.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Clark University is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Economic Geography.
http://www.jstor.org
The dismal record of official development theory during the last four decades
has led some scholars to believe that
poverty could be eradicated better
through the self-conscious efforts of the
poor themselves-i.e.,
through social
movements of community empowerment.
Some of the interest in self-help and social
movements has grown out of frustration
with failed development and a desire to
"somehow do something" as a practical
way out of the impasse (Durning 1989).
These efforts need support from academics, but such help must proceed from an
understanding of why development has
failed to alleviate poverty. I argue that
poverty is not about failed development,
poor technology, lack of resources, mismanagement, or poor planning, but rather
that it represents a routine, everyday,
normal manifestation of the very process
of economic development; indeed, development has caused modern poverty.
By poverty, I mean a situation in which
255
256
ECONOMIc GEOGRAPHY
because it includes far more than technology, goods, and markets. Production is determined at once within a web of relations -technical, social, ecological, cultural,
and academic-whose understandingis distorted by subject-specific views of reductionist science (Fig. 1).2 These relations
should not be conceived as discrete, analytical categories, nor is the list meant to
be exhaustive.3 The relations are dialectical, in that they act and react upon each
other constantly to maintaina dynamic process of production: analytically, there are
no visible seams between any two of them.
In a historical sense, the relations are also
mutually constituted. An entity that appears to be technological from one angle,
or point in time, may be thought of as academic or social from another angle or different point in time, or what appears to be
academic may be better treated with language that is social or cultural, and so on.
Non-orthodoxMarxiantheory describes the
notion of the nexus of relations with the
term "overdetermination," meaning that
-every process is determined simultaneously by every other process in society
(Resnick and Wolff 1989, 1-37).
The concept of overdetermination stands
opposed to essentialism, which is the "presumption that complex realities of any sort
are ultimately reducible to simpler, or essential, realities";among the influences pro-
ACADEMIC
CULTURAL
TECHNICAL
ECOLOGICAL
SOCIAL
257
develop this article by successively focusing on each relation to unpack the ways
we think about high-yielding improved
seeds.
The Green Revolution provides a good
illustration of the concept of the nexus of
productionrelations.The term "Green Revolution" has been attributed to William
Gaud of the United States Agency for International Development in a speech given
to the Society for International Development in March 1968 (Spitz 1987). Gaud
alluded to the possibility of a green technical revolution in food production as counterposed to a red political revolution. In
December 1969, the Green Revolution was
presented to the U.S. Congress as a major
tool of American foreign policy that provided bright market prospects to the pesticide, fertilizer, seed, and tractor industries (Spitz 1987; Cleaver 1973).
Diffusionism and
Technical Relations
The mainstreamconventional view of underdevelopment sees a poor country as having a dual economy, consisting of a dynamic, modern sector and a static,
traditional sector. The static sector lacks
savings, investment, capital, and infrastructure, an imbalance which can be corrected
by the movement (diffusion) of capital,
know-how, and information from the dynamic sector. This two-sector model of development, prominent throughout the
1960s and 1970s, viewed poverty partly as
a technical matter arising from the lack of
capital and technical know-how. This approach enjoyed an unrivaled dominance
within mainstream geography for several
decades, as evidenced by the profusion of
studies on growth poles, central places, regional inequality, diffusion of modernization, diffusion of innovations, and so on
(Soja 1968; Gould 1969; Berry, Conkling,
and Ray 1976; Rondinelli and Ruddle 1978;
Gore 1984; Brown 1981).
A useful point of departure for this
essay is Hagerstrand's (1967) book on
spatial diffusion, where he described the
258
ECONoMic GEOGRAPHY
and location in space were further confirmed during later field visits to several
villages in the study area. I cannot recall
meeting a single local person who was not
aware of the new varieties of corn being
grown in that area. I took special care to
engage farmers who had not adopted
hybrid maize; I learned that several had
carefully considered the new package of
innovations and decided against it for
what appeared to be very rational reasons.
Some told me they could not afford to
adopt because they had no access to
irrigated land necessary for the cultivation
of the new varieties. Many "nonadopters"
I met did not fit the psychological profiles
constructed by rural sociologists of "laggards" and "late adopters."5 Because of
these impressions, we abandoned the
simulations and reanalyzed the adoption
data using a different approach. The
farmers were first divided into two groups
of adopters and nonadopters, and data
were organized into three sets of variables
that were known to impact adoption of
innovations: (1) access to information; (2)
behavioral variables of the type that rural
sociologists deemed important for adoption; and (3) resource variables, such as
access to irrigated land and credit. A
statistical discriminant analysis was used
to ascertain the set of factors that was best
able to separate adopters from nonadopters (Yapa and Mayfield 1978). As we had
come to suspect, the set of variables
describing farmers' access to resources
had a higher discriminant index than the
other two groups. Almost simultaneously,
similar findings emerged from the investigations at the Center for South Asian
Studies at Cambridge University, where
the reasons for nonadoption of highyielding varieties of rice in Tamil Nadu,
India, and in southern Sri Lanka had been
examined (Farmer 1977).
259
260
ECONoMic GEOGRAPHY
Sustainability and
Ecological Relations
For the most part, production involves
the transformation of material into use
values through the application of information, energy, and labor. Production uses
the ecosystem not only as a source of
energy and matter but also as a repository
of waste products, thus continually defining a myriad of interactions within the
biophysical environment. These are ecological relations of production.
The current concern with ecology is
driven largely by issues of environmental
degradation that have led to the destruction of the physical conditions of production (Brown, Flavin, and Postel 1991; O'
Connor 1988), a concern that may be
described as a reactive stance. But an
equally important, "proactive" reason for
studying ecology is to create knowledge
that allows people to directly harness use
values created in nature.7 Examples of
such techniques include biological control
of crop diseases and biological sources of
crop nutrients. Exploration of these ideas
serves the added purpose of illuminating
how development has created social scarcity.
Destruction of the
Conditions of Production
My first appreciation of the ecological
problems arising from the cultivation of
high-yielding new seeds came during field
visits to the Devanahalli district of Karnataka. There I learned of an outbreak of
corn stem-borer, which some farmers said
was new to the area. Soon the technology
of hybridization itself was implicated in
the problem. The vulnerability of the new
hybrids to a variety of pests and diseases,
an area of concern which came to be
known as the "second generation problem," was not clearly recognized at first. It
was soon understood that genetically
uniform varieties of rice, wheat, and corn
grown in monocultural stands were vulnerable to pests and pathogens, a fact that
was dramatically demonstrated in 1970
when some 15 percent of the U.S. corn
crop was lost to a leaf blight. A genetic
factor (Type T cytoplasm) built into hybrid
corn to eliminate the labor-intensive tasks
of manual detassling was believed to be
the cause of corn's vulnerability to this
blight (Kloppenburg 1988, 121-23). In the
early 1980s, there were reports from
South and Southeast Asia that rice pad-
261
262
ECONOMICGEOGRAPHY
263
264
ECONOMICGEOGRAPHY
and
underlying
. . . all
diffusionof development (Rogers 1969; Dalton 1971; Rostow 1960; Lerner 1958; Lewis
1962). It is important to recognize that,
despite the extensive empirical work done
to support it, the concept of traditionalculture as backward has not been established
as a matter of empirical fact. It is an elaborate academic representation of "the
other," an intellectual construction which
actually reflects the values of sociologists
immersed in the dominant world view of
capitalist culture. There is no objective referent in the external world called "backward traditional culture" that is independent of the intellect that constructed it (Said
1979). This conception of traditional culture tells us as much about the nature of
development sociology (the self as it does
about peasant culture (the other).
Indigenous Knowledge
I have used the term "traditional" to
mean a community where the conduct of
activity and the transfer of knowledge is
based on experiences transmitted from one
generation to another (Wilken 1987). The
process of knowledge transfer in traditional cultures is informal and oral. This is
perhaps one reason why traditional societies are perceived as being non-innovative; another reason is that innovations are
often subtle and low cost. Several prominent students of "traditional"agriculture
have written persuasively about the complexity and longevity of mixed farming that
incorporatedanimals, manure, and crop rotation-for example, F. H. King (1973
[1911]) of the U.S. Department of Agriculture and Sir Albert Howard (1973 [1940]).
Among geographers the most preeminent
student of traditionalagriculture was Sauer
(1963 [1938], 1952), who was quite emphatic in his condemnation of the Rockefeller Foundation proposal in the early
1940s to modernize Mexican agriculture
Jennings 1988, 50-55).
In his "uniformitarian"critique of diffusionism, Blaut (1987) offered an excellent
discussion of how and why we have in the
past perceived traditional cultures to be
non-innovative. Blaut noted that the
265
spread of European colonialism and culture was seen as scientifically correct and
morally justifiable because the landscapes
and cultures into which these things were
inserted were seen, in one sense or
another, as empty. Support for Blaut's
argument comes from the recent literature on traditional agricultural technology
(Altieri and Anderson 1986). Based on
surveys of traditional farming conducted
at several sites in southern Mexico and
Middle America, Wilken (1987) described
traditional resource management techniques in energy supply, soil classification, and the management of soil, water,
slope, and space. An important point
made by Wilken is that traditional tools
and techniques are not easily duplicated,
because most traditional technology requires understanding local conditions and
ways of managing local energy and materials. Harrison (1987) reports from Africa
on a wide array of indigenous, traditional
techniques for soil conservation, water
use, and agro-forestry that have been
successful in local areas but often are
unknown to people in neighboring valleys. Harrison calls for the diffusion of a
new green revolution in Africa that
carefully incorporates the better traditional practices, reiterating an argument
made earlier by Richards (1985), who
writes about indigenous agriculture in
West Africa. Other writing that has
argued the importance of paying attention
to indigenous knowledge systems includes: Brokensha, Warren, and Werner
(1980); Chambers, Pacey, and Thrupp
(1989); Chambers (1983); Altieri (1987);
and Geertz (1963).
The modernization literature on diffuision in the Third World profoundly misrepresented and misinterpreted traditionalsocieties as backwardand non-innovative.This
cultural bias, abetted in part by academics,
affected public policy and the course of diffusionof agriculturalinnovations.This is now
formally recognized as a mistake, and effortsare being made to systematicallyrecord
knowledge of traditional cropping techniques, control of crop and animal diseases,
use of organic fertilizers, soil conservation,
266
ECONOMICGEOGRAPHY
potatoes
that have
enabled
10
Zimmerer (1991) has argued that, although there is a general correlation between
the type of variety and elevation, there is no
evidence for the belief in a fine-tuned adaptation of cultivars to specific environments such
as elevational micro-environments.
267
Hegemony and
Academic Relations
The expression "academic relations of
production" is used here to refer to the
work of agricultural scientists who conceived and bred improved seeds and the
work of social scientists who conceived
the social theory that facilitated the
diffusion of that technology. The story of
improved seeds provides an excellent
example of the claim made by critical
social theorists that science and technology are in fact "social processes" directed
by the power relations of the underlying
society, serving to strengthen and reproduce those power relations (Aronowitz
1988; Foucault 1980).
I argued earlier that improved seeds
was not just a technology to better feed
people by increasing food production, but
that it was also an instrument designed to
serve the economic interests of particular
268
ECONoMic GEOGRAPHY
science,"
Proctor
(1991,
separated from each other by transforming seeds into a commodity that had to be
purchased at each planting. Kloppenburg
(1988) has argued that the potential of
turning seeds into a commodity was a
driving force in the choice of hybridization as the technique for improving seeds.
Wheat and corn improvement research
conducted by Norman Borlaug is often
cited as the beginning of the Green
Revolution in Mexico. The Mexican story
goes further back, however, to the 1930s,
when the Ministry of Agriculture in
Mexico during the progressive years of
Lazaro Cardenas (1935-40) initiated a
program of scientific research to improve
corn, the main staple of the peasantry.
The years of Cardenas saw sweeping land
reforms, the expropriation of Standard
Oil, and the threat of take-over of other
U.S. investments in Mexico. With the
installation of Avila Camacho as next
president, the program for the improvement of peasant crops was disbanded.
During the 1940s, with help from the
Rockefeller Foundation, a new program of
agricultural research was started, focusing
on hybrid varieties of irrigated wheat for
large-scale commercial growers of northwest Mexico. The idea was to reverse the
agrarian radicalism of Cardenas and replace it with a model of scientific,
industrial agriculture to produce food
surpluses for urban areas using industrial
inputs. This program later came to be
known as the Green Revolution; it did
much for agribusiness of pumps, machines, fertilizer, and pesticides and little
for the nutrition and welfare of Mexican
peasants (Hewitt de Alcantara 1973-74).
Drawing on Rockefeller archives, Jennings (1988) has reported that Carl Sauer,
who was a strong critic of the model of
industrial agriculture, believed that the
agricultural and nutritional practices of
Mexican peasantry were quite sound, but
that they needed support and strengthening. Sauer's advice went unheeded at the
foundation. Borlaug's work also marginalized the research on rain-fed corn that
was being done by Mexican scientists in
the Institute of Agricultural Investiga-
269
270
ECONOMICGEOGRAPHY
Therefore, it is through academic "deconstruction" that we can begin to understand how improved seeds are actually
constituted. Seeds as technology for increasing food production is simply one
manifestation of what they are. More to
the point is that seeds represent a nexus
of mutually determining relations. Frequently asked questions such as "Wasn't
the Green Revolution a success?" or
"How productive are improved seeds?"
make sense only within a particular
epistemology; the same inquiry makes
little or no sense when viewed in the
wider context of seeds as nexus of
relations.
Economic Development of
Social Scarcity
Production is commonly defined as the
creation of use values. But under certain
circumstances production not only creates
use values but also destroys them-"the
two faces of production." Scarcity is a
relation that grows out of this twin
characteristic of production and appears
in numerous aspects of development. My
focus here has been on the concrete
manifestation of this phenomenon in
agricultural modernization within the
nexus of relations of improved seeds. It
may be useful to recapitulate the argument briefly: The social construction of
scarcity began with the genetic transformation of seeds into a nonreproducing
commodity. The improved seeds were
developed to respond to industrial inputs
such as fertilizer, pesticides, irrigation,
and fuel. The creation of such demand
creates scarcity by creating the need for
these products. The continued use of
inorganic fertilizer over a long period
leads to the deterioration of soil structure
and increased erosion, thus requiring
larger quantities of fertilizer to simply
maintain yields. The long-term use of
chemical pesticides increases the demand
not only for larger applications, but also
for other, more powerful pesticides. The
need for irrigation water to grow im-
271
Conclusion
This paper was partly an exercise in
understanding how problems are identified and solutions are proposed. Since
poverty is a serious problem, development was widely seen as the solution.
Since hunger and malnutrition are problems, the Green Revolution of improved
seeds was adopted as the solution. But
such solutions are in fact part of the
problem, because poverty is a form of
scarcity induced by the very process of
economic development. That argument
was illustrated by narrating a story of
improved seeds. Clearly many other
analyses and examples are needed to
demonstrate the connection between development and scarcity. In this paper I
explored that connection by posing the
question "What are seeds?" or "How do
we know seeds?" Improved seeds are
most commonly described as a technology
to increase yields, a reductionist description that ignores the nexus of relations of
the seeds. We saw that the technologycentered epistemology of the Green Revolution had acted in a manner that
concealed how production can also destroy use values, creating social scarcity.
The problem of poverty must, therefore,
be expanded to include not only concrete
places and people that experience scarcity, but also the epistemology of how we
know that scarcity and poverty.
Frustrated by failed development
projects, groups of poor people in many
parts of the Third World are changing their
life circumstances through their own praxis
of organized social movements. However,
a social theory for the transformation of
relationsof productionthrough social movements and community empowerment does
not yet exist. An important component of
such a social theory is a knowledge of the
epistemic genesis of poverty.
References
Altieri, M. A. 1987. Agroecology: The scientific
basis of alternative agriculture. Boulder,
Colo.: Westview Press.
Altieri, M. A., and Anderson, M. K. 1986. An
ecological basis for the development of
alternative agricultural systems for small
farmers in the Third World. American
Journal of Alternative Agriculture 1:30-38.
Aronowitz, S. 1988. Science as power: Discourse and ideology in modern society.
Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Baran, P. 1957. The political economy of
growth. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Berry, B. J. L.; Conkling, E. C.; and Ray,
D. M. 1976. The geography of economic
systems. Englewood Cliffs, N. J.: PrenticeHall.
Blaut, J. M. 1977. Two views of diffusion.
Annals of the Association of American
Geographers 67:343-49.
. 1987. Diffusionism:
A uniformitarian
Rethinking
crop genetic
re-
272
ECONOMIc GEOGRAPHY
and overdeter-
Mexican agricul-
a history
of needs.
Berkeley: Heyday.
Jennings, B. H. 1988. Foundations of international agricultural research. Boulder, Colo.:
Westview Press.
King, F. H. [1911] 1973. Farmers of forty
centuries. Emmaus, Pa.: Rodale Press.
Kloppenburg, J. R. 1988. First the seed: The
political economy of plant biotechnology
1492-2000. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Lerner, D. 1958. The passing of traditional
society: Modernizing the Middle East. New
York: Free Press.
Levins, R., and Lewontin, R. 1985. The
dialectical biologist. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
273