You are on page 1of 11

IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON ENGINEERING MANAGEMENT, VOL. 49, NO.

4, NOVEMBER 2002 341

Differentiating Market Strategies for


Disruptive Technologies
Steven T. Walsh, Member, IEEE, Bruce A. Kirchhoff, and Scott Newbert

Abstract—The literature is full of anecdotes that show new manufacturing practices. In addition, Bower and Christensen
small firms attacking existing markets with innovations based [10] state that a technology is considered disruptive when its
upon disruptive technologies and achieving phenomenal success. utility generates service products and/or physical products with
Because of this, some theorists argue that disruptive technologies
are best commercialized by new small firms. If this is true, can a different performance attributes that may not be valued by ex-
logical rationale be developed that explains this unique capacity isting customers. Moore [29] first stated this aspect of disruptive
of new firms? If so, can empirical research of new and established technologies by noting that they generate discontinuous inno-
firms in an industry fraught with a disruptive technology identify vations that require users/adopters to change their behavior in
the advantages that new firms have over established firms in the order to make use of the innovation.
commercialization process? The purpose of this paper is to ex-
amine the different roles of established and new firms in disruptive While disruptive technologies promise considerable oppor-
technology commercialization. The authors begin by developing tunities for strong entry into existing and new markets, they
a model of the innovation process beginning with technology also involve high risk of failure because of customer resistance.
creation and ending with user adoption and application. From There are a growing number of corporate executives, especially
this model they develop propositions for testing. The authors use in large established firms who believe that the commercializa-
survey data collected from 72 micro-electro-mechanical-systems
(MEMS) manufacturing firms. Their results from the MEMS tion of disruptive technologies is an increasingly more costly
industry show that established firms rarely commercialize disrup- endeavor with greater uncertainty of success in a more rapidly
tive technologies and then prefer to use market-pull strategies to changing technological environment. This raises the question of
accomplish this. New firms select primarily disruptive technolo- whether commercial activities based on disruptive technologies
gies and choose either market-pull or technology-push strategies can deliver appropriate and timely payoffs to investors. More-
for commercialization. Perhaps more important, time to market
for new firms is one-fourth that for established firms. These results over, firms with broad product lines may find that the disrup-
suggest that new firms have two advantages in commercialization tive technology based innovation “disrupts” markets for their
of disruptive technologies—flexibility in marketing strategy and existing profitable products thereby reducing revenues.
much shorter times to market. Disruptive technology creation and commercialization has
Index Terms—Commercialization, disruptive technology, become the focus of financial concerns for both new and estab-
market strategies, new firms’ advantages, survey of MEMS lished firms (Cooper and Smith [13]). In established firms dis-
industry managers, technology push versus market pull. ruptive technologies have traditionally been the responsibility
of R&D organizations. In new firms, technology creation is the
I. INTRODUCTION responsibility of everyone, especially the founders of the firm.
But, because of its unstructured nature and the uncertainty of the

T HERE IS widespread agreement that the commercializa-


tion of technological innovation has been a major contrib-
utor to contemporary industrialized nations’ wealth and pros-
technological outcomes, commercialization of disruptive tech-
nologies is hard to quantify and therefore justify in financial
terms. The commercial yield or “big payoffs” can take a long
perity. Many of these technological innovations are rooted in time to emerge, many years as compared to the commercializa-
disruptive technologies. The definition of disruptive technolo- tion of evolutionary, or sustaining, technologies that are more in-
gies builds upon the strategic categorization scheme presented cremental in nature and may find widespread application within
by Bower and Christensen [10], Ehrenberg [14], and others. months.
They view technologies as either those that sustain the current Much literature on disruptive technologies addresses the
manufacturing practices and technological capabilities required difficulties organizations have in handling disruptive tech-
in an industrial setting or alternatively disrupt the current ca- nologies rather than the opportunities they afford to those
pability set required by a given market. Furthermore, disruptive that embrace them. There are significant advantages in or-
technologies are those that do not support current firm-based ganizational learning. Argyris and Schon [6] and Senge [35]
provide us with the idea of double loop learning when a firm
Manuscript received Feburary 15, 2001; revised September 15, 2001. Review embraces a “radical” change and the benefits that are derived.
of this manuscript was arranged by Special Issue Editors S. K. Kassicieh, B. A. Such benefits can yield long term strategic advantages and
Kirchhoff, and S. T. Walsh.
S. T. Walsh is with the University of New Mexico, Albuquerque, 87131 NM yield superior profits as compared to the easier “single loop”
USA. learning that occurs when organizations embrace incremental
B. A. Kirchhoff is with the New Jersey Institute of Technology, Newark, NJ (or evolutionary) change. Similarly, the strategic literature
07102-1982 USA (e-mail: kirchoff@njit.edu).
S. Newbert is with Rutgers University, Newark, NJ 07102 USA. stresses the emergence of “strategic flexibility” and the de-
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/TEM.2002.806718 velopment of “dynamic capabilities” in response to disruptive
0018-9391/02$17.00 © 2002 IEEE
342 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON ENGINEERING MANAGEMENT, VOL. 49, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2002

change. Strategic flexibility is a strategy, which allows an differences between new and established firm innovators. Then,
organization to embrace or eschew dynamic and discontinuous we identify and describe an industry currently characterized by
developments in the firm’s environment (Brown and Eisenhardt numerous disruptive technological innovations, the microsys-
[11]). Similarly, the idea of building dynamic capabilities in tems technology-based industry. Our data collection method-
the firm to respond to technological change has been argued by ology is survey data collected from top level managers in this
Teece et al. [37] and Eisenhardt and Martin [15]. These authors industry. Our results show that new small firms and large es-
suggest that such dynamic capabilities provide firms with an tablished firms differ in competencies applied and market entry
ability to use resources to keep up with or create market change. strategies used as well as time to market thereby confirming
Such change creation leads to a new firm-based resource con- most of our initial propositions.
figuration focused more on reacting to as well as developing an
environmental change for a firm-based competitive advantage.
Therefore, the process of identifying and developing strate- II. DEVELOPMENT OF THE MODEL
gically important disruptive technologies is widely viewed as Bower and Christensen [10] suggest a rather radical solu-
vitally important to the future viability of technology intensive tion to the problems of disruptive technology commercializa-
firms. Disruptive technologies are seen as the birthplace of new tion. They recommend that commercialization be assigned to
corporate technological competencies, the center of evolving new firms operating independently of a parent corporation. But,
distinctive corporate competencies, and the epicenter from to understand this recommendation, one must fully appreciate
which generations of improvements in corporate competencies the origins of disruptive technologies and the mechanisms by
spring. Disruptive technologies clearly underlie the competitive which they become commercialized. For this reason, we con-
advantages of such firms. structed a model of the process and describe it in the following
Anecdotal evidence suggests that firms who commercialize paragraphs. The model is shown in Fig. 1.
innovations based upon disruptive technologies face enormous
internal and market problems. It is not unusual for these firms
A. Technology Sources
to experience conflict among technologists about the value of
the technology, difficulty with manufacturing processes, plus Technologies can originate either inside or outside an
resistance and occasionally refusal, by marketing managers to industry. Those that originate inside are said to be based upon
promote and sell the product(s). Internal problems are com- “core competencies” of corporations in the industry as defined
pounded by resistance from users regarding adoption, and, when by Prahalad and Hamel [32]. Those originating outside we
adopted, resistance to major changes in user behavior necessary call “exogenous” borrowing the term from economics (Lambe
to implement the technology. One would expect new firms to be and Spekman [24]). They compete with products based on
more seriously impacted by these problems than are established evolutionary technologies and create new industries [17].
firms but new independent firms seem to handle these more suc- In theory, the pursuit of new technologies consistently cre-
cessfully [7], [4], [22], [34]. In fact, anecdotal evidence com- ates new bases for building new distinctive core competencies
bined with thoughtful analysis led Bower and Christensen [10] that provide sustainable competitive advantages. Prahalad and
to state that well-established corporations are poorly positioned Hammel [32] define core competencies as the technological
to introduce disruptive technologies into markets. Instead, they knowledge and abilities that underlie a corporation’s core prod-
recommend that such corporations form separate, independent, ucts. Competitive advantage stems from the improvement of
new organizations to launch commercialization of new products user productivity and/or applicability of the new technology that
based upon disruptive technologies. makes it preferred over alternative technologies. Sustainability
If new high technology firms outperform their larger more emerges because the original technologies that underlie the core
established and resource rich cousins in the commercialization competencies yield strong patents and/or incorporate new pro-
of disruptive technologies, then the source of their advantage prietary manufacturing technologies.
should be searched out and identified so that technological However, many, perhaps most, disruptive technologies origi-
progress can be enhanced. Especially important are questions nate outside of an existing industry. Some of these technologies
about the technology selection process and the commercial- are developed by individual inventors. Others emerge from
ization methods that new firms apply. Formulated in strategic corporate R&D efforts. Bower and Christensen [10] after
terms, we need to learn what core competencies and capabilities examining a number of innovations based upon disruptive
successful new high-tech firms use. And, we need to know what technologies make a somewhat radical recommendation that
market strategies they choose and why they choose these. It is disruptive technologies originating in corporate R&D labs be
possible that appropriate identification of differences between commercialized by new independent firms. This is because
established and new firms may lead to a better understanding of established firms have sustainable competitive advantages
the innovation process and provide a foundation for improved with many satisfied customers that provide satisfactory profits.
effectiveness in launching new disruptive technologies. Thus, it is difficult for the organization to pursue a technology
To examine the different roles of established and new firms that is highly risky, potentially competitive to its own products,
in disruptive technology commercialization, we begin by devel- and difficult to market since applications are in unfamiliar
oping a model of the innovation process beginning with tech- industries [10].
nology creation and ending with user adoption and application. Bower and Christensen note that new firms have not estab-
This model allows us to develop several propositions about the lished core competencies or a bevy of loyal customers. Thus,
WALSH et al.: DIFFERENTIATING MARKET STRATEGIES FOR DISRUPTIVE TECHNOLOGIES 343

Fig. 1. Disruptive technology innovation model.

such firms are free to tackle high risk technologies and unfa- Disruptive Technology: Bower and Christensen [10] note
miliar markets. Furthermore, they can be highly focused on one that disruptive technologies may not be “ radically new from
technology while having relatively low operating costs com- a technological point of view” but have superior “performance
pared to a corporate department or division. This is why they trajectories” along critical dimensions that customers value.
recommend that disruptive technologies be given to new in- Abernathy and Clark [2] do not agree on this point. They
dependent firms. In this way, these new firms adopt technolo- argue that, due to disruptive technologies’ radical newness
gies from one industry and apply it in another, i.e., exogenous or emergent character, robust manufacturing infrastructure
technologies. Schumpeter [34] observed that innovations with a does not exist or is very limited in any commercial firm or
major impact upon economic activity originate from outside the industrial setting [43]. Further, Anderson, and Tushman [5]
industry that they affect. His observations agree with those of evolve from Abernathy and Clark [2] and others discussing an
Bower and Christensen. Schumpeter also argues that these in- “era of ferment” when a new technology product paradigms
novations emerge from and become the reason for the formation are vying to become the industry dominant design. Measuring
of new independent firms, i.e., entrepreneurship. To the extent and managing these technologies are difficult [9]. Actually,
that Schumpeterian product innovations are technology based, a careful comparison of the two differing views reveals that
he argues that new independent firms are well suited to bring disruptive technologies have alternative forms. In other words,
innovations from outside the existing industry structure and cre- the theorists agree that both forms of disruptive technologies
atively destroy the market structure therein [34]. exist.
In practice, such technologies are not always best developed On the other hand, it is apparent that disruptive technologies
by “spin-offs” from an established firm as suggested by Bower and their discontinuous innovations are important to economic
and Christensen [10]. Technologies also are obtained by license progress. Schumpeter [34] describes capitalism as an economic
or purchase by a new independent firm from an inventor, an system that finds its competitive strength in innovation that
R&D department in an established corporation, or a university creates new demand in new markets while destroying old
laboratory. Either way, disruptive technologies are only recog- existing markets based on older technology. This product
nized after they have been commercialized and have major im- innovative activity Schumpeter calls “creative destruction”
pact upon the market. Thus, early stage sources of inventions is clearly driven by what we call disruptive technologies.
are rarely considered important until their roles in this process Abernathy and Utterback [1] confirm this as they describe
become apparent as the new independent firm achieves success. disruptive technologies as those that create entirely new
technology-product-market paradigms that create new to the
B. Technology Focus world markets that may be opaque to customers. Opaqueness,
Morone [30], Bower and Christensen [10], Bitindo and they note, constrains customer enthusiasm for varying their
Frohman [8], Florida and Kenney [16], Marquis [26], Meyers established behavioral habits.
and Tucker [28], SEST-Euroconsult [36], Utterback [40], and The inventions that emerge from disruptive technologies
many others identify two classes of technology: 1) disruptive, are called discontinuous innovations and present problems to
radical, emergent or step-function technologies, or alternatively, the firms that commercialize them [20], [33]. The inventions
2) evolutionary, sustaining, incremental or “nuts and bolts” based upon disruptive technologies create a growth paradox
technologies. We will use the terms disruptive and evolutionary. [21]. They create challenges to the marketing process since
344 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON ENGINEERING MANAGEMENT, VOL. 49, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2002

the inventions require users to change their behaviors to gain continue to evolve products from them to remain competitive
the advantages the technologies have to offer [25], [41], [29]. in rapidly changing markets.
Moore [29] has described the process of overcoming customer
objections to the change inherent in adopting a discontinuous C. Innovation Type
innovation as “crossing the chasm” by defining differing value
Innovation, by definition, means the commercialization of
propositions that provide enough benefit to overcome resis-
invention [34]. Commercialization is widely perceived as the
tance to change. The mechanism for overcoming buyer/user
process of bringing a product or service into working user ap-
resistance to adopting disruptive technologies is demonstrating
plications. This is heavily dependent upon the process widely
that such technologies provide significant cost reductions
referred to as marketing. Creating the innovative product that
and/or performance improvements. In this way, customers are
can be sold is the most difficult step in converting a technology
found who are willing to take the risks of newness [27]. But,
into an innovation.
customers are not usually resident in single-product/single-in-
There are two types of innovations: discontinuous and
dustry markets and truly disruptive technologies find uses in
continuous. Discontinuous innovations evolve from disruptive
many different markets in “lead user” groups [42].
technology. Continuous innovations evolve from evolutionary
Disruptive technologies create a sustainable competitive
technology. Many theorists argue that discontinuous inno-
advantage because they are based upon new technologies and
vations embody the technology characteristics that make it
new inventions derived there from [19]. Such technologies and
difficult for buyers to adopt the innovative product. However,
inventions carry intellectual property protection that may last
that depends upon the market strategy adopted by the firm that
the life of a patent or copyright, thereby providing a sustainable
controls the technology. In fact, since the processes of product
competitive advantage. But, they also provide proprietary
development, marketing strategy and user application type are
markets for evolutionary technologies. Once user behaviors
not linear, it is best to treat all three steps of the model at once.
are changed, the new technology becomes part of their regular
This we will do.
behavior patterns. As users identify new needs, evolutionary
technologies emerge from the disruptive technology base
and these are used to support research to create continuous D. Factors Underlying the Innovation/Strategy/User
innovations that satisfy these emerging needs of users. In this Application Mix
way, a disruptive technology leads to a stream of evolutionary The innovation /strategy/user application mix is primarily de-
technologies. Evolutionary technologies produce continuous pendent on whether the technology is evolutionary or disrup-
innovations that constantly update and improve the current tive. However, these technology types are more important in
usefulness of the disruptive technology based products [10], designating whether or not the supplier has existing customers.
[29]. Therefore, we will concentrate on the firms with established
Evolutionary Technologies: Evolutionary technologies customer bases first and then on new firms that have no estab-
improve incrementally from a body of existing knowledge [17]. lished customers. However, before we begin the analysis of dif-
Bower and Christensen [10] call evolutionary technologies ferent types of firms, we begin with a review of theory regarding
“sustaining technologies,” that is technologies that sustain the different market strategies.
current manufacturing practices and technological capabilities Strategies and Learning Theory: Most of the literature
required in an industrial setting. We choose to use the term linking learning theory to strategic theory stresses the dif-
“evolutionary” rather than the term “sustaining” because the ficulties in handling a disruptive technology rather than the
latter does not capture the continuously changing nature of opportunities they provide to the organizations that embrace
technology that actually characterizes the technology process. them. Argyris and Schon [6] and Senge [35] provide us with the
Evolutionary technologies create innovations that are modifi- idea of double loop learning when a firm embraces a “radical”
cations of, improvements to, or replacements for existing prod- change versus easier single loop learning when embracing
ucts. These are called continuous innovations (Morone, 1995). incremental change. Similarly, strategic literature stresses
Evolutionary technologies often change incrementally moving “strategic flexibility” and the development of “dynamic capa-
from the simple to the more complex. Evolutionary technolo- bilities” in response to disruptive change. Strategic flexibility
gies do not alter markets the way that disruptive technologies allows an organization to embrace or eschew dynamic and
do as they do not require users to significantly change their be- discontinuous developments in the firm’s environment [11]
havior. Instead, evolutionary technologies often are driven by focusing on the difficulties the firm experiences in this process.
customer demand for improvements of existing products; im- Similarly, the idea of building dynamic capabilities in the firm
provements make better products that fit current customer be- [37] and [15] to respond to technological change provide the
haviors (Morone, 1995). firm with an ability to use resources to keep up with or create
Typically, evolutionary technologies emerge from a dis- market change. This provides firms a resource configuration
continuous innovation which, when successful, creates its that provides options of reacting to or developing an environ-
own market for follow-on continuous innovations that provide mental change for a firm-based competitive advantage.
improvements and upgrades of customer based products. Two Categories of Market Strategies: Thus learning theory
In this way, companies that build on proprietary disruptive gives us a rationale for understanding the interrelationship of
technologies, evolve them into evolutionary technologies and environment characteristics and firm resources that explains the
WALSH et al.: DIFFERENTIATING MARKET STRATEGIES FOR DISRUPTIVE TECHNOLOGIES 345

dual origins of innovations. Innovations may arise from tech- are constrained by this limitation and face resistance from
nological development on its own accord or from buyer de- potential users to adopt their inventions derived from disruptive
mands that motivate technological development. Madiquis [26] technologies. New firm commercialization of discontinuous
addresses this issue in his model of the innovation process that innovations requires different activities and different time
focuses on the effects of discontinuous innovation. In the first periods for actions. Such activities can be characterized as
stage of the Madiquis model, called idea recognition, the source technology-push commercialization. The marketing effort is
of innovation is deemed to come either from the recognition of seen as risky, expensive, and subject to high rates of failure
technological feasibility, that is a “technology push,” or from as new firms push their technologies on resistant potential
the recognition of potential demand, also known as “market users [12]. For this reason, most theorists perceive customer
or buyer pull.” These two distinctions are also evident in eco- resistance as a major barrier to disruptive technology transfer.
nomic theory of entrepreneurial innovation where Kirzner [23] Moreover, a pure technology-push market strategy entails a
hypothesizes that market conditions “pull” entrepreneurs into long sales effort with few early adopters [29], [10].
markets by creating excess profit opportunities. On the other However, anecdotal evidence suggests an alternative mar-
hand, Schumpeter [34] theorizes that entrepreneurs destroy ex- keting approach is often used to reduce the risk, cost, and
isting markets by forcibly entering with inventions of their own failure potential. Since new firms have no established cus-
creation. Theoretically, then, it seems likely that innovations can tomer base, they are free to search for applications of their
occur for either reason. technologies among existing needs of a wide variety of po-
Thus, there are two alternative market strategies to be applied tential customers in multiple industries. The corollary to this
to our innovation model. In practice, these two represent ex- logic is that new firms may find their greatest market advan-
tremes at either end of a continuous scale from technology push tage through offering proprietary disruptive technologies to
to market pull. established customers of established firms. The commercial-
Firms With an Established Customer Base: As noted ization strategy is to seek an entirely new (to the firm) set
earlier, Bower and Christensen [10] perceived that firms with of customers to adopt the firm’s proprietary technology as a
an established customer base seem to have an advantage in replacement or enhancement to the existing products of the
the offering new products to users. Where existing users are dominant firms in an industry; in this way, new firms can build
accustomed to working with the supplier/manufacturer, the link a customer base rather quickly. In other words, they use the
between the user and manufacturer has become very strong buyer-pull market strategy modifying their innovations into
since the installed base and switching costs make the customer user-friendly mechanisms to improve or replace existing prod-
dependent on the manufacturer [1]. Furthermore, the users are ucts of established competitors. This strategy is lower risk,
well aware of additional improvements and or replacements that lower cost, and may provide both a customer base and the
are needed for the products to better serve their needs. Thus, revenue receipts necessary to launch a full technology-push
users are always clamoring for this or that innovation to meet market strategy for a truly discontinuous innovation based
their specific needs and suppliers need only respond to these upon disruptive technology.
buyer demands to remain in a profitable business. The stream Four Technology Strategy Mixes: The advantages of com-
of evolutionary technologies/continuous innovations that flow mercializing disruptive technologies may well offset the greater
from the core competencies built from long-term R&D will risks, costs, and initial longer term return on investment. How-
tie the customer to the supplier’s continuous innovations for ever, as observed by Bower and Christensen [10] and expanded
many years and create a stream of profits for the supplier. True upon by Christensen [45] there remains a strong tendency for
market-pull innovations provide replacements, or substitutes, established firms to resist doing this, so much so these authors
for existing products. Such new products are quickly adopted argue, that it can best be done by new independent firms. Yet, it
by existing customers if the replacements have clear price, cost is apparent that technologies are not easily defined as disruptive
saving, and/or quality advantages over existing products. or evolutionary as no one has been able to define a technology
Occasionally R&D will produce a unique invention that as disruptive until after it has been commercialized long enough
builds on the core competence but does not respond to a known to demonstrate major market share changes.
user need. Such innovations may even require changes in cus- At the same time, experience has demonstrated that early
tomers’ behavior. These innovations will require considerably commercialization of disruptive technologies often occurs as re-
more marketing and sales efforts. As long as the new products placements or substitutes for existing applications where the be-
do not require substantial changes in customer behavior, derive havior change of the users is modest by strategic intent when
from the well known and trusted evolutionary technology base, suppliers of the technology choose market strategies that em-
and offer significant cost and/or quality improvements, existing phasize identification of an existing buyer need and adoption of
customers will gradually adopt the new technology. In such the invention to this need.
situations, the supplier organizes a special marketing effort to This section has described applications of the tech-
“push” this invention onto the users. Since the technological nology-push and market-pull theories of technology transfer
base is similar or identical to the existing products, the tech- adjusting for the two types of technologies. As a result, our
nology-push effort if properly designed is usually successful in model displays four technology/market strategy typologies, two
a relatively short time frame. for each technology category and market strategy. These are:
The Uniqueness of New Firms: New firms have no in- 1) continuous innovations/market-pull strategies; 2) continuous
stalled base nor established customer relationships. They innovations/technology-push strategies; 3) discontinuous
346 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON ENGINEERING MANAGEMENT, VOL. 49, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2002

innovations/market-pull strategies; and 4) discontinuous inno- In addition, we know new firms must have commercialization
vations/technology-push strategies. advantages over established firms. Christensen [45] and Bower
and Christensen [10] argue that new firms have the advantage
E. Summary of the Model of acting quickly so that they can be faster to the market with
new products.
Clearly, research that creates disruptive technologies and ex- Proposition5: New firms will have shorter times spans from
pands technological competencies is fundamental to long-term R&D to market than established firms.
core competence and the competitive advantage. Either a tech-
nology-push commercialization model or a market-pull strategy
IV. EMPIRICAL RESEARCH METHODOLOGY
can be used to gain sustainable competitive advantage.
Still, the common element among both discontinuous and We chose to draw our survey responses from a new industry
continuous innovations is the use of technical personnel to that appears to be emerging from within several other ex-
create marketable products from technologies. Thus, the isting industries with the addition of disruptive manufacturing
technical specialists’ knowledge and skills are applicable to (process) technologies unique to itself. We begin this section
both discontinuous and continuous innovations even though with a brief description of the MEMS technology including
the eventual product applications require different approaches defining three main manufacturing methods. We then describe
to market timing and marketing techniques. results from our survey instrument containing a series of ques-
tions that ask: 1) the firm to define for its first commercialized
product the manufacturing method(s) used; 2) firm resident
III. PROPOSITIONS FOR TESTING distinctive technologies (competencies) and core capabilities
possessed; and 3) whether market-pull or technology-push
To systematically investigate the difference in approach to
dominated product introduction. In addition, demographic
commercialization of technologies offered by established and
information was obtained including establishment and firm age
new firms, we carried out a survey of upper level managers
and size (number of employees). The firm (not the establish-
and owner/founders of the micro-electro-mechanical systems
ment) is defined as the ownership unit of the respondent.1
(MEMS) manufacturing industry. We developed three proposi-
tions to guide the creation of our survey instrument.
A. Microsystems Technologies Description
Based upon Bower and Christiansen’s [10] description of new
independent firms’ advantages in major discontinuous innova- Microsystems technologies are alternatively identified as
tion and their perception that established firms’ R&D is captive MEMS, Microsystems Technologies, or Micro Machined
to existing customers, our first two propositions are as follows. Technologies. The differing nomenclature used to describe
Proposition 1: Established firms will primarily commer- MEMS technologies reflects not only its emergent nature but
cialize evolutionary technologies. also both regional preference and technological scope. MEMS
Since new firms have no existing customers and new tech- technologies are a relatively new and emerging technology
nology is their primary competitive advantage, Proposition 2 is mainly based upon sophisticated manipulations of the same
as follows. silicon used in electronic devices such as RAM memory chips,
Proposition 2: New firms will primarily commercialize dis- micro-processor chips, and a host of others. Instead of molding
ruptive technologies. plastic parts or machining metal to produce products, MEMS
Even if a disruptive technology emerges from R&D, the influ- devices are made by using some of the same processes used
ence of existing customers upon established firms’ innovation to create microelectronic components but other techniques,
commercialization strategies suggests established firms will use radically different than microelectronic techniques, are added
market-pull strategies. that create micromachines in the silicon base material that can
Proposition 3: Established firms will primarily use disrup- communicate with the electronic properties of the material.
tive technologies to respond to market-pull strategies (improve- Thus, the following three basic MEMS process technologies
ments and/or replacement products). characteristics described below suggest they are probable
Proposition 4 derives from the likelihood that new firms’ disruptive technologies.
managers seek to establish a unique sustainable competitive Microsystems technologies can be categorized into three
position, a position that is based upon an intellectual property basic manufacturing technologies: 1) high aspect ratio mi-
protected disruptive technology. Ultimately, the greatest value cromachining (HARM); 2) bulk micromachining (BM); and
can be extracted from a disruptive technology through a creative 3) sacrificial surface micromachining (SSM) [44]. These three
destroying innovation pushed upon skeptical customers. production methods are frequently described as mutually
Proposition 4: New firms primarily develop technology- exclusive technological substitutes but in the future are more
push applications of disruptive technologies. likely to become complementary rather than competing man-
However, as noted earlier, the new firm may turn to supplying ufacturing technologies. Interestingly, to our knowledge, no
replacement or substitute products to users of existing compet-
itive products so as to generate revenues that will be used to
1A firm is a unit of ownership. An establishment is a place of work. For ex-
support their R&D work toward the creative destroying innova-
ample, General Motors is a single firm that owns almost 1000 establishments
tion. Such actions will dilute the appearance of technology-push including manufacturing plants, sales offices, training centers, and even loan of-
activity and cause rejection of Proposition 4. fices (GMAC).
WALSH et al.: DIFFERENTIATING MARKET STRATEGIES FOR DISRUPTIVE TECHNOLOGIES 347

obvious disruptive technology-based discontinuous innovation TABLE I


with creative destruction potential is yet apparent. However, DESCRIPTION OF SURVEY RESPONDENTS
given the typical technology evolutionary time period, it is still
early in the technology process for a truly market destroying
innovation to appear [34].

B. Survey Methodology
The goal of our survey was to establish a baseline for a lon-
gitudinal study to better understand the behavior of firms in an
emerging technology area. Toward this goal, we began with a
survey distributed to managers/owners of all firms that defined
themselves as active in this industry. The mechanism for iden-
tifying these firms was their attendance at the Fourth MEMS Operationalizing Technology Type: MEMS is a manu-
Commercialization Conference held in September, 2000. Over facturing or process technology intensive product. There are
400 representatives from MEMS firms, government research technology subcategories within the three main manufacturing
labs, university research labs, suppliers, consultants, etc., from technologies. We could not expect the survey respondents
locations all over the world attended this conference. The ques- to understand the theoretical concepts of evolutionary and
tionnaire was distributed at the conferences and 74 of the 104 disruptive technologies, and therefore, to determine technology
(71.1%) firms in attendance responded. Of these, only 62 pro- type, the questionnaire contains a list of 21 known technologies
vided complete responses. This gave us a 59.6% response rate. used in MEMS production world wide. This list was prepared
This lower than expected response rate may be due to the fact by one of the authors and reviewed by a panel of 15 other
that many firms at the conference had not commercialized their experts. This panel classified the technologies into those that
first MEMS products as yet. are entirely new to MEMS and those that evolved from the
The survey instrument consists of nine pages. The first page microelectronics industry or another related industry. Given
consists of basic demographic information on the firm. The re- the specific nature of and unambiguous terminology used for
maining eight pages consist of four pages of evaluative ques- the technologies, very high agreement occurred among the
tions using a ten point Likert scale on a “not at all important” to experts. Those that are entirely new to MEMS were defined
“critically important” evaluation scheme. The other four pages as disruptive technologies (four). Fourteen were defined as
ask for specific information on manufacturing costs, product evolutionary technologies. Three were classified as neither but
mix, R&D expenditures, and markets. This latter information as well-known technologies from outside the microelectronics
has not been applied herein.2 industry and were not included in the following analysis.
Operationalizing the Newness: The literature on innovation Respondents were asked to rate the importance of each of the
frequently uses firm size as a surrogate for firm newness [3] 21 technological production methods that fall within the three
[13] [7] [4] [22]. Age and size are found to be highly correlated basic categories described above on a ten point Likert scale. A
among technology intensive small firms but not among large summary score for disruptive technology was calculated as the
established firms. And in our survey, we found that managers of mean score for the four disruptive technology methods. A mean
large established firms often do not know the age of their firm. was also calculated for the fourteen evolutionary technology
Therefore, we chose to use firm size as the variable to separate methods. Given that the production of any MEMS product may
new from established firms. Table I describes respondent firms combine a mix of both disruptive and evolutionary technologies,
by size where we chose the size of fewer than 100 employees to we created a “technology score” by subtracting the mean of the
define new firms. disruptive technology four items from the mean of the evolu-
The basis for determining size was the size of the firm, i.e., tionary technology fourteen items. O’Rielly and Chatman [31],
overall ownership organization of the respondent. In other served as the example for using this scoring method for com-
words, if the respondent’s MEMS producing organization was puting a summary technology score. Firms with positive scores
independently owned and employed 100 or fewer workers, it are classified as using evolutionary technologies. Firms with
was defined as new. If the firm was owned by another and/or negative scores are classified as using disruptive technologies.
the combined employment was over 100, the firm was defined
as established. C. Operationalizing Market Strategies
The firms included in the set of complete responses have ex-
isting commercial products and/or marketable prototypes and The survey asked respondents to describe their reasons for
therefore we assume that they validly represent active industry creating their first fully developed and produced MEMS device.
participants that have commercialized a MEMS product. The There are seven items in this section, four designed to measure
respondents had as few as one microsystems-based product, or a strategy focus on technology and three to measure a strategy
as many as seventy such products, but the median and mode focus on market demand. To assure ourselves that these items
number of products per firm was five. measured two relatively independent aspects of strategy focus,
we factor analyzed the survey results using principal compo-
2Inspection copies of the copyrighted survey instrument are available from nents and varimax rotation. A list of the items and their factor
author Bruce A. Kirchhoff. loadings are shown in Table II. Apparently our survey design
348 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON ENGINEERING MANAGEMENT, VOL. 49, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2002

TABLE II
FACTOR ANALYSIS RESULTS: STRATEGY ITEMS (n = 62)

was appropriate as two clean factors appear, thereby suggesting TABLE III
NUMBER OF FIRMS BY STRATEGY AND TECHNOLOGY (n = 62)
content validity of our selected items and suggesting our con-
cept of market-pull and technology-push strategies is a real part
of MEMS technology firms.
However, it is probable that some, perhaps all, firms use
some combination of market-pull and technology-push strate-
gies. Therefore, we created a single scale value for strategy of
each firm by subtracting the mean of the firm’s Likert scale
scores on the four technology-push items from the mean of the
firm’s Likert scale scores of the three market-pull items. Then,
firms with positive scores were classified as having market-pull
strategy and firms with negative scores were classified as
having technology-push strategies.

V. RESULTS
TABLE IV
Two strategy classes and the two technology classes serve as STRATEGY AND TECHNOLOGY COMPARISON BY FIRM SIZE
the basis for testing of our propositions. The distribution of the
firms among the four cells is shown in Table III.

A. Testing the Propositions


Table IV shows the 62 firms divided into the four
strategy/technology cells and separated into two columns
by new and established firm. The analysis of this matrix shows
that the differences among the cells although numerically
small are statistically significant. These tests are itemized at
the bottom of the table and show statistical significance of
or better.
Proposition 1 states that established firms will primarily com-
mercialize evolutionary technologies. As can be seen, 71.4%
(30) of the established firms commercialized evolutionary tech-
nologies and only 28.6% (12) of the established firms com-
mercialized disruptive technologies. Proposition 2 states that (35%, 7 firms) of new firms used market-pull strategies. Thus,
new firms will primarily commercialize disruptive technologies. our data analysis confirms Proposition 3 but not Proposition 4.
This is not strongly supported by our findings for although 60% All in all, new firms do not show a preference for disruptive
(12) of the new firms commercialized disruptive technologies, technologies with half of the firms choosing evolutionary
40.0% (8) commercialized evolutionary technologies. This is and half choosing disruptive technologies. And, among
not a statistically significant finding. those choosing disruptive technologies, the majority prefer
Proposition 3 states that established firms will primarily use market-pull strategies. This suggests that our belief that that
market-pull strategies to commercialize disruptive technolo- the majority of new firms choose disruptive technologies to
gies. Table IV confirms this proposition since 21.4% (9) of the enter markets because these provide a sustainable competitive
firms used market-pull strategies with disruptive technologies, advantage is incorrect. Perhaps new firms seek the necessary
only 7.1% (3) firms used technology-push strategies. However, revenue for survival first through meeting existing defined
for new firms, Proposition 4 is not confirmed. Rather than new market needs and only later commercialize creative destroying
firms primarily using technology-push strategies to commer- innovations. This should not surprise us for we are not aware
cialize disruptive technologies (25%, 5 firms), the majority of any truly creative destroying MEMS innovation that has
WALSH et al.: DIFFERENTIATING MARKET STRATEGIES FOR DISRUPTIVE TECHNOLOGIES 349

TABLE V
QUESTIONNAIRE ITEMS DEFINING MEMS LIFE CYCLE DESCRIPTIONS

yet entered the market place. Thus, we should expect that TABLE VI
new MEMS firms would have found other ways to fund their CYCLE TIME COMPARISON BY FIRM SIZE

existence. For example, in the 1980s, the U.S. automobile com-


panies were required to install air bags in all their automobiles.
Existing mechanical technology was expensive, large, and
heavy. What was needed was something small, inexpensive,
durable, and reliable. Market demand existed and was widely
known. The need was clearly apparent. MEMS technology
satisfied this demand. All that was necessary was to perfect the
manufacturing and prove the durability and reliability of this
new technology. A hard sell, but MEMS delivered what was
needed and made it economical to install two, three, or even six
or more airbags in every car. This was one of the earliest mass
applications of MEMS technology with millions sold annually
today. But there are many firms manufacturing this product
today since there is no proprietary product technology.
Testing Proposition Five: So, what advantages do new firms
have that draws them into commercialization of technologies?
that it is a major advantage that new firms have in technology
One item we sought to check was the time from product idea
commercialization. And, time is money.
development to sale of the first unit. We asked survey questions
to define three separate phases of the overall “concept to sale”
VI. CONCLUSION
cycle to see whether new firms excel and if so at what phase of
the process. Table V describes the questionnaire items that were Clearly, we have positive evidence supporting our proposi-
used to define the three phases of the cycle. tions about established firms. They tend to emphasize commer-
We requested that respondents provide months and years cialization of evolutionary technologies and prefer market-pull
when answering these questions. The number of firms an- strategies for the majority of their technologies. They especially
swering each phase differs. There is a decline in number eschew technology-push strategies for disruptive technologies.
of responses between the first and third phase suggesting This is not surprising and fits the pattern so many writers on in-
that some of the responding firms are not yet in the revenue novation have described.
generating phase. We included all respondents that answered However, our findings about new firms seem consistent with
each phase. Table VI shows the mean response for new and Bower and Christensen’s [10] conclusions that new small firms
established firms including the number of respondents and a are better able to commercialize disruptive technologies than
test for differences between means in each phase. established firms. Certainly a greater percentage of new firms
From Table VI, it can be seen that in all phases, the magni- commercialize, or attempt to commercialize, disruptive tech-
tude of the differences are huge; established firms require two nologies than do established firms. But, they use market-pull
to three times as long as new firms. But the small sample sizes strategies more often than technology-push strategies to do
and the large variances make Phase 1, idea to first expenditure, this. And, new firms also commercialize evolutionary tech-
and Phase 3, prototype to first sale, the only phases where the nologies and by using both market strategies, slightly favoring
differences are statistically significant at 0.05 or less. The full technology push. Yet, new firms certainly have a significant
cycle analysis shows differences of established firms 2.4 times advantage in time to market. This clearly is a strength that
(greater than two years) more than new firms and it is nearly sig- many innovation writers have noted.
nificant at the 0.05 level. Clearly, cycle time from idea to first But the real world of technological innovation is not as neat
sale is much, much shorter for new firms that for established as Bower and Christianson’s theory. New firms are faster at
firms. bringing ideas into innovations and selling them. But our data
Thus, it is likely that the time required for an idea to become and analysis tells us that they are equally likely to find existing
revenue is so much shorter for new firms than established firms market needs and to bend their disruptive technologies to meet
350 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON ENGINEERING MANAGEMENT, VOL. 49, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2002

these needs as to push their new technology on stoic buyers [3] Z. J. Acs and D. Audretsch, Innovation and Small Firms. Cambridge,
who resist changing their behavior. Surprisingly, the lack of an MA: MIT Press, 1990.
[4] M. Almus and E. A. Nerlinger, “Growth of new technology based
established customer base is an advantage for the new firms firms: Which factors matter?,” Small Business Economics, vol. 13, pp.
attempting to market their new technology. Unfettered by de- 141–154, 1999.
mands from existing customers for improvements on existing [5] P. Anderson and M. Tushman, “Technological discontinuities and domi-
nant designs: A cyclical model of technological change,” Administrative
products based upon evolutionary technologies, new firms can Sci. Quart., vol. 35, no. 6, pp. 604–633, 1990.
be flexible about to whom they chose to sell and what applica- [6] C. Argyris and D. Schon, Organizational Change. Reading, MA: Ad-
tions can be profitably produced and sold. It is this flexibility dison-Wesley, 1978.
[7] D. B. Audrestsch, Innovation and Industry Evolution. Cambridge,
that probably underlies the much smaller cycle time in “proto- MA: MIT Press, 1995.
type to first sale.” [8] D. Bitindo and A. Frohman, “Linking technological and business plan-
Apparently, new firm behavior is less predictable than that of ning,” Res. Management, pp. 19–23, Nov. 1981.
[9] R. E. Bohn, “Measuring and managing technological knowledge,” Sloan
established firms. New firms are not as well understood and de- Management Rev., vol. 36, no. 3, pp. 61–73, Fall 1994.
serve more attention since they are obviously the firms that will [10] J. L. Bower and C. M. Christensen, “Disruptive technologies: Catching
fulfill the promises of disruptive technologies and creative de- the wave,” Harvard Business Rev., pp. 43–53, Jan.–Feb. 1995.
[11] S. Brown and K. Eisenhardt, “Product development: Past research,
struction. Research on new firms and technology commercial- present findings and future directions,” Acad. Management Rev., vol.
ization is badly needed. 20, pp. 343–378, 1995.
We are continuing to conduct surveys of firms in the MEMS [12] P. Carroad and C. Carroad, “Strategic interfacing of R&D and mar-
keting,” Res. Technol. Management, vol. 25, no. 1, pp. 28–33, 1962.
industry year after year in hope of having rich data when the [13] A. C. Cooper and C. G. Smith, “How established firms respond to threat-
big creative destroying innovation emerges from this new tech- ening technologies,” Acad. Management Executive, vol. 6, no. 2, pp.
nology either through new firms or established firms. But, we 55–70, 1992.
[14] E. Ehrenberg, “On the definition and measurement of technological dis-
are researching only one industry. Other researchers should find continuities,” Technovation, vol. 15, no. 7, pp. 437–452, 1995.
similar new industries with potentially disruptive technologies [15] K. Eisenhardt and J. Martin, “Dynamic capabilities: What are they?,”
and begin to track them into the future. Strategic Management J., vol. 21, pp. 1105–1121, 2000.
[16] R. Florida and M. Kenney, The Breakthrough Illusion. New York:
We must caution the reader that our research reported here Basic, 1990.
does not measure success of commercialization by new firms. [17] R. N. Foster, “Timing technological transitions,” in Readings in the
Our survey does not include any firms that started and failed to Management of Innovation, 2nd ed, M. L. Tushman and W. Moore,
Eds: Ballinger, 1986, pp. 215–228.
succeed but only those successful enough to continue in busi- [18] , Innovation: The Attacker’s Advantage. New York: McKinsey,
ness. Kirchhoff [22] researched all firms formed in the U.S. 1996.
during 1977–1978 and estimated the failure rate, after adjusting [19] A. Glasmeier, “Technological discontinuities and flexible production
networks: The case of switzerland and the world watch industry,” Res.
for mergers and acquisitions, at approximately 40% to 50% after Policy, vol. 20, no. 5, pp. 469–485, 1991.
six years. [20] R. H. Hayes and R. Jakimar, “Manufacturing crisis: New technologies,
Furthermore, readers need to be cautious about our use of firm obsolete organizations,” Harvard Business Rev., vol. 66, no. 5, pp.
77–85, 1988.
size as an appropriate indicator of firm newness. In his research, [21] S. M. Kaplan, “Discontinuous innovation and the growth paradox,”
Kirchhoff [22] concluded that employment at over 50% of new Strategy Leadership, vol. 27, no. 2, pp. 16–21, 1999.
firms does not grow at all during the first six years of life. Fur- [22] B. A. Kirchhoff, Entrepreneurship and Dynamic Capi-
talism. Greenwood, CT: Praeger, 1994.
thermore, for those new firms in highly innovative industries, [23] I. M. Kirzner, Perception, Opportunity, and Profit: Studies in the Theory
there is a greater six-year failure rate among firms whose sales of Entrepreneurship. Chicago, IL: Univ. Chicago Press, 1979.
revenue is stagnant. Thus, we might expect that new firms that [24] C. Lambe and R. E. Spekman, “Alliances, external technology acqui-
sition, and discontinuous technological change,” J. Product Innovation
have grown beyond their start up team are actually older than Management, vol. 14, no. 2, pp. 102–116, 1997.
other firms of the same size that started with a larger start up [25] G. Lynn, J. Morone, and A. Paulson, “Marketing and discontinuous in-
team. So size may not be correlated with age as it appears to be novation: The probe and learn process,” California Management Rev.,
vol. 38, no. 3, pp. 8–37, 1996.
in this small sample. If age is not a significant measure of what [26] D. M. Madiquis, “The anatomy of successful innovations,” Managing
is meant by “new firm,” then our size measure may have dis- Advancing Technol., vol. 1, pp. 38–48, 1969.
torted our results. Future research should develop more careful [27] E. Mansfield, The Economics of Technological Change. New York:
W.W. Norton, 1968a.
measures of firm age, a very difficult variable to measure unless [28] P. Meyers and F. Tucker, “Defining roles for logistics during routine and
one asks one or more founders of a firm. This is because a new radical technological innovation,” J. Academy Marketing Sciences, vol.
firm may be formed with every change in majority ownership 17, no. 1, pp. 73–82, 1989.
[29] G. A. Moore, Crossing the Chasm. New York: Harper Collins, 1991.
of the same legal entity; venture capitalists may take control, or [30] J. Morone, Winning in High Tech Markets. Boston, MA: Harvard Busi-
the firm may merge with another or be acquired. When does a ness School Press, 1993.
firm “really” begin operations? It is difficult to find a reliable [31] C. A. O’Reilly and J. A. Chatman, “Working smarter and harder: A lon-
gitudinal study of managerial success,” Administrative Sci. Quart., vol.
methodology to answer to this question. 39, pp. 603–627.
[32] C. K. Prahalad and G. Hamel, “Corporate imagination and expeditionary
marketing,” Harvard Business Rev., pp. 81–92, July–Aug. 1991.
REFERENCES [33] M. P. Rice, G. C. O’Connor, L. S. Peters, and J. G. Morone, “Managing
[1] W. J. Abernathy and J. M. Utterback, “Patterns of industrial innovation,” discontinuous innovations,” Res. Technol. Management, vol. 41, no. 3,
in Readings in the Management of Innovation, 2nd ed., M. L. Tushman pp. 52–58, 1998.
and W. Moore, Eds. Ballinger, 1988, pp. 25–36. [34] J. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York:
[2] W. J. Abernathy and K. B. Clark, “Innovation: Mapping the winds of Harper and Row, 1942.
creative destruction,” Res. Policy, vol. 14, pp. 3–22, 1985. [35] P. M. Senge, The Fifth Discipline. New York: Doubleday, 1990.
WALSH et al.: DIFFERENTIATING MARKET STRATEGIES FOR DISRUPTIVE TECHNOLOGIES 351

[36] “Le Bonzai de I’industrie Japonais, Elements de Reflexion sur L’integre- Bruce A. Kirchhoff received the B.S. degree in chemical engineering from the
tion de Technologie Dans la Function Strategique des Enteprises Japon- Case Institute of Technology and the M.B.A. and Ph.D. degree in business ad-
aises,” French Ministry of Res. Technol., 1984. ministration (with a concentration on finance, economics, management, and sta-
[37] D. Teece, G. Pisano, and A. Shuen, “Dynamic capabilities and strategic tistics) from the University of Utah, Salt Lake City.
management,” Strategic Management J., vol. 18, pp. 509–533, 1997. Prior to receiving the Ph.D. degree, he spent seven years in sales and mar-
[38] M. L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, “Organizational determinants of tech- keting and three years as area manager of international operations for Envirotech
nological change: Toward a sociology of technological evolution,” Res. Corporation. He is currently a Distinguished Professor of Entrepreneurship and
Organizational Behavior, vol. 14, pp. 311–347, 1992. Director of the Technological Entrepreneurship Program, New Jersey Institute
[39] M. L. Tushman, P. C. Anderson, and C. O’Reilly, “Technology cycles, of Technology, Newark, NJ. His prior credentials include service as Chief Econ-
innovation streams, ambidextrous organizations: Organizational re- omist for the U.S. Small Business Administration and as Assistant Director of
newal through innovation streams and strategic change,” in Managing the Minority Business Development Agency, U.S. Department of Commerce.
Strategic Innovation and Change, Tushman and Anderson, Eds. New He was Director of the Center for Entrepreneurship and Public Policy, Fair-
York: Oxford Univ. Press, 1997. leigh Dickinson University, and Director of Research in the Entrepreneurship
[40] J. Utterback, Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation. Boston, MA: Center, Babson College. He also served on the faculties of Chalmers University
Harvard Business School Press, 1994. of Technology; Jonkoping International Business School of Sweden; the Uni-
[41] R. Veryzer, “Discontinuous innovation and the new product develop- versity of Nebraska, Omaha; Purdue University; California Polytechnic State
ment process,” J. Product Innovation Management, vol. 15, no. 4, pp. University; and the University of Utah. He has authored over 100 published
304–321, 1998. articles and papers on entrepreneurship, economic development, and business
[42] E. Von Hippel, “Lead users: A source of novel product concepts,” in strategy in a variety of academic journals, books, trade and popular media. His
Readings in the Management of Innovation, 2nd ed., M. L. Tushman book, Entrepreneurship and Dynamic Capitalism: The Economics of Business
and W. Moore, Eds. Ballinger, 1986, pp. 352–366. Firm Foundation and Growth (Westport, CT: Praeger, 1994), describes how en-
[43] S. Walsh and J. Linton, “Infrastructure for emerging markets based on trepreneurship contributes to economic growth. He was recently cited by INC
discontinuous innovations: Implications for strategy and policy makers,” magazine as one of the 16 outstanding entrepreneurship researchers in the U.S.
Eng. Management J., vol. 12, no. 2, pp. 23–31, 2000.
[44] S. Walsh, J. Linton, R. Grace, S. Marshall, and J. Knutti, “MEMS,
microsystems, micromachines: Commercializing an emergent dis-
ruptive technology,” in MEMS and MOEMS Technol. Applicat., P.
Rai-Choudry, Ed. Billingham, WA: SPIE—Int. Soc. Optical Eng.
Development, 2000, pp. 479–514. Scott Newbert received the B.S. degree from Colgate University and the MBA
[45] C. Christensen, The Innovator’s Dilemma. Boston, MA: Harvard Bus. degree from Monmouth University. Currently he is a doctoral candidate at
School Press, 1997. Rutgers University in the Organization Management Department where he is
majoring in entrepreneurship and strategy.
Prior to joining Rutgers University he worked in sales for Hershey Foods Cor-
poration and as an athletics coach at Monmouth University. His current research
Steven T. Walsh (S’94–M’95) received the B.S.
interests include the macroeconomic antecedents to and growth implications
degree in biomedical engineering and the Ph.D.
of technology intensive entrepreneurial firms. He also co-founded a privately
degree in strategy with specialization in manage-
owned marketing research and consulting firm.
ment of technology and entrepreneurship from
Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy, NY. He also
holds a certificate of Advanced Studies in business
administration from Northeastern University and an
MBA in marketing and new product planning.
Dr. Walsh is the Director of Technological
Entrepreneurship at the University of New Mexico,
Albuquerque, where he has been awarded the Black
Professorship of Entrepreneurship. He has been a director of a Fortune 500
company division and president of entrepreneurial firms. He has published
well over 100 articles serving both the academic and practitioner communities.
He has been a plenary or invited speaker numerous times at many universities
and national laboratories in the United States and on four other continents.
Further, he has served as a plenary speaker for many academic and industrial
organizations such as the International Association of Management of Tech-
nology (IAMOT), The International Society for Optical Engineering (SPIE),
the Micro and Nano Technological Commercialization Education Foundation
(MANCEF), Semiconductor Equipment and Materials International (SEMI),
and the International Association of Product Development Professionals
(IAPD). He is the Founding President for the MANCEF.
Dr. Walsh is a member of the board of reviewers for the IEEE TRANSACTIONS
ON ENGINEERING MANAGEMENT, an Associate Editor for Microsystems Com-
mercialization and Silicon Processing for the SPIE Journal of Microlithography,
Microfabrication, and Microsystems, an Area Editor for the Engineering Man-
agement Journal, and a Special Issue Editor for IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON
ENGINEERING MANAGEMENT and other journals. He is Co-chair for the
international technology roadmap for Micro and Top Down Nano Systems, a
Board Member of the MESA Institute at Sandia National Laboratories, and a
Member of the Board of advisors of R&D magazine’s Micro Machine Devices
magazine.

You might also like