You are on page 1of 5

Chapter 8

Conclusion* 1. Introduction Before India entered its socialist phase in the 1950s, the Indian economy was as competitive as any in the world. But once the planning phase began in earnest, and state monopolies began to be created, gradually almost all competition was eliminated. By the end of the 1960s, after the nationalisation of banks, competition became an alien term with very few having a notion of what it meant and what it could achieve. Then came the reforms of 1991 and competition was given a fresh impetus. In the 16 years that have elapsed since the licence-permit Raj began to dismantled, competition has return to the economy. However, although the need for a competition policy, competition law, and rules that encourage competition has been recognised, progress has been somewhat haphazard. It was within this context that this study was undertaken. The purpose was to assess perception of stakeholders on competition and regulation scenario prevailing in the country along the following lines: 1. Competition law or competition issues in competitive industries 2. Sector regulation or competition/regulation issues in regulated industries 3. Government policy/measures/other legislations A consumer, according to the Raghavan Committee Report on Competition Policy and Law, is a member of a broad class of people who purchase, use, maintain and dispose of products and services. Consumers are affected by pricing policies, financing practices, quality of goods and services and various trade practices. Governments tend, however, to use matters purportedly of public interest in order to formulate policies which are either anti-competitive in nature or which manifest themselves in anti-competitive behaviour. If the consumer is at the fulcrum, consumer interest and consumer welfare should have primacy in all Governmental policy formulations. 2. Anti-competitiveness in the Indian Economy Evidence of anti-competitiveness is found in virtually every sector of the Indian economy. These have been discussed in detail, and are summarised below: In trade policy, the spheres of intellectual property and anti-dumping affect consumers by restricting access to new patented drugs, usually because of prohibitive prices, or cheap imports. In industry, the continued presence of licensing requirements and capacity expansion restrictions, not to mention product protection for small scale industries, serve as obstacles to a truly anti-competitive regime.

DRAFT REPORT

187

With respect to privatisation and disinvestment, the possibility always exists that the erstwhile public sector monopoly will merely be replaced by a private sector one, preventing a truly competitive market to emerge. As far as intellectual property is concerned, the establishment of patents, especially in the field of biotechnology, has the possibility of increasing prices of patented drugs. In particular, gradually doing away with price controls especially in the backdrop of the product-patent regime kicking-in and relevant market inelasticity, could have adverse consumer impacts through prices. In order to make cross-sectoral improvements to the competitive nature of industries in India, the key recommendations with respect to particular sectors are summarised below: In trade policy, the easing of tariffs would generally lead to increased choice for the consumer both in terms of price and quality. Similarly, for industry, policy measures such as delicensing, removal of capacity expansion restrictions, removal of protection (reservation of products) to small-scale industries etc. would allow firms to expand strategically. This will facilitate economies of scale and scope, which can result in better prices and quality for consumers. Privatisation and disinvestment should seek to replace public sector monopolies with a thriving, competitive environment, while at the same time providing for efficient, well-structured regulatory bodies to govern them. The creation of effective regulation is surely beneficial to consumers. Despite all this, the country does not have a comprehensive national competition policy. The government has recently directed the Competition Commission of India (CCI) to form an `Advisory Committee for developing a consultation paper on the National Competition Policy for India. 3. Regulatory Acts and Bodies In order to maintain competitive standards in these and other industries, Indian law has provided, under several Acts, for the presence of regulatory mechanisms. As before, these have been discussed in detail in the preceding chapters, and are summarised below: The Monopoly and Restrictive Trade Practices (MRTP) Act has the power to play an important role in protecting consumer rights through better prices, quality etc of goods and services, by performing the tasks its name suggests. Set to replace the MRTP Act is the Competition Act of 2002. The key difference lies in its emphasis on a behavioural approach in examining competition in market rather than the structural approach followed by MRTP Act. The Competition Act provides for the creation of the Competition Commission of India (CCI) which among other things has a competition advocacy role. The other core areas on which the Act focuses are anti-competitive agreements, abuse of dominance and regulation of combinations. COPRA, or the Consumer Protection Act of 1986, which was subsequently amended in 1993 and 2002, was enacted for the specific purpose of protecting consumers 188

DRAFT REPORT

rights and providing a simple quasi-judicial dispute resolution system for resolving complaints. Among other things the law deals with unfair and restrictive trade practices (like manipulation of price) which are anti-competitive in nature. The COPRA and MRTP Act between themselves play a complementary role with respect to unfair trade practices. The Essential Commodities Act, dating back to 1955, has a supporting legislation `Prevention of Black Marketing and Maintenance of Supplies of Essential Commodities Act, 1980. By controlling black marketing it controls anti-competitive practices while on the whole this supporting legislation and the parent Act addresses the consumers right to basic needs. The Indian Patents Act, amended in 2005, grants significant economic exclusiveness to manufacturers of patented products. There are some in-built mechanisms to check extreme causes of competition restriction. The Act while rewarding innovation has negative implications for consumer access to generic varieties of patented drugs etc. The Bureau of Indian Standards (BIS) Act of 1986 set up the Bureau of Indian Standards, which sets standards (quality, safety etc) for various kinds of products. In certain cases the government in consultation with the BIS can make such standards mandatory for certain products or processes. This Act while geared more towards protection of consumer safety, facilitates competition. As far as specific industries go, there is, for example, the Electricity Act of 2003, which aims to create a liberal policy environment to facilitate the entry of new players into the business of electricity generation. The Act vests the power of determining tariffs to the appropriate regulator (State and Central Electricity Regulatory Commissions) and not the generating company. The State Electricity Regulatory Commissions are expected to regulate prices that final consumers pay and also to foster competition. Similarly for telecom, the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI) Act amended in 2000 empowers the regulator of this sector but falls short of giving it penal powers. 4. Foodgrains In the context of foodgrains, procurement by the government for distribution to the poor people on the basis of competitive bidding might maximise the output it gets for the same price, and reduce the burden on the poor. Instead of totally dismantling the minimum support price system, this should remain only to provide support to small and marginal farmers and for creating a buffer stock for price stability. Further, there are possibilities of a large corporate dominating a regional market, especially for fresh produce. This could affect consumer access (price, choice) in the long run unless there is competition among corporates on a regional basis. Such competition must be ensured. Also there are indications of price fixing by sellers and the existence of informal cartels in markets for agro produce and other items of daily need throughout the country. Inflation statistics and market dynamics often does not dictate the prices of food stuff sold in markets across the nation and vigilance is necessary to point out such anomalies. 189

DRAFT REPORT

5. Power The Indian power sector remains uncompetitive with the paying consumer saddled with one of the highest tariff rates (on PPP basis) in the world. However difficult it might be to execute politically, what is needed is better targeting of subsidies alongwith forward movement on open access and off-grid generation and supply, including the use of renewable energy sources. 6. Transport State Road Transport Undertaking (SRTUs) have become financially unviable and it is possible that states may go out of this business in future while more private operators come in. In the absence of universal service obligations (except for state undertakings), private players are least interested to serve non-lucrative routes affecting access and quality. In case of railways, competition has been introduced in freight transport but no similar initiative for passenger transport has been launched. 7. Pharmaceuticals Gradually doing away with price controls is dangerous especially in the backdrop of the product-patent regime coming into force though some argue that high prices of patented drugs help to fuel innovation. Along with the use of compulsory licensing what is needed is a pro-active regulatory mechanism which concerns itself with preventing crisis through effectively implementing provisions relating to pre-grant opposition, limiting the scope of patentable subject matter, and expediting the grant of compulsory licenses. There is a legitimate concern that the product patents regime will create monopolists in particular medicines and lead to market concentration. 8. Education Anti-competitive practices in the education sector exist. The tied selling of books, uniforms and stationeries among a large number of schools in ten cities of the country. Here also a local-level competition authority would be beneficial for the consumer. 9. General Recommendations As discussed in earlier chapters, while a more appropriate umbrella competition legislation has been designed, its implementation is incomplete while amendments 1 are being discussed. Among these amendments is a suggestion to do away with regional benches2 which would mean lesser checks on anti-competitive practices at regional or local levels. Nor is there a formal mechanism for an interface between the competition authority and the consumer courts mechanism born out of COPRA (which often handle grassroot competition abuses). This is essential if the two systems should work in tandem for the protection of the consumer. Also, as mentioned before, there is a need for wider civil society involvement in the issue of competition and consumer protection, something, which the new competition law would hopefully foster. Other suggestions include the following:
1

Suggestion to split the competition authority into two, namely the CCI and a Competition Appellate Tribunal, among other things. 2 Sec 22,23,24,25 of Competition Act

190

DRAFT REPORT

The suggested amendment (2006) of the Competition Act has several weaknesses which should be removed and there is possible scope of improvement. There should be state ands sub-state level competition authorities and regulatory agencies for all sectors. Sectoral regulators should be strengthened and government interventions through control of budget, appointments, issuing of policy directives and power to supersede should be stopped All regulators should set up well-functioning consumer representation and redress mechanisms (will take the pressure off consumer courts) Sectoral regulators should put more pressure on service providers/operators etc to meet quality objectives (like QoS, Standards of Performance etc) while setting benchmarks and doing performance evaluations on a regular basis. Consumer impact assessment of competition policy should be done periodically 10. The India Competition Perception Index All responses for each question were assigned a certain score in the range 0-5, based on certain criteria and considerations explained earlier. Once all questions were scored, the India Competition Perception Index was calculated as the simple average of normalised scores of all questions. That is, first, for each question the fraction of the maximum points it scored was calculated. This was then normalized to 100 to give the percentage score that the question received. Once this was done, the Index was calculated, as described earlier, as the simple average of normalized scores of all questions. The survey found that on a scale of 0 to 100, the overall competition perception index returns a score of 54.67. This implies that the perception on competition in the country is neither too good nor too bad, it is fair. It indicates that even after the one and half decades of reform, the progress on competition and regulatory issues is slow and anti-competitive practices still prevail in the market at large. The index scored very low on the perceptions like nature of market practices (35.84) and awareness/knowledge of competition and regulatory issues (39.39) indicating that people in general are not familiar with these parameters. The reason for this difference may be that level of competition is more tangible while, on the other hand, the nature of market practices and competition and regulatory issues are not easy to understand. Importantly, the impact of Government policies/measures on competition received a score of 47.43, which implies that the perception of Government interference in the market is not good and Government has not been able to provide fair competition in the market specially the level playing field to public and private enterprises.

*This chapter has been researched and written by TCA Srinivasa Raghavan, Independent Consultant

DRAFT REPORT

191

You might also like