You are on page 1of 22

See

discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/5223109

An Empirical Investigation of the Process of


Knowledge Transfer in International Strategic
Alliances

Article in Journal of International Business Studies February 2004


DOI: 10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400091 Source: RePEc

CITATIONS READS

326 369

1 author:

Bernard L. Simonin
Tufts University
19 PUBLICATIONS 2,682 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

All in-text references underlined in blue are linked to publications on ResearchGate, Available from: Bernard L. Simonin
letting you access and read them immediately. Retrieved on: 10 August 2016
Journal of International Business Studies (2004) 35, 407427
& 2004 Palgrave Macmillan Ltd. All rights reserved 0047-2506 $30.00
www.jibs.net

An empirical investigation of the process of


knowledge transfer in international strategic
alliances

Bernard L Simonin Abstract


This research proposes and tests a basic model of organizational learning that
The Fletcher School, Tufts University, Medford, captures the process of knowledge transfer in international strategic alliances.
MA, USA Based on a cross-sectional sample of 147 multinationals and a structural
equation methodology, this study empirically investigates the simultaneous
Correspondence: effects of learning intent, learning capacity (LC), knowledge ambiguity, and its
BL Simonin, The Fletcher School, Tufts
two key antecedents tacitness and partner protectiveness on technological
University, Medford, MA 02155, USA.
Tel: 1 617 627 5255;
knowledge transfer. In the interest of expanding our understanding of the
Fax: 1 617 627 3712; organizational mechanisms that both hinder and facilitate learning, the
E-mail: bernard.simonin@tufts.edu concept of LC is refined into three distinct components: resource-, incentive-,
and cognitive-based LC. Further, the strength of the relationships between these
theoretical constructs and knowledge transfer is examined in light of the
possible moderating effects of organizational culture, firm size, and the form
and competitive regime of the alliance. Consistently, learning intent (as a
driver) and knowledge ambiguity (as an impediment) emerge as the most
significant determinants of knowledge transfer. Moreover, the effects of partner
protectiveness and LC on the learning outcome are moderated by the firms
own culture towards learning, the size of the firm, the structural form of the
alliance, and the fact that partners may or may not be competitors.
Journal of International Business Studies (2004), 35, 407427.
doi:10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400091

Keywords: strategic alliances; knowledge transfer; learning capacity

Introduction
Over the past 15 years there has been a growing interest in
international strategic alliances and how organizations learn from
their partners and develop new competencies through their
collaborative efforts (Inkpen, 2002; Mowery et al., 2002). This
distinct and multidisciplinary line of inquiry has generated a
wealth of conceptual work and theorizing, but a limited amount
of empirical work (Mjoen and Tallman, 1997; Simonin, 1999a).
Not much has changed since the early warnings of Mowery et al.
(1996, 78):
Empirical research on the role of knowledge within the firm and
Received: 26 February 2003
Revised: 12 February 2004
alliances within firm strategy, has been hampered by the
Accepted: 1 April 2004 widespread reliance on anecdotes and assertion, rather than
Online publication date: 8 July 2004 statistical evidence.
Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
408

To address these limitations, the current study or hinder knowledge transfer. Specifically, it will
will attempt to depart from speculative grounds in account for the concurrent effects of learning
favor of empirically based research that relies on a intent, learning capacity (LC), knowledge ambigu-
large survey sample and on a structural equation ity and tacitness, and partner protectiveness on
methodology. technological knowledge transfer (see conceptual
model in Figure 1). Although many studies have
Commenting on alliance learning research, identified the importance of these variables sepa-
Inkpen (2002, 277) confessed: rately, their simultaneous effects have yet to be
examined and assessed empirically. In particular,
Now that there is a solid base of antecedents the model will refine the concept of LC into three
research, the next step is theoretical and empiri- distinct components: resource-, incentive-, and cogni-
cal work that integrates the diverse perspectives tive-based LC. Further, the strength of the relation-
and establishes some causal links across the ships between these theoretical constructs and
variables. knowledge transfer will be examined in light of
Accordingly, it is the aim of this study to develop the possible moderating effects of four key theore-
and test such an integrated model. Based on a cross- tical constructs: organizational culture, firm size,
sectional sample of 147 multinationals and a latent alliance form (equity vs non-equity), and the
variable approach, this study will introduce and competitive regime of the alliance.
empirically investigate the process of knowledge
transfer in international strategic alliances. The Theoretical model and background
postulated model identifies and integrates various At the heart of the learning process in alliances are
key organizational mechanisms that either enable knowledge-specific, partner-specific (at the level of

Organizational Learning
Organizational

Mechanism Outcome
Motivation

LEARNING
INTENT
H3a (+) H1 (+)

RESOURCE-BASED
H3b (+) L.C.
H2a (+)
Learning Capacity

H3c (+)
INCENTIVE-BASED
(L.C.)

L.C. H2b (+)

H2c (+) KNOWLEDGE


TRANSFER
COGNITIVE-BASED
L.C.

H4 (-) H5 (-)
Learning Hindrance

PARTNER
PROTECTIVENESS
H6 (+)

AMBIGUITY
H7 (+)
TACITNESS

Moderating Effects

Organizational Culture
Firm Size
Alliance Form
Competitive Regime

Figure 1 Conceptual model.

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
409

the knowledge seeker, knowledge provider, and Buckley, 1996), the focus on learning and knowl-
their inter-relationship), and context-specific vari- edge transfer as motives has led to the emergence of
ables (Simonin, 1999a). This view is echoed by a distinct stream of research that covers:
Inkpen (2002), who frames the antecedents of
alliance learning into learning partner character- (1) how knowledge is managed in strategic alliances
istics, teaching partner characteristics, knowledge (Tiemessen et al., 1997; Khanna et al., 1998;
characteristics, relationship factors, and alliance Inkpen, 2002; Martin and Salomon, 2002; Zeng
form. Building on this commonality, the proposed and Hennart, 2002);
model represents a parsimonious, but yet complete, (2) how knowledge is transferred across partners
way of accounting for these various facets of the (Appleyard, 1996; Dodgson, 1996; Mowery et al.,
learning process: learning intent, learning capabil- 1996, 2002; Baughn et al., 1997; Choi and Lee,
ity, organizational culture, size (knowledge-seeker 1997; Simonin, 1999a, b);
level); partner protectiveness (knowledge-holder (3) how knowledge is acquired from the parents by
level); tacitness and knowledge ambiguity (knowl- the joint venture itself (Lyles and Salk, 1996);
edge level); and alliance form and competitive (4) how knowledge about collaborating per se
regime (context level). This model also captures develops over time and impacts on collaborative
the fundamental steps between stimulus and outcomes (Doz, 1996; Powell et al., 1996; Dyer
response: motivation to learn, capacity to learn, and Singh, 1998; Kale et al., 2002; Simonin,
and learning outcome. Finally, the model contrasts 2002); and
learning drivers and learning impediments by (5) how knowledge impacts performance (Lane
isolating organizational specificities and mechan- et al., 2001; Appleyard, 2002; Dussauge et al.,
isms that facilitate and hinder knowledge transfers 2002; Reuer et al., 2002; Tallman and Jenkins,
in international alliances. 2002).
In line with past research that has focused on the
technology or technical-capability side (e.g., Hage- A by-product of this research focus has been some
doorn and Schakenraad, 1994; Zander and Kogut, degree of fascination with the notion of learning
1995; Appleyard, 1996), this study focuses on race a` la Hamel (1990, 1991) or Reich and Mankin
technology and process know-how. The various (1986). More recently, a strong research counter-
components of the proposed model are introduced, movement has surfaced pointing to the pitfalls and
leading to the formulation of the specific hypoth- possible fallacy of this learning race metaphor. Zeng
eses that govern their inter-relationships; in addi- and Hennart (2002, 189), in particular, argue that
tion, the subsequent sections offer a close template racing is not as frequent as commonly believed, and
to the operationalization of the variables in the that it should not be viewed
model.
as a goal for joint ventures, but rather as a
consequence of poor joint venture design and
Learning drivers: learning intent and capacity management when parties are attempting to
follow potentially more rewarding strategies of
Learning intent cooperative specialization.
In the context of individual learning, motivation to
learn is one of the major determinants of learning Mowery et al. (2002) acknowledge that few
(Kelly, 1974; Filley et al., 1976). In an inter- scholars have distinguished between these learn-
organizational setting such as a strategic alliance, ing and co-specialization alliances. More impor-
learning intent (Hamel, 1991) describes the same tantly, these authors warn that the impact of
self-determination, desire and will of an organiza- absorptive capacity varies across these types of
tion to learn from its partner or collaborative alliance and, therefore, that the literatures main
environment. It captures the degree of desire for emphasis on learning alliances fails to capture the
internalizing a partners skills and competencies full understanding of the impact of absorptive
(Pucik, 1988; Hamel, 1990). It is clear that strong capacity and alliance outcomes. The model pro-
rationales for collaborating do not necessarily posed in this study addresses this criticism and
correspond to a strong learning intent. reconciles the two views of alliances (learning race
While the rationales for entering an alliance are vs co-specialization) by formally accounting for an
numerous and well documented (Glaister and organizations learning intent and postulating:

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
410

Hypothesis 1: The higher the learning intent, the overlap between partners (Mowery et al., 2002)
higher the level of knowledge transfer. rather than firm-level singularities.
In comparison, LC is focused less on the specific
combination of partners and the joint space
Learning capacity (membrane) of the alliance. Rather, it is concerned
Under his discussion of awakening LC, Thompson with the firm-specific levers and resources that can
(1995) acknowledges that the starting point for be manipulated so that external knowledge can be
learning in the natural world is curiosity. That recognized, assimilated, and applied beyond the
desire to learn plays the role of a stressor that helps joint space. In short, LC corresponds to the
enact the proper cognitive capacity and translates actionable side of absorptive capacity. In their
into the deployment of other complementary reconceptualization of absorptive capacity, Zahra
resources. Although motivation corresponds to a and George (2002) identify four complementary
required level of stress favorable to stimulating capabilities: knowledge acquisition, assimilation,
learning, the actual level of learning is subject to transformation, and exploitation. For each one of
cognitive and physical limitations as well as to these capabilities, LC represents the firms specific
internal constraints. LC at the organizational level resources and assets that can be deployed opera-
can be thought of as the equivalent of bounded tionally to drive the process and enhance its
rationality at the individual level. Bounded ration- efficiency. LC is a fundamental determinant of
ality corresponds to the limited capacity of human absorptive capacity. Greater LC translates into
beings to obtain, store, process, and share informa- greater absorptive capacity.
tion accurately (Simon, 1978). Under Daft and Hamel (1990) names the capacity of organiza-
Hubers (1987) information-processing paradigm, tions to learn from their partner receptivity. Among
organizational learning can be decomposed simi- the factors determining receptivity, Hamel identi-
larly into information acquisition, distribution, fies the appropriateness of resource deployment,
interpretation, and organizational memory. Under incentive systems, attitude towards learning, and
this approach, efficient communication systems are the propensity to unlearn as crucial. Accordingly, in
the key to alleviating the problem of bounded the context of this study (see Figure 1), we
rationality. In turn, the efficiency of communica- decompose LC into three separate components
tion systems depends on the magnitude and that correspond to three distinct classes of organi-
appropriateness of resources allocated to that end. zational routines and mechanisms that facilitate
In a broader sense, LC, as the collection of all these knowledge transfers in strategic alliances:
dedicated resources, is both the engine and the
bottleneck of the learning system. (1) resource-based LC;
LC is related to, but at the same time distinct (2) incentive-based LC; and
from, absorptive capacity. Originally, Cohen and (3) cognitive-based LC.
Levinthal (1990, 128) defined absorptive capacity as
the ability to recognize the value of new external Finally, the propensity to unlearn is also
knowledge, assimilate it, and apply it to commercial accounted for in the proposed model, not as a
ends. Whereas early investigations have focused on direct antecedent of learning, but rather as a
the issue of prior related knowledge, absorptive manifestation of a particular organizational culture
capacity remains a much more complex construct (if that may or may not be conducive to learning
not concept). Unfortunately, as argued by Zahra and (moderating variable).
George (2002, 186), empirical studies do not always Looking at the first component of LC resource-
capture the rich theoretical arguments and the based LC the appropriateness of resource deploy-
multidimensionality of the construct. In the context ment corresponds to the commitment of both
of learning alliances, research on absorptive capacity human and tangible support assets. As recognized
(Lane et al., 2001; Inkpen, 2002; Mowery et al., 2002) by Inkpen (2002), many studies have stressed the
has evolved with a strong focus on the character- importance of managerial resources in the learning
istics of the particular combination of partners. Dyer process, but few have shed light on how the process
and Singh (1998) refer to it as partner-specific actually works. We contend that two factors have to
absorptive capacity. This conception of absorptive be present.
capacity emphasizes partner similarities (Lane and First, sufficient personnel should be involved
Lubatkin, 1998) and the breadth and depth of in the alliance. Resource-poor staffing strategies

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
411

(Pucik, 1988), driven by cost considerations rather learning can take many forms (e.g., a direct
than an investment outlook, certainly diminish the monetary incentive, a factor in promotion and
capacity to learn (usually by denying the slack advancement, or a source of formal recognition and
resources necessary to learning). Limited staffing acknowledgement in the organization). To be
results in a constant struggle to solve immediate effective, a learning agenda must not only be
problems, leaving no leeway for learning. clearly defined and codified in a language under-
Second, the involvement of key personnel in the stood by all but it must also be communicated to
venture, at both the management and the opera- the relevant parties (Pucik, 1988). As with resource-
tional level, is crucial for effective learning. Low based LC, incentive-based LC is expected to affect
quality of staff assigned to alliances (Pucik, 1988) significantly the learning outcome:
can plague the learning process. Other damaging
practices include insufficient lead time for staffing Hypothesis 2b: The higher the incentive-based
decisions and dependence on the partner for LC, the higher the level of knowledge transfer.
staffing as well as the deliberate lack of assignment
of talented personnel outside headquarters or The third component of LC, cognitive-based LC,
corporate labs or, worse, the dumping of side- captures general attitudes and beliefs towards
tracked employees. learning that prevail in the organization. In line
Next to human resources, support assets in the with Walshs (1995, 294) observation that by
form of information processing, logistic, financial, understanding organization-level cognition, we
and communication capabilities are needed to help may be closer to appreciating the essence of
in the acquisition, processing, storage, and diffu- organizing, the parallel intent here is to move
sion of relevant information and knowledge com- closer to appreciating the nature of learning
ponents. Does LC represented by the combination capabilities. As with the study of organizational
of these resources impact on the learning outcome? change, the existence of cognitive impediments to
In their follow-up investigation of Hungarian learning has been well established. For instance,
international joint ventures, Lane et al. (2001) discussing barriers to organizational learning,
showed some partial support for the relationship Mai (1996, 27) argues that blind spots skilled
between absorptive capacity and knowledge incompetence that prevents us from noticing
learned. Likewise, Mowery et al. (2002) have inherent contradictions in our actions are key
reported that, indeed, the outcome of learning impediments to learning that are a consequence of
alliances is influenced by partner-specific absorp- our own intellectual arrogance. As an antidote, he
tive capacity. In the more inclusive context of this recommends humility with regard to the value and
study, it is also expected that resource-based LC validity of other perspectives. In the context of
drives the learning outcome: strategic alliances, a common related cognitive
limitation pertains to what Hamel et al. (1989)
Hypothesis 2a: The higher the resource-based have coined the arrogance of leadership syn-
LC, the higher the level of knowledge transfer. drome. Under this orientation, a firm tends to
develop an aura of superiority vis-a`-vis its partner; it
Whereas resource-based LC relates to the deploy- starts to assume the position of a teacher and to
ment of human resources and other physical assets, project one of a student onto its partner. In
incentive-based learning capacity corresponds to unequivocal terms, Hamel (1990) further argues
explicit institutional routines, systems, rules and that humility is another prerequisite for learning.
guidelines that clarify individual expectations and On the other hand, ostentatious displays of tech-
duties, steer learning activities in non-ambiguous nological mastery or excessive zeal in showcasing
terms, foster a learning orientation, and induce superior competency may turn into a sure leakage
commitment to a learning objective. Building on of know-how to partners only happy to oblige by
Puciks (1988) framework of organizational learning listening. Not only resource- or incentive-based
obstacles in alliances, two specific manifestations of organizational procedures, competencies, and
this type of LC are considered: (1) the existence of assets, but also, more subtly, cognitive-based LC is
an actual reward system, and (2) the presence of a expected to affect learning outcomes:
clear learning agenda. Successful knowledge-seek-
ing firms reward alliance managers for what they Hypothesis 2c: The stronger the cognitive-based
learn (Baughn et al., 1997). A reward system for LC, the higher the level of knowledge transfer.

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
412

Learning intent on LC To create knowledge, business organizations


Nonaka and Takeuchi (1995, 74) argue: should foster their employees commitment by
formulating an organizational intention and
The knowledge spiral is driven by organizational
proposing it to them.
intention, which is defined as an organizations
aspiration to its goals. Efforts to achieve the Thus, as with resource-based LC, we expect intent
intention usually take the form of strategy within to influence positively the degree of incentive-
a business setting. From the viewpoint of organi- based LC.
zational knowledge creation, the essence of
strategy lies in developing the organizational Hypothesis 3b: The higher the learning intent,
capability to acquire, create, accumulate, and the higher the incentive-based LC.
exploit knowledge.
Finally, it is also postulated that the will to learn
That is, intent must translate into capability is conducive to the establishment of a stronger
building and resource deployment. Low priority cognitive-based LC. Stereotypes and beliefs about
given to learning activities (Pucik, 1988) is com- oneself and others can be resilient for individuals
pounded by the problem of not being able to easily and organizations. When it comes to learning from
price intangible assets that are the direct outcome others, fear of failing, losing face, and punishment
of learning. Under these circumstances, the absence represent strong barriers to learning (Mai, 1996).
of a clear valuation tends to limit the allocation of Nevertheless, these inhibitors can be neutralized
funds and resources to the learning purpose. As a with proper intent and perspectives in place;
result, a conservative cost-driven rather than cognitive changes can take place. For instance, in
investment-driven outlook is likely to prevail, one response to the not invented here syndrome,
that does not favor the build-up of the LC. In a way, opening doors strategies, as coined by Mai
the deployment of appropriate human and support (1996), can be rolled out. These are strategies for
capabilities essential to the transfer of knowledge is encouraging inclusion (i.e., corporate initiatives to
strictly contingent upon the actual commitment of invite other points of view, to create opportunities
top management to the learning agenda. Overall, for joint problem-solving). Given the right impetus
learning intent is expected to affect LC. A strong (e.g., motivation to learn), cognitive-based LC can
motivation to learn from collaboration represents turn more favorable.
the first necessary step in designing an explicit plan
for facilitating the learning process: Hypothesis 3c: The higher the learning intent,
the stronger the cognitive-based LC.
Hypothesis 3a: The higher the learning intent,
the higher the resource-based LC. Learning impediments: partner protectiveness,
ambiguity, and tacitness
Learning intent is not just expected to influence
the deployment of appropriate human and physical Partner protectiveness
resources. It is also expected to translate into the As the various components of LC support knowl-
conception of explicit institutional routines and edge transfer, the degree of protectiveness of a
guidelines that will help shape individual expecta- partner inhibits such transfers. In their conceptua-
tions and steer learning activities. From the pre- lization of knowledge transfer capacity, Martin and
sence of an actual reward system to the existence of Salomon (2002) distinguish between source transfer
clear learning agenda, incentive-based LC is driven capacity and recipient transfer capacity. Whereas
by the real motivation and commitment of the recipient transfer capacity relates to LC in this
organization to learn, past corporate rhetoric and study, source transfer capacity encapsulates the
more abstract vision statements. In fact, Von Krogh ability of a firm to articulate its own knowledge,
et al. (2000) insist that a proper knowledge vision to assess the needs and capabilities of the recipient,
must specify what knowledge organizational mem- and to transmit that knowledge effectively. Next to
bers need to seek and create. That is, the overall the intrinsic ability of the transferor lies its own
intent needs to be articulated and codified in a willingness to engage in such a transfer. This duality
language and a format that resonate with organiza- between ability and willingness of the knowledge
tional members. In this spirit, Nonaka and Takeu- repository has been identified as an important
chi (1995, 75) argue: challenge for researchers (Mowery et al., 2002).

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
413

In strategic alliances, the protection of proprie- understanding of the logical linkages between
tary knowledge from partners is a vital issue to actions and outcomes, inputs and outputs, and
many firms (Pisano, 1988; Baughn et al., 1997; causes and effects that are related to technological
Simonin, 1999a; Inkpen, 2002). Transferring part- or process know-how. It encapsulates the degree of
ners must have an incentive to palliate the cost transferability of information, know-how, compe-
typically associated with the transfer (Dyer and tence, knowledge, or skills. If ambiguity in skill
Singh, 1998). If not, partners can adopt explicit and resource deployment which are sources of
measures, deploy shielding mechanisms, and competitive advantage creates barriers to imita-
engage in defensive actions to protect the transpar- tion among competitors (Reed and DeFillippi,
ency of their competencies, particularly when the 1990) and within the firm (Szulanski, 1996), it also
embodied knowledge is explicit and held by only a affects negatively the propensity to learn from a
few experts (Hamel, 1991; Inkpen and Beamish, strategic alliance partner. It ultimately affects the
1997). Hence protection of technological know- transfer outcome.
how is likely to be prevalent and actively managed.
Hypothesis 5: The greater the degree of knowl-
Therefore, partner protectiveness is expected to
edge ambiguity, the lower the level of knowledge
lead to greater knowledge ambiguity and directly
transfer.
impede knowledge transfer.
As argued above, partner protectiveness is
Hypothesis 4: The more protective the partner is
expected to have a similar direct, negative effect
of its knowledge, the lower the level of knowl-
on knowledge transfer. At the same time, protec-
edge transfer.
tiveness is also expected to be an antecedent of
knowledge ambiguity. That is, the knowledge held
Ambiguity by more protective partners is likely to be more
Far from being readily or easily transferred from the causally ambiguous.
originator to a user, knowledge faces barriers and is
Hypothesis 6: The more protective the partner is
relatively immobile (Kogut and Zander, 1992;
of its knowledge, the greater the degree of
Tiemessen et al., 1997). Knowledge transfer depends
knowledge ambiguity.
on how easily that knowledge can be transported,
interpreted, and absorbed (Hamel et al., 1989). In
this process, Hedlund and Zander (1993) pointed to Tacitness
the need to consider the more subtle aspects of Numerous studies have acknowledged the critical-
knowledge in particular its ambiguity, its resis- ity of tacitness (e.g., Kogut and Zander, 1993;
tance to clear communication, its embeddedness in Zander and Kogut, 1995; Choi and Lee, 1997), but
context, and its idiosyncrasy. Likewise, Crossan and few have examined empirically its exact impor-
Inkpen (1995) acknowledged that successful joint- tance in light of other key theoretical constructs
venture learning strategies call for firms to over- related to knowledge transfer (cf. Simonin,
come the ambiguity associated with their partners 1999a, b). Tacitness is often associated with Pola-
skills. All these studies are indicative of the nyis (1967) observation that we can know more
existence of an important underlying latent con- than we can tell. The dichotomy between tacit and
struct knowledge ambiguity that needs to be explicit knowledge is based on whether knowledge
explicitly recognized and integrated in modeling can or cannot be codified and transmitted in a
efforts (Simonin, 1999a, b). formal, systematic language or representation, and
When studying knowledge ambiguity, a funda- has been well documented (Kogut and Zander,
mental starting point resides in Reed and DeFillip- 1993; Zander and Kogut, 1995; Choi and Lee,
pis (1990) observation that a strong barrier to 1997). Theoretically, Reed and DeFillippi (1990)
imitation originates from the inability of competi- singled out tacitness as a key source of ambiguity
tors to comprehend the competencies that are that raises barriers to imitation. Empirically, in
sources of competitive advantage. These authors their study of the transfer of manufacturing
expanded on Lippman and Rumelts (1982) concept capabilities, Zander and Kogut (1995) found that,
of causal ambiguity that is, the basic ambiguity indeed, the degree to which capabilities are codifi-
concerning the nature of the causal connections able and teachable (i.e., are non-tacit) significantly
between actions and results. In this study, knowl- influences the speed of their transfer. Thus, in this
edge ambiguity is defined as a similar lack of study, next to partner protectiveness, which is also

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
414

expected to exert a direct effect on the learning established wisdom. Keeping in mind the influen-
outcome, tacitness is posited as the main ante- tial work of Argyris and Scho n in this domain, we
cedent of ambiguity. will use the terms single-loop and double-
loop to distinguish between these two types of
Hypothesis 7: The more tacit the partners
organizational culture and to contrast their effect
knowledge, the greater the degree of knowledge
empirically.
ambiguity.
Likewise, the moderating effect of two alliance-
level variables will be considered: (1) the role of
Moderating effects: the role of organizational alliance form (equity vs non-equity), and (2) the case
culture, firm size, alliance form, and competitive of different competitive regimes. With respect to the
regime former, it has been argued that the extent of
The previous relationships are likely to be moder- learning and knowledge transfer among partners
ated by four important variables: organizational is likely to depend on the alliance structure (Osborn
culture, firm size, alliance form, and competitive and Hagedoorn, 1997; Dyer and Singh, 1998;
regime. Both size and organizational culture repre- Anand and Khanna, 2000). Indeed, Mowery et al.
sent pertinent firm-level variables that influence the (1996) found some evidence that equity joint
context in which learning takes place. Some ventures were more effective conduits than con-
organizations are more driven and successful than tract-based alliances for the transfer of complex
others in their approach to develop an open capabilities. Therefore, a closer examination of the
context propitious to learning. Von Krogh et al. role of equity on the proposed model of knowledge
(2000, 25) argue that the most fundamental transfer is warranted.
organizational barrier to knowledge creation Some alliances involve partners that are direct
is the company ingrained paradigms or worldview. competitors, whereas others feature organiza-
These paradigms are useful in socializing new tions that do not compete directly and are likely
members and keeping the organization coherent to remain this way. The former context may
through shared norms, values and goals, and provide a better strategic window onto a compe-
they also have the power to make or break titor/partners technology or competence, but
knowledge creation. In their discussion of the it is also likely to be surrounded by greater levels
barriers to leading learning in organizations, Meisel of protectiveness and mistrust. Some have argued
and Fearon (1996, 205) echo this view, and claim that alliances between competitors tend to
that the greatest barrier to learning is often our create contexts that particularly favor inter-partner
inability to unlearn, to leave the comfort of work- learning (Dussauge et al., 2002). Others have
tested ideas of the way things are supposed to be wondered:
done.
Does competition among partner firms in end-
The propensity to unlearn corresponds to a
product markets interfere with knowledge shar-
necessary safeguard against competency traps and
ing in alliances even when partner-specific
the effect of superstitious learning. In this regard,
absorptive capacity is high? (Mowery et al.,
Hedberg (1981) maintains that the process of
2002, 292).
understanding requires both the learning of new
knowledge and the propensity to discard obsolete Thus, for a more complete understanding
or misleading knowledge. Only through reviewing of the process of knowledge transfer it is perti-
the principles underlying corporate dogma, chal- nent to examine the extent to which the postu-
lenging old premises, questioning prevalent orga- lated model is affected by these conditions.
nizational procedures and norms, can new ideas Rather than explicitly formulating detailed
find a favorable terrain to grow. In fact, in the hypotheses on the nature and direction of these
alliances context, Hamel (1990) argues that, to moderating effects, an exploratory approach is used
learn, a firm must be capable of challenging here.
existing belief. For our study, organizational culture
will then refer more specifically to this type of Methods
learning culture in an organization. It represents
the degree to which employees are encouraged to Sample
rethink the logic of current behaviors, to question The population for this study consists of large
established routines and beliefs, and to challenge and medium US companies (sales greater than $50

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
415

million and a workforce of more than 500 employ- ness and expert knowledge with the collabora-
ees). Accordingly, a sample of 1000 public and tive phenomenon. Over 50% of the companies
privately owned US companies was randomly included in the study had a sales volume greater
drawn from the Corptech directory. From the than $350 million and a workforce larger than 2500
directory, key executives were identified as poten- employees.
tial respondents, following a screening process The possibility of non-response bias was checked
similar to Parkhe (1993). The strategic nature of by comparing the characteristics of the respondents
the surveys content, with its focus on cross- with those of the original population sample. The
corporate boundaries issues such as knowledge calculated t-statistics for the number of employees
transfer, and the probing of organizational issues (t0.19, Po0.85), employee growth (t1.01,
such as culture necessitated the participation of top Po0.31), sales volume (t0.11, Po0.91), exports
executives whose understanding and field of action as a percentage of sales (t0.28, Po0.78), and age of
encompass the overall organization. These top the company (t1.63, Po0.10) are all statistically
executives were the most able to observe and to insignificant, suggesting that there are no signifi-
determine the impact of a specific alliance on the cant differences between the respondent and non-
rest of the organizations activities. respondent groups. Furthermore, as all measures
were collected in the same survey instrument, the
Instrument possibility of common method bias was tested
The questionnaire design and the implementation using Harmans one-factor test (Scott and Bruce,
and conduct of the survey were based on the total 1994; Konrad and Linnehan, 1995). A principal-
design method approach (Dillman, 1978). The components factor analysis on the questionnaire
questionnaire itself prompted the respondents to measurement items yielded five factors with eigen-
focus on a current (at least 1-year old) or past but values greater than 1.0 that accounted for 66% of
recent (terminated less than 3 years ago) interna- the total variance. As several factors, as opposed to
tional strategic alliance with which they were the one single factor, were identified, and as the first
most familiar. Respondents were invited to focus on factor did not account for the majority of the
the technological expertise of their partner and on variance (only 24%), a substantial amount of
the technological aspects of the alliance activities. common method variance does not appear to be
In addition to general facts and descriptive infor- present (Podsakoff and Organ, 1986).
mation about the alliance under scrutiny, the
questionnaire included specific questions related Measures
to the partner, the collaborative objectives of each The latent variables in the model are measured by
party, the context of the alliance, and issues of multiple indicators. All measures were assessed via a
knowledge transfer pertaining to technology and seven-point interval scale ranging from strongly
process know-how. Most of the items in the disagree to strongly agree. These scales were
questionnaire followed seven-point Likert-type reverse-coded where appropriate. The wording of
scales. these measurement items in the questionnaire and
their source in the literature are given in Appendix
Respondents A. To proceed with the multi-group comparisons
From the 192 companies that participated in the advocated for the investigation of the role of
study, 147 completed usable questionnaires were organizational culture, firm size, alliance form,
collected, yielding a response rate not atypical for and competitive regime, the sample was divided
this kind of research. The level of participation (median-split) along each of these variables. This
was even more gratifying when considering the split-half of the sample was performed one variable
profile of the respondents, the sensitive nature of at a time, resulting in four sets of two groups in
many questions, and the detailed nature of the total. Firm size was measured by the number of
questionnaire. The majority of the respondents employees as reported in Corptechs directory, and
were top executives (i.e., presidents, CEOs, vice- alliance form was self-reported in the question-
presidents, directors, or general managers) in naire.
some of Americas largest corporations. On average,
these respondents have been personally involved Model and analysis
with the alliance under scrutiny for a period of To assess the relationships posited by the theore-
5 years, suggesting an appropriate level of aware- tical model in Figure 1, the maximum-likelihood

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
416

LISREL VIII program (Jo reskog and So rbom, 1996) then performing a w2 difference test on the values
was used. This structural equation model approach obtained for the constrained (w2153.24, d.f.79)
is characterized by its flexible interplay between and unconstrained models (w2135.39, d.f.78)
theory and data, bridging theoretical and empirical (Anderson and Gerbing, 1988). The resulting
knowledge for a better understanding of the real significant difference in w2 (Dw217.85, Dd.f.1)
world (Fornell, 1982). Such analysis allows for indicates that the two constructs are not perfectly
modeling based on both latent (unobservable) correlated and that discriminant validity is
variables and manifest (observable) variables a achieved (Bagozzi and Phillips, 1982). That is, from
critical feature in the case of the hypothesized a measurement model point of view, the constructs
model as most of the constructs are abstractions of resource- and incentive-based LC represent two dis-
unobservable phenomena. Furthermore, structural tinct constructs, not one. Likewise, discriminant
equation modeling takes into account errors in validity is also achieved between resource-and
measurement, variables with multiple indicators, cognitive-based (Dw258.22, Dd.f.1) and between
and multiple-group comparisons. In a second stage, incentive- and cognitive-based LC (Dw258.22,
the structural equation modeling module of the Dd.f.1).
STATISTICA 6.1 program (StatSoft, 2003) was used Turning to the structural model itself, Table 1
to assess the robustness of the initial results and the reports the parameter estimates and goodness-of-fit
stability of the models estimated by LISREL. First, indicators of the structural equation system.
all the proposed models (main and multiple Although the overall w2 is significant (w2142.81;
groups) were re-estimated; second, a series of Monte 86 d.f.; Po0.00), as might be expected with this
Carlo simulations were performed on each postu- statistics sensitivity to sample size (Bagozzi and Yi,
lated model and groups using STATISTICAs Monte 1988; Bentler, 1990), the ratio of w2 to degrees of
Carlo Analysis program. freedom (1.66, less than 3) corresponds to a
satisfactory fit (Carmines and McIver, 1981), and
Results the other fit indices (NNFI0.91; NFI0.85;
CFI0.93) and the low standardized root mean
Main model square residual (RMR0.07) are all within accepta-
In terms of the quality of the measurement model ble ranges and show that a substantial amount of
for the full sample, the constructs display satisfac- variance is accounted for by the model (Bagozzi and
tory levels of reliability, as indicated by composite Yi, 1988). Hence, the model is a reasonable
reliabilities ranging from 0.82 to 0.99 and shared representation of the data.
variance coefficients ranging from 0.62 to 0.98 Looking at the parameter estimates, a first,
(computed from the LISREL loading estimates notable result consists of the significant positive
following Fornell and Larckers (1981) formula). effects of learning intent on knowledge transfer in
Convergent validity can be judged by looking at support of Hypothesis 1 (g110.59, t7.34). That is,
both the significance of the factor loadings and the stronger (weaker) learning intent corresponds to
shared variance. The amount of variance shared or greater (smaller) knowledge transfer outcomes for
captured by a construct should be greater than the an alliance partner. Likewise, both partner protec-
amount of measurement error (shared variance tiveness and ambiguity display significant direct
40.50). All the multi-item constructs met this negative effects on knowledge transfer in support of
criterion, with each loading (l) being significantly Hypothesis 4 (g120.15, t2.23) and Hypothesis
related to its underlying factor (t-values greater 5 (b150.50, t5.08), respectively. Finally, LC in
than 4.17) in support of convergent validity. Like- the form of incentive-based programs has a signifi-
wise, a series of w2 difference tests on the factor cant positive effect on knowledge transfer in support
correlations showed that discriminant validity was of Hypothesis 2b (g110.28, t2.24). Taken simul-
achieved among all constructs (Anderson and taneously, these initial results offer some strong
Gerbing, 1988). In particular, discriminant validity empirical support to a fundamental model of
was established for the three latent variables learning that rests on the interplay between
encapsulating LC (resource based, incentive based, motivation, capability, task ambiguity, and learning
and cognitive based). This was done one pair of outcome. Overall, a substantial amount of variance
variables at a time by constraining the estimated is explained in the endogenous variables knowledge
correlation parameter between them (e.g., resource transfer (R20.73) and ambiguity (R20.33) by the
based and incentive based for instance) to 1.0 and model.

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
417

Table 1 Structural parameter estimates and goodness-of-fit indices (full sample)

Hypotheses Paths Estimate t-value

H1 Learning intent-knowledge transfer g11 0.59 7.34**


H2a Resource-based LC-knowledge transfer b12 0.14 1.03
H2b Incentive-based LC-knowledge transfer b13 0.28 2.24**
H2c Cognitive-based LC-knowledge transfer b14 0.09 1.45
H4 Partner protectiveness-knowledge transfer g12 0.15 2.23**
H5 Ambiguity-knowledge transfer b15 0.50 5.08**

H3a Learning intent-resource-based LC g21 0.23 2.64**


H3b Learning intent-incentive-based LC g31 0.08 0.85
H3c Learning intent-cognitive-based LC g41 0.30 3.13**
H6 Partner protectiveness-ambiguity g52 0.07 0.75
H7 Tacitness-ambiguity g53 0.55 3.25**
NFI0.85; standardized RMR0.07; NNFI0.91.
w2 (86 d.f.)142.81; CFI0.93; P-value0.00; n147.
**Significant at the Po0.05 level.

Focusing on the individual effects, the significant has been shown to relate to knowledge transfer
relationship between ambiguity and knowledge trans- (Hypothesis 2b supported), learning intent does not
fer constitutes an empirical verification of Reed and seem to be one of its antecedents (g310.08, t0.85;
DeFillippis (1990) theoretical postulate that causal Hypothesis 3b rejected). That is, stronger (weaker)
ambiguity constitutes a key barrier to imitation. learning intent is associated with the presence of
Out of the three proposed organizational mechan- more (less) resource- and cognitive-based LC (not
isms encapsulating LC (i.e., resource-, incentive-, and incentive-based LC), while, simultaneously, out of
cognitive-based LC), only incentive-based LC shows a these three organizational capabilities, incentive-
significant effect on knowledge transfer. Although based LC is the only one directly affecting knowl-
these variables have been shown to represent three edge transfer.
distinct constructs (discriminant validity), the pre- Although not formally hypothesized, a pertinent
sence of a significant correlation (0.54, Po0.01) question concerns the relative magnitude of these
between resource- and incentive-based LC is not identified significant effects. Are all these compar-
unexpected. able effects equal, or does any one of them affect
Turning to the exogenous variables in the model, knowledge transfer, ambiguity, or LC to a greater
Table 1 reveals that only tacitness (g530.55, extent? Three sets of comparable effects are exam-
t3.25), not partner protectiveness (g520.07, ined, one set at a time:
t0.75), is significantly related to ambiguity. That
(1) positive direct effect of incentive-based LC vs
is, Hypothesis 6 is rejected but Hypothesis 7 is
learning intent on knowledge transfer;
supported. This also means that partner protective-
(2) negative direct effect of ambiguity vs protective-
ness tends to be related to knowledge transfer in a
ness on knowledge transfer; and
direct way (Hypothesis 4), not through the media-
(3) positive effect of learning intent on resource-
tion of knowledge ambiguity (failed Hypothesis 6).
based LC vs cognitive-based LC.
Likewise, it has been established that learning intent
displays a significant direct effect on knowledge To test such hypotheses under LISREL, a w2
transfer (Hypothesis 1); as with the prior case, difference test is performed between a model where
learning intent fails to affect knowledge transfer the estimates are free and a model where these
indirectly through the mediating effect of LC. estimates are constrained to be equal. For the first
Although learning intent exerts a significant positive pair of effects, the corresponding test reveals that,
effect on resource-based (g210.23, t2.64) and statistically, the positive effects of incentive-based LC
cognitive-based LC (g410.30, t3.13) in support of and learning intent on knowledge transfer are of the
Hypotheses 3a and 3c respectively, it has been same magnitude (Dw23.66, Dd.f.1; NS). For the
shown that, in turn, these last two constructs fail to second comparison, a difference exists (Dw27.10,
relate to knowledge transfer (Hypotheses 2a and 2c Dd.f.1; Po0.01), revealing that the overall nega-
rejected). Conversely, whereas incentive-based LC tive effect of ambiguity on knowledge transfer is

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
418

greater in magnitude than the effect of partner rent: t17.00, Po0.00). The results in the single-
protectiveness. This result is consistent with prior loop group are almost identical to the general
research pointing to the criticality and multi- results significant effect of learning intent, incen-
faceted nature of causal ambiguity as a barrier to tive-based LC, partner protectiveness, and ambiguity
imitation and knowledge transfer (Reed and DeFil- on knowledge transfer; learning intent on resource-
lippi, 1990; Simonin, 1999a, b). Lastly, learning based LC; and tacitness on ambiguity with the
intent is found to relate to resource- and cognitive- exception of the relationship between learning
based LC the same way (Dw20.32, Dd.f.1; NS). intent and cognitive-based capacity, which is now
nonsignificant (Hypothesis 3c not supported).
Moderating effects and model robustness In comparison, the double-loop group shows
These first results shed some important light on the that learning intent has a significant effect not only
process of learning and on key organizational on resource-based but also on cognitive-based LC (in
mechanisms that facilitate and hinder technologi- support of Hypotheses 3a and 3c). As with the
cal knowledge transfer between alliance partners. single-loop group, learning intent and ambiguity are
However, further refinement is desirable through shown to have a significant effect on knowledge
the investigation of the possible moderating effects transfer (in support of Hypotheses 1 and 5), and the
of organizational culture, firm size, alliance form, effect of tacitness on ambiguity is also found
and competitive regime. Indeed, Table 2 shows that significant (in support of Hypothesis 7). What
the previous results differ somewhat across groups further varies with the double-loop group is that
characterized by a different organizational culture. none of the LC resources and mechanisms is found
Again, organizational culture here (measured by to be related to knowledge transfer (Hypotheses 2a,
moderating variable M1 in Appendix A) refers to the 2b, and 2c are rejected); also, unlike the single-
learning culture of the organization (the ability to loop group, partner protectiveness does not relate
rethink the logic of current behaviors, to question to knowledge transfer directly. Rather, it relates
established routines and beliefs, or to challenge to it indirectly through the significant mediating
established wisdom). On this basis, the two groups effect of ambiguity (both Hypotheses 5 and 6 are
to be contrasted are very distinct (mean5.58 for supported). This pattern of results across the two
the double-loop group vs mean3.18 for the groups is consistent with a type of substitution
single-loop group; means are significantly diffe- effect depending on the type of organizational

Table 2 Structural parameter estimates and goodness-of-fit indices for two-group comparison on organizational culture and firm size

Paths Hypotheses Organizational culture Firm size

Double loop Single loop Large Small


(n191) (n256) (n174) (n273)

Learning intent-knowledge transfer H1 0.43** 0.50** 0.53** 0.43**


Resource LC-knowledge transfer H2a 0.07 0.30 0.08 0.66
Incentive LC-knowledge transfer H2b 0.10 0.59** 0.42** 0.67
Cognitive LC-knowledge transfer H2c 0.10 0.03 0.03 0.10
Partner protectiveness-knowledge transfer H4 0.09 0.23** 0.21** 0.05
Ambiguity-knowledge transfer H5 0.66** 0.34** 0.38* 0.79**

Learning intent-resource LC H3a 0.19** 0.18* 0.00 0.34**


Learning intent-incentive LC H3b 0.02 0.04 0.09 0.33**
Learning intent-cognitive LC H3c 0.26** 0.08 0.25** 0.35**
Partner protectiveness-Ambiguity H6 0.17* 0.16 0.33 0.14
Tacitness-Ambiguity H7 0.38** 0.66* 1.49** 0.44**

CFI0.89 CFI0.82
Standardized RMR0.12 Standardized RMR0.12
w2 (172 d.f.)265.63 w2 (172 d.f.)378.76
**Significant at the Po0.05 level.
*Significant at the Po0.10 level.

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
419

learning culture: whereas the presence (absence) of corresponds to the case of partners viewed as strong
an explicit incentive-based learning system may and very strong competitors; the not competitive
determine the level of knowledge transfer for group corresponds to the case of partners judged to
single-loop-driven firms, it is not consequential be a weak competitor or not a competitor). Table 3
for double-loop-driven organizations. Is it evidence reveals that, similar to the case of firm size, the two
of a higher order of learning at work? An important sets of group comparisons display similar patterns
element in clarifying this point is to go beyond of effects for the effect of learning intent and
examining the moderating effect of organizational ambiguity on knowledge transfer, learning intent on
culture on the learning process and to assess the cognitive-based LC, and tacitness on ambiguity (in
impact of organizational culture on the actual level support of Hypotheses 1, 5, 3c, and 7).
of knowledge transferred. Based on the mean of the For alliance form, equity and non-equity-based
three indicators of knowledge transfer (Y1 to Y3 in alliances differ in that, for non-equity-based alli-
Appendix A), the difference in the level of know- ances, partner protectiveness and cognitive-based LC
ledge transfer under a double-loop learning culture relate to knowledge transfer (Hypotheses 4 and 2c
(mean3.83) and a single-loop culture (mean supported) whereas, for equity-based alliances, it is
3.29) is found to be statistically significant (t2.34, incentive-based LC that affects knowledge transfer (in
Po0.05). This last finding is important in that it support of Hypothesis 2b). In addition, for non-
demonstrates empirically the superiority of an equity-based alliances, learning intent is found to be a
organizational culture that fosters non-conformity. significant antecedent of the three LC components
Table 2 also reports the results of the multiple (in support of Hypotheses 3a, 3b, and 3c), in contrast
group analysis for the second moderator: firm size to equity-based alliances, where it is only an ante-
(on average, about 1000 employees and sales of cedent of cognitive-based LC (Hypothesis 3c). Thus, for
$250 million for the small firm group vs over non-equity-based alliances, there is both a significant
20,000 employees and sales of $ 2.5 billion for the direct effect of learning intent on knowledge transfer
large firm group). Consistent with the main and an indirect effect through cognitive-based LC.
results, the effects of learning intent and ambiguity Differences across competitive regimes exist as
on knowledge transfer, learning intent on cognitive- well. For alliances falling under a competitive
based LC, and tacitness on ambiguity are significant regime, partner protectiveness is associated with
for both small and large firms (in support of knowledge transfer in a direct way (Hypothesis 4
Hypotheses 1, 5, 3c, and 7). In terms of differences supported) whereas, in the not competitive
between the two groups, a first noticeable result is regime, it is related to knowledge transfer indirectly
that the direct effects of incentive-based LC and through the significant mediating role of ambiguity
partner protectiveness on knowledge transfer are sig- (both Hypotheses 5 and 6 are supported). More
nificant only for large firms (in support of Hypoth- interestingly, the two groups differ significantly
eses 2b and 4). Conversely, learning intent with respect to the role of LC. Under the compe-
significantly affects resource- and incentive-based LC titive regime, none of the LC resources and
simply in the case of small firms. That is, Hypoth- mechanisms is found to be an antecedent of
eses 3a and 3b are supported in the case of small knowledge transfer (Hypotheses 2a, 2b and 2c are
firms, but not of large ones. Taken together, these rejected), reminiscent of the case of double-loop-
distinct results show that, for small firms, the full driven firms. In sharp contrast, under the not
range of resources, routines, and mechanisms competitive regime, the three constructs encapsu-
constituting the firms LC relates directly to learn- lating LC show a significant effect on knowledge
ing intent; at the same time, this LC (or lack transfer. While the positive effects of incentive- and
thereof) fails to relate to knowledge transfer. Large cognitive-based LC are in support of Hypotheses 2b
firms, in comparison, do not display a significant and 2c, the significant negative effect of resource-
effect between learning intent and LC (with the based LC on knowledge transfer is more surprising
exception of cognitive-based LC); on the other hand, and counter to the originally formulated Hypoth-
LC (in the form of incentive-based LC) does affect esis 2a. This last result translates into: under a not
knowledge transfer. competitive regime, the higher (lower) the
We now turn to the two alliance-level modera- resource-based LC of the firm, the lower (higher)
tors: alliance form (equity vs non-equity) and the level of knowledge transfer. This finding may
competitive regime (measured by moderating vari- point to inefficiencies or ceiling effects in resource
able M2 in Appendix A: the competitive group deployment, but it warrants further discussion.

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
420

Table 3 Structural parameter estimates and goodness-of-fit indices for two-group comparison on competitive regime and alliance form

Paths Hypotheses Competitive regime Alliance form

Competitive Not competitive Non-equity Equity


(n160) (n287) (n183) (n264)

Learning intent-knowledge transfer H1 0.57** 0.41** 0.43** 0.41**


Resource LC-knowledge transfer H2a 0.09 0.42** 0.04 0.36
Incentive LC-knowledge transfer H2b 0.16 0.54** 0.06 0.68**
Cognitive LC-knowledge transfer H2c 0.01 0.19** 0.27** 0.02
Partner protectiveness-knowledge transfer H4 0.16* 0.09 0.41** 0.04
Ambiguity-knowledge transfer H5 0.41** 0.82** 0.42** 0.70**

Learning intent-resource LC H3a 0.12 0.19** 0.26** 0.07


Learning intent-incentive LC H3b 0.11 0.10 0.16* 0.11
Learning intent-cognitive LC H3c 0.33** 0.15* 0.13** 0.10**
Partner protectiveness-ambiguity H6 0.01 0.16* 0.01 0.23
Tacitness-ambiguity H7 0.53** 0.39* 0.29* 0.82**

CFI0.91 CFI0.88
Standardized RMR0.10 Standardized RMR0.10
w2 (172 d.f.)259.36 w2 (172 d.f.)282.53
**Significant at the Po0.05 level.
*Significant at the Po0.10 level.

Although not formally hypothesized, another Discussion and future research


issue of interest concerns the possible structural Through a structural equation modeling approach,
differences between these two competitive regimes this study has focused on the process of technolo-
when it comes to outcomes, motivation, and gical knowledge transfer between international
protectiveness. A series of independent t-tests strategic alliance partners. We proposed and tested
reveals that, in fact, the two groups do not differ a comprehensive model that explicitly articulates
with respect to the level of partner protectiveness the role of various key variables that in past
(mean4.23 for competitive regime vs mean3.83 research received only partial and independent
for not competitive regime; t1.45, NS), learning attention. Rather than focusing on any one specific
intent (mean3.55 for competitive regime vs relation, it is the simultaneity of all the hypothe-
mean3.38 for not competitive regime; t0.50, sized relationships that confers integrity and rele-
NS), and knowledge transfer (mean3.54 for com- vance to the model. The following discussion of the
petitive regime vs mean3.69 for not competitive results, shortcomings, and future research direc-
regime; t0.62, NS). tions will:
Finally, given the relatively small size of the main
(1) recap the main findings by highlighting the
sample and subsamples used in group analysis, all the
consistently critical role of learning intent,
models were re-estimated with a second technique to
ambiguity, and tacitness at the core of the
assess the robustness of the LISREL estimates and the
learning process;
stability of the results. First, the structural equation
(2) underscore the changing role of LC and partner
modeling module of the STATISTICA 6.1 program
protectiveness across various conditions; and
was used as a direct comparison. Second, a series of
(3) discuss the dynamic nature of the learning
Monte Carlo simulations was performed using STA-
process on the basis of the presence of likely
TISTICAs Monte Carlo Analysis program. For each
substitution effects.
model and group, a Monte Carlo analysis (using the
Bootstrap data option, with 100 sampling iterations
and a sample size reduction of 510% for re-sampling Learning intent, ambiguity, and tacitness at the
purposes) provided the basis for re-estimating the heart of knowledge transfer
path coefficients and their significance. Overall, the The overall results point to the fundamental roles
initial LISREL results held with the repeat analyses, played by learning intent, knowledge ambiguity,
conferring some degree of reliability to our findings. and tacitness. The significant effects of these three

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
421

constructs on knowledge transfer are found con- This last result concurs with Zander and Koguts
sistently across the main analysis (full sample) and (1995, 85) findings that the more codifiable and
the various group analyses. They are therefore at teachable a capability is, the higher the risk of
the heart of the learning process. rapid transfer. As such, and as evidenced by recent
As isolated by Hamel (1990) and others, learning research foci (e.g., Martin and Salomon, 2002), the
intent represents a key component of the learning seminal work of Polanyi (1967) remains timely and
process. The pervasive nature of this effect helps fundamental to understanding the flow of knowl-
reconcile the emerging divide between the propo- edge transfer between partners of strategic alli-
nents and critics of the learning race. Indeed, some ances. This result also underlines the desirability of
alliances have a learning undertone whereas others implementing knowledge codification programs
rest on co-specialization (Mowery et al., 2002; Zeng whenever active knowledge sharing is a requisite
and Hennart, 2002). What separates the two, and or agreed-upon objective of the alliance. In light of
paradoxically unifies them at the same time, is the the rise of programs targeting the codification of
degree of learning intent by the partners: that is, corporate knowledge (see Davenport and Prusak,
this single construct. It is pertinent to note that, 1998), the task, far from being obvious, is never-
regardless of the competitive regime of the alliance, theless feasible. Positive outcomes are attainable. At
learning intent was found to exert the same direct the same time, much remains to be learned about
effect on knowledge transfer. Furthermore, in the mechanics and limits of codifying knowledge,
absolute terms, no difference in learning intent the value of data-basing corporate knowledge, and
was observed for companies paired with strong the challenges of designing and managing an
competitors and those paired with non-competitors. efficient corporate knowledge system.
Overall, these results tend to show that, if there is a
learning race in strategic alliances, it is principally a LC and partner protectiveness: different
race against oneself. These results also speak to the conditions, different roles
disconnect between learning motivation and degree The effects of learning intent, ambiguity, and
of competition in alliances. For instance, a strong tacitness have been identified at the heart of the
learning intent can exist in a non-competitive knowledge transfer process in a consistent way, but
setting (e.g., a critical benchmarking program by the role of LC and partner protectiveness is more
Xerox on L.L. Bean, the catalog clothing company), contrasted. The effect of these two variables on
whereas the converse is also possible: a weak or non- knowledge transfer depends on pre-existing orga-
existing learning intent in a competitive alliance nizational and contextual factors. The presence of
setting (e.g., a straight-forward cross-distribution these nuances in the results reveals that the actual
arrangement between two global competitors). learning process is dynamic, and more intricate
Turning to learning inhibitors, the significant than often assumed or represented in the literature.
effect of ambiguity on knowledge transfer provides With respect to LC, a first striking result concerns
some empirical support both to Lippman and the general lack of significance of the resource- and
Rumelts (1982) observations that ambiguity acts cognitive-based components. Only the incentive-
as a powerful block on both imitation and factor based component of LC seems to have any
mobility, and to Reed and DeFillippis (1990, 96) recurring influence. Cognitive capacity (encapsu-
postulate that barriers to imitation are dependent lated here by attitudes and beliefs towards teaching
on the ambiguity in a firms competency-based vs learning from a partner, in the spirit of Hamel
advantage. These results underline the theoretical et al.s (1989) arrogance of leadership syndrome)
importance of ambiguity and coinciding with a shows a positive direct effect on knowledge transfer
resurgence of interest (Szulanski, 1996; Mosakows- only for non-competitive and non-equity-based
ki, 1997; Simonin, 1999a, b) the need to account alliances. Thus, in what could be considered a
formally for this construct in future research. In favorable learning environment (in that no compe-
terms of the antecedents of ambiguity, partner titive pressure or threats exists), cognitive capacity
protectiveness is found to play a role only when or limitations do play a significant role in the
either the alliance regime is non-competitive or the learning outcome. Going back to the example of a
prevailing organizational culture of the knowledge benchmarking collaboration between two organi-
seeker is double-loop oriented. On the other hand, zations that operate in radically different sectors,
the effect of tacitness on ambiguity is consistently one could easily see why such cognitive elements
significant across the various analyses. would affect the actual transfer of knowledge from

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
422

one partner to the other. One partner may not needs to be recognized and rewarded to build
be perceived as credible, and the other may feel learning organizations (Marquardt, 1996; Daven-
superior. Thus, under non-competitive alliance port and Prusak, 1998). It also means that a
regimes, the results seem to support Mais (1996) learning agenda needs to be clearly articulated
contention that humility with regard to the value and communicated. As the results show, this is
and validity of other perspectives is not only an more of an issue for large organizations and
antidote to intellectual arrogance, but also a key organizations involved in more formally structured
enabler of learning. Of course, this study has focused alliances. One possible explanation is that, in light
on one facet of cognitive-based LC, and much of the more complex nature of such organizations,
conceptualizing and testing remain to be done to competing tasks and priorities exist at all times.
fully comprehend the role of this component. Thus it is more important to clearly signal what the
More surprising are the results pertaining to actual primary objectives are. Consistent with this
resource-based LC: only significant under non- view is the fact that the effect is present for single-
competitive alliance regimes, where it displays a loop- but not double-loop-oriented firms. When
negative effect on knowledge transfer. The lack of organizational culture does not encourage rethink-
general effect across samples is in sharp contrast ing the logic of current behaviors, questioning
with what prior conceptual work has suggested established routines and beliefs, or challenging
when it comes to resource deployment in alliances established wisdom, again, clear incentives and
(Pucik, 1988; Hamel, 1990, 1991; Inkpen, 2002). A signals become critical. They are needed to foster
possible explanation is the existence of ceiling employees commitment beyond any doubt (Non-
effects and inefficiencies in resource deployment, aka and Takeuchi, 1995).
an important subject for future research. At the Turning to organizational mechanisms that hin-
same time, these results are not inconsistent with der learning, partner protectiveness is found to
other empirical findings. For instance, Buchel and have a significant direct effect on knowledge
Killing (2002) found that initial staffing of the transfer in the main analysis as well as in the case
joint venture is negatively correlated with joint of large firms, single-loop-oriented firms, competi-
venture performance (measured by satisfaction). tive alliance regimes, and non-equity alliances. In
These authors explain that sending the best people the case of non-competitive regimes and double-
actually leads to committing individuals with loop-oriented firms, the effect of protectiveness on
strong parental bonds that may backfire in a knowledge transfer is mediated through knowledge
collaborative setting. Such rationale certainly ambiguity. When interpreting these findings, one
applies to a learning context, where the presence must be cautious of the fact that partner protec-
of too many experts could lead to paralysis and tiveness may not always be detectable or observa-
additional frictions with the partner, impeding ble. In its finest form, it may be totally transparent
learning. The fact that, under a non-competitive to the knowledge seeker. From a managerial point
regime, higher (lower) resource-based LC corres- of view, it would be wise for managers to probe
ponds to lower (higher) levels of knowledge transfer regularly their partners disposition by formulating
is certainly consistent with this explanation. In specific requests that force the issue; only then
non-competitive environments, it seems to be a could an unequivocal opinion be formed and
case of diminishing returns, where more is less: corrective steps adopted if necessary (Simonin,
increasing resource deployment adds complexity, 1999a). Non-equity as opposed to equity-based
inertia, administrative, and coordination costs at alliances may be more propitious for detecting the
the expense of learning. The process derails. For presence of partner protectiveness (clearer signals
greater clarity on this issue, some additional due to formal communication needs and articu-
research is needed, particularly on the question of lated requests) as well as less favorable for mitigat-
optimal levels of resource deployment. ing its effects (more limited options to bypass the
As noticed above, of the three LC components, protective wall). As protectiveness is likely to evolve
the significant effect of incentive-based LC on over time, a greater research focus on alliance life
knowledge transfer is the most widespread. This cycles is warranted.
effect, detected in the main analysis, holds for large
firms, single-loop-oriented firms, non-competitive Substitution effects: a dynamic learning process
alliance regimes, and equity alliances. Thus there is Turning to the relationship between learning intent
some partial support for the idea that learning and LC, the main analysis reveals a significant

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
423

effect between intent and both resource- and LC on knowledge transfer, double-loop firms lack
cognitive-based LC. These effects hold for small any direct effect between capacity and learning
firms, double-loop-oriented firms, non-competitive outcomes. Is this the case of a proper organizational
and non-equity-based alliances. Thus intent seems learning culture supplanting the need for formal
to translate into greater capacity and resource organizational resources and mechanisms? Is this
deployment in environments that are less bureau- evidence of greater efficiency? What this study was
cratic, more flexible, open, and actionable. This able to show is that the learning process is dynamic;
finding echoes Swieringa and Wierdsmas (1992) different critical paths are enacted under different
observation that bureaucracies are more susceptible conditions. More importantly, this study has also
to learning difficulties because of their lack of need, established statistically that greater learning out-
courage, will and ability to learn. Likewise, the fact comes are achieved under a double-loop learning
that the cognitive side of LC can be affected by culture than under a single-loop culture. That is,
learning intent carries some important implica- an organizational culture that fosters non-confor-
tions. The influence of decision makers and chief mity and encourages critical thinking is indeed a
knowledge officers is not restricted simply to better learning organization. Although many
building a proper knowledge strategy, culture, and researchers have stressed the importance of devel-
infrastructure (Davenport and Prusak, 1998). It can oping the right organizational culture for encoura-
also succeed in more tactical ways by shaping ging learning (Marquardt, 1996; Davenport and
attitudes, beliefs and expectations with regard to Prusak, 1998), the question of quantifying these
learning in specific initiatives. learning dividends had remained wide open. Given
In contrast to resource- and cognitive-based LC, the fact that there may be more or less advanta-
learning intent seems to have no effect on incen- geous ways to achieve the same learning outcomes,
tive-based LC, with the exception of small firms the next pertinent question is one of optimal
and non-equity alliances. The case of small firms is choices. In particular, the question of trade-offs
instructive in that, unlike large firms, small firms between generic organizational culture and specific
display a significant and complete association organizational mechanisms warrants further
between learning intent and capacity, but not research.
between capacity and learning outcomes. In a The dynamic nature of the learning process is
way, the build-up and deployment of LC from the well represented in the differences observed
manifestation of an original intent may be more between a competitive and non-competitive alli-
actionable and observable in smaller organizations. ance regime. Here too, the role of LC fluctuates
What is not detected is the impact of this capacity. from being significant in non-competitive regimes
Possibly, LC may be superseded by other key to non-significant in competitive regimes. In terms
intervening variables such as the source of asym- of the role of competition, Mowery et al. (2002)
metric bargaining power between partners (Khanna have reported that learning seems to be attenuated
et al., 1998). The pace of critical capacity building when alliance partners are direct competitors. In
may be slower or, simply, its sheer level may be comparison, the current study shows that there is
insufficient, as smaller firms tend to lack the types no difference in the level of knowledge transferred
of resources mandated by alliances (Hagedoorn and under competitive and non-competitive regimes. In
Schakenraad, 1994). Beyond capacity, it is impor- a sense, this result is a middle path between the
tant to remember that, for both small and large observations of Mowery et al. and the argument of
firms, learning intent exerts a significant direct Dussauge et al. (2002) that alliances between
effect on knowledge transfer. In a type of compen- competitors tend to create contexts that particu-
satory effect, small organizations tend to rely more larly favor inter-partner learning. Maybe it is both.
exclusively on their motivation to learn. Of course, The context is favorable in that there is, by default,
with respect to the effect of firm size, our study has something there to be learned from a competitor;
looked only at large and medium-sized firms; future however, owing to self-interest and other variables,
research should also consider more extreme cases of the path to get at it is more complex and inhibited.
small firms (e.g., start-ups). What our results show is that there is no difference
A similar type of substitution effect with regard to in learning outcomes, but the path may be
the role of LC is observed in the case of double- different. On the protectiveness front, Inkpen
loop-oriented firms. Whereas single-loop firms (2002) acknowledges that firms may be very
experience a significant effect of incentive-based reluctant to share knowledge when there is a high

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
424

competitive overlap between partners. Our study of knowledge transfer in alliances as it pertains to
uncovers no such difference in levels of perceived both voluntary transfers and involuntary spillovers,
protectiveness between partners that are strong and existing vs jointly created knowledge. These
direct competitors and partners that are not effects must be disentangled with greater precision.
competitors. Finally, no substantive difference in On the empirical side, when interpreting and
learning intent was detected between the two building on the results of this study, one must still
competitive regimes. Instead, this study recognizes keep in mind that correlation is not causation. If
the existence of a dynamic learning process whose the linear equations system isomorphic to the path
core is meaningful to all contexts. diagram does fit the data well, it is encouraging, but
The aim of this study was to advance our hardly proof of the truth of the causal model
understanding of the process of knowledge transfer (StatSoft, 2003). Although this study constitutes a
across alliance partners at both the conceptual and significant attempt to operationalize and test
empirical levels. Conceptually, the model has complex organizational variables, its measurement
replicated at the organizational level a fundamental model restrictions are a clear reminder that much
model of individual learning (motivationcapacity empirical work remains to be done on construct
learning outcome). In particular, it has introduced development and validation. Our understanding of
LC as a key determinant of absorptive capacity in a inter-organizational knowledge transfer, be it inter-
way that refocuses attention on firm-level, not firm or intra-firm, as well as of its underlying
simply partner-specific-level, variables. It is impor- rationales, processes, organizational drivers and
tant to understand the issue of similarities (Lane impediments, and efficiencies, will benefit from
and Lubatkin, 1998) and overlap between partners similar empirical undertaking based on large sam-
(Mowery et al., 2002), but it is also fundamental to ples and latent variable modeling.
consider the role of firm-specific factors. LC
represents the actionable side of absorptive capa-
city, its basic operating system. Further refinement Acknowledgements
of the construct, its underlying dimensions, and I am grateful to the two anonymous reviewers and the
measurement are needed. Finally, alternative Editors, Nicolai Juul Foss and Torben Pedersen, for
research designs are needed to capture the duality their helpful comments.

References
Anand, B. and Khanna, T. (2000) Do firms learn to create value? Cooperative Strategies and Alliances, Elsevier Science: Amster-
The case of the alliances, Strategic Management Journal 21: dam, pp: 751771.
295316. Carmines, E. and McIver, J. (1981) Analyzing Models with
Anderson, J.C. and Gerbing, D.W. (1988) Structural equation Unobserved Variables: (Analysis of Covariance Structures), in
modeling in practice: a review and recommended two-step G. Bohrnstedt and E. Borgatta (eds.) Social Measurement:
approach, Psychological Bulletin 103: 411423. Current Issues, Sage: Beverly Hills, CA, pp: 65115.
Appleyard, M.M. (1996) How does knowledge flow? Interfirm Choi, C.J. and Lee, S.H. (1997) A Knowledge-based View of
patterns in the semiconductor industry, Strategic Management Cooperative Interorganizational Relationships, in P. Beamish
Journal 17: 137154. and J. Killing (eds.) Cooperative Strategies: European Perspec-
Appleyard, M.M. (2002) Cooperative Knowledge Creation: The tives, The New Lexington Press: San Francisco, pp: 3358.
Case of BuyerSupplier Co-development in the Semiconduc- Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal, D.A. (1990) Absorptive capacity: a
tor Industry, in F.J. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds.) new perspective on learning and innovation, Administrative
Cooperative Strategies and Alliances, Elsevier Science: Amster- Science Quarterly 35(1): 128152.
dam, pp: 381418. Crossan, M.M. and Inkpen, A.C. (1995) The subtle art of
Bagozzi, R. and Phillips, L. (1982) Representing and testing learning through alliances, Business Quarterly 60(2): 6978.
organizational theories: a holistic construal, Administrative Daft, R. and Huber, G. (1987) How organizations learn: a
Science Quarterly 27: 459489. communication framework, Research in the Sociology of
Bagozzi, R. and Yi, Y. (1988) On the evaluation of structural Organizations 5: 136.
equation models, Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science Davenport, T.H. and Prusak, L. (1998) Working Knowledge, HBS
16: 7794. Press: Boston, MA.
Baughn, C., Denekamp, J., Stevens, J. and Osborn, R. (1997) Dillman, D. (1978) Mail and Telephone Surveys: The Total Design
Protecting intellectual capital in international alliances, Method, Wiley: New York.
Journal of World Business 2(2): 103117. Dodgson, M. (1996) Learning, Trust and Inter-firm Technolo-
Bentler, P.M. (1990) Significance tests and goodness of fit in the gical Linkages: some Theoretical Associations, in R. Coombs,
analysis of covariance structures, Psychological Bulletin 88: A. Richards, P. Saviotti and V. Walsh (eds.) Technological
588606. Collaboration, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, pp: 5475.
Buchel, B. and Killing, P. (2002) Interfirm Cooperation Doz, Y.L. (1996) The evolution of cooperation in strategic
Throughout the Joint Venture Life Cycle: Impact on Joint alliances: initial conditions or learning processes?, Strategic
Venture performance, in F.J. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds.) Management Journal 17: 5583.

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
425

Dussauge, P., Garrette, B. and Mitchell, W. (2002) The Market Lippman, S. and Rumelt, R. (1982) Uncertain imitability: an
Share Impact of Inter-partner Learning in Alliances: Evidence analysis of interfirm differences in efficiency under competi-
from the Global Auto Industry, in F.J. Contractor and P. tion, Bell Journal of Economics 13: 418438.
Lorange (eds.) Cooperative Strategies and Alliances, Elsevier Lyles, M.A. and Salk, J.E. (1996) Knowledge acquisition from
Science: Amsterdam, pp: 707727. foreign parents in international joint ventures: an empirical
Dyer, J. and Singh, H. (1998) The relational view: cooperative examination in the Hungarian context, Journal of International
strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive Business Studies 27(5): 877903.
advantage, Academy of Management Review 23(4): 660679. Mai, R.P. (1996) Learning Partnerships, Irwin: Chicago.
Filley, A., House, R. and Kerr, S. (1976) Managerial Process and Marquardt, M.J. (1996) Building the Learning Organization,
Organizational Behavior, 2nd edn. Scott, Foresman: Glenview, IL. McGraw-Hill: New York.
Fornell, C. (1982) A Second Generation of Multivariate Analysis: Martin, X. and Salomon, R. (2002) Knowledge Transfer
An Overview, in C. Fornell (ed.) A Second Generation of Capacity and Cooperative Strategies: When Should Firms
Multivariate Analysis: Methods, Praeger: New York, pp: 407450. Leverage Tacit Knowledge through Licensing and Alliances?,
Fornell, C. and Larcker, D. (1981) Evaluating structural equation in F.J. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds.) Cooperative Strategies
models with unobservable variables and measurement error, and Alliances, Elsevier Science: Amsterdam, pp: 729748.
Journal of Marketing Research 18: 3950. Meisel, S.I. and Fearon, D.S. (1996) Leading Learning, in S.A.
Glaister, K. and Buckley, P. (1996) Strategic motives for Cavaleri and D. Fearon (eds.) Managing in Organizations that
international alliance formation, Journal of Management Learn, Blackwell: Cambridge, MA, pp: 180209.
Studies 33(3): 301332. Mjoen, H. and Tallman, S. (1997) Control and performance
Hagedoorn, J. and Schakenraad, J. (1994) The effect of strategic in international joint ventures, Organization Science 8(3):
technology alliances on company performance, Strategic 257274.
Management Journal 15: 291309. Mosakowski, E. (1997) Strategy making under causal ambi-
Hamel, G. (1990) Competitive collaboration: learning, power guity: conceptual issues and empirical evidence, Organization
and dependence in international strategic alliances, Unpub- Science 8(4): 414442.
lished dissertation The University of Michigan. Mowery, D.C., Oxley, J.E. and Silverman, B.S. (1996) Strategic
Hamel, G. (1991) Competition for competence and inter- alliances and interfirm knowledge transfer, Strategic Manage-
partner learning within international strategic alliances, ment Journal 17: 7791.
Strategic Management Journal 12(special issue): 83103. Mowery, D.C., Oxley, J.E. and Silverman, B.S. (2002) The Two
Hamel, G., Doz, Y. and Prahalad, C.K. (1989) Collaborate with Faces of Partner-specific Absorptive Capacity: Learning and
your competitors, and win, Harvard Business Review 67(2): Cospecialization in Strategic Alliances, in F.J. Contractor and
133139. P. Lorange (eds.) Cooperative Strategies and Alliances, Elsevier
Hedberg, B. (1981) How Do Organizations Learn and Unlearn?, in Science: Amsterdam pp: 291319.
P.C. Nystrom and W.H. Starbucks (eds.) Handbook of Organiza- Nonaka, I. and Takeuchi, H. (1995) The Knowledge-Creating
tional Learning, Oxford University Press: London, pp: 127. Company, Oxford University Press: New York.
Hedlund, G. and Zander, U. (1993) Architectonic and List-Like Osborn, R. and Hagedoorn, J. (1997) The institutionali-
Knowledge Structuring: a Critique of Modern Concepts of zation and evolutionary dynamics of interorganizational
Knowledge Management, Stockholm School of Economics. alliances and networks, Academy of Management Journal
Inkpen, A.C. (2002) Learning, Knowledge Management, and 40(2): 261278.
Strategic Alliances: So Many Studies, So Many Unanswered Ques- Parkhe, A. (1993) Strategic alliance structuring: a game theoric
tions, in F.J. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds.) Cooperative Strate- and transaction cost examination of inter-firm cooperation,
gies and Alliances, Elsevier Science: Amsterdam, pp: 267289. Academy of Management Journal 6: 794829.
Inkpen, A.C. and Beamish, P.W. (1997) Knowledge, bargaining Pisano, G. (1988) Innovation through markets, hierarchies, and
power, and the instability of international joint ventures, joint ventures: Technology strategy and collaborative arrange-
Academy of Management Review 22(1): 177202. ments in the biotechnology industry, Dissertation University
Jo
reskog, K.G. and So rbom, D. (1996) LISREL VIII, SPSS, Inc.: of California, Berkeley.
Chicago. Podsakoff, P. and Organ, D.W. (1986) Self-reports in organiza-
Kale, P., Dyer, J. and Singh, H. (2002) Alliance capability, tional research: problems and prospects, Journal of Manage-
stock market response, and long-term alliance success: the ment 12: 531544.
role of the alliance function, Strategic Management Journal 23: Polanyi, M. (1967) The Tacit Dimension, Anchor: Garden City, NY.
747767. Powell, W.W., Koput, K.W. and Smith-Doerr, L. (1996) Inter-
Kelly, J. (1974) Organizational Behavior: An Existential-System organizational collaboration and the locus of innovation:
Approach, Richard Irwin, Inc. networks of learning in biotechnology, Administrative Science
Khanna, T., Gulati, R. and Nohria, N. (1998) The dynamics of Quarterly 41: 116145.
learning alliances: competition, cooperation and relative Pucik, V. (1988) Strategic alliances, organizational learning, and
scope, Strategic Management Journal 19: 193210. competitive advantage: the HRM agenda, Human Resource
Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1992) Knowledge of the firm, Management 27: 7793.
combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology, Reed, R. and DeFillippi, R.J. (1990) Causal ambiguity, barriers to
Organization Science 3(3): 383397. imitation, and sustainable competitive advantage, Academy of
Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1993) Knowledge of the firm and the Management Review 15: 88102.
evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation, Journal Reich, R. and Mankin, E. (1986) Joint ventures with Japan give
of International Business Studies 24(4): 625646. away our future, Harvard Business Review 64(2): 7886.
Konrad, A. and Linnehan, F. (1995) Formalized HRM structures: Reuer, J.J., Park, K.M. and Zollo, M. (2002) Experiential learning
coordinating equal employment opportunity or concealing in international joint ventures: the roles of experience
organizational practices?, Academy of Management Journal 38: heterogeneity and venture novelty, in F.J. Contractor and
787820. P. Lorange (eds.) Cooperative Strategies and Alliances, Perga-
Lane, P.J., Salk, J.E. and Lyles, M.A. (2001) Absorptive capacity, mon-Elsevier Science.
learning, and performance in international joint ventures, Scott, S. and Bruce, R. (1994) Determinant of innovative
Strategic Management Journal 22: 11391161. behavior: a path model of individual innovation in the
Lane, P.J. and Lubatkin, M. (1998) Relative absorptive capacity workplace, Academy of Management Journal 37: 580607.
and interorganizational learning, Strategic Management Jour- Simon, H. (1978) Rationality as process and as product of
nal 19: 461477. thought, American Economic Review 68: 116.

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
426

Simonin, B.L. (1999a) Ambiguity and the transfer of know- Developing Cultures for Tomorrows Workplace, Productivity
ledge in strategic alliances, Strategic Management Journal 20: Press: Portland, OR, pp: 8599.
595623. Tiemessen, I., Lane, H.W., Crossan, M.M. and Inkpen, A.C.
Simonin, B.L. (1999b) Transfer of marketing know-how in (1997) Knowledge Management in International Joint Ven-
international strategic alliances: an empirical investigation of tures, in P. Beamish and J. Killing (eds.) Cooperative Strategies:
the role and antecedents of knowledge ambiguity, Journal of North American Perspectives, The New Lexington Press: San
International Business Studies 30(3): 463490. Francisco, pp: 370399.
Simonin, B.L. (2002) The Nature of Collaborative Know- Von Krogh, G., Ichiro, K. and Nonaka, I. (2000) Enabling
How, in F.J. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds.) Coopera- knowledge creation, Oxford University Press: Oxford.
tive Strategies and Alliances, Elsevier Science: Amsterdam, Walsh, J.P. (1995) Managerial and organizational cognition:
pp: 237263. notes from a trip down memory lane, Organization Science
StatSoft, Inc. (2003) STATISTICA 6.1., Tulsa, OK. 6(3): 280321.
Swieringa, J. and Wierdsma, A.F.M. (1992) Becoming a Learning Zahra, S.A. and George, G (2002) Absorptive capacity: a review,
Organization, Addison-Wesley: Wokingham. reconceptualization, and extension, Academy of Management
Szulanski, G. (1996) Exploring internal stickiness: impediments Review 27(2): 185203.
to the transfer of best practice within the firm, Strategic Zander, U. and Kogut, B. (1995) Knowledge and the speed of
Management Journal 17: 2743. the transfer and imitation of organizational capabilities: an
Tallman, S. and Jenkins, M. (2002) Alliances, Knowledge Flows, empirical test, Organization Science 6(1): 7692.
and Performance in Regional Clusters, in F.J. Contractor and Zeng, M. and Hennart, J.-F. (2002) From Learning Races to
P. Lorange (eds.) Cooperative Strategies and Alliances, Elsevier Cooperative Specialization: Towards a New Framework for
Science: Amsterdam, pp: 163187. Alliance Management, in F.J. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds.)
Thompson, J. (1995) The Renaissance of Learning in Business, Cooperative Strategies and Alliances, Elsevier Science: Amster-
in S. Chawla and J. Renesch (eds.) Learning Organizations: dam, pp: 189210.

Appendix A: Questionnaire items

Knowledge transfer Source: Simonin (1999a) Strongly Strongly


disagree agree
Y1 Your company has learned a great deal about the technology/process know-how held by 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
your partner.
Y2 Your company has greatly reduced its initial technological reliance or dependence upon the 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
partner since the beginning of the alliance.
Y3 The technology/process know-how held by your partner has been assimilated by your company 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
and has contributed to other projects developed by your company.

Ambiguity Source: Simonin (1999a) Strongly Strongly


disagree agree
Y4 The technology/process know-how held by your partner is easily transferable back to your company. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Y5 The association between causes and effects, inputs and outputs, and actions and outcomes related 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
to the technology/process know-how held by your partner is clear.

Resource-based Adapted from Hamel (1990) Strongly Strongly


learning capacity and Pucik (1988) disagree agree
Y6 Your company has committed a lot of personnel to this alliance. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Y7 The staff assigned by your company to this alliance is composed of highly trained and 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
talented personnel.
Y8 Your company has committed a lot of physical, financial, organizational, and logistical resources 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
to support the seeking, diffusion and sharing of information originating from this alliance.

Incentive-based Adapted from Strongly Strongly


learning capacity Pucik (1988) disagree agree
Y9 There are clear incentives or a well-established reward system designed to encourage employees 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
to seek and repatriate information from this alliance.
Y10 For this alliance, a learning agenda has been clearly defined and communicated for all 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
personnel involved.

Cognitive-based Adapted from Hamel (1990) Strongly Strongly


learning capacity and Pucik (1988) disagree agree
Y11 In general, your staff involved with the alliance believe that they have less to learn from, than to 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
teach to your partner.

Journal of International Business Studies


Process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances Bernard L Simonin
427

Partner protectiveness Source: Simonin (1999a) Strongly Strongly


disagree agree
X1 Your partner is very protective of its technology/process know-how. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

Tacitness Source: Simonin (1999a) Strongly Strongly


disagree agree
X2 Your partners technology/process know-how is easily codifiable (in blueprints, instructions, 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
formulas, etc.).
X3 Your partners technology/process know-how is more explicit than tacit. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

Learning intent Adapted from Hamel (1990) Strongly Strongly


and Pucik (1988) disagree agree
X4 When deciding to enter into the alliance, your company had a strong desire, determination 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
and will to learn about a particular technology/process owned by your partner.
X5 This alliance is viewed as a means to learn about a particular technology/process held by 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
your partner, rather than as a way to simply use or rent this know-how.

Organizational culture Adapted from Hamel (1990) Strongly Strongly


(moderator) disagree agree
M1 In your company, rethinking the logic of current behaviors, questioning established routines 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
and beliefs, or challenging established wisdom, is encouraged.

Competitive regime Newly developed)


(moderator)
M2 To what extent do you consider your partner an actual or future competitor? (please check one)
Very strong competitor ( )
Strong competitor ( )
Weak competitor ( )
Not competitor ( )

About the author ment. His work has been published in the Journal of
Bernard L Simonin is an Associate Professor of Marketing Research, Journal of Advertising, Journal of
Marketing and International Business at the Fletch- International Marketing, Journal of International Business
er School of Law and Diplomacy (Tufts University). Studies, Journal of Business Research, International
He holds a PhD in International Business from the Executive, Global Focus, Academy of Management
University of Michigan (Ann Arbor). His research Journal, and Strategic Management Journal. He has
interest focuses on symbiotic marketing and spon- taught at the University of Michigan, University
sorship, market orientation, customer satisfaction, of Washington, University of Illinois, Harvard
brand alliances, strategic alliances, global strategy, University, and Kasetsart University in Thailand.
learning organizations, and knowledge manage-

Accepted by Nicolai Juul Foss and Torben Pederson, Departmental Editors, 1 April 2004. This paper has been with the author for one revision.

Journal of International Business Studies

You might also like