You are on page 1of 8

American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2014, 104(5): 8287

http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.5.82

Mandated Risk Retention in Mortgage Securitization:


An Economists View
By Paul Willen*

Economics is a highly sophisticated field Dodd-Frank Act introduced good incentives and
of thought that is superb at explaining to mandated that issuers retain at least a 5 percent
policymakers precisely why the choices interest in the loans they sold.2 Risk retention,
they made in the past were wrong. About according to its proponents, serves to better
the future, not so much. However, careful align [intermediaries] interests with those of
economic analysis does have one impor- investors, and help prevent a future crisis.3
tant benefit, which is that it can help kill
ideas that are completely logically incon- Barney Frank, one of the sponsors of Dodd-
sistent or wildly at variance with the data. Frank, said that mandatory risk retention was
This insight covers at least 90 percent of the single most important part of the bill.4
proposed economic policies. Journalists5 and academics6 have also enthu-
Ben Bernanke, The Ten Suggestions1 siastically supported mandatory risk retention.
In this paper, I take Bernankes challenge and
The most popular theory of the causes of ask whether risk retention is, logically incon-
the financial crisis has incentives at its heart. sistent [and] wildly at variance with the data?
According to the theory, bad incentives led My conclusion is that, like 90 percent of pro-
intermediaries to make bad loans and when bor- posed economic policies, risk retention fails
rowers defaulted on those loans, a crisis ensued. both tests. First, the data show that the financial
As a result, many policy remedies designed to crisis occurred because intermediaries had too
prevent a future crisis have focused on changing much mortgage risk in their portfolios, not too
incentives. If bad incentives led to bad lending little. Second, mandatory risk retention limits
and crisis, then good incentives will lead to good investor choice by blocking any investment in
lending and no crisis. assets in which the intermediary retains no risk,
The leading example of bad incentives is meaning that if the law is binding, intermediar-
securitization. According to its critics, by allow- ies will invest too much effort in screening: in
ing intermediaries to sell loans to others, secu- other words, the law will misalign incentives.
ritization insulated intermediaries from the Third, more broadly, economic theory is at best
consequences of their underwriting decisions ambiguous about whether gains elsewhere in the
and weakened the incentive to expend effort economy will offset the losses to investors.
underwriting loans. To fix this problem, the
I. Wildly at Variance with the Data
*Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 600 Atlantic Ave.,
Boston, MA 02210 and NBER (e-mail: paul.willen@bos. Table 1 illustrates the basic empirical problem
frb.org). The following is loosely based on Willen (forth- with risk retention. While securitization may
coming). I thank Daniel Cooper, Emily Dolbear, Chris
Foote, Andreas Fuster, Kris Gerardi, Bob Triest, Christina
2
Wang, and my discussant, Debbie Lucas, for helpful com- See the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer
ments and suggestions. The views expressed in this paper Protection Act, Title IX, Subtitle D, Improvements to the
are the authors and do not represent the official position of Asset-Backed Securitization Process.
the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston or the Federal Reserve 3
Keys et al. (2013).
4
System. Floyd Norris, Mortgages Without Risk, At Least for

Go to http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.5.82 to visit the the Banks, New York Times, November 28, 2013.
5
article page for additional materials and author disclosure See, for example, Felix Salmon, The Invidious Down
statement(s). Payment Requirement Meme, Reuters.com, April 25,
1
Speech at the Baccalaureate Ceremony at Princeton 2013.
University, June 2, 2013. 6
See Keys et al. (2013).
82
VOL. 104 NO. 5 RISK RETENTION IN SECURITIZATION 83

Table 1Mortgage-Related Losses to Financial Institutions from the Subprime Crisis, as of June 18, 2008

Loss Loss
Institution ($ billions) Institution ($ billions)
1 Citigroup 42.9 11 Washington Mutual 9.1
2 UBS 38.2 12 Credit Agricole 8.3
3 Merrill Lynch 37.1 13 Lehman Brothers 8.2
4 HSBC 19.5 14 Deutsche Bank 7.6
5 IKB Deutsche 15.9 15 Wachovia 7.0
6 Royal Bank of Scotland 15.2 16 HBOS 7.0
7 Bank of America 15.1 17 Bayerische Landesbank 6.7
8 Morgan Stanley 14.1 18 Fortis 6.6
9 JPMorgan Chase 9.8 19 Canadian Imperial (CIBC) 6.5
10 Credit Suisse 9.6 20 Barclays 6.3

Source: Subprime Losses Top $396 Billion on Brokers Writedowns: Table, Bloomberg.com, June 18, 2008.

have offered intermediaries the opportunity to A. Question 1


avoid mortgage risk, they declined and, instead,
took on enormous amounts of it in the years Suppose a consumer is choosing between two
leading up to the crisis. Indeed, the financial cars: a 2014 Honda Accord Hybrid that gets 45
crisis resulted precisely from the fact that the miles per gallon; and a 1995 Oldsmobile Cutlass
losses associated with the collapse in the hous- Ciera that gets 25 miles per gallon. Which car
ing market were so concentrated in the portfo- should he buy?
lios of the intermediaries. To put the numbers
in Table 1 in perspective, consider that the total 1) 2014 Honda Accord
losses on subprime lending from 2005 to 2007
were approximately $275 billion, meaning that 2) 1995 Oldsmobile Cutlass Ciera
risk retention would have imposed a $14 billion
loss on the entire industry. Eight firms individu- 3) Not enough information
ally lost more than that, and one, Citigroup, lost
more than three times that amount.7 The answer is, of course, 3. To opt for 1 or 2,
one would need to know, at the very least, the
II. Logically Inconsistent prices of the two cars, the buyers preferences,
and the cost of gas. While many would view the
If risk retention would not have, in practice, Honda as a better car, millions of people choose
made a difference, is it still a logically consis- used cars: there is a thriving market for 1990s
tent policy? Let me pose this question two ways. vintage General Motors A-bodies like the 1995
First, I will ask whether risk retention aligns Cutlass Ciera.
incentives which I take to mean that risk reten-
tion raises investor welfare. The answer is no B. Question 2
and I will use the device of a quiz to illustrate
why. In Section III, I will turn to the question Now consider an investor who is choosing
of whether the law may increase social welfare. between two loans. Loan 1 is to a borrower
with a 780 credit score, meaning he has little
debt and has almost never missed a payment,
has a loan-to-value (LTV) ratio of 80 percent
and on which the borrower provides incomplete
7
documentation of his income. Loan 2 is to a
Much of the losses resulted from retained portions borrower with a credit score of 550, meaning
of securities issued by the institutions. For example,
Citigroups losses were driven by losses on retained super- he is heavily indebted and has a history of seri-
senior tranches of Subprime ABS CDOs issued by the firm ous credit problems, has an LTV of 100 percent
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission (2011). but does provide full documentation of income.
84 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2014

Historical data shows that loans like Loan 2 are higher-powered incentives for Loan 2a. Higher-
an order of magnitude more likely to default powered incentives lead to more effort, but
than loans like Loan 1. Which loan should our they are costly: the intermediary puts in more
investor buy? effort and must be compensated, and since these
higher-powered incentives impose some risk,
1) Loan 1 (FICO=780, LTV=80, Reduced the investor must compensate the intermediary
documentation) for that as well. As a result, a rational manager
may eschew high-powered incentives even when
2) Loan 2 (FICO=550, LTV=100, Full they elicit more effort. To illustrate the point,
documentation) consider retailers. It is well understood that
high-powered incentives lead to higher sales and
3) Not enough information some highly successful retailers like Nordstrom
make heavy use of them,8 but other equally suc-
The answer is still 3. Without knowing the inter- cessful retailers like Apple avoid them entirely.9
est rate on the loans and the price (mortgages One way to think about risk retention is that
typically sell for more than the outstanding bal- it is just another feature of the loan, like the
ance), one cannot make a rational decision. The FICO score and the LTV. Just as we cannot say
fact that the credit quality of Loan 1 is dramati- whether a particular investor will prefer a high-
cally higher is not sufficient. Losses on credit risk loan or a low-risk loan without knowing the
cards dwarf losses on mortgages, yet banks price and the preferences of the investor, we can-
choose to loan hundreds of billions of dollars not say whether an investor would prefer a loan
on them. Default rates on subprime loans were with risk retention to one without.
more than five times higher than default rates on
prime loans even prior to the crisis, yet investors D. Question 4
eagerly sought them out.
Now suppose there are three loans. Loan 1
C. Question 3 from above (780 FICO, LTV 80, and Reduced
documentation, without risk retention) and loans
We now consider two versions of Loan 2. The 2a and 2b (FICO 550, LTV 100, with and with-
seller of Loan 2a has committed to retain 5 per- out risk retention, respectively). Dodd-Frank
cent of the credit risk, and the seller of Loan 2b restricts investors to only invest in Loan 2a.
has not. Which loan should our investor buy?
True/False/Uncertain: Under the stan-
1) Loan 2a (FICO=550, LTV=100, Full dard assumptions of financial econom-
documentation, Intermediary retains ics, restricting investors to Loan 2a can
some risk) increase social welfare.

2) Loan 2b (FICO=550, LTV=100, Full The answer is False, Dodd-Frank can only
documentation, Intermediary retains no reduce investor welfare. The reason is simple:
risk) Dodd-Frank reduces choice. Risk retention
is an attribute of a good, just like any other: if
3) Not enough information investors believe the benefits of risk retention
exceed the costs, they are free to choose to limit
The answer is still 3. But suppose we had good themselves to loans with risk retention. But in
data that showed that because of the absence of Questions 2 and 3 we showed that a perfectly
risk retention and the resulting low effort on the rational investor does not necessarily prefer
part of the intermediary, Loan 2b suffers from lower default rates to higher default rates, nor
lax screening. Would that change anything? No.
While journalists talk about misaligned incen- 8
tives, contract theorists focus on the difference See Christine Frey, Nordstrom Salesmans Million-
Dollar Secret is in His Treasured Client List, Seattle Post-
between high-powered incentives and low- Intelligencer, March 26, 2004.
powered incentives. Comparing Loans 2a and 9
See David Segal, Apples Retail Army, Long on
2b, one would say that the intermediary has Loyalty but Short on Pay, New York Times, June 23, 2012.
VOL. 104 NO. 5 RISK RETENTION IN SECURITIZATION 85

does she necessarily prefer an incentive scheme price reduces producer surplus for the monop-
that leads to higher effort. Limiting investors to olist, but since the increase in consumer sur-
loans with risk retention, from the standpoint of plus exceeds the loss to producers, social
economics, makes no more sense than limiting welfare increases. So the question here is could
car buyers to late model Honda Accords or forc- distorting incentives for investors and interme-
ing Apple to pay sales commissions. diaries be good for the economy as a whole? To
One popular argument is that the assump- frame the answer, consider a True/False ques-
tion that investors understood the differences tion. Suppose our investor again faces the prob-
between Loans 1, 2a, and 2b is flawed. Perhaps lem of choosing between Loans 1, 2a, and 2b
investors thought they were buying Loan 1 when from above. Consider Question 5:
they were, in fact, buying Loan 2b. The evi-
dence refutes this theory. Gerardi et al. (2008) True/False/Uncertain: Under the stan-
carefully review reports by investment analysts dard assumptions of financial econom-
from 2005 and show that investor beliefs about ics, restricting investors to Loan 2a will
loan quality were very accurate. Investors losses increase social welfare.
resulted from their unwillingness to believe that
house prices could fall as rapidly as they did or, The correct answer, surprisingly, is that the
in fact, that they could fall at all. statement is false, not uncertain. Prescott and
Question 4 illustrates the logical inconsis- Townsend (1984) show that under the financial
tency of risk retention. Hard as this is to believe, economics assumption of a single consumption
if the risk retention constraint is binding, then, good, equilibrium with moral hazard is con-
as far as investors are concerned, the intermedi- strained Pareto optimal, meaning that a planner
ary is expending too much effort, meaning that who lacks superior information to the market
risk retention has actually made the misalign- cannot improve on the market allocation.
ment problem worse, not better. With more general assumptions, government
To conclude, the argument that government- intervention can increase welfare. If defaults
mandated risk retention fails to make economic generate negative externalities, one could, of
sense does not mean that risk retention in con- course, justify any policy that limits default, but
tracts is bad for investors. On the contrary, in risk retention would be a peculiar way to deal
many cases, private actors want to structure con- with externalities: despite the absence of risk
tracts with risk retention.10 In fact, during the retention, Loan 1 has a dramatically lower risk
housing boom, risk retention was a key feature of default than Loan 2a.11
of mortgage lending, as intermediaries retained A more relevant set of results appears in
far more risk than the law mandates. If private the general equilibrium literature. Consider
agents in the mortgage market agree to risk- Question 6:
retention arrangements, then a government pol-
icy that prevented investors from buying loans True/False/Uncertain: With multiple
like Loan 2a would be just as bad as a policy that consumption goods, restricting investors
mandated risk retention. to Loan 2a will increase social welfare.

III. Risk Retention and Social Welfare: The correct answer is Uncertain. Greenwald
Questions 5 and 6 and Stiglitz (1986) show that with multiple con-
sumption goods, equilibrium in economies with
Under the standard assumptions of classical asymmetric information is constrained inef-
welfare economics, restricting choice obviously ficient, meaning that, unlike in the financial
never directly increases individual welfare but it markets economy above, risk retention is not
can lead to higher social welfare. For e xample, automatically welfare reducing. Geanakoplos
forcing a monopolist to charge the c ompetitive and Polemarchakis (1986) and Bisin and

10 11
Extending the analysis outside the private market, risk And one would have to weigh in the balance any posi-
retention could also be valuable in government loan pro- tive externalities of expanded homeownership allowed by
grams like FHA. more credit availability.
86 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2014

Gottardi (2006) show similar results for, respec- effort in underwriting. If house prices are ris-
tively, economies with multiple goods and ing 10 percent a year, a mortgage presents little
asymmetric information and economies with a risk of loss regardless of whether the borrower
single consumption good and adverse selection. can afford the payments. In a bubble, when such
In other words, the best economic theory optimism is rampant, retained risk has little
can say is that, in a general setting, the welfare deterrent effect. Recall that Table 1 showed that
effects of risk retention are uncertain. At first Wall Street firms financed a mountain of risky
blush, the idea that risk retention could increase loans during the housing boom despite retain-
social welfare is surprising. The reason is that ing a great deal of credit risk. This behavior
the welfare losses associated with incomplete is straightforward to explain: recent research
markets and asymmetric information generally shows that intermediaries displayed remarkable
result from the inability of market participants optimism about house prices during the boom
to share risk, not from excessive risk sharing. years.14 In short, theory says that risk retention
Welfare-improving policy interventions typi- will be least effective precisely when it is needed
cally involve doing exactly the opposite of man- most, in the midst of speculative frenzy.
datory risk retention. For example, to mitigate
the adverse selection problem in health insur-
ance, the Affordable Care Act (ACA), following REFERENCES
the insights of Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976),
mandates that individuals buy insurance. In Bisin, Alberto, and Piero Gottardi. 2006. Effi-
other words, whereas Dodd-Frank mandates a cient Competitive Equilibria with Adverse
ceiling on the transfer of risk, the ACA man- Selection. Journal of Political Economy 114
dates a floor. (3): 485516.
Could these textbook models be missing Cheng, Ing-Haw, Sahil Raina, and Wei Xiong.
some important features of the real world? In 2013. Wall Street and the Housing Bub-
particular, could mandated risk retention pre- ble. National Bureau of Economic Research
vent bubbles?12 Risk retention suppresses risky Working Paper 18904.
lending, so if risky lending causes destabilizing Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission. 2011. The
bubbles, one might argue that mandated risk Financial Crisis Inquiry Report: Final Report
retention could be welfare enhancing. While of the National Commission on the Causes
intuitively appealing, this story has little formal of the Financial and Economic Crisis in the
economics to back it up.13 Economic theorists United States. Washington, DC: US Govern-
have trouble devising models that generate bub- ment Printing Office.
bles at all, let alone models in which risky lend- Foote, Christopher L, Kristopher S. Gerardi, and
ing generates bubbles. Paul S. Willen. 2012. Why Did So Many
While economics is unclear about whether People Make So Many Bad Decisions? In
risk retention prevents bubbles, a different link Rethinking the Financial Crisis, edited by
between the two emerges quite robustly: bub- Alan S. Blinder, Andrew W. Lo, and Robert
bles can prevent risk retention from working. M. Solow, 13686. New York: Sage Founda-
The problem is that optimism about the value tion.
of collateral reduces the benefits of exerting Geanakoplos, John D., and Heraklis M.
Polemarchakis. 1986. Existence, Regular-
ity, and Constrained Suboptimality of Com-
12
The authors of the Dodd-Frank bill speculated that risk petitive Allocations when the Asset Market
retention could raise welfare by discouraging asset-price is Incomplete. In Uncertainty, Information,
bubbles. Section 946 of the bill calls for a Study On The and Communication: Essays in Honor of
Macroeconomic Effects Of Risk Retention Requirements
to include, Kenneth J. Arrow, Vol. 3, edited by Walter P.
...an analysis of the effects of risk retention on real Heller, Ross M. Starr, and David A. Starrett,
estate asset price bubbles, including a retrospective
estimate of what fraction of real estate losses may
have been averted had such requirements been in force
in recent years.
13
The policy-driven welfare gains in the theoretical lit- 14
See Foote, Gerardi, and Willen (2012) and Cheng,
erature discussed above have nothing to do with bubbles. Raina, and Xiong (2013).
VOL. 104 NO. 5 RISK RETENTION IN SECURITIZATION 87

6596. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univer- Glaeser and Todd Sinai, 143204. Chicago:
sity Press. University of Chicago Press.
Gerardi, Kristopher, Andreas Lehnert, Shane Prescott, Edward C., and Robert M. Townsend.
M. Sherlund, and Paul Willen. 2008. Mak- 1984. Pareto Optima and Competitive Equi-
ing Sense of the Subprime Crisis. Brookings libria with Adverse Selection and Moral Haz-
Papers on Economic Activity: 69145. ard. Econometrica 52 (1): 2145.
Greenwald, Bruce C., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1986. Rothschild, Michael, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1976.
Externalities in Economies with Imperfect Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Mar-
Information and Incomplete Markets. Quar- kets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect
terly Journal of Economics 101 (2): 22964. Information. Quarterly Journal of Econom-
Keys, Benjamin J., Tomasz Piskorski, Amit Seru, ics 90 (4): 63049.
and Vikrant Vig. 2013. Mortgage Financing Willen, Paul. Forthcoming. Evaluating Policies
in the Housing Boom and Bust. In Housing to Prevent another Crisis: An Economists
and the Financial Crisis, edited by Edward L. view. Cato Papers on Public Policy.
Copyright of American Economic Review is the property of American Economic Association
and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without
the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or
email articles for individual use.
Copyright of American Economic Review is the property of American Economic Association
and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without
the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or
email articles for individual use.

You might also like