You are on page 1of 4

COMMENTARY

Implications of FDI producers and improvement in supply chain


efficiency was absent, which is also reflect-

in Food Supermarkets ed in the performance of these chains. The


latter has been miserable as most of these
chains have either closed down or are scal-
ing down their store and procurement
Sukhpal Singh operations. Subhiksha is not in the market
anymore, Spencer’s has moved out of

T
This survey of the global and he discussion paper “Foreign Direct Gujarat, ITC has shut shop in Chandigarh
Indian experience with retail Investment in Multi-Brand Retail and Birla’s More is also reported to have
Trading” put up by the Department of wound up its operations in Gujarat. Some
supermarkets, against the
Industrial Policy and Promotion (DIPP) for of these like Namdhari Fresh, Fresh@,
backdrop of a recent official paper public comment on 6 July 2010 describes Spencer’s, More and Reliance Fresh still
on foreign investment in retail, the various aspects of the Indian retail operate, though only in the south. On the
highlights malpractices due to sector like its size and nature, recent other hand, 33%-60% of the traditional
growth, and its economic and social sig- F&V retailers (vendors) reported 15%-30%
buying power, employment loss
nificance besides the limitations of the decline in footfalls, 10%-30% decline in sales
in the value chain, and an present set-up. It then examines the posi- and 20%-30% decline in income across
unwillingness to share the risk tive and negative implications of foreign di- Bangalore, Ahmedabad and Chandigarh.
of the growers. rect investment (FDI) in the retail sector The largest impact was felt in Bangalore, a
based on the reports of various commit- city with high levels of supermarket penetra-
In this context, it would be
tees/institutions/bodies – academic and tion (Pritchard et al 2010) and the least was
prudent to slow down business, official and non-official. in Chandigarh. Roadside retailers suffered
supermarket expansion by using This article discusses the existing super- the most, followed by roadside-cum-home
mechanisms such as zoning, market experience in India in the perishable delivery retailers. A majority of them pointed
produce sector – fruits and vegetables (F&V) to the modern supermarkets as the major
business licences and trading
– and examines the global experience of reason for this loss (Singh and Singla 2010).
restrictions. Measures to ensure supermarket practices. It also looks at the
smooth functioning of the implications for smallholders and traditional Growers: Beneficiaries or Losers?
contract farming system should retailers, and regulatory issues and mech- The DIPP paper highlights the case of F&V
anisms for protecting their interests. with estimates of wastages and value
include strengthening
addition potential, for justifying the need
competition laws to limit buying Indian Supermarket Experience for FDI for supply chain improvements.
power, providing legal protection The operations of F&V retail chains in India But F&V crops account for only 2% of the
to contract growers and have, so far, not made any difference to the gross cropped area in India and suffer
share of the producer in the consumer’s from lack of production and/or market
encouraging farmer cooperatives
rupee (a major and valid concern of the risk management at the farmer level due to
and producer groups. DIPP paper), other than lowering the cost of high cost of inputs, high quality standards
marketing of the producer, as retail chains in markets, absence of minimum support
have collection centres in producing areas price, high yield risk, and low bargaining
unlike the Agricultural Produce Marketing power of growers. Further, by and large,
Committee (APMC) mandis (markets) which supermarket retail chains do not work with
are located in distant cities. The retail small­holders due to higher transaction
chains, however, buy only “A” grade pro- costs. Therefore, the noise about small-
duce and only a part of the farmers’ output, holder benefit in high value crops due to
even if all of it is “A” grade. The farmers end retail chain linkage is exaggerated and
up going to the APMC mandi to sell the re- the linkage is either weak or absent.
maining or rejected produce. An important question in the supermarket
Recent studies across chains and states chain linkage is why do chains, in general,
reveal that the chains (with the exception and those in India in particular, have only
of one or two) procured from relatively informal arrangements with growers in-
resourceful “contact” farmers without any stead of contract farming? The answer lies in
contract or commitment to buy regularly the unwillingness of supermarkets to share
Sukhpal Singh (sukhpal@iimahd.ernet.in) (Singh and Singla 2010; Pritchard et al the risk of the growers. The system of infor-
is at the Indian Institute of Management, 2010). Thus, there was little involvement on mal arrangements and consignments places
Ahmedabad.
the part of supermarket chains with the the financial risks solely with the producers/
Economic & Political Weekly  EPW   august 21, 2010  vol xlv no 34 17
COMMENTARY

suppliers and the supermarkets need to retail on traditional food retailers. How- higher private standards, and the down-
maintain no stocks, carry no price risk, and ever, the argument that domestic corpo- stream buyers (consumers) facing higher
have no purchase commitments. But they rate investors in retail are at a nascent prices due to lower competition.
still have control over production and its stage is not logical – how are the domestic The implications of the rise of supermar-
traceability; they enjoy reduced risk of low- players any better than foreign players so kets for farmers do not come from the type
quality produce; and they pay lower prices far as implications of retail investment for of store but from the methods of procure-
as there are no intermediaries. This puts poor producers/suppliers and traditional ment used and the quality standards ap-
farming businesses under pressure which is retailers are concerned? But if one considers plied (Chen et al 2005). Supermarkets
passed on to the workers on the farms, who the impact of FDI on local firms and systems, have multiple channels through the sys-
are often women (Stichele et al 2006). it is important to realise that the diffusion tem of category management, and suppli-
The supermarket chains give market- of ideas from transnational corporations ers range from spot markets, or traditional
price-based prices to their supplying “con- (TNCs, read “global supermarkets”) to local wholesalers, to preferred suppliers and
tact farmers”. Given that in India, market firms is not automatic. Also, the growing direct contracts with independent large
prices fluctuate so widely during the season competitive pressures, resulting from dis- growers, with the latter two increasing in
and across seasons, is this a fair practice? tributional benefits and market power of importance. Carrefour, Malaysia’s fresh
Why not work prices backward or forward supermarkets, may even negatively affect fruit and vegetable supply chain was made
based on the market price of final products the productivity and ability of local enter- up of wholesalers (41% of total supplies),
or cost of production? Further, if market prises (Durand 2007). semi-direct suppliers (wholesalers and sup-
prices are so efficient, why do the chains go pliers) (41%), and direct suppliers (18%).
to growers? This is a serious issue as even a Sketchy Description Similarly, GIANT, another supermarket in
significant premium over the market price The experiences of various countries cited Malaysia, which in 2002 had 200 vegetable
may not benefit the farmer if open market in the DIPP paper are sketchy and not suppliers, reduced them to only 30 in 2004
prices go down significantly, a phenomenon based on any analysis or insights. In the which included specialised wholesalers,
not uncommon in India. Even in organic case of Indonesia, the zoning policy to re- general wholesalers, farmers with oral con-
produce supply chains, this is the norm and strict the impact of retail chains on local tracts, and suppliers without contracts.
there is little transparency in pricing and retailers is not even mentioned. In Mexico, Similar was the case of TOPS in Thailand
costing of operations of private organisers modern retail workers suffered a wage de- which had 250 suppliers to begin with (Chen
of such projects (IFAD 2005; Singh 2009). crease of 18% between 1994 and 2003 and et al 2005). This is known as “supplier ra-
On the retailing end side, there have been the retail sector wages were 14% lower tionalisation” in supermarket terminology.
some corporate social responsibility (CSR) than those in the manufacturing sector. Though supermarkets initially offered
initiatives by supermarket chains to rope in Wal-Mart’s imports into Mexico were 3.5% higher prices to producers than those of-
traditional F&V sellers into their operations, of consumption goods imports, 0.5% of fered by traditional channels, farmers also
though most of these have been unsuccess- global imports, and contributed negatively incurred extra costs like processing and
ful. For instance, to keep local traditional to the Mexican trade deficit in 2002 (ibid). packaging, marketing, transport, and other
F&V retailers (vendors) in business, ITC If the supermarket concentration in the transaction costs unlike their counterparts
Choupal Fresh had provided them push- western markets is any indication, a few in traditional channels (Cadilhon et al 2006).
carts to sell its perishable produce,  but players are likely to dominate the food sec- Due to the sheer size of supermarkets and
this did not succeed and had to be discon- tor over time and then dictate terms to the consequent buying power, the producer
tinued. Similarly, Best Price Wholesale of suppliers and buyers. In 2007, five major prices may be depressed. For example, in
Walmart-Bharti has financed about a dozen chains accounted for more than 50% of the UK, there was a negative relation be-
pushcart vendors in Amritsar but the initia- retail sales in most of the European Union tween the relative market share of a super-
tive did not take off. On the other hand, an countries; even as much as 70%-80% of the market and price paid to the suppliers in
initiative by a local businessperson in retail market in Denmark and Finland. Fur- relation to the average price. The larger
Ahmedabad – under the brand name of ther, consolidation was also indicated by the market share of a supermarket, the
Harra Fresh – seems to be more promising. the increasing size of stores and a decline in lower was the price paid to the suppliers.
It involves former traditional F&V retailers the number of stores per capita by 10%-15% The UK supermarket chain Tesco paid its
selling perishables in mobile vans which during 2002-07 in countries like the United suppliers a price 4% below the average price
have computerised billing and weighing Kingdom (UK), Finland and the Netherlands. paid by retailers due to its buying power
system. The vans serve identified housing Further, own brands of these supermarkets (Stichele et al 2006). This lower producer
colonies/areas on a fixed day and time, accounted for a major share of the total price does not necessarily result in lower
and customers benefit from doorstep sales, i e, 43% in the UK, 40% in Denmark consumer price (Durand 2007).
delivery of fresh fruits and vegetables. and 42% in Belgium (Bukeviciute et al
2009). Thus, rapid rise of supermarket Malpractices and Cost-Cutting
Supermarket Practices chains would lead to concentration of mar- There have been a large number of super-
The DIPP paper highlights the concerns ket power, with upstream suppliers facing market malpractices in the UK and France
about the likely negative impact of FDI in buyer power in terms of lower prices and due to the buyer power they possess. These
18 august 21, 2010  vol xlv no 34  EPW   Economic & Political Weekly
COMMENTARY

include (i) payment to be on the supplier strategies to cut labour costs. Thus, nega- Given the global and the Indian experi-
list (listing fees), (ii) threats of delisting if tive impact of supermarkets include exclu- ence so far, it is important to slow down
supplier price is not low enough, (iii) pay- sion and squeezing out of small producers, food supermarket expansion by using mech-
ment from producers for various promo- loss of jobs in the traditional markets, and anisms such as zoning, business licences,
tions and opening of new stores, (iv) rebate decline of the traditional wholesale markets and trading restrictions. There are several
from producers as a percentage of their su- which may be important for small produc- instances in other countries where large
permarket sales, and (v) minus margins ers and workers (Cadilhon et al 2006). stores are kept away from the traditional
whereby suppliers are not allowed to supply Supermarkets also resort to unfair and markets. Hypermarkets are not allowed
at prices higher than the competitor price unethical practices. Carrefour was fined in within 3.5 km of housing estates or city cen-
(Chen et al 2005; Stichele et al 2006). South Korea for unfair business practices, tres in Malaysia. Indonesia prohibits hyper-
Where they deal with growers directly, i e, forcing suppliers to cut prices to save a markets within 500 m of traditional mar-
malpractices employed by supermarkets are 1.737 billion Won supply order for 10 months kets, and large stores of more than 40,000
(i) delayed payments, despite regulations to in 2005. It was also fined $1,70,000 by the sq ft are to be at least 2.5 km from tradi-
pay within a week in countries like Malaysia, Indonesian Business Competition Authority tional markets (Srivathsan 2007).
(ii) lowering prices at the last minute when (KPPU) in 2005 for not sourcing goods from a Further, there is a need to limit the buy-
supplier has no alternative, (iii) changing listed supplier who then went bankrupt, ing power of supermarkets by strengthen-
quantity and quality standards without which was considered an unfair competi- ing competition laws. This can be initiated
notice and support, (iv) just-in-time systems tion practice. It was also asked to stop mi- by establishing or improving contract regu-
to avoid storage and inventory costs, (v) re- nus margin practices. Its agreement was lations as in the form of legal acts in the US
moving suppliers from list without good found to include listing fees, fixed rebate, and Argentina. Legal protection to contract
reason, (vi) charging high interest on credit, minus margin, terms of payment, regular growers as a group must be considered to
and (vii) using contracts that cannot be discount, common assortment cost, opening protect them from ill-effects of procure-
enforced by suppliers (Stichele et al 2006). cost/new store, fees for bi-weekly advertise- ment practised by supermarkets. There are
Even in Asian developing countries, ments and penalties (Stichele et al 2006). cases of legal protection given to subcon-
supermarket supplies suffer from the follow- tracting industries in Japan in their rela-
ing: (i) supermarket orders can go up and Regulation of Supermarkets tions with large firms. These laws specify
down dramatically as there are no long-term The biggest fear in India is not that the the duties (to have a written and clear
commitments or written contracts, (ii) pur- FDI per se will be more disadvantageous terms contract with the sub­contractor) and
chase prices are often negotiated for a fixed for farmers or traditional retailers than forbidden acts for the large parent firm.
period, such as a week, but are renegotiated domestic corporate investment; it is that The latter include refusal to receive delivery
(only downwards) by supermarkets if the government and its agencies may not of commissioned goods, delaying the pay-
market prices decline during that period, be able to regulate and monitor the opera- ment beyond agreed period, discounting of
(iii) promotion fees are charged from sup- tions of the global retailers. If the monitor- payment, returning commissioned goods
pliers where a product or range of fresh ing of wholesale “cash and carry” stores so without good reason, forced price reduction,
produce is featured in an in-store promotion, far is anything to go by, there is no regulation compulsory purchase by subcontractors of
(iv) discounts for new stores, and (v) pen- and existing players are openly flouting the parental firm’s products, and forcing sub-
alties are invariably levied for failing to norms at the store level. They are known to contractors to pay in advance for materials
supply agreed quantities (Chen et al 2005). carry out retail sales in the garb of wholesale, supplied by the parent firm. These provi-
These practices hamper upgrading of sup- as the size of a single purchase (minimum sions are monitored by the Fair Trade Com-
pliers into better producers and into pro­ ticket size) was just Rs 500 in one store and mission. Interestingly, most of the viola-
cessing and marketing (Stichele et al 2006). Rs 1,000 in case of another store. These are tions by parent firms were on the written
Supermarket expansion also leads to self-imposed limits and do not seem to be form and clear terms of the contracts (Sako
employment loss in the value chain. Metro governed by any regulation. This raises 1992). If contract farming is only an exten-
Cash & Carry employed 1.2 workers per questions about the effectiveness of regula- sion of the flexible production systems
tonne of tomatoes sold in Vietnam com- tion of retail space in India. Also, retail buy- prevalent in industry to farm production,
pared with 2.9 workers employed by tradi- ers can easily use the ID cards issued by then it is only logical to extend such legal
tional wholesale channel for the same these stores because as long as you hold a provisions with necessary modifications to
quantity sold (Cadlihon et al 2006). The card, no further questions are asked at the farming contracts.
spread of supermarkets led to a 14% reduc- entry to the stores. Individual buyers pur- The Indian model contract farming
tion in the share of “mom and pop” stores chase in a group on one card. Thus, one sees agreement under the amended APMC Act
in Thailand which was cornered by foreign more of families and women in these stores (2003) is quite fair in terms of sharing of
supermarket chains within four years than business heads or their employees. costs and risks between the contracting
(Stichele et al 2006). On the other hand, in Further, some of these wholesale stores also agency and the grower. But it leaves out
supermarket stores, low wages, job cuts, sell F&Vs in retail with the minimum pur- many aspects of farmer interest protection
long and irregular working hours, and chase quantity being only 1 kg. Thus, effec- like delayed payments and deliveries, con-
non-contract workers are reported as tively, they are operating in the retail space. tract cancellation damages if the producer
Economic & Political Weekly  EPW   august 21, 2010  vol xlv no 34 19
COMMENTARY

has made firm-specific heavy investments, On the other side, farmers’ organisa- Cadilhon J-J, P Moustier, N D Poole, P T G Tam and
A P Fearne (2006): “Traditional vs Modern Food
inducement/force/intimidation to enter into tions and non-governmental organisations Systems? Insights from Vegetable Supply Chains
a contract, disclosure of material risks, need to monitor and negotiate more equi- to Ho Chi Minh City (Vietnam)”, Development
Policy Review, 24(1), 31-49.
competitive performance-based payments, table contracts with the supermarkets. Pro- Chen K, A W Shepherd and C da Silva (2005): “Changes
and sharing of production risks. Further, it ducers’ organisations amplify the political in Food Retailing in Asia: Implications of Super-
market Procurement Practices for Farmer and
is not known how widely the model contract voice of smallholder producers, reduce the Traditional Marketing Systems”, AMMF Occa-
agreement will be adopted by the agencies costs of marketing of inputs and outputs, sional Paper 8, FAO, Rome.
Durand, C (2007): “Externalities from Foreign Direct
unless it is a conditionality to avail of cer- and provide a forum for members to share Investment in the Mexican Retailing Sector”,
tain other incentives or policies. The vulner- information, coordinate activities, and Cambridge Journal of Economics, 31 (3), 393-411.
ability of the growers due to fluctuations in make collective decisions. On the other IFAD (2005): Organic Agriculture and Poverty Reduc-
tion in Asia: China and India Focus, Thematic
market prices needs to be reduced by mak- hand, they also lower the transaction costs Evaluation, International Fund for Agricultural
Development, Report No 1664, Rome, July.
ing supermarkets offer minimum purchase for the processing/marketing/retailing
Pritchard, B, C P Gracy and M Godwin (2010): “The
prices, not market-price-based premiums. agencies working with growers. The gov- Impacts of Supermarket Procurement on Farm-
Also, provisions for legally binding and ernment should also play an enabling role ing Communities in India: Evidence from Rural
Karnataka”, Development Policy Review, 28(4): 435-56.
clearly worded rules for fair treatment through legal provisions and institutional Sako, M (1992): Prices, Quality and Trust – Inter-firm
of suppliers, an independent authority like mechanisms, like helping farmer coopera- Relations in Britain and Japan (Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press).
a retail commission to supervise and regu- tives, producer companies and producer Singh, S (2009): Organic Produce Supply Chains in
late supermarkets for supplier, consumer, groups, to facilitate smooth functioning of India: Organisation and Governance (New Delhi:
Allied Publishers).
and labour aspects and support to local re- the contract farming system, and not inter- Singh, S and N Singla (2010): “Fresh Food Retail Chains
tailers, are required. Such an agency vene in contracts directly. in India: Impacts on Small Primary Vegetable Pro-
ducers and Traditional Fruit and Vegetable Re-
should ban buying of products below cost tailers”, Final Report, CMA, IIM, Ahmedabad, April.
and selling below cost, improve local tradi- References Srivathsan, A (2007): “Regulating Space”, Frontline,
Bukeviciute, L, A Dierx and F Ilzkovits (2009): “The 13 July, 25-27.
tional markets for small growers, establish
Functioning of the Food Supply Chain and Its Stichele, M V, Sanne van der Wal and J Oldenziel
multi-stakeholder initiatives in the chains Effect on Food Prices in the European Union”, (2006): “Who Reaps the Fruit? Critical Issues in
European Commission, Directorate General for the Fresh Fruit and Vegetable Chain”, Centre for
and provide support to small producers Economic and Financial Affairs, Occasional Paper Research on Multinational Corporations (SOMO),
and traditional food retailers. No 47, European Communities (EC). Amsterdam, June.

Sexual Harassment: O­thers vs the State of Rajasthan (AIR 1997


SC 3011), which came to be known as the

Not Fitting the Bill V­isakha guidelines (incorporating Gene­ral


Recommendation 19 of Committee on the
Elimination of Discrimination against
Women (CEDAW)) to protect women against
Mridul Eapen sexual harassment at the workplace since
the then civil and penal laws in India did

T
In 1997 the Supreme Court issued here are reports in the media (see not contain adequate provisions to address
the Visakha guidelines to prevent for instance, The New Indian Express, this form of violence against women. The
24 May 2010) that the much awaited guidelines were to be “binding and en-
sexual harassment of women at
bill against sexual harassment (SH) at the forceable in law until suitable legislation is
the workplace until a suitable law workplace is likely to be introduced in enacted to occupy the field”. While the
was passed. A draft bill in 2005 Parliament. The draft bill had been put up guidelines were based on the problems of
was followed by yet another draft on the web site of the Union Ministry women working in rural India facing
of Women and Child D­eve­lopment for threats to their life and person, the SC
in 2007. A report of a discussion
comments and suggestions until 31 March judgment was beneficial to women in the
in Kochi. 2007. Three years have gone by and it has organised sector and some complaints
still not been placed in Parliament. A were filed and redressal given under the
group of concerned citizens – academicians, Visakha judgment.
advocates, activists, and policymakers – A few years later the first attempt was
met in Kochi in early May to take a fresh made to frame a suitable draft legislation
look at the bill and submit comments/sug- with considerable involvement of and
gestions anew. pressure from women’s organisations.
This was called “The Protection against
Addressing the Issue Sexual Harassment of Women Bill 2005”.
This bill derives from the Supreme Court However, that too gathered dust till it was
Email: mridul@cds.ac.in
(SC) judgment in 1997 in the Visakha and replaced by “The Protection of Women
20 august 21, 2010  vol xlv no 34  EPW   Economic & Political Weekly

You might also like