Great Traverse
J. Bradford DeLong
Professor of Economics, U.C. Berkeley
Research Associate, NBER
delong@econ.berkeley.edu
1
So we shift the production function we work with away from the resource-
focused “Malthusian” one we have been dealing with up to now to a
different rule-of-thumb for economic growth:
1 1
g(Y ) = g(K ) + (g(L) + g(E))
2 2
where g(Y) is the proportional growth rate of total output, g(L) the growth
rate of the population or labor force, and g(E) the growth rate of the
€ efficiency of labor. Subtract off the growth rate of the labor force from
both sides to get:
1 1
g(y) = g(k) + g(E)
2 2
where now g(y) and g(k) are the growth rates of output per capita and the
capital stock per capita, respectively. Subtract off half of the growth rate
€ of output per capita from both sides:
Multiply by two:
€ g(y) = (g(k) − g(y)) + g(E)
And let’s give the difference between the growth rates of the capital stock
and the growth rate of output per worker a name: d, for capital
€ deepening—the extent to which the economy becomes “more industrial”
in the sense that each unit of output made is backed by and in fact requires
an increasing number of units of capital behind it:
g(y) = d + g(E)
2
What determines the rate of capital deepening? Let’s write down an
equation for the growth rate of the capital stock per worker k, with s being
the share of national output saved and invested in capital and pk being the
price of capital goods in terms of output as a whole:
s Y
g(k) = − δ − g(L)
p k K
And because there is no capital deepening y and k are growing at the same
rate. This tells us that both in 1865 and in 1929:
€
g(y) = g(k)
s Y
g(E) = − δ − g(L)
p k K
s Y
g(L) + g(E) + δ =
p k K
K (s / p k )
=
Y g(L) + g(E) + δ
Now let’s plug in some numbers. In 1865 the rate of population growth is
3% per year, the rate of growth of the efficiency of labor is this 0.9% per
€ year we got from the British Industrial Revolution, the rate of depreciation
δ is some 4% per year, the rate of national savings s is some 20% per year
and the price of capital goods pk we set at 1 in 1865. Thus our equation
becomes:
3
K (s / p k ) (.20 /1) .20
= = = = 2.5
Y 1865 g(L) + g(E) + δ .03 + .009 + .04 .08
By 1929 our rate of population growth has dropped to 2% per year. The
price of capital goods has dropped to 2/3. And the national savings rate
€ has increased by one-quarter to some 25%. So our equation becomes:
The jump from 2.5 to 5.3 in the capital-output ratio (measured at 1865
prices) gives us an annual rate of capital deepening of 1.2% per year. Plug
€ this back into our industrializing-America equation for the growth rate of
output per worker:
And it fits. Between 1865 and 1929 some 4/7 of American economic
growth in measured economic output per capita came from capital
€ deepening—more capital, more produced means of production, more
machines backing up each worker. And 3/7 of American economic growth
in measured economic output per capita came from improvements in the
efficiency of labor—working smarter made possible by more education,
organizational improvements, and other improvements in technology not
directly related to those that made capital goods cheaper.