18 and real
on social services (logarithmic function of per per capita development expenditure (at constant
capita expenditure on social services at 1980– 1980–81 prices). 19 These variables provide
81 constant prices). 14 This variable is treated good instruments for both collective action and
as endogenous given the discussion of Kerala’s redistribution in Kerala as, given the discussion
redistributive model in Section 2. in the previous sections, the three endogenous
Wt is a vector of exogenous independent vari- variables are likely to be closely associated with
ables at time t. It includes a measure for open- the level of poverty in the state, as well as to
1262 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

aggregate development expenditure. Stage 2 is that union fragmentation may have resulted
consisted in the estimation of the covariance in loss of cohesion and instability in labor rela-
matrix of the disturbances, based on the residu- tions, which are, in turn, likely to harm labor
als of the two least-squares estimation of the productivity (Nair, 1994; Sankaranarayanan
structural equation (1). In stage 3, we used gen- & Bhai, 1994; Tharamangalam, 1998). The
eralized least-squares estimation procedures coefficient for the change of government vari-
using the covariance matrix estimated in stage able is positive but statistically insignificant
2 and replacing the endogenous variables in across all models.
model (1) by the instrumental variables esti- Additional control variables have also af-
mated in stage 1 (Greene, 2000). The results fected Kerala’s economic performance in the
listed in Table 3 are marginal effects. They illus- last three decades. As expected, Kerala has
trate the percentage change in state income that benefited from the process of economic liberali-
results from a unit change in the levels of each zation that has taken place across India. Edu-
independent variable. cation also has a positive and statistically
significant impact on state income in column
(a) Results (5). The coefficient is negative and statistically
insignificant in columns (1) and (3), possibly if
The results of the 3SLS estimation (column due to omission biases in the model. More sig-
(1), Table 3) show that the volume of riots nificant is the impact of public expenditure on
has a negative and statistically significant im- social services on Kerala’s state income. This
pact on the state’s level of income. This result coefficient is positive and statistically significant
is consistent across all model specifications (col- across all model specifications. Depending on
umns (3) and (5)). The marginal effect of riots the control variables included into model (1),
on state income decreases as additional inde- expenditure on social services has contributed
pendent variables are included in the model. to between 6% and 7.4% increases in Kerala’s
The impact is, however, still large in column state income during 1975–99. This result dis-
(5): a one unit increase in the level of riots in proves the presence of a trade-off between
Kerala decreases state income by 16.5%. The redistribution and economic growth in
impact of lagged values of riots on Kerala’s Kerala. 20
state income is positive in column (3) but nega-
tive in column (5). The coefficient is always sta- (b) The endogeneity assumption
tistically insignificant.
The impact of strikes and lockouts in column We have explicitly tested the endogeneity
(1) is positive but not statistically significant. assumption. Granger causality tests showed
This is also true in column (3). The coefficient strong signs of double causality between (i)
becomes negative in column (5), suggesting that state income levels and real per capita expendi-
the previous positive coefficient was determined ture on social services, (ii) state income levels
by omission variable biases in the other two and the volume of riots, and (iii) state income
model specifications. The coefficient is, how- levels and the volume of strikes in Kerala, at
ever, never statistically significant. Kerala’s less than the 1% level of significance. This clear
level of state income is, however, positively indication of endogeneity implies that the right-
associated with increases in the lagged levels hand side regressors will be correlated with the
of strikes and lockouts. This coefficient is statis- disturbance term, causing standard OLS esti-
tically significant in column (5) and shows that mates of model (1) to be inconsistent. The com-
one more strike per 1,000 people in any given parison between the results of the 3SLS and the
period is associated with 1.2% increase in state OLS estimators shows the magnitude of the
income in the next period. estimation error we would incur if the endoge-
In addition, Kerala’s state product has been neity nature of collective action is not taken
negatively affected by the number of workers’ into consideration. Notably, the OLS coeffi-
unions in the state. The impact is quite small cients underestimate the extent of the impact
in comparison with other measures of collective of current levels of rioting on state income (col-
action. This result suggests that the fragmen- umns (5) and (6)). The OLS coefficients also
tation of Kerala’s labor organizations into underestimate the effect of strikes and lockouts
several competing unions has had significant on state income, as well as the effect of public
negative consequences on the state’s economic expenditure on social services, trade openness
performance (see Nair, 1994). One hypothesis and, to a lesser degree, education enrolments.
THE IMPACT OF COLLECTIVE ACTION ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1263

(c) Interpretation of the results The results may reflect some measurement
error. As discussed previously, data on strikes
The above results illustrate the complexity of and lockouts are likely to underestimate the ex-
the relationship between collective action and tent of strikes and lockouts in Kerala. This
economic development. On the one hand, col- should not, however, invalidate the above re-
lective action in the form of riots has negatively sults given their strong statistical significance
affected Kerala’s economic performance, pos- and the size of the coefficients. These coeffi-
sibly due to the uncertainty such actions will cients will, at the very least, represent a mini-
cause on the establishment of private property mum impact of strikes and lockouts on
rights and the socio-political stability of the Kerala’s state income. More accurate data on
state. The effect has been enhanced by the pro- strikes and lockouts are likely to increase their
cess of union fragmentation in Kerala’s labor positive impact. On the other hand, estimates
relations. On the other hand, increases in of riots in Kerala (and elsewhere in India) are
strikes have been associated with increases in registered by the police and do not depend on
the level of state income. accurate self-reporting. This allows reasonable
This differentiation in the impact of different confidence in the accuracy of the data. Given
forms of collective actions on state income has the nature of rioting in Kerala (and India),
two potential explanations. The first is the these data may, however, be influenced by
motivation behind each type of action. The re- political pressure. We have tested carefully the
sults in columns (1), (3), and (5) show that in- data against this hypothesis by examining the
creases in public expenditure on social services correlation between riot incidence and the like-
have contributed positively toward Kerala’s lihood of one of the two main political parties
economic performance. This result is in line winning state elections. This coefficient had a
with recent analyses of the impact of redistribu- very small estimate of 0.0174, which was statis-
tion on economic growth, which have shown tically insignificant at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels
that pro-poor redistributive policies may stimu- of significance. We have estimated similar tests
late economic growth due to their positive for every single one of the major 14 Indian
externalities on the size of internal markets, la- states, with similar results. Coefficients were
bor productivity, and accumulation of human higher in other states than in Kerala but none
capital (Justino, 2003; Murphy, Shleifer, & were statistically significant at levels well above
Vishny, 1989; Perotti, 1993). If the implementa- 10%. These tests allow us to conclude with rea-
tion of these policies is a direct result of work- sonable levels of confidence that Kerala’s eco-
ers’ political activism (see Esping-Andersen, nomic development has indeed been hampered
1990; Freeman & Medoff, 1984; Gurr, 1970), by public actions in the form of riots. Labor
then we would indeed expect the coefficient market actions have in contrast contributed
for the relevant collective action variable (i.e., positively toward the promotion of economic
strikes) to be positive. development in the state.
The second reason is the level of economic In order to further test the robustness of the
and social instability caused by certain types results discussed above, we have examined the
of collective actions. In particular, high levels impact of the forms of collective action on pov-
of instability may affect negatively investment erty, as the poor would generally be those who
decisions and ultimately economic growth benefit the most from larger redistributive pol-
(Alesina & Perotti, 1996). Strikes and lockouts icies, better wages and similar demands that
are likely to affect labor relations and invest- motivate workers to strike and populations to
ment climate and have, for that reason, been riot (Barron et al., 2004; Brass, 2003). We have
pointed out as one of the reasons behind Ker- examined more closely the direct impact of
ala’s recent poor economic performance (e.g., riots and strikes on rural and urban poverty
Kannan, 1990). Our results do not, however, in Kerala (columns (7) and (8), respectively).
confirm this hypothesis. If anything, Kerala’s The results show that increases in the current
poor economic record are likely to be associ- level of riots have had positive and statistically
ated with the level of rioting in the state as significant effects on rural poverty in Kerala.
riots are often responsible for the destruction The lagged coefficient is also positive but not
of livelihoods and markets, loss of trust and statistically significant. On the other hand,
social cohesion and the waste of significant increases in strikes are associated with long-
human and economic resources (see Brass, term decreases in rural poverty. The current
2003). and lagged coefficients are both negative and
1264 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

statistically significant. These results strongly straint to socio-economic development. Our


suggest that, even if some riots are motivated results point strongly toward further research
by the demand for better living conditions, they in this area.
may at the same time destroy important sources
of income, depending on the level of violence of
each period of unrest. In contrast, increases in 5. PANEL ANALYSIS
strikes are correlated with decreases in rural
poverty. This suggests that strikes have contrib- How unique is the relationship between orga-
uted positively toward the increase in the living nized forms of collective action and state in-
standards of some population groups, which come that takes place in Kerala? This section
would in turn explain the positive coefficient analyzes that relationship in the context of the
of this collective action variable in column (5). whole of India for the period during 1973–99,
The fact that only lagged values of strikes affect using a panel of 14 major Indian states (Andhra
state income is intuitively plausible as it would Pradesh, Assam, Bihar Gujarat, Karnataka,
take some time for pro-poor policies to impact Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa, Punjab,
on the rest of the economy. Our results do not Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh, and
allow us to infer about the urban sector as the West Bengal). 23 The main objective of this sec-
coefficients in column (8) are statistically insig- tion is to examine the differences between Ker-
nificant. This could be a result of the size of the ala’s development strategy and that of other
rural sector in Kerala. 21 Indian states, and investigate whether the role
These results have important implications for of collective action is specific to Kerala’s model
the explanation of Kerala’s recent poor eco- of development or whether broader lessons can
nomic performance. Our results do not support be derived. The model used in the previous sec-
the widely proposed hypothesis that excessive tion can be modified easily to encompass the
activism in the labor market has been responsi- panel dimension of the Indian data. The result-
ble for Kerala’s poor economic performance. ing model is
Labor disputes have been positively associated
with levels of state income, most likely because Y it ¼ ai þ uY i;t1 þ bX i;t1 þ cZ it
they have resulted in improvements in the living þ dW it þ N t þ eit ; ð2Þ
standards and incomes of the poor. Our results
indicate therefore that collective action in the where the vectors X, Z and W are interpreted as
labor market can be an important vehicle for before. i represents individual states. ai are the
poverty reduction and improvements in human state effects, with i = 1, . . . , 14. The new vector
development via important redistributive ef- Nt is a vector of national-level independent
fects. This empirical evidence supports previous variables, invariant across the various states.
analytical discussions in, for instance, Heller eit is, as before, the error term, which varies
(1996, 2000) and Herring (1983). unsystematically across time and individuals. 24
What then explains Kerala’s poor economic All variables are the same as in model (1) for
performance? From a collective action perspec- Kerala, except for the election variable. In the
tive, two of our results suggest some answers to above model, the election variable is shared
this question. We found that excessive levels of by all states that take the value 1 if the Indian
unionism have affected the state’s economic National Congress Party had the majority of
performance. Large numbers of unions may seats in the Lok Sabha. 25
not necessarily result in increases in strikes. Model (2) can be estimated by standard
Nonetheless, they may affect labor productivity fixed-effects panel estimation techniques. 26 As
if they imply breakdowns in labor relations or before, we have modeled collective action and
increases in caste- and class-based grievances redistributive policies as endogenous vari-
(see Nair, 1994). We also found that the volume ables. 27 We have used two techniques to model
of politically motivated riots may be partially endogeneity. The first is the fixed-effects two-
responsible for Kerala’s low levels of economic stage least-squares models adapted to panel
growth. 22 Kerala has some of the highest num- data developed by Baltagi (1995, Chapter 7).
bers of riots per 1,000 people in India (Table 2). The second is the generalized method of mo-
Remarkably, the large literature on poverty ments (GMM) (Arellano & Bond, 1991), as
and development, in India in general and Ker- model (2) contains lagged endogenous vari-
ala in particular, does not entail any significant ables. Both 2SLS and GMM models are pre-
discussions of this potentially important con- sented in Table 4. This table includes two
THE IMPACT OF COLLECTIVE ACTION ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1265

Table 4. Marginal effects for Indian panel


Dep var: LNSDP (2SLS) Dep var: LNSDP (2SLS)
(with Kerala) (without Kerala)
2SLS (1) GMM (2) 2SLS (3) GMM (4)
Lagged state income 0.095*** 0.018 0.091*** 0.029
Volume of riots 0.101** 0.107** 0.100** 0.056*
Lagged volume riots 0.037 0.063** 0.035 0.028
Volume of strikes 0.018** 0.014*** 0.019** 0.012**
Lagged volume of strikes 0.003 0.002 0.002 0.005
Exp on social services 0.0002 0.0003 0.003 0.0003
Number of workers’ unions 0.0002 0.0002 0.0003 0.0001***
Election results 0.0002 0.001 0.006 0.004
Trade openness 0.020*** 0.010** 0.023*** 0.016***
Education enrolments 0.053 0.048 0.026 0.004

State effects Yes Yes Yes Yes


Within R-squared 0.914 – 0.912 –
Between R-squared 0.769 – 0.813 –
Overall R-squared 0.771 – 0.787 –
No. of observations 70 70 65 65
Note: Test for first order autocorrelation in column (2): Pr > z = 0.3703. Test for second order autocorrelation in
column (2): Pr > z = 0.7379. Test for first order autocorrelation in column (4): Pr > z = 0.4728. Test for second
order autocorrelation in column (4): Pr > z = 0.6047.
*
Significant at the 10%.
**
Significant at the 5%.
***
Significant at the 1%.

model specifications for each technique. Col- underlying development motivations—as


umns (1) and (2) include all 14 states, whereas for instance recent adivasis movements or
columns (3) and (4) exclude Kerala in order public actions leading to the implementation
to test the possibility of the panel results being of reservations for backward castes in gov-
driven by specific characteristics of this state. ernment jobs—may result in overall improve-
The results vary marginally when Kerala is ments in living standards. These must,
removed from the panel. however, remain as conjectures until better
Table 4 shows quite interesting results. Con- disaggregated data on riots in India are made
trary to the Kerala analysis, all forms of collec- available. 28
tive action result in positive economic benefits These results can of course also be due to
across India. With the exception of column measurement error in the collective action vari-
(1), both short- and long-term effects of riots ables. The analysis in this section requires a cer-
and strikes on state income are positive. This tain level of comparability in the data on strikes
may well be due to differences in the nature of and riots across the 14 Indian states. There are
rioting in Kerala and other Indian states. There good reasons to question the comparability of
is good reason to believe that riots in Kerala the data. As discussed previously, data on
have a large political foundation motivated by strikes and lockouts are self-reported. On the
party competition (Heller, 1995; Prabhash, other hand, data on riots are collected by the
2000). Forms of rioting in other Indian states local police and may be subject to political
are likely to result from similar basis (see Brass, pressure. This is more so in states with lower
2003), but also (in larger numbers than in incidence of media influence, lower degrees of
Kerala) from separatist movements and clashes literacy and numeracy rates, more fragmented
between different ethnic and religious groups or absent labor unions and lower levels of law
and different castes (see Hardgrave, 1993; and order and state government accountability.
Varshney, 2002). Although these forms of riots In order to address these potential concerns, we
may be violent and destructive, those with have carefully tested the above results to the
1266 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

removal and inclusion of certain states. We however, that this relationship may not hold
report the results of our regressions with and for all economies at all times. The analysis of
without Kerala in Table 4, but we have under- the Kerala dataset and its comparison with
taken similar tests for each of the 14 states the Indian panel showed that collective action
without finding any statistically significant dif- and public participation are not always positive
ferences between these and the results reported conditions for economic development. Our
in this section. 29 The results in this section empirical analysis demonstrated that the rela-
emphasize, therefore, the importance of forms tionship between collective action and eco-
of collective action for economic development. nomic development will depend on the type
They show, furthermore, that the relationship and the level of collective action, as well as spe-
between collective action and economic devel- cific underlying motivations behind different
opment may have different static and dynamic types of collective action. Large numbers of
effects in different contexts, depending on the uncoordinated workers’ unions may break
volume and type of activism. cohesion in labor markets and offset the poten-
tial gains of more concerted actions, whilst
certain types of politically motivated forms of
6. CONCLUSIONS civil unrest may entail potentially destructive
effects.
Most development texts, including recent It is undeniable that the participation of vul-
World Bank and United Nations publications, nerable groups in the national decision-making
argue that public participation in the process process may help to address economic and so-
of decision making is necessary, if not funda- cial difficulties faced by those typically excluded
mental, for the implementation of successful from fundamental, social, economic, and polit-
development strategies. These studies do not, ical institutions, as well as increasing aggregate
however, consider that collective action can economic performance. There is, nonetheless,
take different forms and be based on different a fine line between public participation and
motivations. Moreover, the development litera- unsustainable socio-political instability, as
ture rarely provides rigorous, empirically based demonstrated by the example of Kerala. This
analysis, of the extent and importance of pub- may have important policy implications. In
lic participation on economic development. particular, the empirical results presented and
This paper examined empirically the impact of discussed in this paper signal the need to com-
collective action and public participation on plement usual development policies with the
economic development in South India. Our establishment of strong institutions that medi-
analysis uncovered important aspects of that ate the interests and needs of all population
relationship, notably the endogenous nature groups. Avoiding potentially negative out-
of collective action and its different static and comes from collective action will require the
dynamic effects. The paper entails, therefore, establishment of well-functioning bargaining
substantial implications for the understanding processes between the state, industry, and civil
of the relationship between collective action organizations, as well as the promotion of ac-
and economic development. tions that encourage civil responsibility from
Overall we concluded that collective action all actors.
may have important endogenous, positive ef- We are still far from understanding the full
fects on economic development. In India, both extent and implications of the relationship be-
labor disputes and politically motivated riots tween collective action, public participation,
have raised state income levels. In Kerala, in and economic development. We expect that
general, labor market activism has resulted the empirical evidence provided in this paper
in significant benefits for the poor, as well as may generate enough interest and motivate fur-
in improvements in economic growth. A partic- ther research on both the nature of collective
ular beneficial outcome in Kerala was the action and public participation, and the ana-
implementation of social policies that pro- lysis of these relationships in the context of
moted human development and widespread so- other case studies. In particular, further empir-
cio-economic security. This confirms the widely ical evidence will be fundamental for better in-
accepted view that collective action and public formed policy actions by civil organizations,
participation are important conditions for suc- local governments, and the international com-
cessful economic development. We showed, munity.
THE IMPACT OF COLLECTIVE ACTION ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1267

NOTES

1. An exception is empirical work on the impact of riots per 1,000 people. These data were collected by the
labor union actions (see Freeman & Medoff, 1984). author from a collection of published records held by the
NCRB since 1969, and updated yearly. The data are net
2. See George (1993) and Lizy (1990) for analyses of of juvenile delinquency as those types of rioting are
Kerala’s fiscal crisis. Government of Kerala (1996), typically not politically driven (private communication
Isaac and Tharakan (1995), Prakash (1994), Ramachan- with S.R. Meena at NCBR). Juvenile delinquency
dran (1997) and Sankaranarayanan and Bhai (1994) comprises less than 1% of total rioting in Kerala (and
provide extensive discussions of the difficulties faced by India). We have tested our results to the exclusion of
Kerala’s agricultural and industrial sectors. NSSO these data and found no statistically significant changes.
(1997) and Tharamangalam (1998) discuss in further
detail the possible causes and consequences of Kerala’s 9. For similar evidence in Indonesia, see Barron,
high unemployment rates. Kaiser, and Pradhan (2004).

3. In 1998, Kerala’s wages ranged between Rs. 19.5 and 10. See for instance www.rediff.com/news. See also
Rs. 114.16 per day, well above the Indian average. These Human Rights Watch (2001) and Justino (2004).
wage rates have been steadily increasing since 1975
(Kerala’s Ministry of Labour, Annual Report, various
11. The choice of the period of analysis was driven by
years).
data availability.

4. The decrease in strikes and lockouts in the late 1990s


is also likely to be the result of the ban on bundhs (short 12. We tested for the presence of stochastic trends.
duration wildcat strikes) by the High Court in 1997. Augmented Dickey–Fuller tests did not show the pres-
ence of unit roots at the 5% level of significance,
suggesting that we have deterministic rather than
5. It is not possible to separate the number of strikes
stochastic trends (Greene, 2000).
from the number of lockouts for the whole dataset at the
state level and thus assess the relative strength of
workers’ unions versus employers. We do not think, 13. Strikes usually take place within the industrial
however, that this shortcoming will significantly affect sector, whereas riots refer to the whole population.
our conclusions as the number of lockouts at the all-
India level is very small. These data are self-reported and 14. These data are published in the Reserve Bank of
are, therefore, likely to underreport the true extent of India’s annual bulletins. The variable includes the
strikes and lockouts in Kerala (and India) (see Indian amount of real per capita public expenditure on educa-
Labour Statistics, 1994 and discussion in Justino, 2001). tion, health, family welfare, welfare of scheduled castes,
This issue is not however a serious problem in this paper schedule tribes and other backward classes, labor
given the strong statistical significance of the results. We welfare, social security, and welfare and nutrition.
will discuss this issue further in Section 4.
15. Economic liberalization has been the most signif-
6. In terms of absolute numbers of strikes and icant economic change that has taken place in India in
lockouts, Kerala is roughly in the middle of the the recent years. For discussion of the liberalization
distribution amongst Indian’s 14 largest states included process in India, see Srinivasan (2001).
in Table 2. Indian states vary, however, widely in terms
of the size of their total and working population. 16. This variable is provided by Kerala’s Assembly
Comparisons should therefore only be made for num- Election Database (http://assembly.expert-eyes.org).
bers of strikes and lockouts per number of factory
workers as illustrated in Table 2. In this case, Kerala’s 17. The OLS regressions in columns (2), (4), and (6)
position in the distribution goes up quite significantly. exhibited serial correlation. This has been corrected by
using a two-step Cochrane–Orcutt transformed regres-
7. See Ranchhoddas, Thakore, and Vakil (1971), cited sion estimator (see Greene, 2000).
in Brass (2003). See also Gurr (1970).
18. Poverty is measured by the headcount index
8. The data were kindly provided by the National derived from household consumption expenditure data
Crime Records Bureau (NCRB), part of the Indian in the National Sample Surveys (NSS) (see Deaton,
Ministry of Home Affairs, and refers to the number of 2001). This variable has been linearly interpolated in
1268 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

order to avoid gaps in the NSS data. As the data have independence until 1977. At that time it was beaten in
not been collected on some years, interpolation does not the national elections by the right-wing Bharatiya Janta
lead to loss of efficiency in the estimators (Greene, 2000). Party, but recovered its position quickly in 1980. The
Bharatiya Janta Party returned to power in the 1990s
19. This variable includes both capital and noncapital and had been the ruling party in India until the latest
public expenditure and is provided by the Reserve Bank elections in 2004 (Election Commission of India, http://
of India. www.eci.gov.in).

20. See Ravallion and Datt (1999) for a recent discus- 26. Breusch–Pagan Lagrange multiplier tests for ran-
sion of the ‘‘redistribution versus growth’’ debate. dom effects and Hausman specification tests suggest the
presence of strong fixed effects. We have not found any
21. Note that in Kerala labor disputes take place both statistically significant evidence for random effects.
in urban and rural areas, where the role of peasant
associations has been significant (Gulati, 1990; Oom-
27. The instruments are all the exogenous variables in
men, 1993).
the equation plus, as before, rural and urban poverty
headcounts and aggregate development expenditure,
22. There will be of course other reasons behind
which guarantee an identified system. We have tested
Kerala’s low state income. Other possible areas of
the endogeneity assumption for the panel using Haus-
research outside the scope of this paper include the role man specification tests (Wooldridge, 2002), and could
of industrial policies, the channeling of remittances not reject the hypothesis that endogeneity was present in
toward productive activities, the inadequacy of Kerala’s
the model. We also found signs of double causality
educational system, amongst others. See Justino (2001). between the three pairs of variables in all states at less
than 1% level of significance.
23. Although it would have been possible to estimate
time-series results for all-India, panel analysis is a more
appropriate technique given the large heterogeneity 28. Brass (2003) argues extensively for the need for
between all Indian states in social, cultural, religious, more appropriate definitions of riots in India, including
economic, and political terms. These states represented better definitions and operationalization of notions of
93.3% of the total Indian population in 1999–2000. The communal riots. To the best of my knowledge, no
analysis in this section uses six data points: 1973–74, dataset exists that allows a separation of motives for
1977–78, 1983, 1987–88, 1993–94 and 1999–2000. These rioting in India. Varshney (2002) and Wilkinson (2004)
dates correspond to the dates of the large sample NSSO have collected a groundbreaking dataset on ethnic riots
surveys. Our analysis focuses on these 6 years in order to in India. These cannot, however, be directly compared
ensure consistency across all variables. with the NCBR sets as methodologies differ. The
Varshney–Wilkinson survey is based on information
24. t exhibits a different periodicity. The usual estima- contained in the Times of India over four decades, while
tion procedures will still yield unbiased estimators for the NCBR data are based on police records. Both data
the true coefficients, since variables included in the sets entail significant biases as well as strengths, though
regression model are observed for the same exact periods none differentiates between different types of riots.
(Greene, 2000).
29. These results have not been included in this paper
25. The Indian National Congress Party, founded in for reasons of space constraints but can be obtained
1885, was in power almost without opposition since from the author upon request.

REFERENCES

Ahmad, E., Drèze, J., Hills, J., & Sen, A. K. (1991). application to employment equations. Review of
Social security in developing countries. Oxford: Clar- Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.
endon Press. Baltagi, B. H. (1995). Econometric analysis of panel data.
Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Income distribution, New York: John Wiley & Sons.
political instability and investment. European Eco- Barro, R. J. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section
nomic Review, 15, 1203–1228. of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106,
Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Tests of specification 407–443.
for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an
THE IMPACT OF COLLECTIVE ACTION ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1269

Barron, P., Kaiser, K., & Pradhan, M. (2004). Local Greene, W. H. (2000). Econometric analysis (4th ed.).
conflict in Indonesia: Measuring incidence and iden- New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.
tifying patterns. World Bank, mimeo. Gulati, L. (1990). Agricultural workers pension in
Brass, P. (1997). Theft of an idol: Text and context in the Kerala—An experiment in social assistance. Eco-
representation of collective violence. Princeton: nomic and Political Weekly, 25, 339–343.
Princeton University Press. Gurr, T. R. (1970). Why men rebel. Princeton University
Brass, P. (2003). The production of Hindu–Muslim Press.
violence in contemporary India. Seattle: University Hardgrave, R. (1993). India: The dilemmas of diversity.
of Washington Press. Journal of Democracy, IV, 54–68.
Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of Heller, P. (1995). From class struggle to class compro-
consent. Ann Arbor. mise: Redistribution and growth in a south Indian
Das, M. K. (2003). Kerala: Politics of pressure groups. state. Journal of Development Studies, 31, 645–672.
Economic and Political Weekly, August 2. Heller, P. (1996). Social capital as a product of class
Deaton, A. (2001). Adjusted Indian poverty estimates for mobilization and state intervention: Industrial work-
1999–2000. Working paper. Research Program in ers in Kerala, India. World Development, 24,
Development Studies, Princeton University. 1055–1071.
Drèze, J., & Sen, A. K. (1991). Public action for Heller, P. (2000). The labour of development: Workers
social security: Foundations and strategy. In E. and the transformation of capitalism in Kerala, India.
Ahmad, J. Drèze, J. Hills, & A. K. Sen (Eds.), Social Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
security in developing countries. Oxford: Clarendon Herring, R. J. (1983). Land to the tiller: The political
Press. economy of agrarian reform in South Asia. London:
Drèze, J., Sen, A. K., & Hussain, A. (1995). The political Yale University Press.
economy of hunger: Selected essays. Oxford: Claren- Human Rights Watch (2001). World report: India. New
don Press. York: Human Rights Watch.
Engineer, A. A. (1984). Communal riots in post-indepen- Isaac, T. M., & Tharakan (1995). Kerala—The emerging
dence India. Hyderabad: Sangam Books. perspectives: Overview of the international congress
Engineer, A. A. (2004). Communal riots after indepen- on Kerala studies. Social Scientist, 23, 3–36.
dence: A comprehensive account. New Delhi: Shipra. Joseph, A. V. (1999). Kerala: Resurgence of politics of
Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare violence. Economic and Political Weekly, December
capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press. 18.
Franke, R. W., & Chasin, B. H. (1992). Kerala: Justino, P. (2001). Social security and political conflict in
Development through radical reform. New Delhi: developing countries, with special reference to the
Institute for Food and Development Policy, Promilla south Indian state of Kerala. Unpublished Ph.D.
& Co., Publishers. thesis, Department of Economics, School of Oriental
Freeman, R. B., & Medoff, J. L. (1984). What do unions and African Studies, University of London.
do? New York: Basic Books. Justino, P. (2003). Social security in developing countries:
George, K. K. (1993). Limits to Kerala model of Myth or necessity? Evidence from India. PRUS
development: An analysis of fiscal crisis and its Working paper no. 20. Poverty Research Unit at
implications. Thiruvananthapuram, Kerala: Centre Sussex, University of Sussex.
for Development Studies. Justino, P. (2004). Redistribution, inequality and political
George, K. K. (1998). Historical roots of the Kerala conflict. PRUS Working paper no. 18. Poverty
model and its present crisis. Bulletin of Concerned Research Unit at Sussex, University of Sussex.
Asian Scholars, 30, 35–40. Kannan, K. P. (1990). Kerala economy at the cross-
Government of India (1998). Selected socio-economic roads? Economic and Political Weekly, September 1–
statistics India 1996–97. New Delhi: Central Statis- 8; 1951–1956.
tical Organisation, Ministry of Planning and Pro- Kannan, K. P. (1995). Public intervention and poverty
gramme Implementation. alleviation: A study of the declining incidence of
Government of India (various years). Annual report. rural poverty in Kerala, India. Development and
New Delhi: Ministry of Labour. Change, 26, 701–727.
Government of India (various years). Indian labour year Lizy, M. A. (1990). Centre-state financial relations in
book. New Delhi: Ministry of Labour. India. New Delhi: Ashish Publishing House.
Government of India (various years). Indian labour McAdam, D. (1982). Political process and the develop-
statistics. New Delhi: Ministry of Labour. ment of black insurgency 1930–1970. Chicago: Uni-
Government of India (various years). Crime in India. versity of Chicago Press.
New Delhi National Crime Records Bureau, Minis- Meinzen-Dick, R. S., & Di Gregorio, M. (2004).
try of Home Affairs. Collective action and property rights for sustainable
Government of India (various years). National accounts development. New York: IFPRI and CAPRi.
statistics. New Delhi: Central Statistical Organisa- Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1989).
tion, Department of Statistics, Ministry of Planning Income distribution, market size, and industrializa-
and Programme Implementation. tion. Quarterly Journal of Economics, CIV, 537–564.
Government of Kerala (1996). Kerala economic survey Nair, M. K. S. (1994). Trade unionism in Kerala. In
1995–96. Thiruvananthapuram: State Planning B. A. Prakash (Ed.), Kerala’s economy: Performance,
Board. problems and prospects. India: Sage Publications.
1270 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

NSSO (various years). Sarvekshana. New Delhi: Na- Sankaranarayanan, K., & Bhai, M. (1994). Industrial
tional Sample Survey Organization. development in Kerala: Problems and prospects. In
Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action: Public B. Prakash (Ed.), Kerala’s economy: Performance,
goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: problems and prospects. India: Sage.
Harvard University Press. Srinivasan, T. N. (2001). Integrating India with the world
Oommen, M. A. (1993). Essays on Kerala economy. economy: Progress, problems and prospects. Depart-
New Delhi: Oxford and IBH Publishing Co. ment of Economics, Yale University.
Perotti, R. (1993). Political equilibrium, income distri- Tarrow, C. (2003). Power in movement: Social move-
bution and growth. Review of Economic Studies, 60, ments, collective action and politics. Cambridge Uni-
755–776. versity Press.
Pillai, P. P. (1994). Kerala economy: Four decades of Tharamangalam, J. (1998). The perils of social develop-
development. India: Institute of Planning and Ap- ment without economic growth: The development
plied Economic Research, John Matthai Founda- debacle of Kerala, India. Bulletin of Concerned Asian
tion. Scholars, 30, 23–34.
Prabhash, J. (2000). CPI(M)’s Muslim league dilemma. Tilly, C. (1993). Contentions repertoires in Great
Economic and Political Weekly, August 19: 3009– Britain 1758–1834. Social Science History, 17,
3011. 253–279.
Prakash, B. A. (1994). Kerala’s economy: Performance, Tilly, C. (2003). The politics of collective violence.
problems and prospects. India: Sage Publications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Przeworski, A. (1985). Capitalism and social democracy. United Nations (1997). Human development report 1997.
Cambridge University Press. New York: United Nations.
Ramachandran, V. K. (1997). Kerala’s development Varshney, A. (2002). Ethnic conflict and civic life:
achievements. In J. Drèze, & A. K. Sen (Eds.), Indian Hindus and Muslims in India. Yale: Yale University
development: Selected regional perspectives. New Press.
Delhi: Oxford University Press. Wilkinson, S. (2004). Votes and violence: Electoral
Ranchhoddas, R., Thakore, D. K., & Vakil, M. R. competition and ethnic riots in India. New York:
(1971). The law of crimes (2nd ed.). Bombay: Cambridge University Press.
Bombay Law Reporter. Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross
Ravallion, M., & Datt, G. (1999). When is growth pro- section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
poor? Evidence from the diverse experiences of India’s World Bank (1997). World development report 1997.
states. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Reserve Bank of India (various years). Bulletin. New World Bank (2001). World development report. Wash-
Delhi. ington, DC: The World Bank.

You might also like