You are on page 1of 33

GettinguptoSpeedontheFinancialCrisis:AOneWeekendReadersGuide

GaryGorton,YaleandNBER

AndrewMetrick,YaleandNBER

January11,2012

Abstract

All economists should be conversant with what happened? during the financial crisis of 20072009.
We select and summarize 16 documents, including academic papers and reports from regulatory and
internationalagencies.Thisreadinglistcoversthekeyfactsandmechanismsinthebuildupofrisk,the
panicsinshorttermdebtmarkets,thepolicyreactions,andtherealeffectsofthefinancialcrisis.

Thanks to Janet Currie (the editor) and Patrick McCabe for helpful comments, and to Jeanne Helene
Gobat, Campbell Harvey, Arvind Krishnamurthy, Nellie Liang, Patrick McCabe, Zoltan Pozsar, Carmen
Reinhart,KennethRogoff,andAlanTaylorforassistancewiththefigures.

1. Introduction

Thefirstfinancialcrisisofthe21stcenturyhasnotyetended,butthewaveofresearchonthecrisishas
alreadyexceededanysinglereaderscapacity,withthepaceofnewworkonlymakingthistaskharder.
Many professional economists now find themselves answering questions from their students, friends,
and relatives on topics that did not seem at all central until a few years ago, and we are collectively
scramblingtocatchup.

Thisarticleisintendedtoserveasastartingpointforeconomistswhowanttogetuptospeedonthe
literature of the crisis, without having to go into a cave and read for a whole year. To this end, the
readinglistisrestrictedto16documents,alistthatanambitiousreadercouldcoverinoneweekendor
atamoreleisurelypaceoverafewweeks.Thus,thisarticleisnotacompletesurveyinanyshapeor
form,andmanyinterestingpapershavebeenomitted.Thecoverageisfrom2007to2009,andwhile
thescopeisglobalduringthistimeperiod,itdoesnotincludeanypapersordiscussionaboutthestill
ongoing Eurocurrency and sovereigndebt crisis. The list is also confined to readings with significant
empiricalcontent,aswehopethatthiscollectioncanatleastanswerthewhathappened?question
aboutthecrisis,evenifthewhy?isnotyetsettled.Inadditiontoagoodnumberofpapersfromtop
journals, the final collection includes several reports from international agencies, a speech and a
congressional testimony from Chairman Bernanke, and several asyetunpublished papers. We have
tried hard to avoid repetition, and on several occasions chose one paper among several worthy
contendersonthesametopic.Thus,thisisanunusualpaperfortheJournalofEconomicLiteraturein
thatcitationsandthereferencelistincludeonlythe16documentscoveredinthereview.

Theproposedreadinglistandarticlearedividedintoeightsections.Followingthisintroduction,Section
2providesanoverviewandtimelineofthecrisis,withsuggestedreadingsthatcoverthatsamebroad
range.Thethreedocumentsinthatsectioncanbethoughtofasanevenbrieferreadinglist,forpeople
whoonlyhaveanafternoontospendontheproject:2010testimonyfromBenBernankeinfrontofthe
FinancialInquiryCrisisCommission,andreportchaptersfromtheInternationalMonetaryFund(2010)
andBankforInternationalSettlements(2009)containingoverviewsofdifferentaspectsofthecrisis.

Section3givesahistoricalperspectiveonfinancialcrises,whichwebelievecrucialforunderstandingthe
recentone.Thetwopaperscoveredhere,ReinhartandRogoff(2011)andSchularickandTaylor(2012),
are the products of Herculean data collection efforts on long historical time series about government
and private debt. Both of these papers demonstrate the strong association between accelerations in
2

economywide leverage and subsequent banking crises. That finding deserves emphasis as the main
empiricalfactabouthistoricalpredicatestofinancialcrises.

Section4coversthebuilduptothecrisis.Inretrospect,theexperienceofthe2000slooksominously
like the prelude to other large crises. Pozsar (2011) documents the important role played by
institutionalcashpools,whichgrewrapidlyinthedecadebeforethecrisis.Thesepools,withascale
uniquetohistory,createdalargedemandforsafeandliquidshorttermdebt,ademandmetinpartby
securitization and other financial innovations. Bernanke (2005) foreshadowed some dynamics of the
crisiswhendescribingandnamingtheglobalsavingsglut.Theresultinggrowthinsovereignwealth
funds,anewinstitutionofthe21stcentury,alsoadded tothe demandforshorttermdebt. By2007,
systemwideleveragehadreachedcriticallevels,butthehistoricalaggregatecreditdatanecessaryfor
earlywarning models would not be built until after the damage was done. Coincident with the
increaseinleveragewasalargerunupinhousingprices.Whilehistoricalcrosscountrydataonhousing
pricesisnotascomprehensiveasthedataoncreditaggregates,ReinhartandRogoff(2008)findsharp
increasesinhousingpricespriortothefivelargestfinancialcrisesofrecenthistory,withtheprevious
decadeintheUnitedStatescomparable(orworse)thanthosepreviouscrises.CaseandShiller(2003),
in a remarkably prescient paper, provide evidence that the United States was already experiencing a
housingbubblewellbeforethecrisisbegan.

Section 5 discusses three papers about the two panic phases of the crisis August 2007 and
SeptemberOctober2008betweenwhichthecrisisexpandedfromarelativelynarrowsliceoffinancial
marketsfocusedonsubprimemortgagesintoabroadbasedrunonmanytypesofshorttermdebt.The
threepapersinthissectionfocusonthreedifferentcomponentsofshorttermfundingmarkets:Covitz,
Liang,andSuarez(2011)onassetbackedcommercialpaper,McCabe(2010)onmoneymarketmutual
funds,andGortonandMetrick(2012)onrepurchaseagreementsandsecuritization.Thecombination
ofthesethreepapersprovidesanarrativeofcontagionwhereeachstepdrainsthebankingsystemof
hundredsofbillionsofdollarsandinduceshigherriskpremiaforbankstoreplacethosefunds.

Section6analyzesthevariousgovernmentresponses,whereopinionremainsdividedbetweenviewsof
governmentassaviororculprit.Therearenowmanypapersfocusingonspecificpolicyactions,butfew
comprehensivesurveys.WechoseChapterIIIoftheIMFsFinancialStabilityReportofOctober2009,
whichincludesataxonomyandanalysesofpolicyactionsacross13countriesfrom2007to2009.The
report finds a few bright spots for policy, with actions to support the liquidity of shortterm debt
marketsmosteffectiveduringthepreLehmanperiodofthecrisis(beforeSeptember2008),andcapital
3

injectionsintobanksmosteffectiveinthepostLehmanperiod.

Forsomeeconomists,thefinancialcrisisonlybecomesinterestingifithaseffectsfortherealeconomy,
atopicdiscussedinSection7.Tomeasuresucheffects,itisimportanttodistinguishbetweenshocksto
credit supply (where a direct line can be drawn to the crisis) and to credit demand (which may have
othercauses).Thepapersinthissectionallattackthisproblemincreativewaysandpresentpersuasive
evidenceofthechannelfromfinancialshockstorealactivity.ScharfsteinandIvashina(2010)analyze
the syndicated loan market in the United States and find that decreases in lending were related to a
banks reliance on shortterm funding and by indirect exposure to a Lehman bankruptcy shock. Puri,
Rocholl,and Steffen (2012)exploitdifferentialexposuresofGermanbanks tosubprimesecuritiesand
findthatshockstocreditsupplyreducedthepropensitytomakeconsumerloans.Campello,Graham,
andHarvey(2010)usedetailedsurveyevidencetoshowthatfirmswithcreditconstraintspulledback
oninvestment.

Section8concludesthepaper.

2.OverviewandTimelineoftheCrisis

TheFinancialCrisisof20072009beganinearlyAugustwithrunsinseveralshorttermmarketsformerly
considered safe. As Ben Bernanke (2010) put it: Should the safety of their investments come into
question,itiseasierandsafertowithdrawfundsrunonthebankthantoinvesttimeandresources
toevaluateindetailwhethertheirinvestmentis,infact,safe(p.3).Table1isanabbreviatedtimeline
ofthemajoreventsofthecrisis.ThecrisishadbeenbuildingforsometimebeforeAugust:Duringthe
firsthalfof2007problemsinthesubprimemarketbecameincreasinglyvisibleandincludedthefailure
of several subprime originators. And even before that there was a credit boom, steeply rising home
prices,andglobalimbalancesinforeigntrade.

Inthissectionwewillbrieflyprovideanoverviewofthecrisis,focusedonthreedocuments.Thefirstis
BenBernankestestimonybeforetheFinancialCrisisInquiryCommission,September2,2010.Bernanke
provides a lucid overview of the crisis, the causes, the policy responses, and the ongoing issues. The
second is Chapter II from the International Monetary Funds (IMF) Financial Stability Report (2010),
Systemic Liquidity Risk: Improving the Resilience of Financial Institutions and Markets. Finally, the
third is Chapter II of the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) 79th Annual Report, The Global
FinancialCrisis.Fromjustthesethreeitems,aclearpictureofthecrisisemerges.

Bernanke makes several important points in developing the idea that the crisis was a like an old
fashioned run. First, he distinguishes between triggers and vulnerabilities. Losses on subprime
mortgages,ormoreaccurately,theprospectofsuchlosses,afterhousepricesstartedtodecline,werea
triggerforthecrisis.But,theycannotexplainthecrisis.AsBernankeputsit,...judgedinrelationto
thesizeofglobalfinancialmarkets,prospectivesubprimelosseswereclearlynotlargeenoughontheir
own to account for the magnitude of the crisis (p. 2). Somehow the prospective losses had to be
amplifiedtogeneratethecrisis.

A second point that Bernanke makes is that the systemic vulnerabilities in large part were due to
changesthathadoccurredinthefinancialsectoroftheeconomy.Thefinancialcrisiswasabankrun,but
in sectors of the money markets where financial institutions provided banklike debt products to
institutionalinvestors.Thesefinancialinstitutionsweremostlyshadowbanks.Bernanke(2010,p.4):

Shadow banks are financial entities other than regulated depository institutions
(commercial banks, thrifts, and credit unions) that serve as intermediaries to channel
savings into investment Before the crisis, the shadow banking system had come to
playamajorroleinglobalfinance;withhindsight,wecanseethatshadowbankingwas
alsothesourceofkeyvulnerabilities.(p.4;emphasisinoriginal)

The main vulnerability was shortterm debt, mostly repurchase agreements and commercial paper.
These markets had grown enormously. Bernanke notes that repo liabilities of U.S. broker dealers
increased2timesinthefouryearsbeforethecrisis(p.5).And,theIMFalsonotesthatTherepo
markethasrepresentedthefastestgrowingcomponentofthewholesalefundingmarkets...(p.64).
Notonlywerethesemarketslarge,buttheywereunregulated,asbothBernankeandtheIMFpointout.

A repo transaction is a collateralized deposit in a bank, as follows. The depositor or lender puts
money in the bank for a shortterm, usually overnight. The bank promises to pay the overnight repo
rateonthedepositedmoney.Toensurethesafetyofthedeposit,thebankprovidescollateralthatthe
depositor takes possession of. Depositors are large institutional investors, money market funds, non
financialfirms,statesormunicipalities,andotherlargeinvestors.Thesizeoftheirdepositsistoobigfor
aninsuredaccountatabank,andhencetheneedforcollateraltotrytoprotectthedeposit.Ifthebank
fails,thenthedepositorcansellthecollateraltorecoverthevalueofthedeposit.Ifthedepositis$100
5

millionandthecollateralhasamarketvalueof$100million,thenthereissaidtobenohaircutonthe
collateral.Ifthedepositis$90million,andthecollateralis$100million,thenthereissaidtobea10
percenthaircut.TheIMF(2010,p.71,73)discussessomedetailsabouthowtherepomarketworks.

Thoughnotasubjectofacademicresearch(priortothecrisis),therepomarketisnotasmall,esoteric,
market.IMF(2010)estimatestotaloutstandingrepoinU.S.marketsatbetween20and30percentof
U.S. GDP in each of the years from 2002 to 2007. Their estimates for the European Union are even
higher, with a low of 30 percent and a peak just above 50 percent of E.U. GDP during the same time
period. While these measurements are imprecise, it is clear that the repo market is sizeable in the
advancedeconomies.

ItwasnotonlyintheUnitedStatesthattherewereproblemsofthissort.DisruptionsintheU.S.short
termdebtmarketscreatedashortageofU.S.dollarsinglobalmarkets.IMF(p.61):U.S.dollarfunding
was required especially by banks in Europe (e.g., Dutch, German, Swiss, and U.K. banks), but also by
banks in Korea, to roll over shortterm funding of longerterm U.S. dollar assets. The shortage in U.S.
dollars also affected the foreign exchange swap market, with the U.S. dollar being used as the main
swapcurrencyforcrosscurrencyfunding.

The bankruptcy filing of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 (see the Timeline) enormously
exacerbatedthesituation.TheBISsummarizeswhathappened:

ThetippingpointcameonMonday15September,whenLehmanBrothersHoldingsInc.
filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy protection: what many had hoped would be merely a
year of manageable market turmoil then escalated into a fullfledged global crisis.
Suddenly, with markets increasingly in disarray, a growing number of financial
institutions were facing the risk of default. The resulting crisis of confidence quickly
spreadacrossmarketsandcountries...(p.23).

Most importantly, the failure of Lehman led to a run on money market mutual funds after one large
fundbrokethebuck(seeIMF,p.65ff;BIS,p.2526).TheU.S.Treasurythenannouncedatemporary
guaranteeofmoneymarketmutualfunds.ConfidenceinthestabilityofthefinancialsystemsintheU.S.
andEuropewaslost.Theresultingturmoilledtobankshoardingliquidity,andthiswillplayanimportant
roleintransmittingthecrisistotherealsectorandinternationally.Inthisway,theprospectivelossesin
6

the subprime market were amplified. Bernanke: Ultimately, the disruptions to a range of financial
marketsandinstitutionsprovedfarmoredamagingthanthesubprimelossesthemselves(2010;p.3).

Central banks engaged in unprecedented interventions and the U.S. Congress eventually passed the
TroubledAssetReliefProgram(TARP).OnOctober8,2008therewasacoordinatedreductioninpolicy
ratesbysixmajorcentralbanks;seeBIS,p.30.But,thiswasnottheend.AstheBISexplained:

Althoughtheglobalcrisisofconfidencehadcometoanend,policyactioncontinuedon
an international scale as governments sought to support market functioning and to
cushiontheblowofrapideconomiccontraction.Evenso,withmanydetailsunspecified,
questionsaboutthedesign,impactandconsistencyofthesemeasuresremained.Asa
result,financialmarkets wereroiled byincreasinglydiremacroeconomic datareleases
and earnings reports, punctuated by shortlived period of optimismoften in response
totheannouncementoffurthergovernmentinterventions.(p.31).

Eventually,thereweresignsofstabilization,frommidMarch2009;seeBIS,p.34ff.But,therealeffects
havepersisted.

3.HistoricalBackground

TherecentcrisisisoftendescribedasbeingtheworstglobalcrisissincetheGreatDepression,andthe
evidencesupportsthislabel.Butthegapbetweencrisesofthismagnitudemeanswemustlooktowards
longhistoricaltimeseriestogainperspectiveonpatternsofglobalcrises.Wearefortunatethatseveral
teamsembarkeduponmassivedatagatheringprojectspriortothiscrisis,sothatsomeoftheirresults
are available now to give us that necessary perspective. In this section, we review two important
contributions to this literature: Reinhart and Rogoff (2011) and Schularick and Taylor (2012). Both
papersidentifyaccelerationsindebtasthekeyantecedenttobankingcrises,withReinhartandRogoff
focusingonpublicandprivatedebtandSchularickandTayloronthestructureofbankingsector.Both
setsofauthorshavedevelopedimportantnewdataseriestoenabletheiranalyses,andbothprovidea
richcollectionofhistoricaldetailsthatmaketheirpapersworthyofclosereading.

ReinhartandRogoffdefineabankingcrisisbytheexistenceofoneoftwotypesofevents:(1)bankruns
thatleadtotheclosure,merging,ortakeoverbythepublicsectorofoneormorefinancialinstitutions;
or (2) if there are no runs, the closure, merging, takeover, or largescale government assistance of an
important financial institution (or group of institutions), that marks the start of a string of similar
7

outcomes for other financial institutions. Using this definition, the historical incidence of banking
crisesisaboutthesameforadvancedeconomiesasforemergingmarkets,andwhilethisincidencehas
beenlowersinceWorldWarII,asoftheirwritingonlyPortugalhadbeensparedinthatinterval.

Theyfindseveralinterestingresults.First,externaldebtincreasessharplyinadvanceofbankingcrises.
Second, banking crises tend to lead sovereigndebt crises. In fact, not only does external debt rise
sharply, but so does domestic government debt a new data series built by the authors for their
analysis.ThesecondfindingthatbankingcrisesleadsovereigndebtcrisesisalsosupportedbyaVAR
analysis.Althoughthedirectionofcausalitycannotbeconclusivelydeterminedfromsuchanalyses,the
consistentfindingsacrossmanydifferentcountriesandtimeperiodssuggeststhatbankingcrisesplayan
importantacceleratorroleinbroaderdebtcrises.

SchularickandTaylor(2012)provideanotherimportanthistoricalperspective,analyzingtherelationship
offinancialcriseswithoverallcreditgrowthintheeconomy.Theybeginbybuildinga140yearpanel
datasetfor14(currently)developedcountries.Themainnoveltyoftheirdatasetistheconstructionof
creditandbankassetseriesforeachcountry,whereaggregatecreditisdefinedasthetotalamountof
bank loans outstanding, and bank assets are defined as the sum of the balancesheet assets for all
banks. Thesenewmeasurescanthenbecomparedtobroadmoneyaggregates (M2orM3),which
havelongbeenavailableformostcountries.

Thebasictimeseriesofcredit,assets,andbroadmoneycomparedtoGDPisshowninFigure1,taken
from their paper. Prior to the Great Depression, all three money and credit aggregates have a stable
relationship with GDP. All three increase sharply just before the depression and then collapse in its
aftermath.Aspointedoutbytheauthors,priorto1950thestabilityoftheseserieswouldbeconsistent
withthemonetaristview,andwouldnotsuggestanyneedtoanalyzebroadercreditaggregates.

Things get more interesting in the postWWII period, when both bank loans and bank assets begin to
steadilyincreaserelativetoGDP,whiletheratioofGDPtobroadmoneyremainedstable.Thisstriking
changeunknownuntiltheirworkisdescribedbytheauthorsasheraldingasecondfinancialera
wherecredititselfthenstartedtodecouplefrombroadmoneyandgrewrapidly,viaacombinationof
increasedleverageandaugmentedfundingviathenonmonetaryliabilitiesofbanks.

Their paper goes on to explore the impact of this change on the incidence and severity of financial
crises.Theiranalysisadoptsanearlywarningsignalapproachthatisstandardinthisliterature,where
macrovariablesareusedtopredicttheonsetofacrisis.Whilethisearlywarningapproachhasbeen
8

usedextensivelyonemergingmarketsforthepost1970period,onlythedatacollectioneffortsofthese
authors allow for an extension to a longer time series while including credit aggregates as regressors.
The results show that changes in credit supply (bank loans) are a strong predictor of financial crises,
particularly when these changes are accelerating, an echo of the findings in Reinhart and Rogoff for
external debt. Furthermore, broad money aggregates do not have the same predictive power,
particularlyinthepostWWIIperiod.Thisfindingmotivatesthetitleoftheirpaperandtheirdescription
offinancialcrisesasCreditBoomsGoneBust.

ReinhartandRogoff(2011)andSchularickandTaylor(2012)provideaconsistentpictureoftherunup
toafinancialcrisis:anaccelerationofdebtfrombothgovernmentsandfinancialintermediariesarethe
mostimportantantecedents.

4.TheCrisisBuildUp

Onthebuilduptothecrisis,wereviewfourdocuments,twothatwerewrittenbeforethecrisis,butare
quiteprescient.

The four are Institutional Cash Pools and the Triffin Dilemma of the U.S. Banking System, by Zoltan
Pozsar (2011); Ben Bernankes 2005 Sandridge Lecture, The Global Savings Glut and the U.S. Current
AccountDeficit;IsThereaBubbleintheHousingMarket,byKarlCaseandRobertShiller(2003);and
Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoffs 2008 paper Is the 2007 U.S. SubPrime Financial Crisis so
Different?AnInternationalHistoricalComparison.

Asdiscussedintheprevioussection,crisesareoftenprecededbycreditbooms.InthecaseoftheU.S.
intherecentcrisis,thecreditboomtooktheformofanincreasetheissuanceofassetbackedsecurities,
particularly mortgagebacked securities. This is related to the development and functioning of the
shadowbankingsystem.Thegrowthintheshadowbankingsystemwastheoutcomeofseveralforces.
The traditional banking model became less profitable in the face of competition from money market
mutual funds and junk bonds. Securitization, the sale of loan pools to special purpose vehicles that
financethepurchaseoftheloanpoolsviaissuanceofassetbackedsecuritiesinthecapitalmarkets,was
an important response. Figure 2 shows the growth of U.S. privatelabel securitization issuance during
20002010:Q1.Althoughsecuritizationbeganinthe1990s,thefiguremakescleartheexplosivegrowth
inthesixorsevenyearsbeforethecrisis,agrowthconsistentwiththenotionofacreditboom.Over
theperiodportrayedinthefigure,theprivatelabelsecuritizationmarketgrewfromunder$500billion
inissuancetoover$2trillioninissuancein2006,theyearbeforethecrisis.
9

Securitization is offbalance sheet financing for banks and other financial intermediaries. But, if these
intermediariesarenotgoingtofinancetheseloanpoolsonbalancesheet,whoisgoingtobuytheasset
backed securities? Pozsar describes institutional cash pools: . . . they are large (typically at least $1
billioninsize)andcentrallymanaged.Thecentralmanagementofcashpoolsreferstotheaggregation
(or pooling) of cash balances from all subsidiaries worldwide in the case of global corporations, or all
funds (including mutual and hedge funds and separate accounts) in the case of asset managers.
Furthermore, the investment decisions that pertain to pooled balances are performed by a single
decision maker (typically a treasurer) and through a fund that is a single legal person, but one that
manages the cash balances of many legal persons (p. 5; emphasis in original). Pozsar documents a
strikingriseinthefundsmanagedbythesepools,fromabout$200millionin1990tonearly$4trillion
ontheeveofthecrisis.

Thekeypointaboutthegrowthofinstitutionalcashpoolsisthattheyhaveanassociateddemandfor
liquidity;inparticular,theyhaveademandforinsureddepositalternatives(Pozsarsterminology).The
amountsofmoneythattheywantedtoallocatedtosafeassetclassesfarexceededtheamountthat
could be insured in a demand deposit account. The problem was that there were not enough safe
assets, U.S. Treasuries, for the pools to hold. Pozsar estimates that between 2003 and 2008,
institutionalcashpoolsdemandforinsureddepositalternativesexceededtheoutstandingamountof
shorttermgovernmentguaranteedinstrumentsnotheldbyforeignofficialinvestorsbyacumulativeof
atleast$1.5trillion;theshadowbankingsystemrosetofillthisgap(p.3;emphasisinoriginal).

Foreign official investors hold large amounts of U.S. Treasuries. And this is where the effects of the
currentaccountimbalancemayhaveplayedarole.Bernanke(2005):Ifacountryssavingexceedsits
investment during a particular year, the difference represents excess saving that can be lent on
internationalcapitalmarkets.Bythesametoken,ifacountryssavingislessthantheamountrequired
tofinancedomesticinvestment,thecountrycanclosethegapbyborrowingfromabroad.IntheUnited
States,nationalsavingiscurrentlyquitelowandfallsconsiderablyshortofU.S.capitalinvestment.Of
necessity,thisshortfallismadeupbyforeignnetborrowing(p.3).Therewerelargeandpersistent
capital inflows from foreigners seeking U.S. assets as a store of value. It is not so clear why the
foreignerswantrisklessassets,ratherthan,say,buylandandpropertyintheU.S.

WithlargeamountsofU.S.Treasuriesheldabroad,institutionalcashpoolshadtofindsubstitutes.The
substituteswereoftwoforms.First,shorttermbankdebtlikeproducts,suchasrepurchaseagreements
and assetbacked commercial paper provided collateral that substituted for government guarantees.
10

Second, there were indirect holdings of unsecured private money market instruments through money
marketmutualfunds,wherethefundsassetportfoliowasshorttermandgloballydiversified.

Thejoiningtogetherofthesupplyofassetbackedsecuritieswiththedemandforprivatealternativesto
insureddepositsledtotheshadowbankingsystem,agenuinebankingsystemprovidingproductswitha
convenienceyield,shorttermdebtofintermediaries,oftenbasedonprivatelyproducedcollateral.

Historically,fortheprivateproductionofhighqualityassetbackedsecurities,mortgageshavebeenthe
preferred collateral. The increase in the production of assetbacked securities appears to be a credit
boom. In credit booms, households and firms are borrowing money. What are they doing with this
money?Onepossibilityisthattheyarebuyinghouses.Creditboomsseemtooftencoincidewithhouse
priceincreases.Thecausalityisnotclear.Isitthatfinancialintermediarieslowertheirlendingstandards
and fuel house price increases? Or, are house prices going up (for some other reason) and
intermediariesarewillingtolendagainstcollateralthatisthenmorevaluable?Thisisanareaforfuture
research.

House prices were rising during the credit boom. Karl Case and Robert Shiller documented the house
priceincreasesin2003.Asthetitleoftheirarticlesuggests,theirmainquestionconcernsthenatureof
thehousepriceincreases:Isitabubble?Astheypointout,...themerefactofrapidpriceincreasesis
notinitselfconclusiveevidenceofabubble(p.300).Theythinkofabubbleasasituationinwhich
excessivepublicexpectationsoffuturepriceincreasescausepricestobetemporarilyelevated(p.299).

How do we determine if expectations of large future price increases can account for price increases
today?CaseandShillerexaminetwokindsofevidencetosuggestthatfundamentalscannotaccount
for the price increases. They first examine U.S. state data on home prices and fundamentals, such as
income and employment, over 1985 to 2002, seventyone quarters. Secondly, they directly elicit the
viewsofhomebuyersbasedonasurveyconductedin2003ofpeoplewhoboughthomesin2002infour
metropolitanareas:LosAngeles,SanFrancisco,Boston,andMilwaukee.Thesurveyreplicatesa1988
survey of the same metropolitan areas. For both analyses, Case and Schiller find evidence broadly
consistentwithabubble.Whilethereisclearlymoreresearchtobedoneonbubbles,keepinmindthat
thispaperwaspublishedin2003.Fromthevantagepointofhindsight,afterthefinancialcrisisandthe
verysignificantdeclineinhouseprices,theCaseShillerevidenceisindeedveryprovocative.

House price runups prior to crises are common. This is shown by Reinhart and Rogoff (2008). Their
researchshowsthatthereareimportantsimilaritiesacrosscrises.Theystudyeighteenbankcentered
11

financial crises from the postWar period, including a subset which they call The Five Big Crises of
Spain (1977), Norway (1987), Finland (1991), Sweden (1991), and Japan (1992) (starting year in
parenthesis). The Big Five crises occurred in developed economies, and were prolonged events with
largedeclinesineconomicperformanceoverextendedperiods.

Althoughtheyexamineanumberofdifferentseries,wefocusontherunupinhousingprices.Figure3
shows the relationship between real housing prices and banking crises. Date t is the first year of the
financialcrisis,andt1,t2,andsoon,tot4indicatesthepreviousfouryears,andt+1etc.arethepost
crisis years. The figure confirms that there was a runup in housing prices in the U.S. that, in fact,
exceededtherunuppriortotheBigFive.

It is not only house prices, Reinhart and Rogoff further show striking similarities with respect to real
rates of growth in equity price indices, current account balancetoGDP ratios, real GDP growth per
capita,andpublicdebtgrowthandcrises.Itishardtoescapetheconclusionthatthefinancialcrisisof
20072009wasnotspecial,butfollowsapatternofbuildupsoffragilitythatistypical.

5.ThePanics

Thissectiondiscussespapersrelatingtothetwomainpanicperiodsofthefinancialcrisis:August2007
andSeptemberOctober2008.Wediscussthreepapersthateachfocusonadifferentcomponentofthe
shorttermdebtmarket.Covitz,Liang,andSuarez(2011)analyzerunsontheassetbackedcommercial
papermarketthatbeganinAugust2007,whichrepresentedthefirstmajoreventofthefinancialcrisis.
McCabe (2010) analyzes money market mutual funds (MMFs) and contrasts their behavior in August
2007(whenMMFslargelyavoidedruns)andinSeptember2008(whentheydidexperienceruns).An
important link between these two crises worked through the repo market, which weakened
considerably in August 2007, limped along for a year, and then partially collapsed after the failure of
Lehman.GortonandMetrick(2012)analyzethesedynamicsandtiethemtothechangesinunsecured
interbanklendingmarkets.

Commercial paper (CP) has been an important security for the financing of industrial firms for many
decades.InthetraditionalCPmarket,highlyratedfirmscanquicklyissuedebtwithminimaltransactions
costs, and typically cover the risk that investors will suddenly disappear by obtaining a backup line of
credit from a commercial bank. Demand for CP is high enough that financial intermediaries have
increasingly made use of the market to finance longterm financial assets, in which case the debt is
known as assetbacked commercial paper, or just ABCP. When CP is used this way, financial
12

institutions can bundle mortgages, creditcard receivables, and other loans into offbalancesheet
vehicles. Like the related structure of securitization, such vehicles can be more transparent than full
bankbalancesheets,whichcanthenenablelowerfundingcosts.Morecynically,suchvehiclescanbe
used to move assets off balance sheets in name only, allowing banks to save on regulatory capital.
Whateverthereason,byJuly2007therewasapproximately$1.2trillionofABCPoutstanding.Withthe
majorityofthispaperheldbyMMFs,theABCPmarketwasdeeplyconnectedwithmorefamiliarpartsof
thefinancialsystem(Covitz,Liang,andSuarez,2011).

Covitz, Liang, and Suarez describe the unraveling of this market in great detail, drawing the analogy
betweenarunonanABCPprogramandatraditionalbankrun.Conceptually,anABCPprogramwould
suffer a run if lenders equivalent to depositors in a bank are unwilling to refinance CP when it
comesdue.Mechanically,theauthorsdefinearunasoccurringinanyweekwhereaprogramdoesnot
issueanynewpaperdespitehavingatleasttenpercentofitsCPmaturing.Ifaprogramisunableto
issuenewpaper,thenitmusteitherrelyonbackupsupportfromtheprogramsponsor(typicallyabank
orgroupofbanks),oritisforcedtosellassets.

Figure4,reproducedfromtheirpaper,showsthepatternofrunsatABCPprogramsduring2007.Here,
thepanicinAugust2007isclear.BeginningintheweekofAugust7,thefrequencyofrunsincreased
dramatically,andthelikelihoodofexitingarunwithlaterissuancefellintandem.Bytheendof2007,
about40percentofprogramswereinarunandunabletofinancethemselvesintheirtraditionalshort
termmarkets.

A nice feature of the ABCP data is that it allows for a crosssectional analysis on the determinants of
runs. Such analysis is rarely possible for bank runs, since the historical record does not allow for the
same detail as is present in this modern data. This crosssectional analysis yields a set of interesting
findings,makingthispaperauniquecontributiontotheliteratureofbankruns,aboveandbeyondits
import for the study of the recent crisis. This analysis shows that programs were more likely to
experience a run if they had high credit risk (from holdings of subprimerelated securities) or high
liquidityrisk(fromamissingorincompleteliquiditysupportfromtheplansponsor).But,importantly,in
thefirstfewweeksofAugust,therewasalsoahighlevelofrunactivityunrelatedtoprogramspecific
measures. Taken together, the evidence indicates that vulnerability to runs is strongly related to
fundamentals, but it takes some time for investors to figure things out. Even in this market, with
relativelysophisticatedinvestors,thefirstfewweekscouldfairlybecharacterizedasapanic.
13

Overall,theABCPmarketfellby$350billioninthesecondhalfof2007.Mostprogramsreliedonbackup
support from their sponsors to cover this shortfall, with a significant impact on the balance sheets of
thosesponsors.Someprogramsmadeuseofcontractualoptionstoextendthematurityoftheirpaper,
effectively reducing the returns for their lenders as compared to market rates. To understand the
contagion of the financial crisis, it is necessary to trace these impacts through the system. McCabe
(2010)isthenextlinkinthischain,withafocusonMMFs,amajorholderofABCPandothersecurities
directlyrelatedtothenowtroubledhousingsector.

WehaveearliermentionedthekeyroleplayedbytheReservePrimaryFund,alargeMMFthatbroke
thebuckafterthefailureofLehmaninSeptember2008.LesswellknownarethestrugglesofMMFsin
theAugust2007panic.AsthemainholdersofABCP,MMFssawthevaluesoftheirstakesdeclinewhen
ABCPyieldsroseforoutstandingpaper.Furthermore,shrinkingABCPprogramswereforcedtoselltheir
underlyingassets,placingfurtherdownwardpressureonassetclassesheldbymanyMMFs.Asaresult
ofthesedynamics,atleast43MMFsrequiredassistancefromtheirsponsorsinordertoavoidbreaking
thebuck.Essentially,thesefundswerebailedoutbythebanksorfundfamiliesthatmanagedthem.
McCabeanalysesthedriversofthesebailoutsandfindthattheyweresignificantlymorelikelytooccur
whenthefundsheldABCPandwhentheyhadpreviouslyearnedaboveaverageyieldsontheirportfolio.
Whilesuchsponsorassistancehadoccurredinearlierstressperiods,thescaleofinterventionin2007
wasunprecedented.

ThesponsorbasedrescueofMMFsin2007preventedanyrunsbyinvestorsonthosefundsthatyear,
butmayhavealsosolidifiedtheexpectationthatMMFswouldalwaysbebailedoutbytheirsponsors.
SuchexpectationsaddtothebeliefthatMMFsaresupersafemoneylikeinstrumentsthatrequireno
duediligencebyinvestors.Inthatenvironment,investorscanchasethehighestyieldingfundswithout
anyperceivedrisk.Figure5,takenfromMcCabe(2010),illustratesthisdynamic.

Panel A of the figure shows the growth of MMFs from 1998 to 2010. Funds are broken into three
categoriesTaxexempt,governmentonly,andprimewherethelastcategoryistheleastrestrictive
oninvestmentsandalsobyfarthelargest.ThetotalassetsofMMFswereover$2trillionbeforethe
ABCPcrisis,afterwhichassetsactuallyrosesignificantlyforbothprimeandgovernmentonlyfunds.The
flighttosafety in August 2007 benefitted both types of funds, as investors sought a safe haven from
riskier asset classes. By September 2008, MMF assets had increased more than 50 percent since the
ABCPpanic.
14

TheLehmanbankruptcywasamajorshocktoMMFs.ThedropfromparityoftheReservePrimaryFund
ledtoarunonsimilarfunds,withFigure5showingthesharpoutflowfromprimeMMFs,withanalmost
oneforonetransferintogovernmentonlyfunds.Thistransfercausedsignificantdisruptioninfunding
markets. Prime MMFs are a crucial supplier of funds to corporations and to financial intermediaries.
When these investors moved to governmentonly MMFs, this liquidity supply was lost from private
creditmarkets.

PanelsBandCofFigure5showhowReservePrimaryFund,traditionallyaconservativefund,beganto
takeonmoreandmoreriskintheyearsbeforethecrisis.Priorto2001,thenetyieldtoinvestorsfrom
thefundwasalwaysbelowaverageforprimefunds.(McCabefindsnoevidencethatyieldisrelatedto
investmentskillinthesefunds;increasesinyieldseemdrivenentirelybyincreasesinrisk.)Beginningin
2001,however,relativeyieldsbegantocreepupwards,andthenincreasedsharplyin2007and2008.
For MMFs, an increase in yields attracts new investors, and these new investors tend to be of the
returnchasingtypethatarewillingtorapidlyleaveifperformanceslips.ThefigureshowsthatReserve
Primarysassetsandrelativemarketshareroseintandemwithitsnetyields.

As a holder of Lehman commercial paper, Reserve Primary was unable to maintain its value after the
Lehman bankruptcy. McCabes analysis shows that the subsequent runs on MMFs happened
disproportionately at funds that, like Reserve Primary, had high relative yields, had recently attracted
newperformancesensitiveinvestors,andhadriskierfinancialinstitutions(asmeasuredbyCDSspreads)
assponsors.TherunsonlystoppedaftergovernmentactiontoexplicitlyguaranteeMMFs.

ThepapersbyMcCabeandbyCovitz,LiangandSuarezarecomprehensiveanalysesofthebreakdowns
intwomajorcomponentsofshorttermdebtmarkets,andthelinkingofABCPandMMFshelpstoshow
howcontagioninthesemarketscanspread.Butthereisstillamissingpiece,becausetheinitialABCP
panic was driven by a weakness in subprime mortgages, whereas the eventual run on MMFs was
triggered by the bankruptcy of Lehman. Indeed, the MMF market showed that it was capable of
absorbingtheABCPlossesalbeitatsignificantcost.Sohowdidthereallossesinmortgageseventually
leadtothemuchmoresignificantfailureofLehmanBrothersandnearcollapseofthewholefinancial
system? We argue in Gorton and Metrick (2012) that the repo markets played a key role in this
contagion.

As discussed earlier, repo is the shadowbanking equivalent of a deposit market. Large institutional
moneypools,whosecashholdingsfarexceedinsureddepositlimits,canlendshorttermtoafinancial
15

institutionandreceivecollateralasprotection.Forevery$100ofcollateral,aninstitutioncanreceive
$(100x)inloans,with$xrepresentingthehaircutand1/xtheallowableleverage.Preciseestimates
forthetotalsizeoftherepomarketarenotavailable,andimpreciseestimatescandifferbyalot,but
theorderofmagnitudeisalwaysinthetrillionsofdollars.ThemainpieceofevidenceinGortonand
Metrickistherisinghaircutindexonvarioustypesofrepocollateral,asillustratedinFigure6.

Atthebeginningof2007,averagehaircutswerenearzeroonmosttypesofcollateral,allowingforvery
high leverage for holdings of these securities. Haircuts get their first shock at the time of the ABCP
panic,andcontinueasteadyrisethroughoutthenextyear.Foreverytrilliondollarsintherepomarket
for these nongovernment assets, each one percent increase in haircuts is equivalent to a $10 billion
withdrawalofliquidityfromthesystem,soa25percentrisefromJuly2007totheeveoftheLehman
failure represents a large drain. Following the Lehman failure, the index rose by an additional 20
percentagepoints,including100percenthaircuts(=notradeatall)forsomeassets.

It is important to note that haircuts rose and prices fell for many assets that had no direct
connectiontosubprimesecurities.Thisisthekeystepthancanallowcontagionfromoneassetclassto
thebroadermarketthatincludesmanyothertypesof(seeminglyunrelated)shorttermdebt.Themain
regressions in Gorton and Metrick (2012) show that the value of nonsubprime assets moved closely
with measures of distress in interbank funding markets, and not with an index of default risk on
subprimesecurities.

Howdidthedeclineinsubprimesecuritiesarelativelysmallcornerofthefinancialsectoreventually
leadtothenearcollapseofglobalfinancialinstitutionsmanytimesthesize?Thepapersdiscussedin
thissectiontraceoneimportantvectorofthiscontagion.First,thesubprimefailurehadadirecteffect
onmanyABCPprograms,withrunsthatbeganinAugust2007eventuallyaffecting40percentofthat
$1.2 trillion market. These runs and related price drops in other subprimerelated securities caused
unprecedented problems for MMFs, where at least 43 funds required support from their sponsors.
AftertheinitialpanicofAugust2007,interbankmarketswereslowtorecover,withspreadsbetween
securedand unsecuredfundingremainingathighlevelsthroughoutthe next year.Thispressurealso
manifested itself in repo markets, where haircuts grew steadily throughout the year, adding to the
fundingpressureonfinancialintermediaries.WhenthispressurefinallyclaimedLehmanBrothersasa
victim,thestressedinterbankmarketsnearlycollapsed,andonlyrecoveredaftersignificantgovernment
intervention.Thisinterventionisdiscussedinthenextsection.
16

6.PolicyResponses

BeginninginAugust2007,governmentsofalladvancednationstookavarietyofactionstomitigatethe
financialcrisis.Giventhechaoticenvironmentandthewidevarietyofinterventions,itisunlikelywewill
everhaveacompleteevaluationofthesepolicies.Giventhattheeconomicsprofessionisstilldebating
theefficacyofactionsduringtheGreatDepression,itwouldbeatallordertohopeforclarityonour
recentcrisis.Soourgoalhereisonlytoprovideanoverviewofthetypesofpolicyactionsundertaken,
alongwithabriefreviewoftheevidenceontheshorttermimpactofthesepolicies.Inadditiontothe
broadoverviewprovided here,thetimelineofthe crisisshowninTable1includessomeofthemajor
policyactionstakenintheUnitedStates.

IMF(2009)analyzestheeffectivenessofpolicyresponsesin13developedeconomies.Theydividethe
crisisintothreeperiods:Period1(PreLehman),fromJune1,2007toSeptember15,2008;Period2
(GlobalCrisis1),fromSeptember15,2008toDecember31,2008;Period3(GlobalCrisis2),from
January1,2009toJune30,2009.Ineachofthesethreeperiods,theyemployeventstudymethodology
to measure the impact of five different kinds of policy actions, each of which was widely used across
manycountriesinthesample.Table2,reproducedfromtheIMFreport,summarizesandclassifiesthese
actions.

Withthisclassificationasaguide,theyidentify153separatepolicyactionsacrosstheir13countries.In
theUnitedStatesalone,theyidentify49actions,coveringalmosteverysubtypefromTable2ineachof
thethreecrisisperiods.TherearemanyfuturePhDdissertationstobewrittenontheseinterventions,
andtheworktodatecanonlyscratchthesurface.Ouronlyhopeatthispointistogetsomeguidance
aboutshorttermefficacy,andeventherewewillneedtoconfineourselvestoanarrowsetofoutcome
measures.TheIMFreportisanexcellentstartonthiswork,usingeventstudiestoevaluatetheshort
run impact of each type of policy (listed in Table 2), with results tabulated separately for each crisis
subperiod.

To evaluate the efficacy of interest rate cuts, the IMF looked at the shortterm reaction of both an
economicstressindex(ESI)andafinancialstressindex(FSI).TheESIisacompositeofconfidence
measures(businessandconsumer),creditspreads,andstockpricesofnonfinancialcompanies.TheFSI
isacompositeofseveralmeasuresofbankcredit,spreads,andstockprices.Centralbanksinallregions
cutinterestratesinallthreecrisisperiods,buttheIMFfindsnoevidenceofshortrunimpactofinterest
17

ratecutsontheESI,andonlylimitedevidenceofapositiveeffectontheFSI.Ofcourse,eventstudies
willnotidentifyanyeffectsifthesechangesareanticipatedamajorlimitationwhenevaluatingcentral
bank actions. The story is better for liquidity support the second category in Table 2 where such
actions often had a significant positive effect on interbank spreads and on the broader FSI measure
duringthefirst(preLehman)period.Inlaterperiods,announcementsofliquiditysupportdidnothave
reliableeffects,eitherbecausesuchannouncementswereanticipatedorbecauseconcernsweremore
aboutsolvencythanliquidity.

To measure the shortterm impacts of other financial sector policies recapitalizations, liquidity
guarantees,andassetpurchasestheIMFlookstoboththeFSIandtoanindexofcreditdefaultswaps
ondomesticbanksintherelevantcountry.Ofthesetypesofinterventions,recapitalizationsarefound
tobeparticularlyeffective,withsignificantimprovementsinanindexofbankCDSspreadsinalmostall
countries during the second and third crisis periods. (There were few recapitalizations in the first
period.)TheseresultsarenotasstrongwhenthebroaderFSIisusedastheoutcomemeasure,which
may be because the benefits of recapitalizations fall mostly to bondholders. Asset purchases and
liabilityguaranteesalsoshowweakerresults,withtheexceptionofnotablesuccessesintheU.K.sasset
protectionscheme(announcedJanuary2009)andintheSwissgovernmentspurchaseofUBSassets.

Overall,theevidencesuggeststhatliquiditysupportintheformsdescribedinTable2waseffective
atcalminginterbankcreditmarketsintheearlystagesofthecrisis,butnotafterthefallofLehman.In
theselaterstages,capitalinjectionswerethemosteffectivepolicy.

7.RealEffectsoftheFinancialCrisis

The run on shortterm debt created fear across the financial intermediary sector, especially after the
failureofLehmanBrothers.Thewidespreadlossofconfidence,concernsaboutsolvencyandliquidityof
counterparties,reachedtherealsectoroftheeconomywhenintermediariesbegantohoardcashand
stop lending. The real effects of the financial crisis were global in nature. In this section we review
three papers that document these phenomena. These papers are Bank Lending during the Financial
Crisisof2008,byIvashinaandScharfstein(2010);GlobalRetailLendingintheAftermathoftheU.S.
FinancialCrisis:DistinguishingbetweenSupplyandDemandEffects,byPuri,RochollandSteffen(2012);
andTheRealEffectsofFinancialConstraints:EvidencefromaFinancialCrisis,byCampello,Graham,
andHarvey(2010.
18

Ivashina and Scharfstein study the supply of credit during the crisis in order to understand the real
effectsofthepaniconthecorporatesector.Theylookatsyndicatedloans,amarketwhichhasevolved
over the last thirty years to become the main portal for large corporations to get loans. The market
includes banks, but also a wide range of entities other than regulated commercial banks, such as
investmentbanks,institutionalinvestors,hedgefunds,mutualfunds,insurancecompaniesandpension
funds.Theirfirstfindingisthatsyndicatedlendingstartedtofallinmid2007,withthefallaccelerating
duringthebankingpanicthatbeganinSeptember2008.Lendingvolumeinthefourthquarterof2008
(2008:Q4)was47%lowerthanitwasinthepriorquarterand79%lowerthanatthepeakofthecredit
boom (2007:Q2). Lending fell across all types of loans: investment grade and noninvestment grade;
termloansandcreditlines;andthoseusedforcorporaterestructuringaswellasthoseusedforgeneral
corporatepurposesandworkingcapital(p.320).

Syndicated lending fell, but commercial and industrial loans reported by the U.S. regulated banking
sectorrosebyabout$100billionfromSeptembertomidOctober2008.But,IvashinaandScharfstein
showthatthisincreasewasnotduetoanincreaseinnewloans.Insteadit wascorporateborrowers
drawingdownexistingcreditlines,thatis,creditlinesthathadbeennegotiatedpriortothecrisis.

Toshowtheeffectsofthecrisistheauthorsfirstshowthatbanksthatweremorevulnerabletoarun,
thosethatweretoagreaterextentfinancedbyshorttermdebtotherthaninsureddeposits,cuttheir
syndicatedlendingbymore.Theyfindthat:Abankwiththemediandepositstoassetsratioreduced
itsmonthlynumberofloanoriginationsby36%intheperiodAugustandDecemberof2008,relativeto
theprioryear.However,abankwithadepositstoassetsratioonestandarddeviationabovethemean
reduced its loan by 49%, while a bank with deposits ratio one standard deviation above the mean
reduceditsloanoriginationslendingbyonly21%(p.320).

It is harder to demonstrate the effects of creditline drawdowns on syndicated lending because there
are no data measuring creditline drawdowns. The authors consider the possibility that banks in
syndicatedcreditlineswhereLehmanBrotherswaspartofthesyndicatemightexperiencelargercredit
linedrawdownsafterthefailureofLehman.Theideaisthatcommitmentsthatwouldotherwisehave
beenmetbytheothermembersofthesyndicatewouldbemorelikelytobedrawnon.They,infact,
find that banks that cosyndicated a large fraction of their credit lines with Lehman reduced their
lendingmore(p.320).
19

Animportantissueforthesefindingshastodowiththefactthatinarecessionthedemandforcredit
falls.Toaccountfortheabovefindings,thefallindemandmustalsoexplainwhythemorevulnerable
banksreducedthelendingmorethantheotherbanks.But,astheauthorspointout,thismaybethe
case.Theypointtotheexampleofinvestmentbanks,whichhavenodemanddepositfunding,lending
moreforcorporateacquisitions.Sincecorporateacquisitionsdeclinedintherecession,perhapsthisfall
indemandaccountsfortheresults,ratherthanthesupplyofloans.Theauthorsfind,however,thatthe
results continue to hold for commercial banks and for loans that are not used for acquisitions. Their
main conclusion then is that the decline in lending was in large part an effect of reduced bank loan
supply.

TheissueofthesupplyofcreditisalsothefocusofPuri,RochollandSteffen(2012)whoexaminethe
effectsoftheU.S.financialcrisisonlendingtoretailcustomersinGermany.Theyarealsointerestedin
whethertherearedetectablereductionsinthesupplyofcreditbybanks,evenwhenoveralldemandis
going down. The setting they study is German savings banks, which operate in defined geographical
areasandaremandatedbylawtoserveonlytheirlocalcustomers.Ineachgeographicalareathereisa
regional bank, a Landesbank, owned by the savings banks in that area. These German Landesbanken
(theregionalbanks,eachinaprovince)hadexposurestoU.S.subprimemortgagestovaryingdegrees.

TheauthorsexploitthefactthattheLandesbankensuffertodifferentextentsduetotheirexposuresto
U.S. subprime mortgages. Importantly, the savings banks had to guarantee or make equity injections
into some of the stricken Landesbanken. The authors make use of this natural experiment in which
some savings banks faced a shock because their Landesbanken had to be assisted. The authors
empirical strategy is to look at whether savings banks that are affected at the onset of the crisis
(becausetheirLandesbankenneededhelp)reducetheirlendingbymorethanthe(relatively)unaffected
savingsbanks.Thedataareespeciallyrich,includingtheuniverseofallloanapplicationsandthecredit
scores,andinformationaboutwhichapplicationsweregrantedandwhichwereturneddown.

There was an overall decrease in demand for consumer loans, as measured by applications to both
affectedandunaffectedsavingsbanks.But,withrespecttothesupplyofcredit,theaveragerejection
rateofaffectedsavingsbanksissignificantlyhigherthanofnonaffectedsavingsbanks(p.34).The
effectisstrongerformortgages,ascomparedtoconsumerloans.Ifaborrowerhadapriorrelationship
with the savings bank, the effect is mitigated, that is, those customers are less likely to have their
applications rejected compared to new customers. Overall, their evidence is consistent with that of
IvashinaandScharfstein:banksreducedthesupplyofcredit.
20

Whateffectdidareducedbankloansupplyhaveontherealeconomy,ontheactivitiesofnonfinancial
firms?ThisbringsustothestudyofCampello,GrahamandHarvey(2010).Toanswerthisquestionof
effectsonnonfinancialfirms,theseauthorsdirectlyask1,050chieffinancialofficersin39countriesin
NorthAmerica,EuropeandAsiainDecember2008whethertheywerefinanciallyconstrainedduringthe
crisis.Theirsurveyasksaboutthecostandavailabilityofcredit,andabouttheeffectsontheirdecisions
and actions, as well as many other questions. The survey asks whether a firms operations are not
affected, somewhat affected, or very affected by the turmoil in the credit markets. Firms that
described themselves as somewhat affected or very affected were then further probed with
questionsconcerningthenatureoftheeffects,e.g.,highercostsofexternalfunds,limitationsoncredit.
For U.S. firms, 244 indicated that they were unaffected by credit constraints, 210 indicated that they
were somewhat affected, and 115 said they were very affected (In Europe, the numbers respectively
were92,71,and26;andinAsia,thenumberswere147,112,and24).

Figure7,fromCampello,GrahamandHarvey(2010),givesasenseoftheeffectsofcreditconstraints.
Thefigureshowsaveragesforeachtypeofactionfortheconstrainedfirmsandtheunconstrainedfirms
(constrained is only very affected, while unconstrained is the other two categories). While all
firms cut back on expenditure and dividend payments and see their cash holdings and the number of
employeesdecline,theconstrainedfirmscontractthesepoliciesmuchmore,inaverynoticeable(and
statisticallysignificantway).Forexample,unconstrainedfirmsreducethenumberoftheiremployees
by2.7percentonaverage,whileconstrainedfirmsreducethenumberoftheiremployeesbyalmost11
percent.

What are the constraints that firms face? Eightyone percent of the very affected firms reported that
theyexperiencedlessaccesstocredit;twentypercentciteproblemswithlinesofcredit.Inotherwords,
it seems that the reductions in credit that Ivashina and Scharfstein reported in their study of banks
resultintheconstraintsstudiedbyCampello,GrahamandHarvey.

Thecategorizationoffirmsintoconstrainedandunconstrainedmayconfoundanumberoffactors.
Theauthorsaddressthisproblemeconometricallybymatchingconstrainedfirmswithanunconstrained
matchbasedonsize,ownershipform,creditrating,profitability,andsoon,sothatthereisasample
of firms that only differs on the degree of access to credit. Tests based on this approach show the
differential effect of financial constraints on corporate policies. Firms that are constrained show
importantdifferencesevenbeforethecrisis,andincreaseverynoticeablyduringthepeakofthecrisis.
21

The authors also delve into firms liquidity management and investment decisions. For example, the
IvashinaandScharfsteinresultthattherewasarunonthebanks,byfirmsdrawingdownontheircredit
linesjustincase,isconfirmed.Thirteenpercentoftheconstrainedfirmssaidthattheywoulddraw
downontheircreditlinesnowtohavecashinthefutures.And17percentdrewdowntheircreditlines
asaprecaution,comparedtosixpercentoftheunconstrainedfirms.Withrespecttoinvestmentduring
the crisis, 86 percent of constrained U.S. firms reported that they bypassed attractive investments,
comparedto44percentofunconstrainedfirms.

Overall,theevidencesuggeststhatbankscutbackoncreditsupply,althoughthedemandforcreditalso
fell.Theresultingreductionincreditsupplyhadsignificantimpactsoncreditconstrainedfirms.

8.Conclusion

The financial crisis of 20072009 was perhaps the most important economic event since the Great
Depression.Allprofessionaleconomistsneedaworkingknowledgeofthekeydetailsofthiscrisis.This
papersummarizesthesedetailsusing16papers,reports,andotherdocuments.Fromthesedocuments,
anarrativeemergesthatisverysimilartohistoricalcrises,whilecloakedininstitutionaldetailnovelto
thiscentury.

Onestrongsimilaritytohistorycomesintheaccelerationofsystemwideleveragejustbeforethecrisis,
thestrongestpredictorofcrisesinthepasttwocenturies.Furthermore,therecentcrisiswaspreceded
byrapidincreasesinhousingprices,alsoafeatureofallmajorcrisessinceWorldWarII.Atthismacro
level,thepattern(butnotthescale)ofourcrisisisveryordinary.

The crisis was exacerbated by panics in the banking system, where various types of shortterm debt
suddenlybecamesubjecttoruns.This,also,wasatypicalpartofhistoricalcrises.Thenoveltyherewas
in the location of runs, which took place mostly in the newly evolving shadow banking system,
including moneymarket mutual funds, commercial paper, securitized bonds, and repurchase
agreements. This new source of systemic vulnerability came as a surprise to policymakers and
economists, and some knowledge of its details is necessary for understanding the contagion that
eventuallyspreadtotherealeconomy.


22

References

BankforInternationalSettlements(BIS)(2009),79thAnnualReport(April1,2008March31,2009);
Seehttp://www.bis.org/publ/arpdf/ar2009e2.pdf.

Bernanke, Ben (2005), The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit, The Sandridge
Lecture,April14,2005;
seehttp://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2005/200503102/.

Bernanke, Ben (2010), Causes of the Recent Financial and Economic Crisis, Statement by Ben S.
Bernanke, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Financial
CrisisInquiryCommission,WashingtonD.C.(September2,2010);
seehttp://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20100902a.htm

Campello, Murillo, John R. Graham, and Campbell Harvey (2010), The Real Effects of Financial
Constraints:EvidencefromaFinancialCrisis,JournalofFinancialEconomics97,470487.

Case,KarlandRobertShiller(2003),IsThereaBubbleintheHousingMarket?,BrookingsPaperson
EconomicActivity2,299362.

Covitz,Daniel,NellieLiang,andGustavoSuarez(2011),TheEvolutionofaFinancialCrisis:Panicinthe
AssetBackedCommercialPaperMarket,FederalReserveBoard,FinanceandDiscussionSeries
#200936;seehttp://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2009/200936/200936pap.pdf.

Gorton, Gary and Andrew Metrick (2012), Securitized Banking and the Run on Repo, Journal of
FinancialEconomics,forthcoming.

InternationalMonetaryFund(2009),NavigatingtheFinancialChallengesAhead(October2009),Chapter
III;seehttp://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2009/02/index.htm.

InternationalMonetaryFund(2010),GlobalFinancialStabilityReport:Sovereigns,Funding,andSystemic
Liquidity(October2010);seehttp://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2010/02/index.htm.

Ivashina, Victoria and David Scharfstein (2010), Bank Lending during the Financial Crisis of 2008,
JournalofFinancialEconomics97,319338.
23

McCabe,Patrick(2010),TheCrossSectionofMoneyMarketFundRisksandFinancialCrises,Federal
Reserve Board, Finance and Economics Discussion Series #201051; see
http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2010/201051/201051pap.pdf.

Pozsar, Zoltan (2011), Institutional Cash Pools and the Triffin Dilemma of the U.S. Banking System,
InternationalMonetaryFund,workingpaper#WP/11/190;
seehttp://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=25155.

Puri,Manju,JrgRochollandSaschaSteffen(2012);GlobalRetailLendingintheAftermathoftheU.S.
Financial Crisis: Distinguishing between Supply and Demand Effects, Journal of Financial
Economics,forthcoming.

Reinhart,CarmenandKennethRogoff(2008),Isthe2007U.S.SubprimeFinancialCrisisSoDifferent?
AnInternationalComparison,AmericanEconomicReview98,339344.

Reinhart,CarmenandKennethRogoff(2011),FromFinancialCrashtoDebtCrisis,AmericanEconomic
Review101,16761706.

Schularick, Moritz and Alan M. Taylor (2012), Credit Booms Gone Bust: Monetary Policy, Leverage
CyclesandFinancialCrises,18702008,AmericanEconomicReview,forthcoming.


24

Table1:FinancialCrisisMajorEventsTimeline

2007
Jan.July SubprimemortgageunderwritersOwnit MortgageSolutionsandNewCenturyFinancialCorp.
file for bankruptcy. Massive downgrades of mortgagebacked securities by rating agencies.
Kreditanstalt fr Wiederaufbau (KfW), a German governmentowned development bank,
supportsGermanbankIKB.
August Problemsinmortgageandcreditmarketsspilloverintointerbankmarkets;haircutsonrepo
collateralrise;assetbackedcommercialpaper(ABCP)issuershavetroublerollingovertheir
outstandingpaper;largeinvestmentfundsinFrancefreezeredemptions.
August17 RunonU.S.subprimeoriginatorCountrywide.
September9 RunonU.K.bankNorthernRock
December15 Citibank announces it will take its seven structured investment vehicles onto its balance
sheet,$49billion.
December NationalBureauofEconomicResearchsubsequentlydeclaresDecembertobethebusiness
cyclepeak.
2008
March11 Federal Reserve announces creation of the Term Securities Lending Facility to promote
liquidity.
March16 JPMorgan Chase agrees to buy Bear Stearns, with Federal Reserve Assistance, and Federal
ReserveannouncescreationofthePrimaryDealerCreditFacility.
June4 MonolineinsurersMBIAandAMBACaredowngradedbyMoodysandS&P.
July15 U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission issues an order banning naked shortselling of
financialstocks.
September7 FederalgovernmenttakesoverFannieMaeandFreddieMac.
September15 LehmanBrothersfilesforbankruptcy.
September16 TheReservePrimaryFund,amoneymarketfund, breaksthebuck,causingarunonMMFs.
FederalReservelends$85billiontoAIGtoavoidbankruptcy.
September19 U.S.TreasuryannouncestemporaryguaranteeofMMFs,andFederalReserveannouncesthe
AssetBackedCommercialPaperMoneyMarketMutualFundsLiquidityFacility..
September25 Washington Mutual, the largest savings and loan in the U.S. with $300 billion in assets, is
seizedbytheauthorities.
October FinancialcrisisspreadstoEurope.
October3 U.S.CongressapprovestheTroubledAssetReliefProgram(TARP),authorizingexpenditures
of$700billion.
October8 CentralbanksinUS,England,China,Canada,Sweden,Switzerland,andtheEuropeanCentral
Bankcutinterestratesinacoordinatedefforttoaidworldeconomy.
October13 MajorcentralbanksannouncedunlimitedprovisionofliquiditytoU.S.dollarfunds;European
governmentsannouncesystemwidebankrecapitalizationplans.
October14 U.S.Treasuryinvests$250billioninninemajorbanks.
2009
May ResultsoftheSupervisoryCapitalAssessmentProgram(stresstests)announced.
June NationalBureauofEconomicResearchsubsequentlydeclaresJunetobethebusinesscycle
trough.
October Unemploymentratepeaksat10.0percent.

25

Table2:ClassificationofEvents

CentralBankMonetaryPolicyandLiquiditySupport

Interestratechange
Reductionofinterestrates

Liquiditysupport
ReserveRequirements,longerfundingterms,moreauctionsand/orhighercreditlines

GovernmentFinancialSectorStabilizationMeasures

Recapitalization
Capitalinjection(commonstock/preferredequity)
Capitalinjection(subordinateddebt)

Liabilityguarantees1
Enhancementofdepositorprotection
Debtguarantee(allliabilities)
Debtguarantee(newliabilities)
Governmentlendingtoanindividualinstitution

Assetpurchases2
Assetpurchases(individualassets,bankbybank)
Assetpurchases(individualbadbank)
Provisionsofliquidityincontextofbadassetpurchases/removal
Onbalancesheetringfencingwithtoxicassetskeptinthebank
Offbalancesheetringfencingwithtoxicassetsmovedtoabadbank
Assetguarantees

Source:Table3.1,IMF(2009)
1
IncludestheFederalReservesliquiditysupporttoAIGfortoxicassetremovaltoaspecialpurposevehicle,coupledwith
governmentslosssharing.

2
Includesbusinessloanguaranteesaspartoffinancialsectorstabilizationmeasures(e.g.theUnitedKingdom,Germany);for
somecountries,assetpurchaseswerenotconductedbythegovernment,but(also)bythecentralbank(oracentralbank
sponsored)agentsuchastheUnitedStatesandSwitzerland.
26

Figure 1: Money and Credit Aggregates Relative to GDP


(14-country averages by year)

2
Bank loans/GDP
Bank assets/GDP
Broad money/GDP

1.5

0.5

0
1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Source:SchularickandTaylor(2012).


27

Figure2:U.S.PrivateLabelTermSecuritizationIssuancebyType
(InbillionsofU.S.dollars)
2500
CDO2

2000 CDO
RMBS

1500 ABS

1000

500

0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 20092010Q1
Sources:IMF(2010).

28

Figure3:RealHousingPricesandBankingCrises
135

130

125 US, 2003=100

120

115
Index

110 Average for banking crises in

105

100 Average for the "Big


Index t-4=100
5" Crises
95
t4 t3 t2 t1 T t+1 t+2 t+3

Source:ReinhartandRogoff(2008).


29

Figure4:RunsonAssetBackedCommercialPaperPrograms

60
Weekly

Fraction of ABCP programs


50 experiencing runs

40
Percent

30

20

10
17-
31-
14-
28-
14-
28-
11-
25-

23-

20-

18-

15-
29-
12-
26-
10-
24-

21-

19-
9-

6-

1-

7-

5-
0
3-Jan-07

4-Jul-07

Thesolidlineplotsthepercentofprogramsexperiencingarun.Wedefinethataprogramexperiencesa
runinweekswhenitdoesnotissuepaperbuthasatleast10%ofpapermaturingorwhentheprogram
continuestonotissueafterexperiencingaruninthepreviousweek(seeequation(1)inthetext).The
dotted line plots the unconditional probability of not experiencing a run in a given week after having
experienced a run in the previous week (i.e., the hazard rate of leaving the run state). The figure is
basedonweeklydatafromDTCConpaperoutstanding,maturities,andissuancefor339ABCPprograms
in2007.

Source:Covitz,Liang,andSuarez(2011).


30

Figure5:MoneyMarketFunds(McCabe(2010))


31

Figure6:AverageHaircuts(onnineassetclasses;equallyweighted)

50%
45%
40%
35%
Percentage

30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%

Source:GortonandMetrick(2012).
32

Figure7:PlansofConstrainedvs.UnconstrainedFirms

10

0
0.6
2.7 2.7 2.9
4.5
10
%Change

9.1 9
10.9
15 14.2
20
22

30

32.4
40
ConstrainedUnconstrained

Techexpenditures Capitalexpenditures
Marketingexpenditures Numberofemployees
Cashholdings Dividendpayments

Source:Campello,GrahamandHarvey(2010).

You might also like