You are on page 1of 5

Pareto Law in a Kinetic Model of Market with Random Saving Propensity

Arnab Chatterjee,1, ∗ Bikas K. Chakrabarti,1 and S. S. Manna2


1
Saha Institute of Nuclear Physics, Block-AF, Sector-I Bidhannagar, Kolkata-700064, India.
2
Satyendra Nath Bose National Centre for Basic Sciences Block-JD, Sector-III, Salt Lake, Kolkata-700098, India.
arXiv:cond-mat/0301289v3 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 27 Jan 2004

We have numerically simulated the ideal-gas models of trading markets, where each agent is
identified with a gas molecule and each trading as an elastic or money-conserving two-body colli-
sion. Unlike in the ideal gas, we introduce (quenched) saving propensity of the agents, distributed
widely between the agents (0 ≤ λ < 1). The system remarkably self-organizes to a critical Pareto
distribution of money P (m) ∼ m−(ν+1) with ν ≃ 1. We analyse the robustness (universality) of
the distribution in the model. We also argue that although the fractional saving ingredient is a
bit unnatural one in the context of gas models, our model is the simplest so far, showing self-
organized criticality, and combines two century-old distributions: Gibbs (1901) and Pareto (1897)
distributions.

PACS numbers: 87.23.Ge;89.90.+n;02.50.-r

Considerable investigations have already been made to N is fixed. No production or migration occurs and the
study the nature of income or wealth distributions in only economic activity is confined to trading. Each agent
various economic communities, in particular, in differ- i, individual or corporate, possess money mi (t) at time
ent countries. For more than a hundred years, it is t. In any trading, a pair of traders i and j randomly
known that the probability distribution P (m) for income exchange their money [5, 7, 11], such that their total
or wealth of the individuals in the market decreases with money is (locally) conserved and none end up with neg-
the wealth m following a power law, known as Pareto law ative money (mi (t) ≥ 0, i.e, debt not allowed):
[1]:
mi (t) + mj (t) = mi (t + 1) + mj (t + 1); (2)
P (m) ∝ m−(1+ν) , (1)
time (t) changes by one unit after each trading. The
steady-state (t → ∞) distribution of money is Gibbs one:
where the value of the exponent ν is found to lie be-
tween 1 and 2 [2, 3, 4]. It is also known that typically
less than 10% of the population in any country possesses
P (m) = (1/T ) exp(−m/T ); T = M/N. (3)
about 40% of the wealth and follow the above power law.
The rest of the low-income group population, in fact the Hence, no matter how uniform or justified the initial
majority, clearly follows a different law, identified very distribution is, the eventual steady state corresponds to
recently to be the Gibbs distribution [5, 6, 7]. Studies Gibbs distribution where most of the people have got
on real data show that the high income group indeed fol- very little money. This follows from the conservation of
low Pareto law, with ν varying from 1.6 for USA [6], to money and additivity of entropy:
1.8 − 2.2 in Japan [3]. The value of ν thus seem to vary
a little from economy to economy. P (m1 )P (m2 ) = P (m1 + m2 ). (4)
We have studied here numerically a gas model of a
trading market. We have considered the effect of saving This steady state result is quite robust and realistic too!
propensity of the traders. The saving propensity is as- In fact, several variations of the trading, and of the ‘lat-
sumed to have a randomness. Our observations indicate tice’ (on which the agents can be put and each agent
that Gibbs and Pareto distributions fall in the same cat- trade with its ‘lattice neighbors’ only), whether compact,
egory and can appear naturally in the century-old and fractal or small-world like [2], leaves the distribution un-
well-established kinetic theory of gas [8]: Gibbs distribu- changed. Some other variations like random sharing of
tion for no saving and Pareto distribution for agents with an amount 2m2 only (not of m1 + m2 ) when m1 > m2
quenched random saving propensity. Our model study (trading at the level of lower economic class in the trade),
also indicates the appearance of self-organized criticality lead to even drastic situation: all the money in the mar-
[9] in the simplest model so far, namely in the kinetic ket drifts to one agent and the rest become truely pauper
theory of gas models, when the stability effect of savings [12, 13].
[10] is incorporated. In any trading, savings come naturally [10]. A saving
We consider an ideal-gas model of a closed economic propensity factor λ is therefore introduced in the same
system where total money M and total number of agents model [7] (see [11] for model without savings), where each
trader at time t saves a fraction λ of its money mi (t) and
trades randomly with the rest:
∗ Electronic address: arnab@cmp.saha.ernet.in mi (t + 1) = mi (t) + ∆m; mj (t + 1) = mj (t) − ∆m (5)
2

where (white) within an interval 0 to 1 (see [15] for preliminary


results): agent i saves a random fraction λi (0 ≤ λi < 1)
∆m = (1 − λ)[ǫ{mi (t) + mj (t)} − mi (t)], (6) and this λi value is quenched for each agent (λi are in-
dependent of trading or t). Starting with an arbitrary
ǫ being a random fraction, coming from the stochastic initial (uniform or random) distribution of money among
nature of the trading. the agents, the market evolves with the tradings. At each
The market (non-interacting at λ = 0 and 1) becomes time, two agents are randomly selected and the money
‘interacting’ for any non-vanishing λ(< 1): For fixed λ exchange among them occurs, following the above men-
(same for all agents), the steady state distribution Pf (m) tioned scheme. We check for the steady state, by looking
of money is exponentially decaying on both sides with at the stability of the money distribution in successive
the most-probable money per agent shifting away from Monte Carlo steps t. Eventually, after a typical relax-
m = 0 (for λ = 0) to M/N as λ → 1 (Fig. 1(a)). ation time (∼ 105 for N = 200 and uniformly distributed
This self-organizing feature of the market, induced by λ) dependent on N and the distribution of λ, the money
sheer self-interest of saving by each agent without any distribution becomes stationary. After this, we average
global perspective, is quite significant as the fraction of the money distribution over ∼ 103 time steps. Finally
paupers decrease with saving fraction λ and most peo- we take configurational average over ∼ 105 realizations
ple end up with some fraction of the average money in of the λ distribution to get the money distribution P (m).
the market (for λ → 1, the socialists’ dream is achieved It is found to follow a strict power-law decay. This de-
with just people’s self-interest of saving!). Interestingly, cay fits to Pareto law (1) with ν = 1.02 ± 0.02 (Fig. 2).
self-organisation also occurs in such market models when Note, for finite size N of the market, the distribution has
there is restriction in the commodity market [14]. Al- a narrow initial growth upto a most-probable value mp
though this fixed saving propensity does not give yet the after which it falls off with a power-law tail for several
Pareto-like power-law distribution, the Markovian na- decades. As can be seen from the inset of Fig. 2, this
ture of the scattering or trading processes (eqn. (4)) Pareto law (with ν ≃ 1) covers the entire range in m of
is lost and the system becomes co-operative. Indirectly the distribution P (m) in the limit N → ∞. We checked
through λ, the agents get to know (start interacting with) that this power law is extremely robust: apart from the
each other and the system co-operatively self-organises uniform λ distribution used in the simulations in Fig. 2,
towards a most-probable distribution (mp 6= 0). we also checked the results for a distribution

2.5 2.5
ρ(λ) ∼ |λ0 − λ|α , λ0 6= 1, 0 < λ < 1, (8)
(a) λ = 0.6 6
λ=0 λ = 0.8
2.0 2 of quenched λ values among the agents. The Pareto law
Pf /(1-λ)

λ = 0.5 λ = 0.9 4
λ = 0.9 with ν = 1 is universal for all α. The data in Fig. 2
~

1.5 1.5 2
corresponds to λ0 = 0, α = 0. For negative α values,
Pf(m)

Pf(m)

0
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 however, we get an initial (small m) Gibbs-like decay in
~

1.0 1 m (1-λ)
P (m) (see Fig. 3).
(b)
0.5 0.5

0.0 0
0 1 2 3 0 1 2 3 0
m m 10
mp M/N=1

FIG.1: Steady state money distribution (a) Pf (m) for the fixed N = 1000
10
-2 0.1 1 + ν = 2.0
(same for all agents) λ model, and (b) P˜f (m) for some typical
values of λ in the distributed λ model. The data is collected from
the ensembles with N = 200 agents. The inset in (b) shows the
P(m)

scaling behavior of P˜f (m). For all cases, agents start with average 10
-4
mp

0.07
money per agent M/N = 1.

In a real society or economy, λ is a very inhomogeneous -6


10
parameter: the interest of saving varies from person to 0.05
0.001 0.01
person. We move a step closer to the real situation where N
-1

saving factor λ is widely distributed within the popula- 10


-8
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3
tion. One again follows the same trading rules as before, 10 10 10 10
m
10 10 10
except that

∆m = ǫ(1 − λj )mj (t) − (1 − λi )(1 − ǫ)mi (t) (7) FIG.2: Steady state money distribution P (m) in the model for
distributed λ (0 ≤ λ < 1) for N = 1000 agents. Inset shows that
the most probable peak mp shifts towards 0 (indicating the same
here; λi and λj being the saving propensities of agents i power law for the entire range of m) as N → ∞: results for four
and j. The agents have fixed (over time) saving propensi- typical system sizes N = 100, 200, 500, 1000 are shown. For all
ties, distributed independently, randomly and uniformly cases, agents play with average money per agent M/N = 1.
3

10
0 (a) λ=0 4 (d) λ = 0.1
α = − 0.7 8
α = − 0.3 3
α = + 0.3 mi(t) mi(t)
α = + 0.7 4
2
-2 1+ν=2
-2 10 1
10
0 0
(b) λ = 0.5 4 (e) λ = 0.5
P(m)

10
-3 8
3
-4 mi(t) mi(t)
10 2
4
-4 1
10
0 0
(c) λ = 0.9 4 (f) λ = 0.9
-6
10 -5
8
3
10 1
10 mi(t) mi(t)
2
-2 -1 0 1 2 4
10 10 10 10 10 1
m
0 0
0 5000 10000 0 5000 10000
t t

FIG.3: Steady state money distribution P (m) in the model for FIG.4: Money of the i-th trader with time. For fixed λ for all
N = 100 agents with λ distributed as ρ(λ) ∼ λα with different agents in the market: (a) with λ = 0, (b) λ = 0.5, (c) λ = 0.9.
values of α. The inset shows the region of validity of Pareto law For distributed λ (0 ≤ λ < 1): for agents with (d) λ = 0.1, (e)
with 1 + ν = 2. For all cases, agents play with average money per λ = 0.5 and (f) λ = 0.9 in the market. All data are for N = 200
agent M/N = 1. (M/N = 1).

In case of uniform distribution of saving propensity λ


(0 ≤ λ < 1), the individual money distribution P˜f (m) 10
0

for agents with any particular λ value, although differs (a)


considerably, remains non-monotonic: similar to that for -2
fixed λ market with mp (λ) shifting with λ (see Fig. 1). 10
0 < λ < 0.5
P(m)

Few subtle points may be noted though: while for fixed 0.5 < λ < 1.0
-4
λ the mp (λ) were all less than of the order of unity (Fig. 10
1(a)), for distributed λ case mp (λ) can be considerably
larger and can approach to the order of N for large λ 10
-6

(see Fig. 1(b)). The other important difference is in the


scaling behavior of P˜f (m), as shown in the inset of Fig. 10
0
0.2 < λ < 0.4
1(b). In the distributed λ ensemble, P˜f (m) appears to 0.75 < λ < 0.95
0.8 < λ < 1.0
have a very simple scaling: 10
-2
P(m)

-4
10

P̃f (m) ∼ (1 − λ)F (m(1 − λ)), (9) 10


-6
(b)
-8
10 -2 -1 0 1 2
10 10 10 10 10
m
FIG.5: Money distribution in cases where saving propensity λ is
for λ → 1, where the scaling function F (x) has non- distributed uniformly within a range of values: (a) When width
monotonic variation in x. The fixed (same for all agents) of λ distribution is 0.5, money distribution shows power-law for
λ income distribution Pf (m) do not have any such com- 0.5 < λ < 1.0; (b) When width of λ distribution is 0.2, money
parative scaling property. It may be noted that a small distribution starts showing power-law when 0.7 < λ < 0.9. Note,
the exponent ν ≃ 1 in all these cases when the power law is seen.
difference exists between
R the ensembles considered in Fig All data are for N = 100 (M/N = 1).
1(a) and 1(b): while mPf (m)dm = M (independent
R
of λ), mP˜f (m)dm is not a constant and infact ap- We now investigate on the range of distribution of the
proaches to order of M as λ → 1. There is also a marked saving propensities in a certain interval a < λi < b,
qualitative difference in fluctuations (see Fig. 4): while where, 0 < a < b < 1. For uniform distribution within
for fixed λ, the fluctuations in time (around the most- the range, we observe the appearance of the same power
probable value) in the individuals’ money mi (t) gradually law in the distribution but for a narrower region. As may
decreases with increasing λ, for quenched distribution of be seen from Fig. 5, as a → b, the power-law behavior is
λ, the trend gets reversed (see Fig. 4). seen for values a or b approaching more and more towards
4

unity: For the same width of the interval |b − a|, one gets and USA in recent years is quite intriguing. In fact, for
power-law (with same ν) when b → 1. This indicates, negative α values in (8), the density of traders with low
for fixed λ, λ = 0 corresponds to Gibbs distribution, and saving propensity is higher and since λ = 0 ensemble
one gets Pareto law when λ has got non-zero width of yields Gibbs-like income distribution (3), we see an ini-
its distribution extending upto λ = 1. This of course tial Gibbs-like distribution which crosses over to Pareto
indicates a crucial role of these high saving propensity distribution (1) with ν = 1.0 for large m values. The po-
agents: the power law behavior is truely valid upto the sition of the crossover point depends on the magnitude of
asymptotic limit if λ = 1 is included. Indeed, had we α. The important point to note is that any distribution
assumed λ0 = 1 in (8), the Pareto exponent ν immedi- of λ near λ = 1, of finite width, eventually gives Pareto
ately switches over to ν = 1 + α. Of course, λ0 6= 1 law for large m limit. The same kind of crossover behav-
in (8) leads to the universality of the Pareto distribu- ior (from Gibbs to Pareto) can also be reproduced in a
tion with ν = 1 (independent of λ0 and α). Indeed this model market of mixed agents where λ = 0 for a finite
can be easily rationalised from the scaling behavior (9): fraction of population and λ is distributed uniformly over
R1
P (m) ∼ 0 P˜f (m)ρ(λ)dλ ∼ m−2 for ρ(λ) given by (8) a finite range near λ = 1 for the rest of the population.
and m−(2+α) if λ0 = 1 in (8) (for large m values). We also considered annealed randomness in the saving
propensity λ: here λi for any agent i changes from one
Income m (in thousand dollars) value to another within the range 0 ≤ λi < 1, after each
10
0
0 1
10 10
2 3
10 trading. Numerical studies for this annealed model did
10 not show any power law behavior for P (m); rather it
Gibbs again becomes exponentially decaying on both sides of a
most-probable value.
-2
10 USA We have numerically simulated here ideal-gas like mod-
ν = 1.6
Cumulative Probability Q(m)

Japan els of trading markets, where each agent is identified with


a gas molecule and each trading as an elastic or money-
10
-4
0
Pareto conserving two-body collision. Unlike in the ideal gas,
10
we introduce (quenched) saving propensity of the agents,
distributed widely between the agents (0 ≤ λ < 1). For
10
-6 ν = 2.0 quenched random variation of λ among the agents the
Q(m)

-3
10 system remarkably self-organizes to a critical Pareto dis-
M/N = 1, α = - 0.7 tribution (1) of money with ν ≃ 1.0 (Fig. 2). The ex-
-8 N = 1000 ponent is quite robust: for savings distribution ρ(λ) ∼
10
-6
|λ0 − λ|α , λ0 6= 1, one gets the same Pareto law with
10
10
-2
10
0
10
2 ν = 1 (independent of λ0 or α). It may be noted that
m the trading market model we have talked about here has
-10
10 3 4 5 6 got some apparent limitations. The stochastic nature of
10 10 10 10
Income m (in thousand yens) trading assumed here in the trading market, through the
random fraction ǫ in (6), is of course not very straightfor-
R∞ ward as agents apparently go for trading with some def-
FIG.6: Cumulative distribution Q(m) = m P (m)dm of wealth
m in USA [6] in 1997 and Japan [3] in 2000. Low-income group inite purpose (utility maximization of both money and
follow Gibbs law (shaded region) and the rest (about 5%) of the commodity). We are however, looking only at the money
rich population follow Pareto law. The inset shows the cumulative transactions between the traders. In this sense, the in-
distribution for a model market where the saving propensity of the
agents is distributed following (8) with λ0 = 0 and α = −0.7. The
come distribution we study here essentially corresponds
dotted line (for large m values) corresponds to ν = 1.0. to ‘paper money’, and not the ‘real wealth’. However,
These model income distributions P (m) compare very even taking money and commodity together, one can ar-
well with the wealth distributions of various countries: gue (see [13]) for the same stochastic nature of the trad-
Data suggests Gibbs like distribution in the low-income ings, due to the absence of ‘just pricing’ and the effects
range [6] (more than 90% of the population) and Pareto- of bargains in the market.
like in the high-income range [3] (less than 10% of the Apart from the intriguing observation that Gibbs
population) of various countries (Fig. 6). In fact, we (1901) and Pareto (1897) distributions fall in the same
have compared one model simulation of the market with category and can appear naturally in the century-old and
saving propensity of the agents distributed following (8), well-established kinetic theory of gas, that this model
with λ0 = 0 and α = −0.7. This model result is shown study indicates the appearance of self-organized critical-
in the inset of Fig. 6. The qualitative resemblance of the ity in the simplest (gas) model so far, when the stability
model income distribution with the real data for Japan effect of savings incorporated, is remarkable.

[1] V. Pareto, Le Cours d’Economique Politique, Lausanne [2] S. Moss de Oliveira, P. M. C. de Oliveira and D. Stauffer,
& Paris, (1897).
5

Evolution, Money, War and Computers, B. G. Tuebner, ford, (1997).


Stuttgart-Leipzig (1999). [10] P. A. Samuelson, Economics Mc-Graw Hill Int., Auck-
[3] Y. Fujiwara, W. Souma, H. Aoyama, T. Kaizoji, and M. land, (1980).
Aoki, Physica A 321 598 (2003). [11] A. A. Dragulescu and V. M. Yakovenko, Eur. Phys.
[4] M. Levy and S. Solomon, Physica A 242 90 (1997). J. B 17 723 (2000); S. Ispolatov, P. L. Krapivsky, S.
[5] B. K. Chakrabarti, and S. Marjit, Ind. J. Phys. B 69 681 Redner, Eur. Phys. J. B 2 267 (1998); J. C. Ferrero,
(1995). cond-mat/0306322; F. Slanina, cond-mat/0311235.
[6] A. A. Dragulescu and V. M. Yakovenko, Physica [12] A Chakraborti , Int. J. Mod. Phys. C 13 1315 (2002).
A 299 213 (2001); ibid in “Modeling of Complex [13] B. Hayes , Am. Scientist, 90 400 (Sept-Oct, 2002).
Systems: Seventh Granada Lectures”, AIP Confer- [14] A. Chakraborti, S. Pradhan, B. K. Chakrabarti, Physica
ence Proceedings 661, New York, 2003, pp. 180-183 A 297 253 (2001).
(http://www.lanl.gov/abs/cond-mat/0211175 and [15] B. K. Chakrabarti and A. Chatterjee in Application
http://proceedings.aip.org/proceedings/confproceed/661.jsp). of Econophysics: Proc. 2nd Nikkei Econophys. Symp.
[7] A. Chakraborti and B. K. Chakrabarti, Eur. Phys. J. B (Tokyo, 2002), ed. H. Takayasu, (Springer, Tokyo, 2004),
17 167 (2000). pp. 280-285; A. Chatterjee, B. K. Chakrabarti and S.
[8] See e.g, L. D. Landau and E. M. Lifshitz, Statistical S. Manna, Phys. Scr. T 106 36 (2003); A. Chatterjee,
Physics, (Pergamon Press, Oxford, 1968). (2002, unpublished).
[9] P. Bak, How Nature works, Oxford University Press, Ox-

You might also like