You are on page 1of 2

Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci.

USA
Vol. 73, No. 10, pp. 3747-3748, October 1976
Economic Sciences

A theorem on homogeneous functions and extended Cobb-Douglas


forms
(production and distribution theory)
A. CHARNES*, W. W. COOPERt, AND A. P. SCHINNARt
* Center for Cybernetic Studies, The University of Texas, Austin, Texas
78712; t Harvard University Graduate School of Business Administration, Boston,
Massachusetts 02163; and t School of Urban and Public Affairs, Carnegie-Mellon University, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania 15213
Communicated by Jacob Marschak, July 27, 1976

ABSTRACT A form for homogeneous functions is presented as "output elasticity" since the associated mathematical notation
which shows them to be a very simple extension of the well- can generally be relied on to make clear which input is being
known Cobb-Douglas functions with similar properties in pro- referred to.
duction (and distribution) economics. This form thus suggests Taking logarithms in [2] and then differentiating as in [3],
new possibilities for interpreting a wide variety of empirical
and theoretical results in economics; it also provides contact we see that the exponents bi are output elasticities. They are all
with developments in other fields, such as information theory also constant. Because, in general, output elasticities are as-
and geometric programming. sumed to be positive for any actually used input, the 5s in these
Cobb-Douglas functions are also assumed to be positive con-
One of the most extensively used forms for empirical studies stants. This assumption follows from the fact that the output
of production (and other areas, too) in economics is the Q and all inputs xj are positive and so are the derivatives (called
"Cobb-Douglas function" (see refs. 1 and 2), "marginal productivities") 8Q/&rt, since all inputs have positive
Q = AL"K'". [1] prices and hence it would not be economical to use any input
that does not produce some positive output. In keeping with
Here we have written it as a homogeneous form, of degree a common assumption we shall also assume that all output elas-
+ f3, in terms of Q, a single output, which results from the ticities are positive, although not necessarily constants, in the
amounts of two inputs, labor, L, and capital, K. Interchange- discussion that follows.
ably, we shall also refer to such inputs as "factors of production," With these assumptions, we now extends the above forms
or, more briefly, as "factor inputs." A, a, and ,B are positive and elasticities to
constants, and a and ,@ represent "output elasticities" or re- n

sponses of Q to variations in the factor amounts, L and K, re- Q = A(x) HI xii(x). [4]
spectively. (See [3] and the following below.) i=I

More generally, where Q is now a homogeneous function that is "sufficiently


n smooth," i.e., has continuous partial derivatives, and bi5(x) and
Q = A H| xj6'= AxI6'X262 -- X)', [2] A(x) are functions depending on the vector x = (xi, . . .,xn) with
xj > 0, and defined in such a way that, as will be shown, the bi5(x)
where xi is the amount of the ith factor input and the constant also satisfy
as is its corresponding "output elasticity", namely, n

a ln Q xiOQ i.
E: bl.(x)
= I
= I, bi(x) > O. i -= 1, ... , n. [5]
a In xi Qax,
Q [3]
We call this an "extended" Cobb-Douglas form and observe
which is assumed to be positive, as are also all the variables that it is a new form that holds for all sufficiently smooth ho-
Xi. mogeneous functions.
As [3] makes clear, output elasticity is essentially a measure
of the incremental response in output, Q, to variation in the
amount of the ith factor input, xi. The statement of the deriv- THEOREM ON HOMOGENEOUS FUNCTIONS
ative in logarithmic units produces a "dimensionless" measure§,
as is shown by the second term in [3]. As this second term also To state and motivate our theorem we first consider the ex-
makes clear, the value of this elasticity will, in general, depend pression
not only on aQ/8x1 (and the point where it is evaluated) but also n

on the already attained ratio of the ith input to total output, i.e., hf(x) = E fix,
-I
[6]
xt/Q. i

Sometimes [3] is called the "partial output elasticity" or, more which, by Euler's theorem, always holds when the function f(x)
precisely, the "partial output elasticity for the ith factor input," is homogeneous of degree h with continuous partial derivatives
but we shall follow common usage and refer to this more briefly ("marginal productivities" if f is the production function),

§ This was an original motivation in the choice of such logarithmic units I A. Charnes, W. W. Cooper, and A. P. Schinnar, "An extended
for characterizing these "proportionate responses" of output to each Cobb-Douglas form for use in production economics" (unpublished).
indicated input (see ref. 3). P. A. Samuelson (4), p. 126, footnote 4, The University of Texas Center for Cybernetics Studies, BEB 203E,
shows, however, an example that eliminates this "dimensionless" Austin, Texas, 78712, where the subject of the paper is treated in
property. greater detail.
3747
3748 Economic Sciences: Charnes et al. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 73 (1976)

d=f(x) in terms of specified behavioral hypotheses (e.g., with respect


f
i- Xi [7] to cost minimizing behavior) in economics so that [11] may also
be used for empirical inquiries to provide a very natural sum-
THEOREM. Let hf(x) > 0, where f(x) is a function that is mary measure of the degree of departure (if any) from the
homogeneous of degree h, and let f(x) have continuous partial hypothesized behavior.
derivatives. Then
n CONCLUSION
f(x) = A(x) H xjai'x' [8] From what has just been said, it should be evident that the above
i. = I
theorem provides contacts with a variety of other disciplines.
where h b6(x) is the output elasticity of the ith factor input, As we have just shown, for instance, such a contact is explicitly
i.e., made with information theory, and thus to other parts of sta-
n
tistics, too (see ref. 6). Further developments of an analogous
b6(x) = (fixj/Zfjxj) = (fixi/hf(x)), kind provide similar contacts with geometric programming (7),
j =1 dimensional analysis (8), and other disciplines as wells.
and where Doubtless other such generalizations can also be effected
\6,x
(refs. 9 and 10). On the other hand, by a variety of specializing
n f assumptions with respect to the nature of the functions con-
x
I hbi(x) * [10] sidered, the results of the above theorem can also be brought
to bear for new insight into large bodies of already developed
Proof: Insert [9] and [10] into [8] and use [6]. economic theories and empirical findingsT.
Of course, the output elasticities are no longer constants, as
in the ordinary Cobb-Douglas functions, but the above theorem We thank Professor Jacob Marschak for numerous suggestions which
now provides an opening for further justification and inter- have helped to improve the above presentation.
pretations in the use of such functions and their extensions, 1. Cobb, C. W. & Douglas, P. H. (1928) "A theory of production,"
which have become almost canonical in empirical econometric Am. Econ. Rev. 18, 139-165.
investigations at aggregate-i.e., economy wide or industry 2. Douglas, P. H. (1948) "Are there laws of production," The Am.
wide-levels. Econ. Rev. 38,1-39.
Finally, the b5(x) as represented in the theorem provide a 3. Marshall, A. (1920) Principles of Economics (The MacMillan
ready means for testing a variety of economic hypotheses (e.g., Company, New York), 8th ed. pp. 830-832.
with respect to cost minimizing behavior) that are of interest 4. Samuelson, P. A. (1947) Foundations of Economic Analysis
in economics. In fact, turning to A(x), as represented in [10], (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass.), p. 126.
we can give it economic meaning as the geometric mean of the 5. Tinbergen, J. (1975) Income Distribution (North-Holland
Publishing Co., Amsterdam), pp. 81-84.
ratios of factor (i.e., input) marginal productivities and output 6. Kullback, S. (1959) Information Theory and Statistics (John
elasticities. Further we can also represent it, for each x, as Wiley & Sons, New York), pp. 36-65.
7. Duffin, R. J., Peterson, E. L. & Zener, C. M. (1967) Geometric
ln A(x) =-n h - 6x) In 6f (x) Programming (John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York), pp. 79-
81.
8. Bridgman, P. W. (1931) Dimensional Analysis (Yale University
But now recalling, see [5], that b6(x) 2 0 and libi(x) = 1, we Press, New Haven, Conn.) pp. 1-112.
then see that this is, essentially**, the negative, of the "Khin- 9. Charnes, A. & Cooper, W. W. (1974) "Constrained Kullback-
chin-Kullback-Leibler" measure of the mean information for Leibler estimation; generalized Cobb-Douglas balance, and
discrimination in favor of the "as distribution" against the "fj unconstrained convex programming," Rendiconti di Accademia
distribution" (see ref. 6). Here "distribution" means "frequency Nazionale dei Lincei, Classe di scienze fisiche, matematiche e
naturali, Serie VIII, 56,556-561.
distribution" as in statistics. It can also be given an interpretation 10. Charnes, A., Cooper, W. W. & Kortanek, K. 0. (1971) "Semi-
infinite programming, differentiability and geometric pro-
1I See e.g., the extension effected by Tinbergen (5) for a typical vari- gramming, Part I: With example applications in economics and
ant. management science," R. S. Varma Memorial Volume, J. Math.
** i.e., apart from a "norming factor" (see footnotes). Sci. 6, 19-40.

You might also like