You are on page 1of 13

WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: ADJUSTING TO LOWER COMMODITY PRICES

Figure 1.11. External Sector Figure 1.12. Capital Flows in Emerging Market Economies
Gross capital inflows to emerging market economies began slowing markedly in
Global trade volumes weakened more than GDP in the first half of 2015, 2014 and, as a percent of GDP, reached their lowest level since the recovery from
highlighting that economic growth in the services and other nontradables sectors the global financial crisis in the first quarter of 2015. As gross capital outflows
has been relatively stronger than in the tradables sectors. Global current account have held up, and with little change in the aggregate current account balance,
imbalances are expected to narrow further over the forecast horizon, with most of these economies as a group started selling foreign exchange reserves in 2014.
the contribution coming from smaller surpluses in oil exporters. In contrast, global
creditor and debtor positions have increased further as a share of world GDP.
40 1. Net Flows in Emerging Market Funds
30 (Billions of U.S. dollars)
May 22,
60 1. World Real GDP and Trade Volume 15 20
2013
(Annualized quarterly percent change) 10
40 10 0
–10
20 5 Greek 1st ECB Bond
–20
–30 crisis Irish LTROs Equity
crisis EM-VXY
0 0 –40
2010 11 12 13 14 Aug.
–20 Trade volume Real GDP (right scale) –5 15
15 2. Capital Inflows Emerging Europe Emerging Asia excluding China
–40 –10 12 (Percent of GDP) Latin America China
2007 09 11 13 15: Saudi Arabia Total
Q2 9
6
4 2. Global Current Account Imbalances
(Percent of world GDP) 3
3
0
2
–3
1
0 –6
2007 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15:
–1 Q1
–2 15 3. Capital Outflows Excluding Change in Reserves
–3 12 (Percent of GDP)
USA OIL DEU+EURSUR OCADC
CHN+EMA JPN ROW Discrepancy Emerging Europe Emerging Asia excluding China
–4 9 Latin America China
–5 6 Saudi Arabia Total
1998 2000 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 20
3
20 3. Global Net Financial Assets Imbalances
(Percent of world GDP) 0
15
–3
10
5 –6
2007 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15:
0 Q1
–5
15 4. Change in Reserves
–10 (Percent of GDP)
–15 12 Emerging Europe Emerging Asia excluding China
9 Latin America China
–20 USA OIL DEU+EURSUR OCADC
Saudi Arabia Total
–25 CHN+EMA JPN ROW Discrepancy 6
–30 3
1998 2000 02 04 06 08 10 12 14
0
Sources: CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis; and IMF staff –3
estimates. –6
Note: Data labels in the figure use International Organization for Standardization 2007 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15:
(ISO) country codes. CHN+EMA = China and emerging Asia (Hong Kong SAR, Q2
Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan Province of China,
Thailand); DEU+EURSUR = Germany and other European advanced surplus Sources: Bloomberg, L.P.; EPFR Global; Haver Analytics; IMF, International Financial
economies (Austria, Denmark, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland); Statistics; and IMF staff calculations.
OCADC = other European countries with precrisis current account deficits (Greece, Note: Capital inflows are net purchases of domestic assets by nonresidents. Capital
Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain, United Kingdom, WEO group of emerging and outflows are net purchases of foreign assets by domestic residents. Emerging Asia
developing Europe); OIL = Norway and WEO group of emerging market and excluding China comprises India, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and
developing economy fuel exporters; ROW = rest of the world. Thailand; emerging Europe comprises Poland, Romania, Russia, and Turkey; Latin
America comprises Brazil, Chile, Colombia,Mexico, and Peru. ECB = European
Central Bank; EM-VXY = J.P. Morgan Emerging Market Volatility Index; LTROs =
longer-term refinancing operations.

18 International Monetary Fund | October 2015


CHAPTER 1   Recent Developments and Prospects

with net sales of foreign reserves by China, Russia, and projected changes in current account balances relative
Saudi Arabia representing the lion’s share.5 to GDP in 2015 in relation to the current account gaps
Current account deficits and surpluses across the for 2014 discussed in the 2015 External Sector Report.6
main creditor and debtor regions declined further The figure shows a modest general tendency for current
in 2014, albeit relatively modestly (Figure 1.12, panel account balances to move in the direction of narrow-
2). Nevertheless, global creditor and debtor positions, ing 2014 current account gaps, but with large econo-
as measured by net international investment positions, mies such as China, Germany, and the United States
continued to grow in 2014 as a share of world GDP being notable exceptions, such gaps would not narrow
(Figure 1.12, panel 3). Valuation effects play an impor- on a global scale. Panel 2 of Figure 1.13 undertakes
tant role in explaining such widening. Specifically, the the same exercise for real effective exchange rates, and
appreciation of the U.S. dollar and the increase in the it shows that exchange rate changes in 2015 relative to
value of U.S. assets related to interest rate and equity their 2014 average are not systematically consistent with
price movements have increased the net external liabili- a reduction in the exchange rate gaps identified for 2014
ties of the United States and symmetrically boosted by the 2015 External Sector Report. Of course a norma-
asset values in holders of U.S. financial instruments. tive assessment of external balances and exchange rates
Projections for 2015 suggest changes in the com- must also take into account changes in the underlying
position of global current account deficits and sur- current account and real exchange rate “norms” as well,
pluses, reflecting the impact of declining prices of oil and such an assessment will be undertaken in next year’s
and other commodities, as well as the large exchange External Sector Report.
rate movements that have taken place since last year. More generally, a desirable pattern of global
As discussed in Chapter 3, the evidence suggests rebalancing would depend not just on exchange rate
that exchange rate movements continue to have an changes and their attendant current account implica-
economically significant impact on external bal- tions, but on policies underpinning desirable shifts to
ances. However, the aggregate size of global current relative demand and consistent with sustaining world
account deficits and surpluses will remain broadly growth.
stable. Specifically, the contraction in the surpluses Although the compression of global current account
of oil-exporting countries will continue to be broadly imbalances following the global financial crisis has
offset by increasing surpluses in oil importers such as been discussed extensively (see, for instance, Chapter
European surplus countries as well as in China, while 4 of the October 2014 WEO), large current account
the reduction in deficits for some oil importers is and surpluses and deficits in smaller countries have received
will remain offset by a deteriorating current account less attention. Their number—especially the number
balance in the United States. of deficits—remains elevated. During 2012–14, more
From a normative perspective, there is of course no than 80 countries ran current account deficits that
presumption that current account deficits and surpluses exceeded 5 percent of GDP but altogether accounted
should necessarily decline. But as discussed in the 2015 for only 3½ percent of world GDP. For comparison,
External Sector Report (IMF 2015a), a number of during 2005–08 the number of countries with current
countries’ 2014 current account imbalances appear too account deficits above 5 percent of GDP was only
large relative to a country-specific norm consistent with slightly larger (90), but they accounted for a share of
external stability. These countries have made limited world GDP that was larger by a factor of 10. And the
progress in reducing the excess imbalances remaining number of countries running large surpluses is much
after the large narrowing of imbalances in the aftermath smaller than in the previous period. Box 1.2 discusses
of the global financial crisis. As discussed earlier, external the characteristics of countries that have run large
balances in 2015 are affected by substantial shocks, current account deficits in recent years in more detail,
including changes in commodity prices and large fluctu- highlighting a variety of different drivers (ranging
ations in exchange rates. Panel 3 of Figure 1.13 depicts from domestic shocks to commodity price booms to
increased access to external finance after debt forgive-
5The decline in the stock of reserves for emerging market and

developing economies overstates the amount of actual sales because


of valuation effects. Namely, the appreciation of the U.S. dollar with 6These gaps measure deviations of current account balances from a

respect to most other reserve currencies in recent quarters implies a level consistent with underlying fundamentals and desirable policies.
decline in the stock of reserves measured in U.S. dollars. Real exchange rate gaps are defined analogously.

International Monetary Fund | October 2015 19


WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: ADJUSTING TO LOWER COMMODITY PRICES

Figure 1.13. Real Exchange Rates and Current Account Gaps ness) within the general tendency for poor countries,
as well as for small countries (in terms of population),
Currencies of many major emerging market economies have depreciated further in
real effective terms since the projections for the April 2015 World Economic Outlook to run current account deficits. Box 1.3 addresses a
(WEO) were prepared, reflecting to an important extent weaker fundamentals, related question—namely, the impact of capital flows
notably weakening growth prospects and worsening terms of trade. As for external
imbalances, the assessment in the 2015 External Sector Report is that these to low-income developing countries on those coun-
remained too large in 2014 relative to underlying norms. WEO projections suggest tries’ credit growth. Its findings suggest an important
some general tendency for the expected current account balances in 2015 to move
in the direction of narrowing the implied 2014 current account gaps. However, in
influence of external financial conditions on domestic
some large economies, including China, Germany, and the United States, no credit expansion in those countries. Clearly, reliance on
narrowing is expected. external finance among countries with pressing devel-
opment needs and high rates of return on investment
15 1. Changes in Real Effective Exchange Rates and Revision to Terms-
of-Trade Growth is to be expected. However, given declining commodity
10 (Percent) prices and worsening external conditions, these two
5
boxes suggest that some countries that relied heavily on
private external financing may face significant external
0 adjustment pressures in the future.
–5

–10 REER percent change, Feb.–Aug. 20151


Revision to ToT growth (vs. April 2015 WEO)
Risks
–15 The distribution of risks to global growth remains
MYS KOR JPN SWE EA THA IND IDN USA TUR ZAF
SGP CHN MEX POL HKG CAN CHE RUS AUS GBR BRA tilted to the downside. Compared to the risk assess-
ment in the April 2015 WEO, downside risks to
30 2. Changes in Real Effective Exchange Rates and Gaps in Real growth for emerging market and developing economies
Effective Exchange Rates2
20 (Percent) have increased, given the combination of risks from
10 China’s growth transition, more protracted commod-
0 ity market rebalancing, increased foreign-currency
exposure of corporate balance sheets, and capital flow
–10
reversals associated with disruptive asset price shifts.
–20
REER percent change, 2014 (average)–Aug. 2015
In advanced economies, contagion risks from Greece-
–30 REER gap for 2014 (midpoint) related events to other euro area economies, while
–40 lower than earlier in the year, remain a concern, as do
MYS KOR JPN SWE EA THA IND IDN USA TUR ZAF
SGP CHN MEX POL HKG CAN CHE RUS AUS GBR BRA risks from protracted weak demand and low inflation.
Oil price declines since June (and lagged effects from
6 3. ESR Current Account Gap in 2014 versus Change in Current previous declines) could imply some upside risk to
Change in current account, 2014–15

Account, 2014–15 THA


Correlation = –0.12 domestic demand and growth in oil importers.
4 (Percent of GDP)
JPN
GBR RUS SWE
CHE
2 TUR FRA POL CHN DEU
ITA
KOR
SGP The Fan Chart: Risks around the Global GDP Forecast
ZAF BEL IND
0 The fan chart for the global GDP forecast suggests
BRA ESP HKG NLD MYS that the confidence interval around the projected path
IDN
–2
USA MEX for global growth in 2016 has narrowed, especially on
CAN AUS
–4 the upside (Figure 1.14, panel 1). Hence, high growth
–4 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 outcomes much above the baseline forecast are now less
ESR current account gap, 2014
likely compared to what they were in the April 2015
Sources: Global Insight; IMF, 2015 Pilot External Sector Report (ESR); IMF, WEO.7
International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: Data labels in the figure use International Organization for Standardization The smaller probability of growth outcomes much
(ISO) country codes. EA = euro area; REER = real effective exchange rate; ToT = above the baseline is consistent with the view that an
terms of trade.
1
The data for the euro area are calculated by taking the average of the data for
France, Germany, Italy, and Spain.
2 7The indicators used in the construction of the fan chart are based
REER gaps and classifications are based on the IMF's 2015 Pilot External Sector
Report. either on prices of derivatives or on the distribution of forecasts for
the underlying variables.

20 International Monetary Fund | October 2015


CHAPTER 1   Recent Developments and Prospects

even stronger growth rebound above trend than is Figure 1.14. Risks to the Global Outlook
already incorporated in current forecasts is unlikely in
The fan chart, which indicates the degree of uncertainty about the global growth
advanced economies. Productivity growth has turned outlook, suggests that upside risks to the forecast have narrowed compared to the
out weaker than expected, and potential output growth April 2015 World Economic Outlook (WEO), while the distribution of downside risks
is broadly unchanged. The distribution of the risks to the forecast for global growth
is projected to remain substantially below precrisis rates is thus tilted more to the downside. Measures of forecast dispersion and implied
(see the discussion earlier and in Box 1.1). In addition, volatility for equity and oil prices as well as the term spread in major advanced
economies suggest an increase in perceived uncertainty about key variables for
downside risks to growth in many major emerging the global outlook.
market economies have increased.
While upside risks from large positive growth sur- 6 1. Prospects for World GDP Growth1
(Percent change)
prises have decreased, the probability of global growth 5
falling below 2 percent remains small and broadly 4
unchanged relative to that in the April 2015 WEO. 3 WEO baseline
Simulations using the IMF’s Global Projection Model, 90 percent confidence interval
2 70 percent confidence interval
which draw on past shocks over a longer horizon, 50 percent confidence interval
1
suggest a small increase in the probability of a reces- 90 percent confidence interval from April 2015 WEO
0
sion in the major advanced economies and in the Latin 2012 13 14 15 16
America 5 economies over a four-quarter horizon rela- 2.0 2. Balance of Risks Associated with Selected Risk Factors
2

tive to April 2015 (Figure 1.15, panel 1). This increase 1.5 (Coefficient of skewness expressed in units of the underlying
variables)
primarily reflects the lower starting values for growth 1.0
for some of the economies and the somewhat lower 0.5
0.0
growth forecast under the baseline. With the latter, the
–0.5
probability of negative shocks leading to a technical 2015 (Apr. 2015 WEO)
–1.0 Balance of risks for 2015 (Oct. 2015 WEO)
recession is higher compared to a situation in which –1.5 2016 (Oct. 2015 WEO)
the baseline forecast is stronger. –2.0
Term spread S&P 500 Inflation risk Oil market risks
Dispersion of Forecasts and Implied Volatility3
Risks to the Global Outlook 80 3. GDP (right scale) 1.2 125 4. Term spread 0.5
VIX (left scale) (right scale)
Downside risks differ between advanced and emerg- 60
1.0 100 Oil (left scale) 0.4
ing market economies to some extent. However, there
0.8 75
would be spillovers if any of the risks discussed in 40 0.3
this subsection materialized, and these spillovers, as 0.6 50
illustrated in Scenario Box 1 and in the October 2015 20 0.2
0.4 25
GFSR, could be substantial. In regard to upside risks,
0 0.2 0 0.1
lower oil and commodity prices could have a stronger 2006 08 10 12 Aug. 2006 08 10 12 Aug.
impact on demand than currently expected (including
Sources: Bloomberg, L.P.; Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE); Consensus
through lagged effects of earlier price declines). Economics; Haver Analytics; and IMF staff estimates.
1
The fan chart shows the uncertainty around the WEO central forecast with 50, 70,
Disruptive Asset Price Shifts and Financial Market and 90 percent confidence intervals. As shown, the 70 percent confidence interval
includes the 50 percent interval, and the 90 percent confidence interval includes
Turmoil the 50 and 70 percent intervals. See Appendix 1.2 of the April 2009 WEO for
As elaborated in the October 2015 GFSR, disrup- details. The 90 percent intervals for the current-year and one-year-ahead forecasts
from the April 2015 WEO are shown relative to the current baseline.
tive asset price shifts and financial turmoil could take 2
The bars depict the coefficient of skewness expressed in units of the underlying
a toll on global activity. Emerging market economies variables. The values for inflation risks and oil price risks enter with the opposite
sign since they represent downside risks to growth.
are particularly exposed, as these risks, if they material- 3
GDP measures the purchasing-power-parity-weighted average dispersion of GDP
ized, could involve capital flow reversals. Four factors growth forecasts for the G7 economies (Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan,
United Kingdom, United States), Brazil, China, India, and Mexico. VIX is the CBOE
underpin these risks. Standard & Poor's 500 (S&P 500) Implied Volatility Index. Term spread measures
• Term premiums and risk premiums in bond markets the average dispersion of term spreads implicit in interest rate forecasts for
Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States. Oil is the CBOE crude
are still very low by historical standards. Estimates oil volatility index. Forecasts are from Consensus Economics surveys. Dashed lines
of the term premium on longer-term U.S. Treasury represent the average values from 2000 to the present.
bonds suggest that it turned negative in late 2014,
and estimates of term premiums for other advanced

International Monetary Fund | October 2015 21


WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: ADJUSTING TO LOWER COMMODITY PRICES

Figure 1.15. Recession and Deflation Risks those economies. Deflation risks, for example, which
(Percent) appear to have partly underpinned very low bond
term premiums, should decrease as output gaps
The IMF staff's Global Projection Model suggests that recession risks have close. Under the baseline, the change in term premi-
increased for most advanced economies and the Latin America 5 group, mostly
reflecting relatively weaker baseline projections. The risk of deflation, while ums is assumed to be gradual, but news that changes
decreasing, remains elevated in the euro area. expectations about these fault lines and unexpected
portfolio shifts could trigger disruptive asset price
60 1. Probability of Recession, 2015:Q3–2016:Q2 adjustments. These adjustments might be related to
50 April 2015 WEO: the start and especially the pace of monetary policy
2015:Q1–2015:Q4 normalization in the United States, also in light of
40
the remaining divergence between market expecta-
30 tions and estimates by members of the Federal Open
Market Committee about the path of U.S. policy
20
rates over the next few years.
10 • Vulnerabilities and financial stability risks in
0 emerging market economies have likely increased
United Euro area Japan Emerging Latin Rest of the
amid lower growth, recent commodity price
States Asia America 5 world
declines, and increased leverage after years of
30 2. Probability of Deflation, 2016:Q41 rapid credit growth. Hence, unfavorable news in
these areas could trigger higher risk premiums and
25
disruptive declines in emerging market asset prices
20 April 2015 WEO: and currency values.
2016:Q2
15 • Financial market reaction to the protracted uncer-
tainties surrounding the negotiations for a new
10
financing program with Greece was limited, reflect-
5 ing the strength of euro area firewalls and European
Central Bank policies, as well as declining systemic
0
United Euro area Japan Emerging Latin Rest of the linkages with Greece. Risks have diminished since
States Asia America 5 world
the agreement on a new European Stability Mecha-
nism program for Greece, but should policy and
Source: IMF staff estimates.
Note: Emerging Asia comprises China, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, Korea, political uncertainty reemerge in Greece, sovereign
Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan Province of China, and Thailand; Latin and financial sector stress in the euro area could also
America 5 comprises Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru; Rest of the world
comprises Argentina, Australia, Bulgaria, Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, reemerge, with potentially broader spillovers.
Estonia, Israel, New Zealand, Norway, Russia, South Africa, Sweden, Switzerland,
Turkey, United Kingdom, and Venezuela. Lower Potential Output
1
Deflation is defined as a fall in the price level on a year-over-year basis in the
quarter indicated in the figure. Potential output is projected to grow at a rate
lower than it did before the crisis, in both advanced
and emerging market economies.9 Risks are that the
growth rate of potential output could be even lower
economies are also low if not negative. A correction than expected. Indeed, recent revisions in U.S. national
to higher term premiums in the United States could accounts data suggest that productivity growth in
lead to sharply higher yields abroad, given the strong recent years was weaker than estimated previously. That
linkages among longer-term bond yields.8 said, the growth rate of potential output will likely
• The context underlying this asset price configura- continue to differ between advanced and emerging
tion—in particular, very accommodative monetary market economies even if this risk materializes. In the
policies in the major advanced economies, as well latter, potential output growth will remain substantially
as crisis legacies and deflation risks—is expected to
start changing with improved recovery prospects in 9Chapter 3 of the April 2015 WEO discusses prospects for

potential output in major advanced and emerging market economies


8See, example, Chapter 3 of the April 2014 WEO. in more detail.

22 International Monetary Fund | October 2015


CHAPTER 1   Recent Developments and Prospects

higher than in the former, given demographic trends increase, and policy space would shrink. This could
and the forces of convergence in per capita income. mean a sharper growth slowdown in the medium
Some of the forces underlying the risks of lower term when the vulnerabilities would be more dif-
potential output growth are the same in the two ficult to manage.
groups of economies, while others differ.
•• In terms of common forces, lower capital stock Lower Commodity Prices
growth is a concern in both groups. In advanced Prices of commodities have fallen sharply in recent
economies, the protracted crisis legacies—notably months. They could fall further if market rebalancing
financial sector weakness, still-high public debt in response to recent excess supply conditions were
ratios, and private debt overhang—are the main to take longer than expected.10 Growth in commod-
concern. In emerging market economies, the ity exporters would be negatively affected, and their
concerns are structural constraints, less favorable vulnerabilities would increase further in light of lower
external conditions for investment, notably tighter revenue and foreign exchange earnings. In com-
financial conditions and lower commodity prices, modity importers, however, the windfall gains from
and a possible greater credit overhang after the lower commodity prices from more persistent supply
recent credit booms. As a result, capital stock growth improvements would lower costs and increase real
could be lower for longer, which, in turn, might incomes, which should boost spending and activity,
also lower productivity growth at least temporarily as discussed in the April 2015 WEO for the case of
because of capital-embodied technological progress. oil. In that case, the spending increases by importers
•• In terms of differences, risks of negative productivity should more than offset lower spending in exporters, as
effects from longer-lasting high unemployment (skill the latter tend to smooth spending more in the aggre-
losses, lower labor force participation) apply primar- gate, and global demand would increase (see Husain
ily to advanced economies. Conversely, lower total and others 2015). The case is less clear-cut for other
factor productivity growth than expected under cur- commodities: exporters of metals may not smooth
rent convergence assumptions is primarily a concern spending to the same extent as oil exporters, given that
for emerging market economies. exhaustibility considerations generally play a smaller
role for the former.
Risks to Growth in China However, possible nonlinear effects of lower com-
Growth has slowed in China in recent years, and modity prices are a concern. Specifically, if lower prices
a further moderate slowdown has been factored into also led to significant financial stress, defaults, and
the baseline projections. There are risks of a stronger broad contagion among commodity exporters, the
growth slowdown if the macroeconomic manage- negative impact on activity in these economies would
ment of the end of the investment and credit boom be larger, as exporters might not be able to smooth
of 2009–12 proves more challenging than expected. spending to the extent they would otherwise. This
Risks span a broad spectrum, with real and finan- would also lead to larger adverse spillovers to commod-
cial spillovers, including through commodity market ity importers.
channels:
• A moderate growth shortfall: Given risks of a further A Further Sizable Strengthening of the U.S. Dollar
growth slowdown in the future and expectations of The constellation underpinning dollar apprecia-
policy reforms that may increase input and capi- tion over the past year or so is expected to remain in
tal costs, firms may lower investment more than place for some time in the baseline forecast. It includes
expected. But unlike in 2013–14, the Chinese domestic demand strength relative to most other
authorities could put greater weight on reducing advanced economies, monetary policy divergence among
vulnerabilities from recent rapid credit and invest- major advanced economies, and an improved external
ment growth, rather than on supporting growth. position with lower oil prices. U.S. dollar appreciation
• Hard landing in China: In this case, the authorities
would use their policy space to prevent growth from 10Specifically, the demand increases in response to lower prices or

slowing by shoring up investment through credit capacity adjustment through lower investment might be very grad-
ual. In the meantime, spot prices might have to fall more relative to
and public resources. Vulnerability from boom- expected future prices, so as to create incentives for further inventory
ing credit and investment would thus continue to buildup to absorb excess flow supply in the meantime.

International Monetary Fund | October 2015 23


WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: ADJUSTING TO LOWER COMMODITY PRICES

against most currencies could thus continue, causing a and the considerations previously presented under risks
lasting upswing in the dollar, as has happened previ- from lower potential output apply.
ously. If this risk were to materialize, balance sheet and
funding strains for dollar debtors could potentially A Combined Risk Scenario
more than offset trade benefits from real depreciation in The possible global repercussions of a general-
some economies. In addition, if dollar appreciation were ized slowdown in emerging market and developing
driven by increases in longer-term bond yields, the latter economies are presented in Scenario Box 1. The
would likely be transmitted rapidly to other economies, scenario includes the materialization of a number of
which might negatively affect the interest-sensitive com- risks highlighted earlier—a slowdown in investment
ponents of domestic demand. Balance sheet and funding and growth across emerging market economies, more
constraints are a particular concern for emerging market severe in faster-growing economies such as China and
economies with considerable international financial India; lower commodity prices, arising from this slow-
integration, in which—as discussed in the 2015 Spillover down; and higher risk premiums and exchange rate
Report (IMF 2015b) and the October 2015 GFSR— depreciation across emerging market economies. The
foreign-currency corporate debt has increased substan- implications for growth in emerging market econo-
tially over the past few years. Much of the increase mies and developing countries would be sizable, with
has been in the energy sector, in which a high share growth rates 1.5 to 2 percentage points lower after five
of revenue in U.S. dollars provides a natural hedge, years—even though the model assumes no “sudden
although increased leverage in the sector remains a stop” in capital flows or crisis outcomes with contagion
concern, especially if energy prices were to fall while the effects. Spillovers onto advanced economies would also
dollar appreciated. In addition, foreign-currency debt is be material, with growth about 0.2 to 0.3 percentage
also higher in firms operating in sectors without natural point lower after five years, depending on whether risk
revenue hedges, especially the nontradables sector. aversion toward emerging market assets increases, and
a sizable deterioration in current account balances,
Geopolitical Risks despite the partial offset from lower commodity prices.
Ongoing events around Ukraine, the Middle
East, and parts of Africa could lead to escalation in
tensions and increased disruptions in global trade Policies
and financial transactions. Disruptions in energy Raising actual and potential output continues to be
and other commodity markets remain a particular a general policy priority. Specific policy requirements
concern, given the possibility of sharp price spikes, vary from country group to country group and among
which, depending on their duration, could substan- individual countries, although there is a broad need for
tially lower real incomes and demand in importers. structural reforms in many economies, advanced and
More generally, an escalation of such tensions could emerging market alike. In this regard, more coun-
take a toll on confidence. tries should capitalize on the opportunities that lower
energy prices offer to reform energy subsidies and taxes.
Secular Stagnation and Hysteresis Addressing external vulnerabilities is also of the essence
The risk of a protracted shortfall of domestic in a number of emerging market and developing econo-
demand associated with excess saving (discussed in mies facing a more difficult external environment.
more detail in a scenario analysis in the October 2014
WEO) will remain a concern. In some advanced econ-
omies, especially in the euro area, demand continues Policies for Full Employment and Stable Inflation in
to be relatively weak, and output gaps are still large. Advanced Economies
Inflation is expected to stay below target beyond the With nominal policy rates still at or close to the
usual monetary policy horizons, and deflation risks— zero lower bound in many countries, reducing risks to
while lower than in April—remain elevated amid crisis activity from low inflation and prolonged demand defi-
legacies and constraints on monetary policy at the ciency remains a priority for macroeconomic policy.
zero lower bound (Figure 1.15, panel 2). Furthermore, In particular, to prevent real interest rates from rising
after six years of demand weakness, the likelihood of prematurely, monetary policy must stay accommoda-
damage to potential output is increasingly a concern, tive, including through unconventional measures (such

24 International Monetary Fund | October 2015


CHAPTER 1   Recent Developments and Prospects

Scenario Box 1. A Structural Slowing in Emerging Market Economies


Two simulations employing the IMF’s G20 Model 10 percent relative to the dollar. The increase in risk
are used to examine the global impact of a stronger- aversion and premiums is akin to the decompression
than-expected slowing in potential output growth in of risk premiums in the global asset market disruption
emerging market economies. In both simulations, inves- scenario in the October 2015 Global Financial Stability
tors expect lower growth in the future, because of slower Report, except that in the risk scenario examined in
catching up and lower productivity growth, as well as this box, it is confined to emerging market economies
because of lower capital inflows and tighter financial where the shock originates.
conditions. Hence, they reduce investment expenditure In the first simulation (red lines in Scenario Fig-
relative to the World Economic Outlook (WEO) baseline ure 1), growth in 2016 would be about 0.4 percentage
projections, resulting in weaker domestic demand in point below the WEO baseline (blue lines in the fig-
emerging market economies. In particular, the sizable ure). Economic growth in the major emerging market
decline in investment and growth in China—together economies (Brazil, Russia, India, China, South Africa)
with the generalized slowdown across emerging market would gradually decline by 1 percentage point relative
economies—implies a sizable weakening of commodity to 2015. Compared with the baseline, this would
prices, particularly those for metals, resulting in a weak- amount to a sizable growth differential of 2 percent-
ening of the terms of trade for commodity exporters. age points after five years. In other emerging market
Investment growth in emerging market economies economies, growth would remain broadly unchanged
is assumed to decline annually by about 4 percentage relative to 2015, rather than increasing by about 1 per-
points on average relative to the baseline in both simu- centage point under the baseline.
lations. The decline varies within regions: countries The growth rebound in advanced economies in 2016
with weaker baseline medium-term growth projections would be smaller. Lower global interest rates and a more
see a smaller decline. This reflects the assumption of a modest recovery in oil prices would boost domestic
broader slowing in economic convergence in the cur- demand in these economies relative to the baseline.
rent global environment. Lower interest rates would reflect both weaker global
The lower investment growth and the resulting activity and the monetary policy response across the
weaker domestic demand conditions reduce potential globe. But the positive domestic demand impact from
output in emerging market economies. The nega- lower interest rates and oil prices in advanced econo-
tive impact operates not only through the relatively mies would be more than offset by the effects of weaker
lower growth in the capital stock, but also through external demand. In fact, the scenario suggests substan-
a reduction in total factor productivity growth. The tial demand rebalancing. Currencies of emerging market
latter reflects the assumption of new technology being economies would depreciate in real effective terms,
embodied in new capital. Lower investment growth and these economies’ current accounts would improve
therefore results in a lower rate of technological prog- with the positive impact on net exports. Conversely,
ress, with the decline assumed to be proportional to advanced economies would see real appreciation and a
the slowing in investment growth. In addition, weaker deterioration in current accounts. Overall, the spillovers
domestic demand leads to higher unemployment, to advanced economies from the structural slowdown in
which, in turn, results in a reduction in labor supply. emerging market economies would be negative.
Skill depreciation among the unemployed leads to a In a second simulation, in which lower growth pros-
higher natural rate of unemployment, and discouraged pects in emerging market economies also heighten risk
workers withdraw from the labor force. aversion, growth in emerging market economies would
The first simulation focuses on the real side of the decline by more (yellow lines in the figure). While the
shock, while in the second simulation, the stronger depreciations and initial tightening in financial condi-
slowing in potential output also leads to increased risk tions would gradually dissipate, there would be some
aversion toward emerging market assets. The reason persistent tightening in financial conditions broadly
is that investors worry about return prospects on proportional to emerging market economies’ growth
assets and default risks on loans made before expected slowdowns, highlighting the amplifying role of financial
growth fell. As a result, risk premiums on assets issued channels in the transmission of the shock. There would
by entities in these economies increase at the outset be no pickup in global growth in 2016, and average
by 100 basis points, and their currencies depreciate by growth would be lower across all country groups over

International Monetary Fund | October 2015 25


WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: ADJUSTING TO LOWER COMMODITY PRICES

Scenario Box 1 (continued)


Scenario Figure 1. World Economic Outlook Stagnation Scenario
(Percent, unless noted otherwise)

World Economic Outlook baseline Structural slowing in emerging Structural slowing plus capital
economies outflows

4.0 1. Global GDP Growth 2. Global Nominal 3.4 3. Nominal Oil Price 65
Interest Rate (U.S. dollars a barrel)
3.8
3.0 60
3.6
2.6 55
3.4
2.2 50
3.2

3.0 1.8 45
2015 16 17 18 19 20 2015 16 17 18 19 20 2015 16 17 18 19 20

2.4 4. Advanced Economies 5. BRICS GDP Growth 6.0 6. Other Emerging Market 5.0
GDP Growth Economies GDP Growth
2.2 5.5
4.5
2.0 5.0
4.0
1.8 4.5
3.5
1.6 4.0

1.4 3.5 3.0


2015 16 17 18 19 20 2015 16 17 18 19 20 2015 16 17 18 19 20

2 7. Advanced Economies 8. BRICS Current Account 5 9. Other Emerging Market 1


Current Account Balance Economies Current
Balance (Percent of GDP) 4 Account Balance
1 0
(Percent of GDP) 3 (Percent of GDP)

0 2 –1
1
–1 –2
0
–2 –1 –3
2015 16 17 18 19 20 2015 16 17 18 19 20 2015 16 17 18 19 20

Sources: IMF, G20MOD simulations; and IMF staff estimates.


Note: BRICS = Brazil, Russia, India, China, South Africa. Other emerging market economies = Albania, Antigua and
Barbuda, Argentina, Armenia, The Bahamas, Bangladesh, Belarus, Belize, Benin, Bhutan, Bolivia, Bosnia and Herzegovina,
Bulgaria, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cabo Verde, Cambodia, Cameroon, Chile, Colombia, Comoros, Democratic Republic of
the Congo, Costa Rica, Côte d'Ivoire, Djibouti, Dominica, Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Eritrea, Ethiopia, The Gambia,
Georgia, Ghana, Grenada, Guatemala, Guinea, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Hungary, Indonesia, Jamaica, Kenya, Kiribati,
Kosovo, Kyrgyz Republic, Lao P.D.R., Latvia, Lesotho, Liberia, Lithuania, FYR Macedonia, Madagascar, Malawi, Maldives,
Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius, Mexico, Moldova, Montenegro, Morocco, Mozambique, Myanmar, Namibia, Nepal, Niger,
Panama, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Romania, Rwanda, Samoa, São Tomé and Príncipe, Senegal,
Serbia, Sierra Leone, Solomon Islands, South Sudan, Sri Lanka, St. Kitts and Nevis, St. Lucia, Sudan, Suriname,
Swaziland, Tajikistan, Tanzania, Thailand, Tonga, Tunisia, Turkey, Tuvalu, Uganda, Ukraine, Vanuatu, Vietnam, Zambia,
Zimbabwe.

the next five years. The decline in growth in emerg- domestic demand as well as the real depreciation. On
ing market economies would be partly cushioned by the other hand, advanced economies would see a sizable
stronger net exports, and their current account balances deterioration in current account balances, given weaker
would improve substantially, reflecting the weakness in external demand and stronger currencies.

26 International Monetary Fund | October 2015


CHAPTER 1   Recent Developments and Prospects

as large-scale asset purchases, but also negative policy their fiscal targets. In general, all countries should
rates where effective). It is important, however, that pursue growth-friendly fiscal rebalancing that lowers
the overall policy mix be supportive. Monetary policy marginal taxes on labor and capital, financed by cuts
efforts should be accompanied by efforts to strengthen to unproductive spending or measures to broaden
balance sheets and the credit supply channel, and by the tax base. Swift implementation of investments
the active use of macroprudential policies to address related to the European Fund for Strategic Invest-
financial stability risks. Complementary fiscal policy ments could help support the recovery, particularly
action in countries with fiscal space is also important, in countries with limited fiscal space.
supporting global rebalancing, and demand-­supporting In Japan, near-term prospects for economic activity
structural reforms are necessary, in particular to have weakened, while medium-term inflation expecta-
improve productivity and stimulate investment. Man- tions are stuck substantially below the 2 percent infla-
aging high public debt in a low-growth and low-infla- tion target. At the same time, potential output growth
tion environment also remains a key challenge in many remains low.
advanced economies. Nominal income growth contrib- •• On the monetary policy front, the Bank of Japan
utes little to reducing debt ratios in this environment, should stand ready for further easing, preferably by
and fiscal consolidation would be the main means for extending purchases under its quantitative and qual-
achieving more sustainable public debt levels. But if itative monetary easing program to longer-maturity
the pace of consolidation is not attuned to the strength assets. It should also consider providing stronger
of the economic conditions, it risks lowering growth guidance to markets by moving to more forecast-
and putting downward pressure on prices, thereby oriented monetary policy communication. This
offsetting the direct positive effect of consolidation on would increase the transparency of its assessment
debt ratios. of inflation prospects and signal its commitment to
Within these broad contours, challenges differ con- the country’s inflation target, mainly through the
siderably across countries. discussion of envisaged policy changes if inflation is
In the euro area, the pickup in activity is welcome, not on track.
but the recovery remains modest and uneven. Output •• On the fiscal front, the announced medium-term
gaps are still sizable, and projections suggest that euro- fiscal consolidation plan provides a useful anchor
area-wide inflation will remain below target into the to guide fiscal policy. Japan should aim to put debt
medium term. Hence, ensuring a stronger euro-area- on a downward path, based on realistic economic
wide recovery must remain a priority, helping global assumptions, and specific structural revenue and
rebalancing and with positive spillovers through trade expenditure measures should be identified up front.
and financial channels. In the United States, conditions for further job
•• On the monetary policy front, the European Central creation and improvement in labor market conditions
Bank’s expanded asset purchase program has boosted remain in place, notwithstanding lower productivity
confidence and eased financial conditions. These growth and the less favorable prospects for exports in
monetary policy efforts must continue and should light of the sharp dollar appreciation.
be supported by measures to strengthen bank bal- •• On the monetary policy front, the main near-term
ance sheets, which would help improve monetary policy issue is the appropriate timing and pace of
policy transmission and credit market conditions. monetary policy normalization. The Federal Open
Stricter supervision of nonperforming loans and Market Committee’s decisions should remain data
measures to improve insolvency and foreclosure dependent, with the first increase in the federal
procedures are a priority in this regard. funds rate waiting until there are firmer signs of
•• On the fiscal policy front, countries should adhere inflation rising steadily toward the Federal Reserve’s
to their commitments under the Stability and 2 percent medium-term inflation objective, with
Growth Pact. Nevertheless, countries with fiscal continued strength in the labor market. At present a
space, notably Germany and the Netherlands, could broad range of indicators suggest a notable improve-
do more to encourage growth, especially by under- ment in the labor market, but there is little evidence
taking much-needed infrastructure investment and of accelerating wage and price pressures. Regard-
supporting structural reforms. Countries without less of the timing of the initial policy move, the
fiscal space should continue to reduce debt and meet data would suggest that the pace of subsequent rate

International Monetary Fund | October 2015 27


WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: ADJUSTING TO LOWER COMMODITY PRICES

increases should be gradual. An effective monetary •• In a number of advanced economies (including


policy communication strategy will remain essential, several countries in the euro area as well as the
particularly in an environment of higher financial United States), there is a strong case for greater
market volatility in which spillovers through finan- infrastructure investment. In addition to boosting
cial channels could be material. medium-term potential output, partly by making
•• On the fiscal policy front, the priority remains to private investment more efficient, such investment
agree on a medium-term fiscal consolidation plan would also provide much-needed short-term support
to prepare for rising aging-related fiscal costs, while to domestic demand in some of these economies.
avoiding disruptive changes to the fiscal stance in •• In euro area economies, lowering barriers to entry in
the short term because of political gridlock. A cred- product markets and reforming labor market regula-
ible medium-term fiscal plan will need to include tions that hamper adjustment are critical. In debtor
higher tax revenue. economies, these changes would strengthen external
competitiveness and help sustain gains in external
Structural Reforms adjustment while economies recover, whereas in
Potential output growth in advanced economies creditor economies, they would primarily strengthen
is expected to remain weak compared with precrisis investment and employment. Further progress
standards. The main reasons for the subdued forecast should also be made in implementing the European
are population aging, which underlies the projected Union Services Directive, advancing free-trade agree-
low growth and possible decline in trend employment ments, and integrating capital and energy markets,
under current policies affecting labor force participa- which could raise productivity. And as mentioned
tion, and weak productivity growth. A first priority for earlier, reforms tackling legacy debt overhang (for
structural policies therefore is to strengthen both labor instance, through resolving nonperforming loans,
force participation and trend employment. facilitating out-of-court settlement, and improving
•• In Japan, removing tax disincentives and raising the insolvency frameworks) would help credit demand
availability of child care facilities through deregula- and supply recover.
tion would help to boost female labor force partici- •• In Japan, more forceful structural reforms (the
pation further. Increasing reliance on foreign labor third arrow of Abenomics) should be the priority.
and providing incentives for older workers to remain Measures to increase labor force participation are
in the workforce should also help in avoiding essential, as previously discussed, but there is also
declines in trend employment. scope for raising productivity in the services sector
•• In the euro area, where structural, long-term, and through deregulation, invigorating labor productiv-
youth unemployment are high in many economies, ity by reducing labor market duality, and supporting
an important concern is skill erosion and its effect on investment through corporate governance reform as
trend employment. In addition to macroeconomic well as improvements to the provision of risk capital
policies to boost demand, priorities include lower by the financial system.
disincentives to employment—among them lowering
the labor tax wedge—as well as better-targeted train-
ing programs and active labor market policies. Policies to Foster Growth and Manage Vulnerabilities in
•• In the United States, expanding the earned income Emerging Market and Developing Economies
tax credit, better family benefits (including child Policymakers in emerging market economies face the
care assistance), and immigration reform would help challenge of dealing with slowing growth, more difficult
boost labor supply. external conditions, and increased vulnerabilities after
Increasing productivity growth through structural a decade or so of buoyant growth. While the resilience
policies is challenging. But a number of high-priority to external shocks has increased in many emerging
structural measures would likely boost productivity market economies because of increased exchange rate
through their direct or indirect effects on investment flexibility, higher foreign exchange reserves, more robust
(as new technology is embodied in new capital) and external financing patterns, and generally stronger policy
through the effects of labor market reforms on incen- frameworks, there are a number of important policy
tives for learning and human capital development. challenges and trade-offs to consider.

28 International Monetary Fund | October 2015


CHAPTER 1   Recent Developments and Prospects

•• The extent of economic slack might be small despite In some countries, this may require strengthening
the growth slowdown. An important consideration the credibility of monetary and fiscal policy frame-
for the calibration of macroeconomic policies is works, while balance sheet exposures to foreign
the degree of economic slack. The latter might exchange risks need to remain manageable. The
be smaller than the sizable growth slowdown latter calls for enforcing or (if needed) strengthen-
since 2011 in many emerging market economies ing prudential regulation and supervision as well as
might suggest. The reason is that the growth slow- adequate macroprudential frameworks.
down partly reflects a cyclical return to potential •• Increased vulnerabilities might also introduce fiscal pol-
output after overheating in broad credit and invest- icy trade-offs. Public debt ratios are relatively low in
ment booms, driven by factors such as increasing a number of emerging market economies, although
commodity prices and easing financial conditions budget deficits generally remain above precrisis
for emerging market economies.11 In addition, ratios despite the strong recovery after the global
as discussed in Chapter 2, in countries where the financial crisis. Fiscal easing could support demand
growth slowdown has been partly driven by lower when output gaps are large and monetary policy is
commodity prices, potential output growth is likely constrained, but it would also increase vulnerabili-
to have declined as well and might decrease further, ties in the current context, mostly because of risks of
given the weaker commodity price outlook. The higher country risk premiums in the broader context
evidence of slowing productivity growth in major of capital flow reversal risks. In economies with
emerging market economies in recent years adds to preexisting fiscal vulnerabilities, the fiscal space is
these concerns.12 thus likely to be limited. In addition, in economies
•• Monetary conditions have eased with exchange rate with downward revisions to medium-term growth
depreciation, but vulnerabilities might limit the scope prospects, fiscal policy might have to adjust to lower
for monetary easing. Amid greater exchange rate flex- fiscal revenue at full employment, a first-order issue
ibility, substantial currency depreciation in real effec- notably in commodity exporters, given commodity
tive terms in many emerging market economies has price declines.
contributed to easier monetary conditions. Whether Beyond the common context, policy considerations
economic conditions also call for monetary policy for net commodity exporters generally differ from those
easing raises difficult trade-offs. Real policy rates are for net commodity importers.
already below natural rates in many economies, and •• In many net commodity importers, lower com-
lowering rates could trigger sizable further deprecia- modity prices have alleviated inflation pressure and
tion. This could increase financial stability risks, reduced external vulnerabilities with the terms-of-
given higher corporate leverage and balance sheet trade windfall gains. The trade-off between sup-
exposure to foreign-currency risks in many emerging porting demand if there is economic slack and
market economies (as analyzed in Chapter 3 of the reducing macroeconomic vulnerabilities has become
October 2015 GFSR). Moreover, if monetary policy less pronounced as a result. In some importers with
frameworks lack credibility or policy credibility commodity-related subsidies, the windfall gains
is strained, the concern is that depreciation could from lower oil prices have been used to increase
also lead to persistently higher prices and pressure public sector savings and strengthen fiscal positions.
for further exchange rate depreciation, a particular Whether the improved fiscal policy space should be
worry when inflation is already above target. used depends on the extent of economic slack, the
•• The likelihood of further currency depreciation in strength of the economy’s fiscal position, and the
emerging market economies may require stronger need for structural reforms or growth-enhancing
regulatory and macroprudential frameworks. Emerg- spending (on, for example, infrastructure).
ing market and developing economies not relying •• In commodity exporters, fiscal positions have dete-
on exchange rate pegs have to be ready to allow the riorated and external and fiscal vulnerabilities have
exchange rate to respond to adverse external shocks. increased. The urgency to adjust policies varies con-
siderably, depending on fiscal buffers. Exporters with
11See Box 1.2 of the October 2013 WEO. buffers can afford to adjust government spending
12See Chapter 3 of the April 2015 WEO. gradually to avoid exacerbating the slowdown. Nev-

International Monetary Fund | October 2015 29


WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: ADJUSTING TO LOWER COMMODITY PRICES

ertheless, with some of the commodity price decline tion to decline to the inflation target in the medium
expected to be permanent, it will be important to term, given upside risks to inflation. Continued fiscal
assess the revenue implications and plan for fiscal consolidation is also essential, but it should be more
adjustment. In exporters with limited policy space, growth friendly (tax reform, reduction in subsidies).
allowing substantial exchange rate depreciation will With balance sheet strains in the corporate and
be the main avenue available to cushion the impact banking sectors, financial sector regulation should be
of the commodity price shock on their economies. enhanced, provisioning increased, and debt recovery
As discussed in the October 2015 Fiscal Monitor, strengthened. Structural reforms should focus on relax-
the weaker commodity price outlook also highlights ing long-standing supply constraints in the energy,
that in some commodity exporters, fiscal policy mining, and power sectors. Priorities include market-
frameworks might need to be upgraded to factor in based pricing of natural resources to boost investment,
commodity-market-related uncertainty and to provide addressing delays in the implementation of infrastruc-
a longer-term anchor to guide policy decisions. ture projects, and improving policy frameworks in the
Turning to policy requirements in large emerging power and mining sectors.
market economies, policymakers in China face the Several years of downgraded medium-term growth
challenge of simultaneously achieving three objectives: prospects suggest that it is also time for major emerg-
avoiding a sharp growth slowdown in the transi- ing market economies to turn to important structural
tion to more sustainable patterns of growth, reduc- reforms to raise productivity and growth in a lasting
ing vulnerabilities from excess leverage after a credit way. Although the slowing in estimated total factor pro-
and investment boom, and strengthening the role of ductivity growth in major emerging market economies
market forces in the economy. Modest further policy is partly a natural implication of recent progress in con-
support to ensure that growth does not fall sharply vergence, as discussed in Chapter 3 of the April 2015
is likely to be needed, but further progress in imple- WEO, the concern is that potential output growth has
menting the authorities’ structural reforms will be become too dependent on factor accumulation in some
critical for private consumption to pick up some of economies. The structural reform agenda naturally dif-
the slack from slowing investment growth. The core fers across countries, but it includes removing infrastruc-
of the reforms is to give market mechanisms a more ture bottlenecks in the power sector (India, Indonesia,
decisive role in the economy, eliminate distortions, South Africa); easing limits on trade and investment and
and strengthen institutions. Examples include financial improving business conditions (Brazil, Indonesia, Rus-
sector reforms to strengthen regulation and supervi- sia); and implementing reforms to education, labor, and
sion, liberalize deposit rates, increase the reliance on product markets to raise competitiveness and productiv-
interest rates as an instrument of monetary policy, and ity (Brazil, China, India, South Africa) and government
eliminate widespread implicit guarantees; fiscal and services delivery (South Africa).
social security reforms; and reforms of state-owned
enterprises, including leveling the playing field between
the public and private sectors. The recent change in Policies in Low-Income Countries
China’s exchange rate system provides the basis for Growth in low-income countries as a group
a more market-determined exchange rate, but much has stayed high while growth in emerging market
depends on implementation. A floating exchange rate economies has weakened. But with weak activity in
will enhance monetary policy autonomy and help the advanced economies, a slowdown in emerging market
economy adjust to external shocks, as China contin- economies, and lower commodity prices, low-income
ues to become more integrated into both the global countries’ growth prospects for 2015 and beyond have
economy and global financial markets. been revised downward. In addition, greater access to
In India, near-term growth prospects remain favor- foreign-market financing has increased some low-
able, and the decrease in the current account deficit income countries’ exposure to a possible tightening in
has lowered external vulnerabilities. The faster-than- global financial conditions.
expected decline in inflation has created space for Policies must respond to the increased challenges
considering modest cuts in the nominal policy rate, and vulnerabilities. In some countries, fiscal posi-
but the real policy rate needs to remain tight for infla- tions must be improved against the backdrop of lower

30 International Monetary Fund | October 2015

You might also like