You are on page 1of 21

The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at

www.emeraldinsight.com/1751-1062.htm

IJWBR
22,1
From co-operation to competition:
market transformation among
elite Napa Valley wine producers
6 Ian M. Taplin
Department of Sociology, Wake Forest University, Winston-Salem,
North Carolina, USA
Abstract
Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to argue that cooperative behavior by key actors is often
crucial for collective organizational learning to occur and new markets to become established. Such
cooperation is gradually replaced by competition as network interactions become formalized
following the codification of knowledge and the growth of a collective identity.
Design/methodology/approach – Using detailed ethnographic studies from a broad sample, this
paper uses key informants who played a role in creating and sustaining a viable market for a high
status good.
Findings – The sharing of tacit knowledge complements technical skills for key industry actors and
facilitates collective organizational learning in ways that expedite the emergence of a high status
sector. Once knowledge is codified as the sector gains legitimacy, there is less need for informal
structured interactions as vital conduits of knowledge sharing.
Originality/value – This paper shows how knowledge sharing via cooperative relationship
underlies competitive market formation and provides firms with requisite quality enhancements
necessary for status attainment.
Keywords United States of America, Viticulture, Wines, Marketing strategy, Organizational change
Paper type Research paper

In this paper I use the example of ultra-luxury wines to examine how knowledge sharing
between incumbents and newcomers was crucial in the formation of a market place for
high status goods in a specific region. I argue that firms, through their winemakers,
collaborated to forge a collective identity that led to operational upgrading and
subsequent improved consistency and quality in their products. As such improvements
were affirmed by official ratings groups, the region acquired high status attributes that
in turn attracted new entrants. The cooperative relationships that were crucial to
organizational learning in the early phase, and embedded in networks, became gradually
recast in more competitive terms as firms now search to differentiate themselves from
others. Given the codification of knowledge that has occurred with industry maturity, it
is now less likely that reciprocal exchange relationships are necessary for new firms to
attain performance capability; instead details are disseminated through educational
programs and institutional bodies that are public goods.
I argue that the growth of a collective identity among specialist organizations has
become more structured so that organizational sub-populations co-exist in what is now
a more formally circumscribed marketplace. Differentiation of sub-populations occur
not because actors are on the periphery of a market dominated by generalists as
International Journal of Wine ecological models of resource participation argue (Carroll, 1985; Swaminathan, 2001).
Business Research Instead, they compete in separate niches where varying levels of resource availability
Vol. 22 No. 1, 2010
pp. 6-26 shape market positioning and performance. Opportunities for resource rich specialists
# Emerald Group Publishing Limited
1751-1062
have encouraged new entrants but it has not necessarily led to high mortality rates for
DOI 10.1108/17511061011035170 incumbents as organizational ecology scholars might predict (see, for example,
Delacroix et al., 1989). But it does explain the growth of niche resources that enable From
newcomers to be less dependent upon informal knowledge networks.
My focus is on Napa Valley which in the last three decades has attained an
co-operation to
indisputable recognition for quality (Kramer, 2004; Taber, 2005; Wall Street Journal, competition
November 3, 2006). By concentrating upon a fairly small geographic region where
brand recognition and generalized high status permit premium prices, I analyze how
this luxury market[1] has emerged. By identifying the circumstances under which
economic transactions are embedded in networks, internal labor markets, trust, and/or
7
institutions, one can assess the salience of such features in incipient market growth
when product quality is difficult to measure or to predict in advance. Specifically, I look
at the cooperative knowledge sharing role played by key actors who were often owner/
winemakers and whose network activities occurred within a quasi-competitive
framework and an emerging institutional structure that sustained production norms. I
also show how the status signaling mechanisms that provided gradual legitimacy for
the industry in its infancy (when quality was either unknown or questionable) are now
used by newcomers as a benchmark for their own aspirations.
If we are to understand how markets develop and operate, including the evolution of
specialist organizations therein, we need to determine how they are structured and
what role is played by key individuals whose knowledge and expertise can aid firms
that are attempting to establish a market presence in such a sector. It is precisely the
network or relations between key actors that provide resources for firms in the
aggregate (Burt, 1983) and permit some form of structuring that results in overall
governance becoming institutionalized (Podolny, 1993; Campbell et al., 1991).
Meanwhile information exchange by key actors can act as conduits for organizational
learning and efficient market transactions (Granovetter, 1985; Uzzi, 1997). Ties among
such actors are crucial for this exchange to occur (Powell, 1990), as is an element of
trust and a willingness to exchange information that might seem to undermine the
competitive advantage of a particular firm.
As markets mature, key actors within firms establish performance parameters by
relying upon information derived from similar placed actors in competitor firms. I
hypothesize that such knowledge (rather than merely information) sharing is crucial to
the performance of individual firms but also promotes enhanced quality in outputs of
the market as a whole. In other words, embedded relationships structure knowledge
transfer in ways that enhance overall efficiency and sustain market growth.
Opportunistic behavior is less prescient here than informal and formal channels of
communication that are distinctly cooperative in nature. In a luxury goods market
where quality and status (or brand) are at a premium, gaining access to core
operational competencies is essential for firms, but so is their success contingent upon
the market as a whole continuously upgrading its performance indicators. In such a
symbiotic relationship, firms establish reputations by market association but markets
depend upon individual firms to continuously demonstrate their individual capabilities
according to external evaluations.
As brand identity increases, however, the industry inevitably attracts newcomers
who often possess resources that enable them to purchase requisite inputs (best land,
best viticulturalist, and best winemaker) and focus upon attaining high quality as
measured by industry rating groups. This presumes that incumbants are willing to sell
(and realize a profit on their initial investment) and/or that additional land for
viticulture becomes available in the area (transformations within the existing
agricultural sector). An increasingly fluid labor market for winemakers (greater firm
IJWBR density, more formal training programs that increase the supply of winemakers) result
in firms bringing in outside specialists or poaching winemakers from incumbent firms.
22,1 Therefore, I further hypothesis that the accessibility of community experience and
codified knowledge as the market has matured renders high-quality goals attainable
without necessary recourse to established networks, hence diluting the cooperative
endeavors that sustained the industry in its ascendancy.
8 Research methodology
Semi-structured interviews with winery owners, general managers, and wine makers
at 40 Napa Valley wineries were conducted between 2005 and 2007. Each winery in this
sample produces at least one wine classified in the luxury category; some produced
several wines in this category, others one high priced and several lower priced wines
(although all fall under the general rubric of ultra-premium). I focused almost
exclusively on wineries that produced a Cabernet Sauvignon or a Bordeaux blend since
these are the signature grapes for this region and ones which are largely responsible
for its reputation. It is typically the varietal wine that a person entering the market in
Napa Valley will make (possibly alongside Chardonnay). Wineries were selected from a
list derived from specialist publications, principally Wine Spectator and The Wine
Advocate, as these are the principal ratings sources that score individual wines on
quality and are accepted as industry benchmarks. Frequent rankings and listings of
Napa Valley Cabernet Sauvignons and Bordeaux blends are published and I focused
upon wineries which produced wines that obtained scores of at least 90 points from
one of the two publications in the past ten years. I used a ten-year period to
include established wineries as well as new entrants to the market. From an initial list
of 51 wineries, 28 of the interviews resulted from ‘‘blind’’ calling; the remaining 12
followed the use of two informed insiders who contacted a resource person at a
designated winery and then provided me with an introduction. This proved an
expeditious way of securing interviews with wineries who otherwise (as several
subsequently commented) would not have agreed to a meeting.
I further classified wineries according to size based upon the number of cases of
wine produced annually. Small wineries are those producing less than 15,000 cases;
small to medium (15-75,000 cases), and medium (over 100,000 cases annually). All of
the wineries in the sample were privately owned. Also, I endeavored to get a balance of
established wineries (founded at least 20 years ago) as well as newcomers (entered the
market in the last five to ten years) in order to discern how differences between
industry founders and newcomers might be apparent. My assumption was that smaller
wineries were more likely to be recent start ups, were better capitalized, and more
intent upon exploiting the reputational effects by establishing a high price, limited
production wine. They were also more likely to hire an established winemaker to gain
instant credibility.
Interviews lasted between 1 and 3 h and typically involved a tour of the winery and
in some cases the vineyards. In four instances repeat visits were made. When
interviewing the owner, I was able to gain specific information about the winery’s
financial operations as well motivations behind the firm’s start-up, initial capitalization
costs, revenue streams (including when profitability was attained, if at all), vision, and
strategic goals. With general managers much of the same information was provided
but less personal background was available. In my interviews with wine makers
I asked specific questions about information sharing, relationship building, and inter-
firm mobility since these were crucial to understanding market stability. From prior
research in this area I realized that cooperation had become normative in the early From
phase of the industry’s growth; in my interviews I wanted to pursue this line of enquiry co-operation to
further and systematically determine the mechanism for such cooperation and asked
specifically about this when questioning winemakers. In nine cases the owner was also competition
the winemaker, hence I was able to gain a further nuanced perspective from this joint
position. Table I provides a summary of the sample.
The questions were grouped into the following basic categories: history of winery
and personnel; production decisions and operational questions; interactions, both
9
formal and informal with others in the industry; marketing and brand building;

Firm size: cases Number of


produced Date of founding Person interviewed interview hours

Medium 100,000 1974 President and CEO 5 (on 2 visits)


Medium 180,000 1972 President and COO 2
Medium 100,000 1972 General manager 2
Medium 20,000 1994 President 2
Medium 30,000 1992 Wine maker 3
Medium 40,000 1973 Estate manager 3
Medium 60,000 1981 Controller 1
Medium 30,000 1982 President 2
Medium 30,000 1998 President/owner 2
Medium 25,000 1978 CEO 2
Medium 75,000 1981 General manager 9 (on 4 visits)
Medium 35,000 1978 President/owner 7 (on 4 visits)
Medium 45,000 1979 General manager 2
Medium 63,000 1969 President/ CEO 1
Small 2,500 1997 Manager 1
Small 10,000 1995 Winemaker 1
Small 20,000 1991 General manager/winemaker 2
Small 1,300 1998 Owner 2
Small 2,000 1992 Owner/winemaker 2
Small 2,400 1987 Owner/winemaker 1
Small 2,500 1989 Owner/winemaker 3
Small 2,500 1996 Owner/winemaker 3
Small 10,000 1986 General manager 1
Small 12,500 1995 General manager 2
Small 8,500 1994 Owner/winemaker 1
Small 9,000 1996 Vice-President/winemaker 6 (2 visits)
Small 1,200 1996 Owner/winemaker 2
Small 4,200-6,200 1982 President 1
Small 10,000 1992 Winemaker 2
Small 3,000 1994 Manager 1
Small 2,000 1992 Owner/winemaker 1
Small 2,500 2003 Owner/winemaker 2
Small 7,500 1986 Sales director 2
Small 7,000 1985 Sales and operations manager 1
Small 10,000 2000 Owner 3
Small 3,700 1984 Director 2 Table I.
Small 5,500 2002 Co-owner 1 Summary of interviews
Small 4,400 1999 Owner/winemaker 2 and organizational
Small 4,000 1988 General manager 2 characteristics of firms
Small 4,500 1999 Manager 1 in the sample
IJWBR regulatory problems; competitive pressures; and supply chain issues. I was also able to
ask about reputation building and the problems associated with that, plus solicit
22,1 general comments about industry evolution, cooperation and competition within the
Valley, and perceived problems about stability within the industry. I encouraged
individuals to share their thoughts on what made the industry successful, what sorts of
threats were emerging and how they thought the industry would be changing. A full
list of the open ended questions is provided in the Appendix.
10 This detailed ethnographic approach permits one not only to determine answers to
specific question sets but also to provide an opportunity for respondents to add their
own stories. For example, wine makers were encouraged to talk about the pressures
they experienced in producing certain types of wines; general managers how they
determined the intent of owners who in many cases were absent from the property and
balance that with operational exigencies; and finally what owners saw as the
limitations of their endeavors. It also provided rich and detailed information on how
information is exchanged through personal contacts, both formally among owners and
informally among winemakers, and general managers. In the latter cases, personal
relationships with fellow winemakers clearly shaped business activities in ways
resonant of Granovetter’s (1985) notion of embeddedness, yet they complemented the
more arms-length relationships that existed between owners. I did ask winemakers
who had earlier worked for wineries that had been sold about their experiences in such
firms in order to gain a sense of how prior circumstances might have led to success or
in their case firm failure. As with any organizational population it is difficult to gain
detailed information on firm failures other than second hand. Mortality rates among
Napa wineries in the period under discussion, however, did not appear to be extensive
and it is only in recent times that a pattern of sales to corporate entities who
subsequently consolidate operations has emerged. While understanding firm failures
can be an important dimension, I nonetheless felt that information derived from
winemakers (their narratives and experiences) would provide sufficient details to
support the analysis of network activities in the early phase of market formation.

Napa Valley: background


Both the context and the structure which governs knowledge transmission are
important components of the effectiveness of organizational learning within individual
firms. In the case of Napa valley one has a local market within a broader regional
market of California as a whole which continues to be the primary producer of wine in
the USA. With 391 brick and mortar wineries (and 704 grape growers), Napa valley
produces 4 percent of California’s wine by volume but accounts for 27 percent of the
sales value of the state’s wine (MKF Research, 2005). A combination of favorable terroir
and climate, sophisticated viticulture techniques, adequate supplies of skilled
managerial, and technical labor, a supportive institutional structure, plus individuals
with sufficient capital resources to fund new initiatives (see Siler, 2007) all combine to
ensure that premium prices for wines and grapes continue and the region’s status
reinforced.
Although American Viticulture Areas (AVA classifications are not a guarantee of
product quality they are nonetheless an important source of identity for wineries since
they both formalize and differentiate relationships between firms (Benjamin and
Podolny, 1999; Zhao, 2005). In the case of Napa valley, the first AVA in California, there
has been a further subdivision into 14 smaller appellations although the official
delimitation of ‘‘Napa Valley’’ appears on the bottle’s label. Wineries draw general
reputational status from the broader collective identity (Napa Valley) but highlight From
unique aspects of site specificity by referring to their sub-viticultural area (Spring co-operation to
Mountain, Oakville, Rutherford, etc.). Since some of the top quality wines come from
very specific vineyard designations, price premiums and reputational effects have competition
inevitably followed. The subsequent status ordering between different appellations
emphasizes the consumer’s perception of respective quality and permits price
premiums to be assigned to wines affiliated with the prestigious regions. As Benjamin 11
and Podolny (1999) and Podolny (2005) argue, maintenance of high status affiliations
signifies product quality and therefore higher prices for their wine. This allows such
wineries to move away from being an undifferentiated commodity where price
competition is paramount.
Unlike luxury French wines where a long track record of high quality denotes high
status, Napa valley producers have had to manufacture such status. They have done
this, especially in the last decade, by producing a high-quality product in very limited
quantities and at a high retail price. The resulting product, often sold on allocation to a
select group of customers, creates the perception of scarcity while the high price
suggests quality. The success of this strategy has acted as a stimulus for new market
entrants with the requisite resource capabilities who seek external validation of their
desired quality by district affiliation. Because high status affiliation wineries are likely
to produce high-quality wines (Benjamin and Podolny, 1999), such expectations on the
part of the winery and the resources they bring to the venture further legitimizes the
status hierarchy.

Structure and governance


The spatial proximity of firms within a strongly demarcated area, and the ensuing
formal and informal interactions that structure inter-firm relationships, point to the
existence of a cluster. The neo-Marshallian notion of clusters or industrial districts is
important here because it refers to ways in which relationships between firms are
shaped by institutional activities, de facto governance by dominant firms and an
operational logic that emerges from consensual behavior by individual firms. Norms of
reciprocity consolidate individual relationships and legitimize specific organizational
forms, thus further sustaining the carrying capacity of the niche. This evolving
population of organizations produces valuable knowledge resources which when
eventually systematized and codified, create a modified organizational structure less
overtly dependent upon informal cooperation. Similar clusters have evolved in other
wine regions (Chile and New Zealand for example) but the distinctiveness of Napa is its
quickly attained high status identity that was a product of effective network
governance in the early development phase.
It has been argued that informal contacts within clusters provide an easy conduit
for information and tacit knowledge transfer (Lazerson and Lorenzoni, 1999; Breschi
and Lissoni, 2001). Tacit knowledge refers to specific skill sets possessed by key
individuals within cluster firms which when aggregated becomes community
knowledge. Information on the other hand can be more widely available and accessible
to a broader audience, is less complex and more generalized. Knowledge transfer is
structured informally, based upon trust and social capital (Inkpen and Tsang, 2005).
Informal relations between individuals provide an impetus for reciprocity-based
collective learning since shared knowledge is indispensable for the maintenance of
reputation and status.
IJWBR I hypothesize that close relationships existed (embedded ties) among winemakers
whose sense of cohesion as a professional group was predicated upon interaction in
22,1 which often proprietary information was knowingly divulged, and mutual obligations
and expectations existed in what amounts to communities of practice. The resulting
network was dense (many links between individuals) and decentralized (no one
member exerts a centrifugal pull). Winemakers shared their wines with other
winemakers as a form of benchmarking and non-codifiable knowledge-seeking
12 behavior. This enabled them to learn about site-specific issues and gain access to non-
technical details. By promoting long term, shared interests over short-term gains, such
action further stimulated organizational learning in the network setting (see Visser and
deLangen, 2006). This form of collective learning depends upon synergies among
individuals rather than firms as others have argued (Staber, 2001). I further
hypothesize that firms that failed – or have not been able to consistently produce high
scoring wines which amounts to de facto failure – had winemakers who were less
active participants in such informal networks[2].
As populations of organizations evolve and the market legitimized, operational
knowledge becomes available without recourse to informal networks. Instead it is
accessible to actors with more or other resources. By eroding the rationale for informal
networks of knowledge sharing, does this necessarily replace co-operation with
competition? However, collective organizational learning can minimize tendencies
toward information hoarding and high status winemakers might be as likely to share
operational details with newcomers as they were with their counterparts even if they
are not dependent upon networks for their own information sources.
Typically firms in a cluster operate within a set of rules that constrain them to
cooperate to address competitive problems. Cluster governance involves a mix of
coordination mechanisms, the efficacy of which is determined by the degree of trust, the
role of leader firms, intermediaries, and how successful efforts are at minimizing free
rider problems (deLangen, 2004). Because regional identity is crucial for reputational
status, firms must adhere to common practices and conform to guidelines that are in
many instances self-imposed although in some cases shaped by leader firms that are
able to take the initiative on a particular issue. Trust refers to a sense of common
identity and shared norms among key firms and individuals and the recognition that
collective action can diminish opportunistic behavior. While institutional bodies provide
regulatory parameters that govern basic operating procedures, industry-specific
organizations (intermediaries) emerge to promote products and protect identity.

Identity protection and constraints


Cluster governance in wineries has been institutionalized in two ways: directly through
trade organizations and indirectly through ratings agencies. Nationally, the Wine
Institute’s (2007) role is to be an advocate for the industry, inform public policy and be a
general resource for members. At a local level the Napa Valley Vintners (NVV)
represents the shared interests of 310 member wineries and protects the integrity of the
Napa Valley appellation. In 1975 the Napa Valley Grapegrowers was organized to
represent over 500 grapegrowers in the valley and help promote best practices in
agriculture, preserve the heritage, and strengthen the industry’s economic viability, as
well as be a link with NVV members. Finally, a quasi-formal Napa Valley Wine Tech
group was formed in the 1970s so that winemakers and winery owners could share
information. They met regularly, sampled each other’s wines, and discussed ways of
addressing problems that were part of an industry struggling in its infancy. The
respondents in my sample who were part of this group at its inception argued that it From
was one of the most important ways of learning non-technical aspects of winemaking
and viticulture and crucial for the valley’s subsequent rise in status. To varying
co-operation to
degrees, membership of these organizations endowed a certain affiliational legitimacy competition
and sustained and formalized a network of individuals in firms.
While winemakers shared knowledge with each other within the cluster and
benchmarked their wines against each other through shared tastings, it is important to
note the role played by agencies that evaluate wine quality using a scoring system. The 13
two widely accepted leaders in this category are Wine Spectator and Robert Parker’s
The Wine Advocate. It is generally acknowledged that a high score (90þ points on a
scale of a 100) awarded to a wine by one of these signifies to the consumer that the
wine is of the highest quality (and therefore status) and is a guarantee of increased
sales and enhanced reputation for the winery (and winemaker)[3]. Within the industry,
it is recognized that such ratings reflect a certain style of wine (big, high alcohol, fruit
forward, and immediately accessible rather than ageworthy)[4]. Such tangible features,
which are certainly compatible with growing conditions in Napa Valley, therefore
provide a useful template for winemakers there. Given such stylistic parameters, not
surprisingly winemakers (and winery owners) attempted, and continue, to make their
wines accordingly. This can both lead to a convergence of style but also a product that
more consistently reflects the preferences of such taste arbiters. Such agencies
reinforced product stylistic constraints that confer status but also provided firms within
this cluster with the requisite guidelines for production. This effectively established
norms, structures tacit knowledge, and helped consolidate regional identity around a
particular style of wine.

Status, identity formation, and the structure of knowledge sharing


Winemakers are key actors in shaping the identity of a winery and through their skills
contribute to the status and reputation of the winery. As they move beyond formal
learning (institutionally provided and focusing upon techniques and the chemistry of
winemaking) and the informal apprenticeships at wineries, there are two mechanisms
whereby systematic knowledge transmission actually occurs within the cluster:
informal exchanges and shared opinions on product characteristics and occupational
mobility by winemakers between wineries within the district.
As in any occupational specialty where incumbents have site-specific knowledge,
wine makers rely upon localized tacit operational details that are gleaned from others
in the geographical area where they work in addition to their professional training.
Since grape growing and the resulting attributes of wine vary from region to region
(the concept of terroir perhaps best expresses these idiosyncratic aspects) learning
what others are doing is crucial for newcomers, as is the sharing of routine techniques
that are discussed between established winemakers.
Every winemaker in my sample indicated how crucial such knowledge sharing was
for them. One (10,000 case winery) said that quality is increasingly vineyard driven
with an emphasis upon how vines are farmed, the land, viticulture techniques, etc.
Gaining access to this knowledge by talking with fellow winemakers is vital and was
expected. It was presumed that you share problem-solving details; that you solicit
advice on certain technical aspects, and actively discuss site-specific attributes. As
another (30,000 case winery) commented:
There’s a lot of cooperation among winemakers. That’s what’s expected and you’d be foolish
not to do it. You help your neighbor in times of trouble, you share information, you visit other
IJWBR wineries, you go tasting. All of this helps you discern quality so that you can benefit and
make your own wine better. So in this sense, this constantly tasting other peoples’ wines
22,1 means you can strive to make your wine better, and if everybody is doing that everybody is
making wines better.
He added that such cooperation was both structured (through quasi-formal meetings
and organized tastings) and informal (show up at another winery and bring a bottle
14 and solicit comments from the wine makers and his/her staff there) but the essence was
to learn – both what to do and what not to do. Could it be that people merely brought
their best wines to communal tasting, I asked in my interviews? Respondents said
probably no since there was ‘‘a lot of bad wine we tasted in the early days.’’
An owner/winemaker (2,400 case winery) said that she believes her own success in
building the reputation of her brand over the years was predicated upon the input of
others who were frank and sometimes brutally honest about the quality of her early
wines. Her goal was to make a high-quality wine and she knew the techniques (learned
at UC Davis) but not necessarily the site-specific problems, information on which could
best come from others. As she said, ‘‘you can learn by doing but it takes a long time to
properly evaluate the product (from vineyard management techniques in the growing
stages, to harvesting, and then aging in barrels before bottling can be up seven or eight
years) so if you’re not doing it properly along the way you don’t find out until it’s too
late. It wasn’t so much basic mistakes but the more subtle things that can be easily
overlooked. I probed, questioned, solicited from other winemakers.’’
Another owner/winemaker of a very small (2,000 case) winery said that she found it
crucial to establish links with the winemaking community and to routinize such
activities.
It has to be fairly systematic and I find that my knowledge grows, not always in simple
increments but in lots of subtle ways that cannot be really taught. I really believe that the
success of wines in the valley [Napa] is based upon ways in which we keep trying to make
better wines, a sort of one-upmanship. We talk about what we do, then strive to make a great
wine so that’s it better than so and so’s, but once we’ve done that, we’re happy to talk about
how we did it, why we did it, etc. It’s very competitive but in a friendly sort of way because we
figure that our own reputations can be built but not in isolation. We need to cooperate but by
doing this we’re constantly pushing the quality up and hence seeking a small competitive edge.
Almost 80 percent of the winemakers in my sample of wineries had worked for at least
four other Napa Valley wineries, and another 15 percent for at least two during the past
15 years[5]. Winemakers make a reputation slowly, by working their way apprentice-
like as cellar assistants, assistant winemakers, and then finally as winemakers. Such
inter-firm labor force mobility is unique because knowledge transcends individual
firms but remains within the district. Also hiring is often done by word of mouth rather
than in a formal labor market which further emphasizes the importance of the network.
The enduring nature of relationships between actors fosters ties that enhance
efficiency as well as permit some diversity. Such ties are of strategic significance for
firms that implicitly encourage them (Gulati, 2000), but the knowledge sharing (resource
dynamism) becomes more dense, tacit, and informal the more restrictive de facto group
membership is. It is not just the quantity of interactions that sustains the network
(Podolny and Page, 1998), but the quality that incumbents bring to the network. This is
more than the social capital that Inkpen and Tsang (2005) correctly identify as crucial
components in contextualizing network resiliency. It is also the status gradations that
occur on the basis of past individual successes that shape the dynamics of information
exchange. Individual wine makers possess different but complementary resources. The From
problem of asymmetrical information is overcome and the knowledge base deepened
precisely because individuals bring specialized knowledge that qualitatively and
co-operation to
incrementally add to the resource pool (Maskell, 2001). competition
The actors within such a network have strong and mutual ties because their
collective identity was predicated upon the success of the district’s wine while their
individual reputation was aided by the production and diffusion of detailed knowledge.
As one (owner/winemaker, 4,400 case winery) said, ‘‘most of the time we know what
15
we’re good at and are willing to talk about it in the hope that someone else will tell us
something that’s puzzled us.’’ Another (owner/winemaker, 2,500 case winery)
commented that it was a like a barter situation, ‘‘with everyone bringing something to
the table to exchange; not formal but we recognized that this was what going on. I
basically understand what they’re doing with vineyard management, etc.; it’s what
goes on after harvest that intrigues me. This comes out at tastings and if it’s good they
want to talk about it.’’ With more and more wineries able to produce a high-quality
wine on a regular basis, it suggests performance outcomes indicative of effective
knowledge transfer within the district. But it also belies the heuristic of measurable
performance outcomes following the widespread use of ratings.
While critics argue that more and more of the high scoring wines have the same
taste profile – a criticism that is also leveled at the mass produced wines that are
easily manipulated to ensure consistency that suits consumer taste (Colman, 2008) –
site-specific characteristics are encouraged by winemakers to differentiate their wine.
The nuances are often subtle and derive from location attributes as well as stylistic
features. However they nonetheless fall under the general rubric of critic friendly
styles. Better understanding of wine chemistry and the science of yeasts and
fermentation, plus the growth of specialist consulting firms and individuals in these
areas, allows winemakers to tailor-make their product (Goode, 2005). Now winemakers
have both the skills sets and the operational parameters to make certain styles of wines
and an institutional framework that facilitates production efficiency. Utilizing such
resources they can reinforce their own reputation and if they so desire, move to another
winery where their mandate is probably to replicate their earlier success. Since every
winery in my sample indicated that ratings are very important (‘‘they can make or
break you, especially if you’re a new entrant’’), winemakers who can rise to the
challenge gain instant credibility and legitimize the reputation of the winery at which
they work.
Such parameters (both externally derived and internally encouraged) imposed
production guidelines, the understanding of which on a day-to-day basis came from
learned techniques and tacit knowledge shared within the winemaking cluster. The ties
of reciprocity that bind individuals within this cluster foster collaboration by
encouraging the collective benefits of competition. Subsequent operational norms
maintained market stability since even newcomers strive to adhere to them because of
the reputational implications. This helps eliminate much of the instability that often
occurs within markets between incumbents and new entrants, even as status
hierarchies within the market are changing as newcomers attain legitimacy.
From the winemaker comments, I was unable to detect any significant differences
until recent years in relational network activities between winemakers at cult wineries,
those with consistently high scoring wines, and those whose scores were in the 80-90
range other than those one might normally attribute to personality issues. I was told on
repeated occasions that while a few cult winemakers could be ‘‘prickly,’’ ‘‘arrogant,’’
IJWBR ‘‘conceited,’’ or ‘‘condescending,’’ most were approachable and eager to discuss their
wines. As one owner/winemaker (2,500 case winery) said, ‘‘we’re passionate about our
22,1 wines and what we do. I won’t say that egos aren’t out there – they are. But for the most
part we’re a community and we learn from each other.’’ And another (president/owner,
35,000 case winery) commented:
I think that folks realize that even if they’re top of the heap this year, another harvest could
16 see them fall. It’s a fickle agricultural product; there are no guarantees. I don’t have to like the
person to deal with him [her] or nonetheless respect them for what they’ve done. You’ve got to
have a certain amount of humility to survive around here even though there are a lot of egos
clashing at formal settings.
The existence of a less systematic hierarchy and differentiated pattern of knowledge
might be a function of labor market mobility. Movement between wineries by
winemakers might dilute some of the expected restrictions on knowledge sharing since
it diminishes some of the exclusivity that status differentials might impose. Whether
interpersonal relationships have developed from informal settings, solidifying network
configurations despite hierarchies of knowledge and ability is certainly plausible.
Aggregating these relationships provides a social capital dimension to understanding
how network ties are structured and network stability maintained (Adler and Kwon,
2002; Inkpen and Tsang, 2005), but it also suggests how trust-based knowledge
sharing can occur within the wider context of skepticism. As one winemaker/owner
(2,500 case winery, with a long history in the industry that includes vineyard manager
and winemaker to several major wineries in the area) said:
The innovators in this industry have been the small folks such as myself, with flair and
creativity that keeps the industry and quality improving. It might sound conceited but having
worked with Mondavi and other big ones I realize that we’re the ones that take the big risks,
not them. But to do this I’ve got to know what’s going on, who’s growing the best grapes, who
does the best custom crush. I know exactly what it costs to grow grapes and who’s good at
vineyard management. How do I know this? Because I maintain ties and work with folks,
talking through concerns. I do consulting for several wineries and that helps me keep abreast
of what others are doing.
From comments such as the above and other remarks that highlighted the annual
uncertainty around the final product (wine), it appears that optimal levels of
cooperation emerged because to do otherwise was fraught with risk. Gaining access to
the resources and capabilities that inhere in networks of specialists (local winemakers)
was important if one was to minimize learning curves and was crucial should
operational problems emerge and one needs a ‘‘favor.’’ It is such ties of reciprocity that
bound together otherwise disparate individuals and sustained norms of cooperation
that were crucial for market stability. Rather than growth of the wine cluster leading to
fragmentation, the sharing of industry-specific knowledge led to innovation and
improvements that actually consolidated the cluster’s initial advantages[6].
I was unable to discern any reliable association between network membership/
interaction (specifically lack thereof) and organizational mortality. All of the winemakers
whom I interviewed had been part of such networks and therefore adducing failure
through non-membership is spurious at best. Aside from possible selection bias (I was
unable to locate winemakers who had not been network members), it appears more
likely that some form of associational endeavor was commonplace. Three winemakers
specifically stated that not belonging to such informal groups would be impractical and
inconceivable since such interactions were a rite of passage for newcomers coming to
the area. Not all would necessarily gain the same benefits; hence individual capabilities From
might be the telling factor in explaining different organizational outcomes.
Respondents talked freely about cult wineries and ‘‘top gun’’ winemakers, noting
co-operation to
particularly the visibility that such individuals and organizations brought and continue to competition
bring to the industry and the struggle for those without such resources to compete.
Succinctly put, one owner (30,000 case winery) said of boutique wineries (100-1,000 cases):
that they are people with deep pockets looking for the cache of owning a Napa winery. They 17
don’t look to make money but acquire it for status, selling their wines to friends and visitors.
They charge a premium and are willing to pay a premium for land etc. They’re buying into
the industry but with their resources are able to maneuver themselves into a high visibility
situation.
Another (President/COO, 180,000 case winery) said:
The top winemakers have really established not just their own reputations but that of the
valley in general. They’ve put their mark on the product, producing big, bold cabs [Cabernet
Sauvignon] that Parker and Laube [Wine Spectator] like. Some are unpretentious and just do
their job, others clamor for recognition. Whatever the case, what they’re doing is spreading
around the valley. They’re the yardstick now and as long as you got some good blocks [areas
within vineyards of specific plantings] you try and do what they’re doing. Why not [. . .] it
generates buzz.
A general manager (75,000 case winery) commented:
Wine tastes better now because of improvements in production techniques. Winemakers can
also take much credit for this. There’s about half a dozen who are really good and they set the
standard for the opulent wines of limited quantity and very high price. But the reason they
are good is often great attention to detail across the whole spectrum of the operation [as well
as having the best grapes etc.] and this is something that others can learn to do and have
done. The real difference between the cult wines and other chateau style wineries [20-30,000
case production] is perception. Limited production, high price, sold on allocation – all of this
creates hype and seduces those who want the feel good effect of buying into luxury and a
scarce product. I believe there are many good wines being made because winemakers have
learned that with good grapes you can make good wines, and Napa has many good grapes.
The pricing is where the real differences emerge.
This status deference has complicated the market structure in recent years, creating
hierarchies that in some respects are artificial but are nonetheless resonant because of
the perceptions of quality that inform consumer behavior. Diversification within the
regional marketplace is increasing alongside complexity as individuals with deep
pockets and utility maximizing aims have entered the sector. While intra-
organizational struggles are inevitable (Fligstein, 2001) as a market matures, what is
occurring here is the gradual decline of cooperative behavior and a more nuanced
competitive edge to structured relationships. While this does not necessarily
destabilize the network (nor the market), if anything it strengthens it by affirming an
individual commitment to high quality. But it also limits the potential for core firms
seeking to coordinate and control networks because there is less collective recognition
of group norms of reciprocity. What ‘‘controls’’ come now in the form of reinvigorated
institutional supports and formal designed to protect the Napa brand.

Network competition
If informal networks were crucial in building market prestige given limited formal site-
specific operational knowledge, as such knowledge becomes codified and operational
IJWBR parameters more clearly defined and externally constrained, such networks
22,1 conceivably become less relevant. Given decreased incentives for cooperative
knowledge transfer and brokering, logically the population of organizations should
evolve into a more competitive structure as actors have the possibility (needs?) to
differentiate themselves as density increases. Relatedly, as firm density increases,
incumbents are more likely to differentiate themselves from each other and doing
18 introduce an element of competition that in the past was noticeably absent.
In evaluating such propositions, there are several dimensions to consider. First, it is
well accepted that the high status identity associated with the Napa brand came from a
collective improvement in production methods since the 1970s[7]. While such
improvements are individual winery-based, the majority in the AVA recognize that
their reputation adheres from their regional association and it is therefore incumbent
on them to ensure that their production methods are consistent with best practices that
maximize their efficiency. Second, striving to differentiate themselves from their
competitors by accentuating terroir, they nonetheless protect the integrity of their
Napa AVA since this is seen as the basis for their prestige (and high price)[8]. With
increased density, firms with more valuable resources (prime vineyard location, top
winemakers) leverage those resources in their pricing and are able to command high
status when receiving consistent high ratings. This results in a more differentiated
structure within the region, as ‘‘luxury’’ producers meet different market segments
from those less able to exploit scarcity/high-quality/high prices niches. But all retain an
affiliational identity with Napa Valley as this is the overarching imprimatur of quality.
Because of secular increases in the overall demand for higher end wines (consumers
trading up in their habits), producers do not see the market as a zero sum game.
Owners capitalize on any high scores that they have received and use that in their
marketing efforts; they work with distributors who play a crucial role in placing their
wines in appropriate markets. But unlike many competitive marketplaces where
producers emphasize their strengths and their competitors’ weaknesses, Napa
producers are more likely to highlight the somewhat unique characteristics of their
wine as a differentiating tool and/or rely upon high scores by experts to validate their
product. As one owner commented ‘‘my wines are good but so are many others here.
I work hard to market my wines but in doing so I’m also pushing the brand so in a way
every one benefits.’’ I asked him if he saw the several wineries that abut his property as
competitors. He responded that ‘‘in a way they are but they’re not trying to drive me out
of business. I help them sometimes with vineyard stuff and they help me. There are
some who I’m not particularly friendly with, some who are really secretive, some who
I’m amazed at what they are trying to do. Do I get on with them? Superficially yes, with
some; close friends with others, neighborly with the rest. At the end of the day we all
have to work hard to keep the product out there. We go to the same pourings, work
with the same distributors and restaurants, do the same charity events. The bottom
line is we’re selling a similar product that’s expensive.’’
What does appear to have changed, and this might merely be a function of
increased density, is that interaction is more likely to occur in formal settings where
information flow is more structured and less reciprocity-based. Trust remains because
winemakers and winery owners have encouraged institutional agencies to foster
collective norms and they have agreed to abide by them. But weak ties now are more
likely to characterize many of these interactions even thought the sense of belonging by
individuals is strong. While not necessarily arms length of the type found in
contractual market relationships, there is more differentiation among participants, with From
interactions more likely to be between winemakers of similar status and reputation.
A winemaker who now owns his own 2,500 case winery best summed up the
co-operation to
opinion of so many of my respondents on how relationships have changed in the Valley. competition
He said in a 2007 interview:
What we’ve got now is a much more complex and competitive landscape. In the past you’d
help others because that was the way to learn and most of us were novices when it came to the 19
different aspects of winemaking. Sure I had technical skills but it’s so different with the
practical skills that you needed. Our various winemaker groups really helped me learn and I
believe they were crucial and getting the industry on the firm footing. It’s a lot different now
because the newcomers bring so much money and there are so many [winemakers] with the
necessary skills out there. That means you don’t really need all those informal groups. We still
taste but it’s more to show off your wine than to say ‘‘hey [. . .] help me make this better.’’ We’re
still friendly and we talk a lot about the industry but there’s an edge now to conversations. I
think a lot of it is because the stakes are so much higher now and everyone’s expected to make
great wines. We’re Napa and that brand drives expectations so you’d better deliver. In the past
I’d say we cooperated to help everyone make a better wine that would be competitive; now
we’re competing to see who can make the best wine and get ahead of the pack.
Informal friendships inevitably exist and many owners claimed mentoring relationships
with more ‘‘old timers’’ in the Valley. But there’s also as one said ‘‘a healthy suspicion that
publicly some individuals could not be relied upon to be entirely accurate.’’ One GM said
that the annual pre Christmas parties and meetings are times when wineries can claim
that they have had the ‘‘best harvest ever,’’ the ‘‘best quality grapes ever’’ and lie about all
sorts of things! Nobody really believes this rhetoric but it is the annual ritual of make
believe. This is consistent with Johnson et al.’s (2002) argument about the role of
declarative knowledge or ‘‘know-what’’ which is predicated upon low levels of information
complexity. In this case it emanates from the desire to trumpet the virtues of an individual
winery and hence imply a competitive advantage for that producer. According to my
sample, new winery owners were more likely to ‘‘accentuate’’ or ‘‘distort’’ facts pertaining
to production and established vintners more guarded about their successes. As one owner
of a medium sized (35,000 cases) winery with a long track record of success said:
There’s a couple of people whom I trust and respect in the valley, who’ve been at this for
decades and who’ve taught me a lot. Others have come in and thrown money around and
bought success but not necessarily respect. The latter want instant credibility but it takes
time. They’re impatient but often don’t listen. They rely upon a few staff and possibly a high
paid consultant and think that they can ignore what goes on among the rest of us. Often they
succeed but it diminishes the trust that used to exist in the valley.
Another owner of a similar sized winery (30,000 cases) echoed these comments but
went on to add that:
the new money and corporate wineries have moved aside the old agriculturalists who were
pioneers back in the 1970s. A lot’s changed and while we still meet and talk, it seems more
formal now than in the past. I don’t necessarily think of them as my competitors but I do
recognize that they have resources that I cannot match so I have to be careful[9].
The owner of a small (1,300 cases) winery, whose family has owned land in the valley
for generations, was quite prescient in identifying the issues. She commented:
We make 1300 cases and we don’t have lots of dot com money to throw around so there’s no
way we can realistically compete with the cult or even corporate owned wineries. We can
make good wine and look for smaller distributors to sell it, rely upon a few restaurants to
IJWBR promote it, and the rest goes through our wine club. Really we don’t compete in the same
marketplace as the others yet we share a similar product. We go to the same meetings, sit on
22,1 the same boards, offer wines for charity events etc. Our winemaker gets around and he’s great
at trying new things he learned from others. I suppose my conversations with fellow owners
is at a different, more formal level. But we’re all part of the same industry and I suppose we
get along because we have to. There’s argument and dissent and even hostility to some of the
newcomers. They might not be bothered about being accepted into the community but they
20 desperately want to make a good wine [they hired a top winemaker to do this] and so in a way
they become part of the whole valley scene.
While this might sound like nostalgia for the old times and a reverence for the old
timers, it nonetheless captures the perception by established producers that a certain
formality now structures interactions and there is less transparency. There is certainly
resentment by old owners that they lack the resources to match the impact that new
owners have been able to bring for their product. But the sub-population of small
producers operate in a niche as specialists, competing on the periphery because of their
limited resources. Such a view of resource partitioning allows parallel markets of
specialists to co-exist, some with extensive resources (new entrants) and others
without, but without this necessarily affecting mortality rates in which that earlier
studies predicted (Delacroix et al., 1989; Swaminathan, 2001).
All of the respondents commented that relationships now are more formalized and
prescriptive and there is much more obsession with ratings and scores. New owners
have less need for informal community membership since it does not come with any
greater access to information nor is it often even possible given their absentee nature.
Their principal emphasis is to ensure that the collective identity of the Napa brand is
maintained since it is an indispensable part of their own aspirational/reputational
identity.

Conclusion
Research on clusters continues to emphasize the link between localized learning and
innovation (Maskell, 2001), building upon earlier work that identified the dynamism of
geographically proximate firms as drivers of growth (Porter, 1990). These complement
studies in organizational evolution that focus upon resource partitioning (Carroll, 1985;
Swaminathan, 2001). However, what is often lacking in such studies is the precise way
in which knowledge is transferred other than to suggest that firms are embedded in
networks, and how such actions can promote the successful growth of a cluster. This
study attempts to specify exactly what the mechanisms are which structure learning
and establish specialist organizations in what becomes a high status marketplace. It
then shows how eventual industry stability around high status production norms
means new entrants are less likely to need access to informal networks to attain such
effectiveness levels. Instead of claiming that increased density mitigates network
efficiency, I argue that the consolidation of operating principles renders network
membership less important for new entrants than in the past when the industry was
still climbing the quality ladder. Resource partitioning is both an enabling and a
differentiating concept whereby sub-populations of specialists co-exist in a market
niche despite having different resource bases.
Since the focus has been on luxury wineries, understanding how status is attained
and maintained is crucial. I have argued that the pursuit of a high status product, with
attendant price premiums, has encouraged and required key actors to negotiate dense
and tacit forms of knowledge sharing in a geographically specific network. While this
network is inevitably restrictive in terms of membership, the success of individual From
members is tied to the collective reputation of the region. Individual winemakers/
owners are a constituent part of this network, the parameters of which are sustained by
co-operation to
internally accepted group norms of knowledge sharing plus externally by formal competition
organizational affiliations of the wineries themselves. New entrant firms typically seek
out winemakers with established reputations and bring resources that permit them to
gain immediate entry into the high status marketplace. But the winemakers
themselves become part of the multifaceted sets of formal and informal relationships
21
within Napa Valley that structure interactions and shape behavioral conventions.
While no clear evidence of leader firms shaping overall regional governance was
found, it does appear likely that the most successful winemakers (those who garner the
highest scores) become effective benchmarks for others. Greater resource availability
therefore improves organizational survival and encourages new specialist foundings.
The growth of a collective identity has been crucial for such organizational survival as
well as facilitating differentiation within the market for specialist firms. This means
that high status producers are more likely to be able to reproduce that status, and
sufficiently well resourced new entrants gain such status, without disruption to the
marketplace. More resource scarce firms (generally small producers) nonetheless
survive in a separate niche, but continue to draw their legitimacy from membership of
the regional cluster (collective identity).
To conclude, there are three important findings that have been presented. First, I
show how the interaction between key individuals within a marketplace of firms was
the primary conduit for crucial knowledge sharing that was indispensable for the
attainment of requisite quality for the growth of this luxury product. This was
predicated upon principles of reciprocity and a cooperative framework that sustained
trust and respect among key actors. The practical learning that occurred within such
embedded networks (learning by doing) supplemented more formal training that
individuals acquired either through educational programs or ‘‘working one’s way up
the winery’’ (de facto apprenticeships). No matter what their background, the essence of
the hands-on experience that enabled winemakers to comprehend the complexity of
site-specific idiosyncrasies becomes part of the collective knowledge pool through such
interactions. The ties between winemakers were dense and structured largely, but not
solely, through informal contacts. These interactions promoted common approaches or
conventions and contributed to the upgrading of the sector over the past two decades.
Such networks of embedded interactions are responsible for the success of emerging
specialist organizations, the growing collective identity of which furthers resource
partitioning but in ways that do not necessarily lead to increased firm mortality.
Second, once the industry became unambiguously associated with the production of
high status products, the means whereby such excellence could be easily replicated with
sufficient resources increased. This allowed new resource rich entrants to ‘‘buy their way
into the market’’ and enabled them to function effectively without necessarily embracing
the cooperative network of relationships that had sustained the sector’s growth. This did
not destroy reciprocal exchange relationships within the sector. It did, however, render
their utility more superfluous. Given easier access to tacit knowledge that hitherto had
been more privileged, new entrants were less likely to invest time and energy into
relationship building which in turn eroded the collective benefits of networks.
Third, competition has supplanted cooperation as winery owners compete to attract
the top winemakers and differentiate their product according to site-specific
characteristics. This is not the cut throat competition one finds in less concentrated
IJWBR product markets but it is demonstrably different from the situation of several decades
22,1 ago when the market was in its infancy. The risks are lower now than before which
might explain current disincentives to embrace cooperation; similarly extant
knowledge is widely available and publicly disseminated. Nonetheless, new and old
owners strive to maintain market parameters, enforce district conventions, and abide
by institutional stipulated rules to create stability.
22 While this might sound like an elegy for old timers and the old ways of doing things,
it is nonetheless an accurate depiction of what happens when an industry emerges from a
small collection of specialists, builds a collective identity that becomes a resource in itself,
but then becomes a victim of its own success by attracting new entrants whose own
resource base permits a different form of network interaction. There are not necessarily
‘‘good guys and bad guys,’’ merely different actors with varying resource bases who
forge an evolving collective identity which encourages further sub-specializtion of
organizational populations albeit in a more structured competitive framer than before.
As with cluster evolution in other wine regions such as Chile, and in the USA,
Oregon and Washington State, such growth was often predicated on creating informal
structures that supported the knowledge through cooperative endeavors. This was
even more crucial given the complexity of knowledge required to consistently make a
high status product. Such sharing might seem inimical to normal competitive
marketplaces, but such sharing enabled new firms and established ones to attain and
reproduce requisite quality levels to support their desired high status goals. Market
maturity resulted in changes in such relationships precisely because the benefits of
such arrangements had diminished and boundaries are created that reinforce status
distinctions. Competition replaces cooperation but only when the market has matured
significantly to render the latter’s utility less crucial to stability.
Research on other industries with similar growth trajectories, tacit knowledge
parameters, and high status aspirations would be useful to see if such a pattern has
been replicated elsewhere. Similarly, it would be useful to see whether other wine
districts experienced a similar growth stage only to be thwarted by the lack of
institutional supports, the complete breakdown of consensual norms or high mortality
rates by firms lacking in resources to respond strategically to the challenge of
increased specialist density.

Notes
1. Wine classifications according to price typically assign the top segment as ultra
premium which includes wines priced over $14 a bottle (retail). However, in this study I
classify ultra-luxury wines as a sub-sector of this category and involve those whose
retail price is over $40 a bottle.
2. Actual mortality rates are difficult to determine. Here I use failure to secure high scores
as a proxy measure since this can seriously affect reputation and status and most
importantly sales of wine.
3. Such ratings enable people who feel insecure about wine to use a seemingly objective
measure of quality and therefore look to scores to inform their buying. Retailers and
restaurants typically emphasize high scores as a sales tactic, and wineries invoke them
in their own marketing. These agencies therefore legitimate tastes and also the high
price that is subsequently paid for the wine.
4. See Taplin (2006) and Colman (2008) for more detailed discussion on the role of ratings
and particularly the criticism leveled at Parker for his numerical scoring system and his
preference for powerful wines that inevitably stand out in blind tastings but are perhaps From
less food friendly than other wines.
co-operation to
5. Steve Heimoff’s (2008) recent book on his conversations with classic winemakers in
California provides interesting insights into how these individuals build reputations at competition
wineries then often move on.
6. See Enright (1998) for further discussion of how new forces energize clusters sometimes
replacing those that gave it its initial advantage. 23
7. In 1976 at a blind tasting of French and California wines held in Paris, French judges chose
several virtually unknown California wines over the more established and famous French
ones. This brought significant attention and fame to the re-emerging California wine
industry and demonstrated that Napa Valley in particular could produce wines of extremely
high quality that would match the best from Europe. For further details of the event and how
this permitted the industry to gain credibility and status, see Taber (2005).
8. Bulk wine producer Fred Franzia, CEO of Bronco Wine Co., who came to fame recently with
his ‘‘two buck chuck’’ Charles Shaw wines that sell 5.5 million cases annually through Trader
Joe’s, has suffered legal setbacks after attempting to use the name Napa on three of his
Napa-named brands (Napa Ridge, Napa Creek, and Ruherford Vintners). The law requires
75 percent of the grapes to come from the location listed on the label and since his wines do
not have that percentage (most coming from the Central Valley of California), the NVV took
legal action. Franzia lost in court because he was unwilling to pay the higher prices for Napa
grapes that would be necessary if he were to continue the use of Napa on his labels. On their
part, the NVV were arguing that they were merely protecting the integrity of their brand. See
Sogg (2006) for a fuller discussion of Franzia and this case.
9. Conaway (2003) and Siler (2007) provide interesting commentaries on the transformations
that have occurred in Napa Valley during the past few decades, replete with personality
clashes, the flood of new money, and the ambitions of newcomers, hirings and firings, and
struggles over regulatory issues. Such nuanced narratives are a useful complement to the
staid academic studies of power and privilege.

References
Adler, P.S. and Kwon, S.-W. (2002), ‘‘Social capital: prospect for a new concept’’, Academy of
Management Review, Vol. 27, pp. 17-40.
Benjamin, B.A. and Podolny, J.M. (1999), ‘‘Status, quality, and social order in the California wine
industry’’, Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 44 No. 3, pp. 563-89.
Breschi, S. and Lissoni, F. (2001), ‘‘Knowledge spillovers and local innovation systems: a critical
survey’’, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 975-1005.
Burt, R. (1983), Corporate Profits and Cooptation: Networks of Market Constraints and
Directorate Ties in the American Economy, Academic Press, New York, NY.
Campbell, J., Hollinsgworth, J.R. and Lindberg, L. (1991), Governance of the American Economy,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Carroll, G. (1985), ‘‘Concentration and specialization: dynamics of niche width in populations of
organizations’’, American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 90, pp. 530-47.
Colman, T. (2008), Wine Politics, University of California Press, Berkeley, CA.
Conaway, J. (2003), The Far Side of Eden, Mariner Books, Boston, MA.
Delacroix, J., Swaminathan, A. and Solt, M.E. (1989), ‘‘Density dependence versus population
dynamics: an ecological study of failings in the California wine industry’’, American
Sociological Review, Vol. 54, pp. 245-62.
IJWBR DeLangen, P.W. (2004), The Performance of Port Clusters: A Framework to Analyse Cluster
Performance and an Application to the Seaport Clusters of Durban, Rotterdam and the
22,1 Lower Mississippi, Erasmus Research Institute of Management, Rotterdam.
Enright, M.J. (1998), ‘‘Regional clusters and firm strategy’’, in Chandler, A., Hagstrom, P. and
Solvell, O. (Eds), The Dynamic Firm, Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York, NY.
Fligstein, N. (2001), The Architecture of Markets, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
24 Goode, J. (2005), The Science of Wine, University of California Press, Berkeley, CA.
Granovetter, M. (1985), ‘‘Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness’’,
American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 91, pp. 481-510.
Gulati, R. (2000), Managing Network Resources, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Heimoff, S. (2008), New Classic Winemakers of California, University of California Press,
Berkeley, CA.
Inkpen, A. and Tsang, E. (2005), ‘‘Social capital, networks and knowledge transfer’’, Academy of
Management Review, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 146-65.
Johnson, B., Lorenz, E. and Lundvall, A.-B. (2002), ‘‘Why all the fuss about codified and tacit
knowledge?’’, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 11 No. 2, pp. 245-62.
Kramer, M. (2004), New California Wine, Running Press, Philadelphia, PA.
Lazerson, M.H. and Lorenzoni, G. (1999), ‘‘The firms feed industrial districts: a return to the
Italian source?’’, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 8, pp. 235-66.
Maskell, P. (2001), ‘‘Towards a knowledge-based theory of the geographical cluster’’, Industrial
and Corporate Change, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 921-43.
MKF Research (2005), ‘‘Economic impact of wine and vineyards in Napa County’’, pp. 1-7.
Podolny, J.M. (1993), ‘‘A status-based model of market competition’’, American Journal of
Sociology, Vol. 98, pp. 829-72.
Podolny, J.M. (2005), Status Signals, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Podolny, J.M. and Page, K.L. (1998), ‘‘Network forms of organization’’, Annual Review of Sociology,
Vol. 24, pp. 57-76.
Porter, M.E. (1990), The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Macmillan, London.
Powell, W. (1990), ‘‘Neither market nor hierarchy: network forms of organization’’, in Staw, B. and
Cummins, L.L. (Eds), Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 12, JAI Press, Greenwich,
CT, pp. 295-336.
Siler, J.F. (2007), The House of Mondavi, Gotham Books, New York, NY.
Sogg, D. (2006), ‘‘Bad boy of California wine’’, Wine Spectator, 16 November, pp. 168-75.
Staber, U. (2001), ‘‘The structure of networks in industrial districts’’, International Journal of
Urban and Regional Research, Vol. 25 No. 3, pp. 537-52.
Swaminathan, A. (2001), ‘‘Resource partitioning and the evolution of specialist organizations: the
role of location and identity in the US wine industry’’, Academy of Management Journal,
Vol. 44 No. 6, pp. 1169-85.
Taber, G. (2005), Judgment of Paris: California vs. France and the Historic 1976 Paris Tasting
that Revolutionized Wine, Scribner, New York, NY.
Taplin, I.M. (2006), ‘‘Competitive pressures and strategic repositioning in the California premium
wine industry’’, International Journal of Wine Marketing, Vol. 18 No. 1, pp. 61-70.
Uzzi, B. (1997), ‘‘Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: the paradox of
embeddedness’’, Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 42, pp. 35-67.
Visser, E.-J. and deLangen, P. (2006), ‘‘The importance and quality of governance in the Chilean
wine industry’’, GeoJournal, Vol. 65, pp. 177-97.
Wine Institute (2007), ‘‘Premium growth trend for California wine continues in 2006 as From
mainstream wine culture emerges in the US’’, pp. 1-4, available at www.wineinstitute.org/
industry/statistics/2007/wine_sales.php (accessed 1 June). co-operation to
Zhao, W. (2005), ‘‘Understanding classifications: empirical evidence from the American and competition
French wine industries’’, Poetics, Vol. 33, pp. 179-200.

Further reading
Frank, R.H. (1999), Luxury Fever, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
25
Laube, J. (2006), ‘‘California’s top 50’’, Wine Spectator, 15 November, pp. 48-60.

Appendix. Questionnaire*
Open ended questions. (*strict confidentiality is maintained and names of wineries or people
involved in study not identified)
History of winery
Can you tell me about your founding, who was involved in it and where your resources came from?
Principal types of wine sold:
# cases:
Acres under production:
Ownership: family/corporate/private partnership
Staff numbers.
Production and operational aspects
Are you profitable?
Are you changing anything about your approach to winemaking?
Do rating agencies (Parker, Wine Spectator etc) affect the way you make your own wine? Do you
see these agencies as causing a homogenization in winemaking, a convergence of taste? Is this
good, bad or irrelevant to your winery?
How much has changed in your winery over the last few years? Would you describe these
changes as pro-active or re-active?
Do you plan to expand production? Reduce capacity? Any partnerships or joint ventures with
other wineries in other areas/countries planned or currently existing?
What are the challenges that you face in the current environment?
Networks and interaction
Would you say that a cooperative environment exists amongst premium producers whereby
information is shared informally through established networks? Or is it more secretive and
competitive?
How much interaction do you have with fellow winemakers/owners/general managers?
How would you characterize these interactions?
Are there informal norms that encourage information sharing?
How do you learn winemaking techniques and issues that are site specific?
What attempts are made to collectively market the Napa brand as a status wine? Do you think
more should be done to limit production and ensure quality control? If so what exactly?
Regulatory problems
Does the recent Supreme Court ruling on inter state shipments effect your winery? What are its
implications for the premium producers if any?
Do you foresee other government regulations affecting your production (environmental issues for
example)? What steps do you take to anticipate potential changes?
Competitive pressures
What changes in the competitive landscape do you perceive?
How are they affecting your particular winery?
IJWBR What about increased competition from overseas? What countries? Has this increased and do
you expect it to continue to increase?
22,1 How have you responded to these changes? Are your strategies different now than in the recent
past?
Do you think that your own position is more vulnerable now than in the past and if so what are
you doing about this?
Supply chain issues
26 What are your thoughts on the recent concentration trend amongst distributors? Does this affect
your winery and if so how? Do you see further concentration occurring?
Are there other changes in the supply chain that you anticipate affecting premium producers in
Napa in general and your winery in particular? If so how do you plan to respond to them?
What’s happening in the valley and the industry in general
Share your thoughts on how trends are developing and what this means for incumbents.
This research is purely for academic purposes and has no commercial intent.
All participants will remain anonymous.
Thank you for your help

Corresponding author
Ian M. Taplin can be contacted at: Taplin@wfu.edu

To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: reprints@emeraldinsight.com


Or visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints

You might also like