You are on page 1of 35

THREE ESSAYS ON

SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT
by
ANDRES GOMEZ-LOBO
KIRK HAMILTON
and
CARLOS EDUARDO YOUNG

CSERGE WORKING PAPER GEC 93-08

Three Essays on
Sustainable Development
by
Andres Gomez-Lobo
Kirk Hamilton
and
Carlos Eduardo Young

The Centre for Social and Economic Research


on the Global Environment
University College London
and
University of East Anglia

Acknowledgements:
The Centre for Social and Economic Research on the Global Environment (CSERGE) is a
designated research centre of the U.K. Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC)
ISSN 0967-8875

Abstract

This is a collection of three Papers on the economic issues encapsulated within the debate
surrounding the definition of sustainable development.

The first essay examines one issue in the debate concerned with the correct formulation of
sustainable income when resources are being depleted: in particular the treatment of outflows
due to debt service. It concludes that such outflows should be deducted in order to arrive at a
NNP measure that is more intuitively sustainable.

The second essay examines the difference between the concepts of optimal growth and
sustainable development. The concepts diverge when the discounting of future utility and other
issues are considered.

The third essay examines the implications of incorporating a sustainability constraint into a
macro-economic model of an economy, where optimal growth is defined in terms of full
employment of labour. In combination, the essays take further the debate over whether, and in
what form, trade-offs exist, between economic growth and sustainable development.

ESSAY 1

SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT,
OPTIMAL GROWTH AND NATURAL RESOURCE ACCOUNTING
IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY
Andres Gomez-Lobo E.1

1.

INTRODUCTION

Contrary to common belief, optimal economic growth and sustainable develop-ment are not
different nor antagonistic concepts. Sustainable development is just one type of "optimal"
growth, namely one where the rule by which to judge an "optimal" from a "non-optimal" path is
based on a particular, and strong, view of intergenerational equity.

It is important to establish what is meant by sustainable development and optimal economic


growth. Development is not synonymous with growth but is a much wider and encompassing
concept. To avoid this issue, in this paper sustainable development is understood to mean
sustainable growth, and sustainable growth is a growth path that allows future generations to
enjoy at least as much welfare as the current generation. In other words, a growth path is
sustainable if it does not entail future decreases in welfare.

To define optimal growth an objective function that ranks different growth paths is required. In
neoclassical growth theory this function is usually a present value utility function that weighs
utility levels at different moments in time by a discount factor. Since the discount factor becomes
smaller for periods further into the future it is possible to have large welfare costs in the distant
future that, once discounted, are not very significant. This possibility violates the ethical rule of
intergenerational equity and is the reason why sustainable growth has gained so much attention
lately.

However, the present value utility function is not the only possible objective function to use in
1

I would like to thank David Pearce, M. Pemberton, Kirk Hamilton, Carlos Young and Edward Barbier for their
excellent comments. I would also like to thank the Ford Foundation and the British Council for their financial
assistance.

calculating an optimal growth path. If instead, the objective function is of a Max-Min type where
the objective is to maximize the utility of the least well off generation then the "optimal" growth
path will be sustainable. In that case all generations should have the same consumption level
per capita. Solow (1974) shows that such a path exists even without technological change in a
simple model with an exhaustible resource and sufficient substitution possibilities between
reproducible capital and natural resources. The need to worry about intergenerational equity
arises when there is an exhaustible resource that the current generation may be using too fast.
Hartwick (1977) showed that, in a model with similar assumptions to Solow (1974), investing the
rents accruing from resource extraction in other types of capital is sufficient to maintain a
constant consumption path.

A key concept for understanding sustainable development is "economic income". The Hicksian
notion of income is the maximum amount an agent (or country in this case) can consume in the
present period and expect to consume the same amount in the future. Income is then
sustainable by definition. Therefore the relevant question when assessing the sustainability of a
growth path is whether economic growth is measuring true income growth.

The answer is no. The way the current system of national accounts works in practice does not
guarantee that aggregate economic indicators are true Hicksian income figures. One important
bias arises by the fact that variations in natural capital stocks are usually accounted for as
income instead of asset changes. Therefore a high growth figure may be hiding an underlying
process of asset reduction and may not be measuring true income. It is this fact that causes the
apparent paradox that national economic figures may show positive growth but which may not
be sustainable in the middle to long run. The important thing to notice is that the real problem is
the erroneous way in which economic growth is being measured and not a difference in
paradigm between optimal growth and sustainable development.

2.

THE MEASUREMENT OF SUSTAINABLE GROWTH

The effort to correct the national accounts, known as natural resources accounting, has been a
lively research area in the last few years. There have been two basic methodologies to go about
this, the depreciation method (Repetto, et.al, 1989), and the user cost approach (El Serafy,
1989).

In this paper I will try to show the reasons why both methods differ and also extend the

depreciation method to a small open economy.

The depreciation method basically says that one should deduct from GDP an allowance for
natural capital depreciation equal to the rents obtained from the exploitation of natural
resources2. The rationale for this approach is Hartwick's rule, which states that to maintain a
constant consumption path one should reinvest in reproducible capital all rents accruing from
the extraction of natural resources. The reason for this is that rents reflect the asset value of the
resource and therefore is a measure of the asset loss when one unit of a natural resource is
drawn down3.

Hartwick's rule was developed in a closed economy context. This is reflected by the exclusion of
foreign trade and foreign assets. In a comment to Solow (1986), Svensson notes that

"For an open economy, intertemporal trade, i.e., borrowing and lending, implies that
consumption need not equal output of the consumption good at each point in time.
In particular, for a small open economy, the interest rate is given by the world capital
market, and consumption and investment decisions become separable. A small
open economy should simply choose investment so as to maximize wealth. If there
is a social preference for a constant consumption path, it can simply be chosen
subject to an intertemporal budget constraint, and is otherwise completely
independent of the specific investment and production path. These circumstances
combined make me believe that Hartwick's rule, although a very neat theoretical
result, is of limited interest for discussing intergenerational equity in small open
economies."
I will try to show that in a small open economy Hartwick's rule of reinvesting all resource rents is
still valid. However, an allowance has to be made for the change in foreign assets.

3.

HARTWICKS RULE IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY? 4

The approach of this section is based on Solow (1986) and Hartwick (1990). They use a result
due to Weitzman (1976) which states that the Net National Product is equal to the current value
Hamiltonian of the corresponding optimal growth problem. In an economy with natural resources
2

In theory, even the strong sustainability school of thought may be included in this argument since nonsubstitutable
natural capital will have a marginal productivity tending towards infinity. Therefore any growth path that draws down
these resources will be unsustainable because the depreciation allowance will be infinite.
3

As Hartwick has correctly pointed out, rent should be defined as the price of the resource minus the extraction costs of
the marginal unit. The use of an average rent (price minus average extraction costs) in most empirical work probably
causes an overestimation of the depreciation if there are increasing marginal costs of extraction.
4

Asheim (1986) shows that Hartwick's rule does not hold in an open economy because, due to resource depletion, the
terms of trade will improve for future generations. In contrast to Asheim (1986), in the present model the country is
assumed to be small and thus is unable to affect its terms of trade.

this Net National Product will be equal to GDP minus the rents from natural resource extraction5.
Solow (1986) shows that if Hartwick's rule is imposed on such an economy then consumption
will be constant. Therefore, NNP is the income measure we are seeking.

The extension to an open economy is straight forward. The maximization problem is,
(1) Max
St:

(2)

e tU (C (t )dt

A& = X M + rA = Y ( K , R) C I f ( R, S ) + rA

(3) K& = I
(4) S& = R

where A is the stock of foreign assets, X is exports, M is imports, r is the international interest
rate (exogenous for this small economy), Y(K,R) is the production function of the composite
good with the capital stock, K, and resource extraction, R, as arguments (labour is assumed
fixed), C is the aggregate consumption, I is investment, f(R,S) is the cost of extraction
(measured in terms of the composite good), S is the stock of the natural resource, and is the
discount rate6.

The current value Hamiltonian for this problem is,


(5)

= U(C)+1[I]+2[-R]+3[Y(K,R)-C-I-f(R,S)+rA]

and the corresponding first order conditions are,

For simplicity we assume that the man-made capital stock does not depreciate. If this was not so the depreciation of
this stock would also have to be deducted from GDP to arrive at a NNP figure.

Time subscripts have been omitted to simplify notation. However, except for the discount rate and the international
interest rate, each variable above is a function of time.


= 1-3 = 0
I

(6)

(7)

= -2+3(YR-fR) = 0
R
(8)

= Uc-3 = 0
C

(9)

1 = 1-3YK

(10)

2 = 2+3fS

(11)

3 = 3-3r

Substituting (6), (7) and (8) into (5) yields the value of the Hamiltonian in an optimal path
expressed in utility units,
(12)

= U(C)+UcI-Uc(YR-fR)R+Uc(Y(K,R)-C-I-f(R,S)+rA)

Using a linear approximation to utility, U(C)=UcC, and dividing (12) by Uc we get a monetary
value of the Hamiltonian in an optimal path, or the Net National Product,
(13)
(14)
(15)

= NNP = C+I-(YR-fR)R+A
Uc
NNP = C+I-(YR-fR)R+X-M+rA
NNP = GDP-(YR-fR)R+rA

This result is similar to the closed economy case. To derive NNP, resource rents have to be
deducted from GDP, but, in addition, the interest earned on the foreign asset stock has to be
added7. In most developing countries, where the small open economy hypothesis is relevant, A
will be negative due to net foreign indebtedness. Thus, to arrive at NNP foreign debt services
have to be deducted from GDP.
7

The adjustment to GDP for the change in foreign assets is limited to the interest earned on these assets only. The
other components of the change in foreign assets, exports minus imports, are already accounted for in the traditional
measure of GDP.

This result is intuitively simple and is not new. Solow (1986) expresses Hartwick's rule in a
setting with multiple types of capital as p(t)(K/t)=0, where p(t) is a vector of shadow prices for
investment goods and (K/t) is a vector in which each element is the change in one type of
capital. Since foreign assets are just another type of capital, the change in this asset has to be
accounted for. Since the traditional measure of GDP already includes foreign trade, only a
correction for interest earnings or payments has to done.

To anyone familiar with national accounting concepts it will be immediately clear that the above
procedure is equivalent to deducting resource rents from GNP, since this last figure includes
foreign assets interest payments. In fact Hartwick (1990) correctly considers GNP as the
measure that has to be modified to arrive at NNP. However, in this paper the role of foreign
assets is stressed for several reasons.

In the first place, empirical studies such as Repetto, et.al (1989) use GDP instead of GNP,
possibly because GNP figures are not always calculated as often as GDP by the statistical
offices of developing countries. In many developing countries severely affected by the foreign
debt crisis during the eighties, the change in foreign assets is probably a more important
determinant of sustaina-bility than the loss of natural resource assets. Therefore, it is important
to stress that the change in foreign assets must be explicitly accounted for when deriving
sustainability indicators for a developing economy.

More importantly, by formulating the role of foreign assets explicitly in the above optimization
problem, some insight is gained as to the difference between the depreciation method and the
user cost approach. This will be made clear in the next section.

Following Solow (1986) it can be shown that an extended Hartwick rule (invest in reproducible
capital an amount equal to the rents from resource extraction minus the change in foreign
assets) will ensure a constant consumption path for the small open economy case. This is
shown in the appendix of this paper.

The aim of natural resource accounting is to have a better indicator of National Income, in a
Hicksian sense, and therefore evaluate the sustainability of an economic growth process. As far
as I know, all empirical studies on natural resource accounting have ignored the change in
foreign assets. Therefore, an important element in determining whether an economy is on a

sustainable path has been omitted8.

3.

THE DIFFERENT APPROACHES TO NATURAL RESOURCE ACCOUNTING

The result in the previous section shows that to arrive at the Net National Product all rents from
resource extraction have to be deducted from GDP (as well as interest earnings or payments of
foreign assets). This is consistent with the depreciation approach to natural resource accounting
as in Repetto, et al. (1989). However, El Serafy (1989) criticizes the depreciation approach and
instead proposes an alternative method whereby only a fraction of current rents are deducted
from GDP to arrive at a sustainable growth indicator.

El Serafy's main criticism to the depreciation approach is that because all rents are deducted
from GDP a country with a large endowment of natural resources would not seem to have an
income (ie. permanent consumption) edge over other countries. This result would obviously be
flawed.
As an alternative, El Serafy (1989) proposes the following9,
(16)

n
e-rtIdt = e-rtR(0)dt
0
0

where I is income, R(0) is the rent generated in the current period, n is the number of years that
the resource will last given a constant extraction equal to the current extraction, and r is an
exogenously given interest rate.

Equation (16) transforms a finite cash flow (from resource extraction rents) to an infinite income
flow. Since I and R(0) are constant we can integrate both sides of (16) and arrive at,
(17)

1
I
= (1- )
R(0)
ern

Equation (17) gives the proportion of current rents (if maintained for n years) that can be
transformed into income and thus consumed. Therefore, not all resource rents are asset
8

It is interesting to note that the inclusion of foreign assets not only has implications for Hartwick's rule for reinvesting
resource rents, but also for the optimal rate of resource depletion, particularly if the stock also has value. On this see
Barbier and Rauscher (forthcoming).
9

El Serafy (1989) derives his formula in discrete time. However, in this work it is derived in continuous time.

depreciation but only a fraction (1-I/R(0)).

Before discussing El Serafy's approach we will pursue a point that was not mentioned in the
optimal control problem of section (b). Namely, that there is an additional restriction to that
optimal control problem that might shed some light as to the reason why El Serafy's method
differs from the results of that section.

What is the maximum constant sustainable consumption that an economy characterized by


equations (1) to (4) may enjoy? As Svensson mentions:"...it can simply be chosen subject to an
intertemporal budget constraint, and is otherwise completely independent of the specific
investment and production path".
The intertemporal budget constraint is given by the following condition10,

(18)

lim -rt
e A=0
n

which states that in the long run a country cannot be a net lender or borrower in present value
terms. This implies that a country's foreign debt should not grow faster than the interest rate it
has to pay.

The first restriction of the optimization problem (equation (2)) was,


(2)

A = Y(K,R)-C-I-f(R,S)+rA

Integrating this differential equation yields,


(19)

t
A(t) = A(0)ert+ert e-r(Y(K(),R())-C()-I()-f())d
o

and using the limit condition (18) yields11,

10

The following derivations follow Sachs (1982) very closely.

11

For simplicity it is assumed that A(0)=0.

(20)

e-rt(Y(t)-C(t)-I(t)-f(t))dt = 0
0

This last equation is the intertemporal budget constraint. It states that the present value of trade
deficits has to equal the present value of trade surpluses.

We can transform equation (20) into an alternative form that will be more useful. Let us define
the "permanent" or "perpetual equivalence" of a variable as,

e-r(-t)Xp(t)d = e-r(-t)X()d
0
t

Xp is the constant value of the variable that over the horizon will give the same present value as
the changing variable path X()12.
Defining Yp(0), Cp(0), Ip(0), fp(0) as the permanent values of Y(t), C(t), I(t) and f(t) respectively,
the budget constraint after integrating is,

(21)

Cp(0) Yp(0)-Ip(o)-fp(0)
=
= Wealth
r
r

(22)

Cp(0) = rW

Therefore the maximum consumption feasible in this economy is the interest from the wealth
that is possible to generate with the initial endowments.

Now we are ready to discuss El Serafy's formula. Implicitly, his method is only valid for a small
open economy, because the interest rate is exogenous. In addition, the flavour of his argument
implies a small open economy since the intuition behind his result is that part of the resource
rents that can be invested in the international market and the return on these assets will be used
to finance consumption after the resource is exhausted.

From the previous discussion it should be clear that El Serafy's calculation of "consumable"
12

As an example, Weitzman (1976) showed that NNP at time t is the perpetuity equivalent of the optimal and variable

income, I, is just the perpetuity equivalent of the wealth generated by the natural resource rents.
This is what equation (16) does. Therefore El Serafy is correct in the sense that consumption is
a fraction of total wealth. However, in the open economy case consumption and investment
decisions are independent. Therefore the level of consumption is independent of the amount of
resource rents generated in the current period. The extraction path of the resource should be
such that wealth is maximized.

We have seen that in an efficient path to construct an NNP indicator we have to deduct all of
resource rents from GDP as well as any foreign debt interest payments. In the case where the
country is exploiting its resource base to built up foreign assets, rA will be positive. Therefore the
amount of investment necessary to maintain a constant consumption path is less than the total
resource rents of the period, confirming El Serafy's intuition. However, the correct way to
account for such an effect is to deduct all resource rents and then incorporate the change in
foreign assets.

Since El Serafy (1989) does not postulate a behavioral model of resource extraction it is not
clear why rents are generated in his formulation in the first place13. Therefore it is not possible to
see whether the correcting factor derived from our optimization model, ((YR-fR)R+rA), would be
equal to the depreciation allowance of El Serafy method, (R(0)/ern). We do know however that in
an optimal growth path, where resource extraction is efficient, NNP is equal to GDP minus
resource rents and net interest payments.

The main thrust of El Serafy's criticism of the depreciation approach is no longer valid.
Deducting rents from GDP will not reduce NNP to zero since the current account will adjust to
make NNP equal to permanent consumption (if Hartwick's extended rule is imposed).

4.

CONCLUSIONS

The conflict between sustainable development and optimal economic growth is really a problem
of how to measure growth. In this paper an approach to measuring national income for a small
open economy was discussed. The result shows that the two principal methods for accounting

consumption path.
13

His assumption of a constant rent stream R(0) for n periods is a highly unlikely outcome of any model in which
resource owners are somehow optimizing intertemporally. If they are not optimizing intertemporally then resource rents
should not arise in the first place.

natural resource depreciation are not valid in a small open economy context. However, the
depreciation approach would be the correct method if it is extended to include interest earnings
or payments on foreign assets.

There are many other topics in natural resource accounting that merit discussion. One
empirically relevant point is the correct way to account for discoveries. Hartwick (1990) includes
a discovery function in the optimal growth problem and concludes that the correct depreciation
measure is the value of the net change in assets (extraction minus discoveries).

It is unlikely that real world discoveries follow the deterministic smooth function that Hartwick
uses. In particular, some natural resource accounting exercises show that the variance of
proved or probable reserves is many times larger than the variance of GDP (see Young, 1992).
Therefore the NNP figure will be very volatile and useless as an income or sustainability
indicator.

A different approach might be to assume discoveries to be unexpected. The optimal control


problem of equations (1) to (4) is solved subject to the initial stock of the resource. If discoveries
are unexpected (or in unexpectedly high discrete quantities) then the optimal control problem
would be solved again and a new optimal extraction path will arise.

The interesting aspect of this approach is that only resource extraction should be considered as
depreciation. No correction should be made for discoveries because the wealth enhancing
effect would be automatically captured through a rise in the conventional measure of GDP. In
other words, when there is an unexpected discovery wealth increases and this should induce an
increase either in consumption, investment or exports. For example, in the case where the
economy is maximizing a constant consumption path, then equation (19) states that
consumption should rise by a similar proportion as wealth. Then the only correction needed to
derive NNP is to subtract rents from the (new) extraction path.

One final point worth mentioning is that the models used to derive constant consumption paths
are extremely simplified versions of an economy and therefore care has to be taken when
extracting policy implications. In particular, if there is technological change then Hartwick's rule
is too conservative as a way of guaranteeing intergenerational equity. Hartwick's rule, more than
a precise theoretical result, should be viewed as a rule of thumb to help us think about
sustainability. In Solow's words: "...I could see the rule as a rebuttable presumption, as a way of
constantly reminding ourselves that there are considerations other than immediate utility to be

taken into account" (Solow, 1986).

References
Asheim, G., (1986) "Hartwick's rule in open economies", Canadian Journal of Economics XIX
No. 3, 395-402.
Barbier, E.B. and M. Rauscher, (forthcoming) "Trade, Tropical Deforestation and Policy
Interventions", Environmental and Resource Economics.
El Serafy, S., (1989) "The Proper Calculation of Income from Depletable Natural Resources", in
Ahmad, Y., S. El Serafy and E. Lutz, Environmental Accounting for Sustainable
Development, The World Bank, Washington D.C.
Hartwick, J., (1977) "Intergenerational Equity and the Investing of Rents from Exhaustible
Resources", American Economic Review 66, 972-4.
Hartwick, J., (1990) "Natural Resources, National Accounting and Economic Depreciation",
Journal of Public Economics 43, 291-304.
Repetto, R., McGrath, W., Wells, M., Beer, C., and Rossini, F., (1989) Wasting Assets: Natural
Resources in the National Income Accounts, World Resources Institute, Washington,
D.C.
Sachs, J., (1982) "The Current Account in the Macroeconomic Adjustment Process",
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 84 (2), 147-159.
Solow, R., (1974) "Intergenerational Equity and Exhaustible Resources", Review of Economic
Studies (Symposium), 29-45.
Solow, R., (1986) "On the Intergenerational Allocation of Natural Resources", Scandinavian
Journal of Economics 88 (1), 141-149.
Weitzman, M., (1976) "On the Welfare Significance of National Product in a Dynamic Economy,
Quarterly Journal of Economics 90, 156-62.
Young, C.E., (1992) Renda Sustentavel da Extracaon Mineral no Brazil, Tesis de Maestria,
Instituto de Economia Industrial, USRJ, Rio de Janeiro.

Appendix
The following appendix shows that the extended Hartwick rule implies a constant consumption
path. To see this we use Weitzamn's result regarding the welfare meaning of NNP. Weitzman
(1976) shows that the net present value of the optimal consumption path is exactly equal to the
net present value of a constant consumption stream equal to the current NNP. In other words,
NNP in period t is the perpetual equivalence of the optimal consumption path from t onwards.
Mathematically,

(A.1) e-(s-t)NNP(t)ds = e-(s-t)C*(s)ds


t
t

where NNP(t) is the current period Net National Product and C*(s) is the consumption level at
each moment of time given by the optimal growth path.

The extended Hartwick rule would be,


(A.2) I = (YR-fR) -A = (YR-fR) -(X-M+rA)

By equation (14) we see that if the extended Hartwick rule is imposed on the economy in period
t then NNP(t) will just be the consumption level C*(t). Therefore we can write equation (A.1) as,

(A.3) C*(t) = e-(s-t)C*(s)ds


t

taking the derivative of equation (A.3) with respect to t we have,

(A.4)

C*(t)
= [et e-sC*(s)ds + et-e-tC*(t)]
t
t
(A.5)

C*(t)
= [C*(t) - C*(t)] = 0
t

Therefore, the extended Hartwick rule guarantees that consumption is constant over time.

ESSAY 2

OPTIMAL GROWTH AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

Kirk Hamilton

In what ways, if any, do the concepts of optimal growth and sustainable development differ? As
Pezzey (1989) remarked, the notion of optimality as maximizing the present discounted value of
utility is quite widely accepted in economics.

Similarly, the idea of sustainability as the

preservation of capital has had wide currency at least since Hicks wrote "Value and Capital"
(1939). What has given many economists the impetus to re-examine these concepts in recent
years is the growing concern about environmental quality and the role that this plays in
determining the welfare of both current and future generations. Issues of resource depletion,
the public good nature of environmental resources, and the public bad nature of pollution have
led to a re-appraisal of the meaning of sustainability.

This article will argue, along with Dasgupta and Heal (1979), that discounting future utility can
lead to a divergence between optimality and sustainability. The degree of substitutability of
human-made and natural resources is also a key consideration. Finally, a few thoughts on the
ethical basis of sustainable development and how this relates to the degree of binding of
sustainability constraints will be offered.

Pezzey has collected some 51 different quotations from the literature, each offering a definition
or a shade of meaning in the definition of sustainable development.

This abundance

notwithstanding, he offers a succinct and serviceable definition for the economist: that utility not
decline over time or, mathematically,
u 0.

If the rate of change is zero, then utility is constant over all time - this will be referred to as
minimal sustainability in what follows.

It is straightforward to demonstrate how discounting can lead to a divergence between optimal


growth and sustainability. In Figure 1 we see one path for utility that is constant, and therefore

minimally sustainable, and another that grows at some rate g then collapses to 0 at time T. The
discount rate is assumed to be r > 0.

T
Suppose u0egte-rtdt > u0e-rtdt, 1
0
0

u0
u0
(e(g-r)T - 1) > ,2
g-r
r

(g-r)T > lng - lnr.3

The mathematical derivation shown next to Figure 1 shows that for either an appropriate choice
of the growth rate g or for

T>

(lng - lnr)
(g - r)

then the present value of utility for the "grow and crash" scenario will be greater than that for the
"minimal sustainability" scenario. This result is only possible if utility is being discounted.

As Pezzey points out, sustainable development as defined above is a constraint rather than an
optimizing criterion. This means that it is still possible in principle to define optimal sustainable
growth as the solution to:

max ute-rtdt
0
subject u 0.

Scenarios such as the "grow and crash" example above are optimal if the sustainability criterion
is ignored. Note that utility is still discounted in this formulation. As Dasgupta and Heal (1979)
argue, while early writers such as Ramsey (1928) felt that discounting future utility was "ethically
indefensible", there is at least one rational motivation for discounting: to represent uncertainty
with respect to the existence of future generations14. Norgaard (1991, p.30) argues that we
cannot ignore rates of return (and therefore discounting) in looking at sustainability from the
point of view of intergenerational equity, when he says that "if we are concerned with the
distribution of welfare across generations, then we should transfer wealth, not engage in
inefficient investments". Mler (1989) arrives at similar conclusions by more formal means
when he argues that the relevant discount rate in judging the endowment of capital that one
generation leaves another is the return on capital in the future - this is important because it
makes the discount rate endogenous and, moreover, it is a rate that is not necessarily identical
to the pure rate of time preference of the current generation, which is one of the standard
criticisms of discounting in an intergenerational context.

This being said, the analysis of Dasgupta and Heal (1979, ch. 10) of optimal consumption in
economies with exhaustible resources puts severe limits on the relationship between
discounting, optimality and sustainability. Their model contains three critical assumptions:

i.

production follows a Cobb-Douglas functional form, with constant elasticity of


substitution between resources and reproducible capital equal to 1.

14

As David Pearce pointed out in an earlier version of this paper, however, sufficiently high discount rates may be one
way of ensuring that future generations do not exist.

ii.

elasticity of output with respect to capital is greater than that with respect to resources.

iii.

elasticity of marginal utility with respect to consumption is constant and greater than 1.

The basic model for utility discount rate r, utility u, stock of resources S, resource extraction R,
capital stock K, output F and consumption C, is therefore:

max ue-rtdt
0
given K = F-C, S = -R
where:
u(C) = -C-(-1), > 1
F(K,R) = KR
for , > 0, + = 1, > .

Under these conditions Dasgupta and Heal show that efficiency of an optimal consumption path
implies the following relationships:
(1)

FR
= FK, the Hotelling rule,
FR

C
(2) r+ = FK, the Ramsey rule.
C

For the Cobb-Douglas production function, expression (2) reduces to


C
(3) =
C

R
( ) -r
K
.

Since efficiency requires that the resource be exhausted over infinite time, this implies that
R 0 as t . For consumption (and therefore utility) to be non-declining, expression (3)
therefore requires that K 0 as well, which implies that output F must also decline. This in turn
requires that consumption C decline in the long run, as must utility. A positive rate of discount
for utility implies that optimal growth is not sustainable.

If the rate of discounting utility is zero, Dasgupta and Heal show that for suitably large elasticities
of marginal utility of consumption then optimal paths are sustainable, with increasing utility over

time. For this class of model, some of whose precepts will be discussed further, discounting of
utility and sustainability are apparently incompatible.

However, there is a nuance to this story that the literature does not bring out. Hartwick (1977) is
working with essentially the same model in examining consumption paths with exhaustible
resources. He shows that if the economy follows the rule that investment equal rents on
resource extraction, then a constant consumption level (and therefore level of utility for the utility
function employed by Dasgupta and Heal) is optimal. The Hartwick rule is simply:

(4) K = FR R.

The rate of change of consumption is derived as:

d
C& = ( F K& )
dt
=

d
( F FR R)
dt

= F& F&R R FR R&


= F& FK FR R FR R& [from (1)]
= 0.
We have therefore the result that the optimal growth model, when augmented with a dynamic
constraint in the form of the Hartwick rule, will lead to minimal sustainability as its optimal path.
The nuance is that Solow (1974) and Dasgupta and Heal start from a Rawlsian maxi-min
principle for intergenerational equity, show that this implies constant consumption over time,
then derive conditions for this to be an optimal growth path in the face of exhaustible resources.

The degree of substitutability of capital and resources is critical in this analysis of optimal growth
with exhaustible resources. Dasgupta and Heal demonstrate that if the elasticity of substitution
between capital and resources is greater than 1, then resources are not essential: positive
output is possible with zero resource input, so resources do not constrain consumption sustainability would be equivalent to maintaining non-negative net investment levels over time.
If this elasticity is less than 1, then output (and therefore consumption and utility) must be finite sustainability is impossible. Only for an elasticity of substitution exactly equal to 1 are resources
essential and output potentially unlimited.

If we assume this degree of substitutability, the 1986 paper by Solow places the Hartwick rule in
a particularly elegant light: if the rule "investment equals resource rents" is followed, this is
equivalent to living on the (constant) flow of interest from a fund of capital whose value is
maintained constant over time. The capital fund in this instance consists of the values of
reproducible capital and natural resources - as natural resources are used up, an identical value
of investment in reproducible capital must take place.

If at least some elements of natural resources do not have ready substitutes, or, more precisely,
if their elasticity of substitution is less than 1 with reproducible capital, then this sustainable
programme is in some difficulty.

This is essentially the argument of Pearce, Barbier and

Markandya (1990), although it may appear in stronger forms, for instance that the total value of
stocks of natural resources must be maintained constant (as opposed to the sum of
reproducible and natural capital as appears in the Solow article). It is certainly arguable that
particular critical functions of the natural environment (for example the ozone layer or
biodiversity) have limited substitution possibilities, and that therefore sustainability is threatened
by their depletion.

Pearce et al.'s notion of maintaining capital intact is not necessarily inconsistent with optimal
growth, particularly as Solow (1986) presents it. Solow conceives the total capital stock of an
economy as being represented by a vector of individual items, beginning perhaps with
categories of reproducible capital, such as buildings, machines and infrastructure, followed by
categories of natural capital - preserving capital means preserving the total of this vector. While
the particular context in which Solow was writing would probably have limited natural capital to
forests, fish, energy and minerals, there is no reason not to extend the list to include air, water,
wildlife, etc., provided consistent valuations could be constructed. What is required to make this
interpretation of the capital stock consistent with sustainability (and optimal growth) is that the
uses made of the critical elements of the natural stock not be depleting; in general this can be
achieved for the exploitation of renewable resources or for the enjoyment of amenity values
(although even eco-tourism has its limits in this regard).

This casting of the optimal growth problem as one of maintaining capital suggests,
parenthetically, an approach to "green national accounting" that has not been fully exploited: the
expansion of wealth accounts to include environmental resources. Hamilton (1991) argues that
total wealth per capita, so defined, is a superior national accounts indicator of sustainability.

So far in this argument it has been assumed that there is no technical progress or population

growth. Solow (1986) describes how if the simple model of optimal growth is extended in the
following way,
F = emtKR,

where F, K, and R are output, capital and resource extraction per unit of labour, labour grows at
rate n, the rate of technological change is m, and 1--4 is the Cobb-Douglas elasticity for
labour, then investing rents according to the Hartwick rule will lead to optimal growth at the rate
(m-n)
.
(1-)

In this instance, therefore, optimal growth will be sustainable at a positive rate, given the very
plausible restriction m>n5. It is clear that exponential growth in technological progress can
offset the limit to growth that is imposed if the elasticity of substitution of resources for capital is
less than 1. However, for any critical elements of natural capital which have no substitutes
technological progress cannot be the answer: how many widgets are required to substitute for
declines in the life-supporting functions of the biosphere?

Finally, it is worth reflecting on a more sophisticated example than the "grow and crash"
scenario of Figure 1, in order to examine more closely the ethical principles that underlie
sustainability. Figure 2 presents two alternative development paths.

Along path B the generation at time T reduces consumption and increases investment,
leading to greater growth for future generations. Along this path, u06 for t > T.

Along path A, u07 for all t.

The question we wish to pose is this: is path B consistent with our notions of sustainability?
Clearly the path is sustainable from time T onwards, and the level of consumption soon
overtakes and remains greater than on path A. The answer to the question would appear to be:
path B is sustainable if the generation at time T voluntarily agreed to reduce consumption and
increase investment in order to produce greater welfare in the future. If this choice were
imposed by a previous generation15 then we would be inclined to say that this is not a
sustainable path. If this argument is correct, then we cannot insist blindly that sustainability
means u08 for all time, but rather (or perhaps, in addition) that no generation can force
involuntary hardship on a future generation. This is clearly a long way from the classical
Utilitarianism that underlies the optimal growth models, since by this notion path B would be
unequivocally superior to path A.

Conclusions
By assuming a very simple definition of sustainability, that utility be non-declining, it is clear that
discounting of utility plays a critical role in determining whether optimal growth with exhaustible
resources is sustainable. It is minimally sustainable if the Hartwick rule, that resource rents be
invested, is followed - otherwise, only if the discount rate for utility is 0 or if there is sufficient
(and continual) technological progress can optimal growth be sustainable. Preserving wealth,
and critical elements of the natural environment in particular, is consistent with this notion of
sustainability.

The desirability of sustainable development is, of course, an ethical question rather than an
economic principle.

It is nonetheless illuminating to explore its ramifications in traditional

economic models of optimal growth. Ramsey's view on the ethical defensibility of discounting
utility bears repetition in this context. The discussion of the strict adherence to the principle that
utility be non-declining suggests, however, that sustainability as an ethical position requires a
15

It is not hard to conceive of examples: suppose earlier generations profligately consumed conventional energy, so
that the generation at T had to go on a crash programme of development of alternative energy sources.

more sophisticated representation in our models than has been provided to date.

References
Dasgupta, P., and Heal, G., (1979) Economic Theory and Exhaustible Resources, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge.
Hamilton, K.E., (1991) Proposed Treatments of the Environment and Natural Resources in the
National Accounts: A Critical Assessment, National Accounts and Environment Division,
Discussion paper no. 7, Statistics Canada, Ottawa.
Hartwick, J.M, (1977) Intergenerational Equity and the Investing of Rents from Exhaustible
Resources, American Economic Review, 67, No. 5, 972-4.
Hicks, J.R., (1939) Value and Capital, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Mler, K.-G., 1989) Sustainable Development, (mimeo), Stockholm.
Norgaard, R.B., (1991) Sustainability as Intergenerational Equity, Report IDP 97, Asia Regional
Series, The World Bank.
Pearce, D.W., Barbier, E., and Markandya, A., (1990) Sustainable Development, Earthscan,
London.
Pezzey, J., (1989) Economic Analysis of Sustainable Growth and Sustainable Development,
Environment Dept. Working Paper No. 15, The World Bank.
Ramsey, F., (1928) A Mathematical Survey of Saving, Economic Journal, 38, 543-59.
Solow, R.M., (1974) Intergenerational Equity and Exhaustible Resources, Review of Economic
Studies (Symposium) 29-46.
Solow, R.M., (1986) On the Intergenerational Allocation of Natural Resources, Scandinavian
Journal of Economics, 88(1), 141-49.

ESSAY 3
SUSTAINABILITY, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND EMPLOYMENT16
Carlos Eduardo Frickmann Young17

1.

INTRODUCTION

The trade-off between sustainability and economic growth is still the subject of controversy. The
use of macroeconomic growth models subject to environmental constraints is an interesting
theoretical way to treat the problem.

In general, studies on this theme use neoclassical macroeconomic models, where the objective
is to find the optimal path of growth. The optimal growth path means that path which maximises
social welfare in a certain period of time. Sustainability appears as a constraint, imposing an
additional intertemporal goal. For example, utility per capita (or consumption per capita, or
capital stock level) cannot be decreasing (for a review in this issue see Pezzey, 1989).

However, a very important assumption is usually made: 'conventional' factors of production man-made capital and labour - are fully employed. The justification for this procedure is derived
from the belief that there is no involuntary unemployment in the long term. But there is no
definitive evidence (empirical or theoretical) supporting this belief. On the contrary, long term
unemployment characterizes the majority of economies, especially in developing countries.
Hence, the determination of effective demand, and the functioning of an economy out of the fullemployment equilibrium, is the main issue for several approaches not considered mainstream
(Keynes, 1973; Kalecki, 1991a). Economic growth is not thought of as oscillating around an
assured long run equilibrium path since full-employment is not an assumption but a desired
objective.

The aim of this paper is to present a simplified non-conventional macroeconomic model which
relates effective demand and the sustainable use of natural resources. It supposes a small nondeveloped economy based on the exports of a natural resource and with a heavy income

16

I am grateful for the comments of Prof. David W. Pearce.

17

Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro and visiting fellow at CSERGE-UCL.

concentration. 'Optimal growth' is understood as maintaining labour full-employed18 and


sustainability is defined as maintaining a non-decreasing capital stock level. The model is based
in a modified Kaleckian equation of income determination (Kalecki, 1991b) where exports of the
natural resource substitute for the role of investment as autonomous expenditure. Therefore,
employment is a direct function of resource depletion and is negatively related to sustainability.

The paper shows the effects of changes in some macroeconomic variables (income distribution,
terms of trade, external debt, exchange rate) on sustainability. The paper concludes that the
management of macroeconomic variables influences the sustainability of natural resource
based economies.

2.

THE MACROECONOMIC MODEL

We suppose an economy is characterized by a huge disproportion in the income distribution. As


a simplification, there are two basic classes, 'poor' and 'rich'19, each one with very distinct
patterns of income and consumption.

Four distinct uses for final products are possible:

investment, consumer goods for the 'rich', consumer goods for the 'poor', and exports. Thus, this
economy can be divided into four departments, each one representing the integrated production
(including all intermediate consumption) of final demand categories (see Table 1).

Table 1: Production and Income Generation


P(I) + P(Cr) + P(Cp) + P(X) = P
W(I) + W(Cr) + W(Cp) + W(X) = W
M(I) + M(Cr) + M(Cp) + M(X) = M
-------------------------------------------------------I +

Cr +

Cp + X

= Yg+M

where: P: gross profits (including rents)


W: wages
M: total imports (including imported inputs)
I: gross investment
Cr: consumer goods for the 'rich'
Cp: consumer goods for the 'poor'

18

This condition itself may not warrant optimality in neoclassical terms, but it is certainly a necessary condition.

19

In the original model 'workers' and 'capitalists', respectively (Kalecki 1991b).

X: exports
Yg: gross income

The 'poor' receive wages and spend all their income. Hence, the production of consumer goods
to the poor is equal to the total amount of wages.

Cp = W

(1)

The 'rich' receive the profits obtained from domestic production and exports. Since the economic
importance of the domestic market is small, the consumption level of the rich is a function of
exports.

Cr = r.X (0<r<1) (2)

The investment in man-made capital is assumed to be equal to its depreciation and is done with
imported equipment. Since there is no domestic production of capital goods, P(I) and W(I) are
equal to zero, and there are no multiplier effects from it.

Exports are totally based on the natural resource. Their value in domestic prices is a function of
the international price of the resource (pi), the exchange rate (e) and the quantity depleted (Q).

X = pi.e.Q (3)

Kn(t) is the economic value of the stocks of the natural resource in the period t. The rate of
growth of Kn if the resource is not depleted is g, and expresses changes both in economic and
physical terms. The rate of actual depletion of the resource is d. The variation of Kn in time can
be expressed as:
Q = d.Kn (4)

S(t) = dKn(t) = (g-d).Kn(t) (5)


dt

By assumption, there is no change in man-made capital stock. Hence, S(t) is the 'sustainability
indicator'20.
20

Following the definitions presented in Pearce and Atkinson (1992), it is a 'weak-sustainability indicator'.

The imports are proportional to the net product level (Y).

M = m.Y

(0<m<1)

(6)

Analogously to Kalecki (1991b), the net product can be determined as follows (the complete
development of the model is shown in the Appendix):

Y = 1 .(1+r+ r.wr+ wx ).X = .X (7)


1+m

1-wp

where: wr: the share of wages in the total income of consumer goods to the 'rich'
wx: the share of wages in the total income of exports department
wp: the share of wages in the total income of consumer goods to the 'poor'
:

income-multiplier of autonomous expenditure (X)

The product level is a direct function of the exports, i.e., the depletion of the natural resource.
Assuming m, r, wr, wx, wp and the labour-productivity as constants, there is one level of natural
resource exports (X*) which assures full-employment.
Y* = .X* (7a)

The full-employment extraction level and correspondent rate of depletion are:


Q* = X*

(8)

pi.e
d* = Q*

(9)

Kn

Consequently, there are three possibilities for the sustainability of this economy:
(i)
(ii)
(iii)

d* < g

Full-employment is compatible with an increasing level of sustainability (S>0).

Full-employment implies a constant level of sustainability (S=0).

Full-employment implies a decreasing level of sustainability (S<0).

d =g
d <g

Figure 1 presents these results:

Figure 1
Kn

S
i

ii

ii
iii

iii

In situations (i) and (ii), the ambition of full-employment in the present does not compromise the
same objective in the future. However, in situation (iii), short-run full-employment means
unemployment in the long run. In this case, changes in the macroeconomic conditions are
strictly necessary to reconcile sustainability and full-employment.

It becomes clear that the macroeconomic environment has important impacts on sustainability.
In the next session, the model is used to highlight these impacts in sustainability due to changes
in some macroeconomic variables.

3.

CHANGE IN MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES

3.1

Improvement in income distribution

In that case, wages represent a bigger share of total income. As a consequence of the increase
in wr, wp and wx, the multiplier becomes bigger. It means that a smaller depletion of the
natural resource is necessary to maintain full-employment. Due to the reduction of d*,
sustainability increases when the share of the 'poor' in total income increases (see Figure 2).

Figure 2
S

W
Y

If the income distribution along the time behaves as a Kuznets Curve, i.e., with a U-shape for
the ratio wages-total income, the sustainability function will also have a U-shape format (see
Figure 3).

Figure 3
Conventional Kuznets Curve
W
Y

Environmental Kuznets Curve


S

Y per capita

Y per capita

There is an important assumption for these results. It is supposed that there is unemployed
capacity in the production of 'poor' consumer goods. If not, the excessive demand will start an
inflationary process and a fall of real wages, which would restore the income distribution to its
original situation.

3.2

Change in terms of trade (price of the resource in the international market)

There is a controversy about the price path of natural resources in international trade. There are
two opposing positions: the 'Hotelling Rule', which points to an increasing price due to growing
scarcity of the resource, and the 'Prebisch-Singer Rule', which points to a decrease of natural
resources prices in the long term. Both situations can be examined and their results are
symmetric.
In the first case, there is an increase in the value of the exports measured in domestic prices (d*'
< d*). Therefore, a smaller depletion can lead to full-employment. On the other hand, a loss in
terms of trade implies the necessity to expand depletion (d*' > d*). Figure 4 illustrates these
results.

Figure 4

pi
3.3

Structural adjustment and external indebtedness

In general, developing countries have relatively high levels of external indebtedness. The
payment of the service of the debt implies the necessity to increase exports. Hence, adjustment
programmes to stimulate exports are very frequent. In our hypothetical case, two solutions are
possible.

The first one is a shortage of the supply, considering that the country has a monopolistic power
in the international market for the resource. The shortage produces a rise in the price of the
resource and a reduction in the depletion rate, as discussed above.

But the exporter country usually has a small share of the international trade of the resource. A
devaluation of the exchange rate (i.e. increasing e) is often recommended to stimulate exports.
The resource can be sold at a lower internat-ional price without damage to the exporter's profit
measured in domestic prices.

The devaluation also changes the income distribution against the 'poor', since real wages
decrease21. Therefore, the fall in sustainability should be bigger than in the case discussed in
section 3.2 (see Figure 5).

Figure 5

21

If wages in domestic prices are held constant, real wages fall through a rise in the prices of imported consumer
goods.

e I : revaluation

4.

e I : devaluation

CONCLUSION

The purpose of this paper has been to present a dilemma: the pursuit of current full-employment
in economies based on natural resources depletion can bring future unemployment. In poor
countries, the degrees of freedom to 'postpone' welfare are strongly reduced since people live
very close to subsistence.

However, the management of macroeconomic variables influences decisions related to the


exhaustion of the resources. In some circumstances the results on sustainability are positive, in
others negative. Table 2 reviews the principal hypothetical cases discussed in this paper.

Table 2
Macroeconomic circumstance

Effect on sustainability

Improvement in the income distribution

Increase

Loss in terms of trade

Decrease

Devaluation of exchange rate

Decrease

In more mathematical terms:


+

S(t) = f{g(t), d(t), w(t), pi(t), e(t)}

Nevertheless, it is important to highlight two of the assumptions adopted. The most important is
the absence of domestic production of capital goods. Withdrawing this assumption can lead to
different results, since current depletion can be used to enlarge the stock of man-made capital,
with positive effects on long-run employment.

The second one is the belief about the future economic importance of the resource. Forecasts

are generally based on current trends but unexpected changes in technology and consumers'
preferences may make depletion economically not feasible. Past experiences (latex in Brazil,
saltpetre in Chile, etc.) are not sufficient to prevent new cases, since the course of technical
progress and human behaviour are uncertain.

The extreme simplicity of the model requires that results in this paper should not be viewed as
definitive statements. Empirical case study analysis is essential for a better comprehension22.

References
Jonish, J. (1992) Sustainable Development and Employment: Forestry in Malaysia. Working
Paper No. 234. International Labour Office, Geneva
Kalecki, M. (1991a) 'Theory of Economic Dynamics: An Essay on Cyclical and Long-Run
Changes in Capitalist Economy', in Osiantynski, J. (ed.) Collected Works of Michal
Kalecki, v.2, Oxford University Press, Oxford. pp.205-348.
Kalecki, M. (1991b) 'The Marxian Equations of Reproduction and Modern Economics', in
Osiantynski, J. (ed.) Collected Works of Michal Kalecki, v.2, Oxford University Press,
Oxford. pp.259-466.
Keynes, J.M. (1973) 'The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money'. Collected
Writings of John Maynard Keynes, v.7. Macmillan, London.
Pearce, D.W. and Atkinson, G. (1992) Are National Economies Sustainable? Measuring
Sustainable Development. GEC Working Paper 92-11, Centre for Social and Economic
Research in the Global Environment, University College London and University of East
Anglia.
Pezzey, J. (1989) Economic Analysis of Sustainable Growth and Sustainable Development.
(Environment Department Working Paper No.15) World Bank, Washington.

22

A good example is Jonish, 1992.

Appendix

Equation (1) can be re-written as:


Cp = W(I) + W(Cr) + W(Cp) + W(X)

By assumption, W(I) is null. Assuming wr=W(Cr)/Cr; wp=W(Cp)/Cp and wx=W(X)/X:

Cp = wr.Cr + wp.Cp + wx.X

Cp = wr.Cr + wx.X

(10)

1 - wp

The general macroeconomic equation is:


Yg + M = I + Cr + Cp + X

Investment is just equal to depreciation, so the net income is:


Y + M = Cr + Cp + X

Using equations (2), (6) and (10):


Y + m.Y = r.X + wr.(r.X) + wx.X + X
1 - wp

Y = 1 .(1 + r + r.wr + wx).X


1+m

1 - wp

You might also like