You are on page 1of 17

MARIO BUNGE

DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS*

(Received 6 May, 1980)

ABSTRACT. This paper discusses some of the methodological problems involved in the
design of indicators of development. To begin with, two kinds of social indicator are
distinguished and defined: descriptive and normative. Unlike the former, the latter
involve value judgments. Secondly, the very notion of development is briefly discussed.
The idea favored by economists, that development is identical with industrialization,
is criticized. It is proposed that genuine development is not only economic but also
biological, cultural, and political, for each of these factors conditions the other three.
The matter of independent vs. dependent development is discussed, to dispel the illusion
that increase in GNP is a faithful development indicator. An indicator of dependence is
introduced. Then a whole battery of development indicators is proposed, some of them
dominant, others weak, some relative, others absolute, some stray, and others systemic.
A case for systemic or theoretical, as opposed to stray or empirical, indicators is made.
Finally some ideas on development dynamics are proposed, as a possible basis for a set of
deeper and more faithful indicators of development.

INTRODUCTION

The construction and use o f social indicators pose a number o f intriguing


methodological problems that the sociologist usually solves along the way in
a more or less tacit and intuitive fashion. Some such problems are: What is an
indicator", What exactly is it we want it to indicate?, Must every indicator be
descriptive or should some indicator be normative?, How are indicators
related to nonobservable variables?, Are indicators definitional or hypothet-
ical?, and How are indicators validated?
The applied social scientist, faced as he is with urgent tasks o f social
significance, has rarely time to deal with methodological issues and cannot
wait for the theoretical sociologist to solve them. This pragmatic attitude is
not only nearly unavoidable but it often works and it may prod the theoreti-
cian. But it is not without dangers. This paper will attempt to show some o f
the dangers lurking behind the use o f insufficiently analyzed development
indicators. It will also make certain constructive proposals. These proposals
concern mainly the introduction o f normative indicators, t h e incorporation
o f indicators o f independence and o f fairness into the set o f development

Sociallndicators Research 9 (1981) 369-385. 0303-8300/81/0093-0369501.70


Copyright 9 1981 by D. Reidel Publishing Co., Dordrecht, Holland, and Boston, U.S.A.
370 MARIO BUNGE

indicators, and the construction of an absolute indicator of overall develop-


ment, i.e. one not dependent upon any particular country taken as a base
line. We shall also emphasize the need for u~ng systemic rather than stray
indicators - which amounts to stressing the need for building deffmite
dynamical models of development involving, among other variables, the
development indicators.

1. D E S C R I P T I V E AND NORMATIVE INDICATORS

Until a few years ago social science proper, in contrast to social philosophy,
tried to keep clear from value judgments and normative or prescriptive
statements. The increasing application of the social sciences to the solution
of social problems, as well as the birth of decision theory, have changed that
attitude. Today there is a tendency to face up to values and norms, rendering
them explicit and keeping them under control instead of just ignoring them
and thereby being at the mercy of tacit valuations and norms. However, this
change does not seem to have penetrated the important field of social indica-
tors: practically all of the work in this field is limited to descriptive indicators.
We shall argue for the need to use both descriptive and normative indicators.
But first a quick characterization of each.
The parameters of an income distribution are descriptive. On the other
hand the parameters of an optimal income distribution are normative. Like-
wise the actual degree of participation in social or political matters, as
indicated e.g. by the percentage of the population taking part in political
decision making, is a descriptive indicator. A corresponding normative
indicator would be the optimal degree of participation ensuring both a fair
distribution of power and an efficient running of the social machine.
There is nothing wrong with a normative indicator, just as there is nothing
wrong with a prescription, whether technological, medical, social or of any
other kind, intending to correct an imbalance of some sort, as long as there
are reasons to believe that the corresponding balance is better than the im-
balance. For one thing a normative indicator can be just as objective as a
descriptive one. Indeed in principle it is possible to determine which value or
values of a variable correspond to the goal or goals agreed on beforehand.
(Think of nutrition indicators.) For another, some of the normative indica-
tors are just maximal (or minimal) values of the corresponding descriptive
indicators. For example, the optimal life expectancy may be taken to be the
one actually attained in Scandinavia.
DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS 371

Of course the construction of normative indicators may present problems -


but so does the construction of descriptive indicators. Let us look into this
matter.

2. T H E C O N S T R U C T I O N O F N O R M A T I V E I N D I C A T O R S . T H E C A S E
OF EQUITY

A first problem posed by the construction of normative indicators is of


course how to decide what the optimal value or values of a variable are. In
principle this problem could be solved rigorously if it were possible to set up
an accurate model of the community in question and moreover a dynamical
model, and preferably a whole family of models enabling one to compare the
effects of choosing different goal values of the variable(s) concerned. But in
practice such models are scanty, so we must resort to less rigorous methods.
Take for instance the determination of the optimal fraction of free leisure
time (as opposed to forced leisure or unemployment). In highly industria-
lized countries the working week could be as low as 24 hrs provided waste
were controlled and a slightly lower standard of living were accepted. On the
other hand in some developing countries twice as long a working week might
not be enough to attain the preset goals. In any case if the goals are formulated
explicitly and the productivity is known, it is possible to compute the
optimal number of working hours per week. This value will depend on the
region concerned and will serve as a development indicator: the more leisure
time the greater the degree of development.
It may of course be rejoined that this method presupposes that the choice
of normative indicators is wholly in the hands of the technocrat, while in
practice it is the people, or else the politicians, or perhaps the big corpora-
tions, that will choose whatever optimizes their own utilities. But this, even
if true, is no argument against the possibility of setting up technically cor-
rect normative indices, i.e. indicator values that are optimal from a technical
point of view even though, for some reason or other, they may not be
accepted by the powers that be.
Once the optimal value, or the optimal distribution, of a variable has been
established the actual construction of the corresponding normative indicator
is straightforward. Thus a possible formula for a normative indicator N con-
sisting in a single number is this:

N= 1 Optimal value - Actual value


max (Optimal, Actual)
372 MARIO BUNGE

If the indicator is a whole distribution of something (e.g. wealth, political


power, or number of schooling years), then the first step is, as indicated, to
establish the optimal distribution of the same variable - call it X. And the
second step is to measure the deviation from the actual distribution of X.
There are two possibilities: either the optimal distribution is symmetrical
or it is not. In the former case the greater the asymmetry the greater the
imbalance or inequity. That is, the inequity in the distribution of X equals
the skewness Sk(X) or, if preferred, its absolute value. (This can in turn be
taken to be Pearson's skewness measure or, what is perhaps more practical,
Yule and Kendall's, which is assigned a value between - 1 and 1 .) If the skew-
ness measure is normalized to unity, then the equity (or equilibrium) in X
can be defined as

Eq(X)= 1 -Sk(X).
Maximal equity corresponds thus to minimal asymmetry in the distribution
and conversely.
If on the other hand the optimal distribution is asymmetrical (as is the
case with longevity and the number of schooling years) then the skewness
value itself, or some linear function of it, may be taken as a measure of
equity.
Finally, in the case of a cumulative distribution (such as a Lorenz curve
of land distribution) one would presumably adopt the Gini index as a
measure of inequality.
I submit, in sum, that it is possible to construct normative indicators.
Moreover I suggest that normative indicators of economic equity, social
balance and cultural opportunity are among the most important develop-
ment indicators.

3. D E V E L O P M E N T : INDUSTRIAL OR INTEGRAL, DEPENDENT OR


INDEPENDENT, UNFAIR OR FAIR

Many a study of development rests on at least one of the following assump-


tions:
(i) Development is the same as industrial growth (or in general moderni-
zation), or at least the overriding variable is the rate of industrialization.
(ii) Whether or not development is attained at the cost of gross inequities
is irrelevant.
DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS 373

(iii) Whether or not development is essentially self reliant (independent)


is immaterial.
So much are these assumptions taken for granted in many studies, that
whereas the fraction of manufactured goods in the GNP is regarded as a
dominant indicator of development, the degree of equity and the degree of
independence are simply ignored. And when the importance of these variables
is pointed out no effort is made to quantify them, so that their discussion
remains at the intuitive or even the ideological level.
I submit that all three presuppositions should be subjected to critical scru-
tiny and moreover that the choice of an alternative set of assumptions need
not throw us into the arms of any unscientific ideology, for it is possible to
fred objective measures of both equity and independence. (For the former
see Section 2, for the latter see the second half of the present section.)
Ad industrialization. After praising industrialization for its own sake, for
over two centuries, we are beginning to realize that industrialization is far
from being good in itself: it is a means and as such it should be controlled.
Suffice it to mention that unbridled industrialization has certain evil side
effects such as pollution, the decay of agriculture, an excessive urban concen-
tration, the disappearance of crafts, and a feeling of anomie and alienation.
To be sure these effects can be brought under control at least to some ex-
tent. But the point is that industrialization, if reckless, can bring about a
disastrous and in some cases irreversible degradation of certain values, whence
a distinctive backward motion of society in a number of important respects.
If these other respects are not taken into account when computing the over-
all degree of development of a society, then an unrealistic result is bound to
be obtained. We need then not only descriptive indicators of industrializa-
tion but also normative indicators telling us what the imbalance (in excess or
in defect) with respect to an optimal value is. Or, if this proves technically
difficult to achieve, then we should include among the development
indicators those concerning the effects of industrialization. It may well turn
out that these effects are largely negative in certain cases, so that their contri-
bution offsets that of industrialization.
Ad equity. If we agree that fairness or equity is a desideratum then we
cannot fail to include it amongst the development indicators. Take again
industrialization. Whereas in some countries it has contributed to equity
in others it has exaggerated the existing inequities to the point of threatening
the stability of the social fabric. Just think of the destruction of the village
374 MARIO BUNGE

society and the corresponding emergence of the shanty town society com-
posed of former peasants hoping to be employed in the industries or in the
services, and leading an almost marginal existence. To discard these and other
effects of industrial growth is to entertain a queer notion of development.
Ad independence. If a country, region, company or any other group
pushes the development of another area for its own benefit, then such a
development is bound to be lopsided or even harmful to the developing
region. Thus, much of what goes under the name of development, when con-
trolled by foreign interests, consists in the sheer plunder of the natural resour-
ces of the developing nation or region. Just as with the case of equity, we
have got to include independence among the development indicators, for an
industrialized colony is not more highly developed than a moderately
industrialized but independent country. But before we can include independ-
ence indicators among the development indicators we must build them. Let
us then proceed to this task.

4. I N D E P E N D E N C E I N D I C A T O R S

The qualitative concept of independence is insufficient, for a country or


region may be independent in some respects and dependent, though perhaps
not entirely, in others. We need a concept of dependence relative to a definite
respect (e.g. f'mances) and one allowing us to compare degrees of dependence,
in a given respect, of various countries or regions. We should, in other words,
be able to say that country A depends upon country B in respect C to degree
D. Thus in the case of financial dependence we may take the ratio: Foreign
investments/Total investments, or D f = FIT for short. Hence the degree of
financial independent would be defined by If--- 1 - F I T . Let us generalize
this notion.
Let P be the set of countries or regions under consideration and R the
set of respects in question (e.g. industrial and cultural). Then for each k in
R there will be a function from the country-country pairs to the real num-
bers in the unit interval, i.e.
/k : exe- [o,1]

such that, for any p and q in P,

Ig (p, q) = 1 - Volume of item k in country p controlled by country q


Total volume of item k in country p
DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS 375

is the degree of independence, in respect k, of country p with respect to


country q.
In some cases the independence indicators are already there and so are the
data necessary to evaluate them. The total fraction of imported manufactured
goods is a case in point. In other cases, such as those of political and cultural
independence, it is not obvious what can be taken to be the volume occurring
in the above formula. However there is no reason to suppose that it is impos-
sible to fred an adequate measure in the cases concerned.
Once the various independence indicators have been adopted and evaluated
we can compute the total degree of independence of each country in any
given respect k:

Finally we may wish to assign each such value a certain weight wk in the
range 0 to 1. This would allow us to compute the overall independence
indicator for each country:

I p ~X~_R wklk(P, q).

An interesting result would probably be that no industrial giant is wholly


independent and that no small country is totally dependent. In other words,
dependence comes in degrees.

5. D O M I N A N T A N D W E A K D E V E L O P M E N T I N D I C A T O R S

It is well known that one of the curses of social science is not the dearth of
empirical data but rather the overload of unimportant and highly correlated
empirical information. (Other curses are the scarcity of good mathematical
models and of good social indicators - both of which go hand in hand.)
Consequently one of the problems in every field of social science is to find
dominant, independent and reliable indicators that will enable one to
dispense with the weaker, dependent and ambiguous ones. Let us take for
example the health indicators.
Both the number of physicians and the number of beds per 1 000 inhab-
itants can be misleading indicators of public health even though they are
valuable in themselves. Indeed if the doctors and hospitals are concentrated in
few and distant towns then they may not give good service. And even if they
are in plenty and well distributed this may indicate either poor health or
376 MARIO BUNGE

affluence or a lack of public sanitary education or poor organization of the


health services or even professional incompetence. So those are poor health
indicators. We should look for better ones.
It so happens that, after all, doctors, hospitals and other health services
are means to keep the population in good health or improve it. And the only
way to gauge the efficiency of such means is to look at the results. In this
case the singly most important result is longevity, for normally only healthy
people live long. Why then not take life expectancy as the main health
indicator? This does not entail discarding the others: they should be kept
in order to know what should be done to improve the life expectancy.
To be sure, life expectancy is not an unambiguous indicator of industrial
growth, as some social scientists have been quick to point out. But if we are
concerned with integral development rather than with just one facet of it
(namely industrialization) then the objection holds no water. No matter how
industrialized a country may be it cannot be regarded as advanced if it has an
abnormally low life expectancy.
The general problem is that of discerning and constructing a subset of
social indicators with the properties of dominance, independence and
reliability. To discover how to go about this task it may help to list some
typical indicators, whether available or desirable, and class them.

6. C A T E G O R I E S OF SOCIAL INDICATORS

A useful partition of the set of social indicators (not just development


indicators) is into the following categories: biological, economic, sociopolitical,
and cultural. We list only a few indicators per category just for purposes ot
illustration. And we mark with a + sign those which prima facie look lik~
good candidates for dominant indicators.
1. Biological indicators
1.1 Family
+ Averagefamily size (counting all relatives living under one roof)
Average number of children per family
Concentration of births in relation to mother's age
1.2 Health
Per capita consumption of proteins
No. of physicians per 1 000 inhabitants
+ Life expectancy
2. Economic indicators
2.1 Production
Per capita GNP
Percentage of manufactured goods in GNP
DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS 377

+ Agricultural and industrial surplusses


2.2 Organization
Percentages of skilled labor force (blue and white collar)
Efficiency of the commercialization net
+ Economic (agricultural, industrial and financial) independence
3. Sociopolitical indicators
3.1 Social
Spontaneous social cohesion
+ Equity of wealth distribution
Fraction of national budget devoted to social services
3.2 Political
+ Popular participation in political and social decision making
Political independence vis ~ vis other countries
Political stability
4. Cultural indicators
4.1 Educational
+ Number of schooling years
Literacy rate
+ Percentage of scientific and technological graduates
4.2 Cultural proper
+ Humanistic output
+ Scientific output
+ Technological output

Most of the indicators in the above list are available. The rest can in principle
be built and evaluated with the help of existing data.
It is of course debatable whether the ones singled out as being possibly
dominant and consequently marked with a + sign are in fact dominant. For
example it might be thought that both political independence and political
stability under heading 3.2 are key indicators. However it may be rejoined
that popular participation subsumes them both, in the sense that the stronger
it is the greater both independence and stability are. But a detailed discussion
of these matters goes beyond the limits of the present study. (See Bunge and
Garcla-Sucre, 1976).
If all the indicators are quantitative and are uniformly normalized, so that
their values lie within the unit interval, their ordering becomes a trivial task.
What is not trivial is, of course, the assignment of relative weights with a view
to constructing an overall indicator of some sort, be it of economic soundness
or of cultural level or of degree of development. We turn next to this problem.

7. O V E R A L L D E V E L O P M E N T I N D I C A T O R S : R E L A T I V E
AND A B S O L U T E

There exists an indicator of overall development, namely Ivanovid's. (See


Unctad 1970, and Unesco 1973.) lvanovid's is a relative overall indicator in
378 MARIO BUNGE

the sense that it takes an arbitrary country as a base line and computes the
degree of development of any given country relative to that country. It might
be of some interest to attempt to construct, in addition, an absolute overall
development indicator, i.e. one not depending upon any particular country
taken as a base line and moreover one assigning different weights to different
indicators, according as they are dominant or not. In the following we sketch
a method for constructing a whole class of overall indicators of this kind.
Let X = {X1, X2 ..... Xn ) be n development indicators defined as so many
functions

Xk : P x T ~ [0, 1]

such that Xk (p, t), for p in P and t in T, is the degree to which the kth
respect has been developed in country p at time t. Furthermore pick the
subset X i of the total set X such that no two members of X i are strongly
correlated. (That is, X i is a set of practically mutually independent indicators.
To build it we must begin by finding the value rpq of the linear correlation
coefficient of every pair (Xp, Xq) of indicators in the original set X. We
assume this statistical job to have been performed.) Suppose the set X i of
independent indicators has m ~<n members. Then the overall degree of
development of country p at time t is defined to be
m
D(p, t) = kZl wk(p, t)Xk(p, t),with ~ w k = 1,

where w k (p, t) is the weight or importance of the kth aspect for country p
at time t.
Note that the weights wg have been assumed to be country and time
dependent, for (a) what is important to one country may not be so to
another, and Co) the same factor may acquire or lose importance as the goals
are attained or recede further away. Note also that those weights are not
related to the degree of statistical independence of the corresponding variables.
The problem of the statistical independence is supposed to have been solved
prior to the selection of the subset X i of independent indicators. The weights
wg are assigned by those who design development plans, not by the statisti-
cian.
Finally suppose we reduce further the set of development indicators by
picking only the dominant ones, i.e. those which, being statistically
independent, have also maximal weight for the country and time in question.
DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS 379

That is, form the subset X a of X i and assume that there are q indicators in
this set. Suppose further that these indicators are all equally important, i.e.
set w s = 1[q for every X, in X a. Then the formula for the overall degree o f
development simplifies to
q
O(p, t) = (l/q) s~=l Xs(p, t), with X s in X a.

It goes without saying that the rate o f overall development is defined by the
time derivative of D:

R(p, t) = dD(p, t)/dt.

These are absolute indicators. But of course they allow one to compare levels
(or rates) of development of different countries. That is, an absolute indicator
gives all the information a relative indicator conveys without introducing any
irrelevant information, namely the one referring to the base line country.

8. I N D I C A T O R S : STRAY AND SYSTEMIC

Lest it be thought that the study of development is restricted to the con-


struction and evaluation of development indicators, let us hasten to recall
that (a) indicators are validated not in isolation from but in conjunction with
definite mathematical models, and (b) mathematical models, if deep, will
contain unobservable variables, such as social differentiation, social cohesion,
economic equilibrium, political power, and cultural level. Such unobservables
cannot be read off directly from statistical yearbooks. But of course they
will not become scientific concepts unless they are somehow linked to ob-
servables or indicators that can be read off or at least computed out of
statistical yearbooks.
Let us emphasize that the unobservable-observable relations (in particular
functions) are hypothetical. They do not consist of arbitrary definitions
although they are sometimes mistakenly dubbed 'operational definitions'.
That is, the deep variable-indicator relations are assumptions that may be true
or false and must therefore be subjected to rational criticism and empirical
test. For example, if it be claimed that the number of newspapers printed
per 1 000 inhabitants is a reliable indicator of cultural level, then it must be
shown that the population in question takes newspapers for the information
they convey rather than, say, not to miss the sales in the department stores.
380 MARIO BUNGE

In sum an indicator is valuable insofar as it indicates a feature that is


not directly observable and insofar as it is part and parcel of a body of
theory. This holds for indicators of molecular weight as well as for develop-
ment indicators. Hence in order to make the most out of development
indicators and validate them we should try and set up full fledged mathematical
models of development rather than resting satisfied with a bunch of correla-
tions and trend lines. It is common knowledge that correlations are often
spurious and trend lines temporary. On the other hand a scientific theory
proper, one including laws and in particular dynamical laws, can tell us
something about development dynamics. It can therefore offer a firm ground
for forecast, where trend lines are insecure extrapolation tools. Let us there-
fore wind up our study by sketching how models of development can be
built.

9. D E V E L O P M E N T KINEMATICS

A kinematical model consists of a set of assumptions, definitions, and


deductive consequences of either, concerning evolving systems of some kind.
Each assumption, definition, or theorem, will in turn be a formula (e.g. an
equation) involving certain variables, each of which will represent some
property of the system concerned.
Since we are interested in developing countries, the referents of our
models will be developing countries. And since we are interested in develop-
ment we must choose only variables that are favorably relevant to develop-
ment. These variables must be 'positive', such as literacy rather than illiteracy
rates, and degree of freedom from parasitosis rather than parasitosis rates.
Whether or not our variables are observable is immaterial as long as all of the
unobservables in the model are functionally related to either direct observables
or to indicators, so that the values of the former can be inferred from the
values of the latter with the help of definite unobservable-observable hypoth-
eses.
Assume that we pick n 'positive' aspects of development and represent
each of them by a quantitative concept. More precisely, suppose we have n
functions A k, with 1 ~< k ~< n, of the kind

Ak : P x T ~ R ,
where P is the set of countries (or zones of some kind), T the time interval,
DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS 381

and R the set of real numbers. Then the value Ak (P, 0 , for p in P and t in
T, will represent the level of development of country p, at time t, in respect
k. For example, if A s represents the degree of industrial independence, then
'A s (P, t) = 0.5' means that the degree of industrial independence of country
p at time t is one half. Likewise if we represent by

Rk(P, t) = d/dAk/dt
the rate of change of the kth aspect, then a formula such as 'Rs(p, t) = 0.1'
means that country p, at time t, is obtaining its industrial independence at
the rate of 10% per unit time (e.g. per annum).
Since development is a many sided process we need all the variables and
their rates of change. Moreover we had better lump each set into a column
matrix, so as to be able to deal with all aspects at the same time. In other
words, we display the level of development of country p at time t by writing

A I (p, t)
A2(p, 0
a(p, O=

an(p, 0
and the rate of development as the time derivative of the former:

Rl (p, t)
R2(p, t)
R(p, t)= " ,with Rk(p, t)= dA(p, t)/dt

Rn (p, t)
The state of development of country p at time t may be construed as the
ordered pair <A (p, t), R (p, t)> = <A (p, t), ~ ) > . This may be regarded
as a vector whose fh'~t coordinate or component summarizes the level, and the
second the rate of development. As time goes on this vector (or rather its tip)
describes a trajectory in the state space of the developing country, which
space is a 2n dimensional cartesian space. So much for the kinematics of
development.
382 MARIO BUNGE

10. DEVELOPMENT DYNAMICS

Charting or describing the development of a country consists in tracing the


motion of the tip of its state in the state space of the country. It requires
no theory proper: the conceptual framework we have just sketched suffices
for that task. Planning the development of a country is another matter, as
it consists in controlling, so to speak, the rate matrix R, i.e. in having its
entries acquire certain values, so that the development level matrix A itself
(or rather its elements) will attain the desired value at the end of a certain
period. Scientific planning, then, requires a knowledge of the law of motion
of A, hence of the 'forces' regulating its evolution. In other words planning,
at least if thoroughly rational, is based on some dynamical model. In
particular, the rational planning of development rests on some dynamical
model or other.
The gist of a dynamical model for a system (e.g. a country) p is an
equation of the form

dA (p, t) _
dt F(p, t)

where the RHS is the prescribed 'force' matrix, each element Fk of which is
supposed to 'drive' the corresponding state variable Ak. In general each Fk
is a function of time and of Ag itself as well as of some other variables in
the set A = {,41, A2 ..... An) of state variables. In other words, the develop-
ment equation is in general of the form

d__AA= G(A, t)
dt

for each country p. Knowing the initial values of the various state variables
and prescribing the F~s we shall be able to forecast the future values of all the
components of Ak. If these values do not agree with the desired or goal
values then we shall have to change the 'force' assumptions. It goes without
saying that such readjustments cannot be made arbitrarily but are constrained
by the natural and human resources of the country concerned as well as by
the psychological, economic and social laws, not to speak of considerations
of political opportunity.
The simplest (and therefore perhaps also the worst) G function is of course
the linear function. In any case we may start by hypothesizing that the rate
DEVELOPMENT'INDICATORS 383

of development in any given respect depends linearly upon the development


level in every respect. For a two property system this assumption boils down
to the equations
dA1
dt - a l l A t +a12A2
dA2
dt - a21A1 + a ~ A 2

where the aq, for i, ] = 1,2, are real numbers. For certain combinations of
these coefficients there will be progressive development on both fronts, for
others decay, for still others stagnation, and again for others a combination of
the various elementary modes of development. Thus for a n = azz = 0 and

al2 = a21 = c 4: O, the solutions are

At(t) = aie cr + bte-Ct, at, bi E R .

In this case there will be growth in the two aspects just in case at I> bt; other-
wise there will be decay.
We emphasize that the above is only a general framework for development
models. The actual construction of specific models, be they descriptive or
prescriptive (normative), is a tough task that goes far beyond methodology.
Yet it may well be the case that a closer look at methodological matters could
speed up the process of modelling development.

CONCLUDING REMARKS

We have glanced at the complex methodology of development indicators. We


have seen that the design of suitable indicators is a tricky affair involving a
considerable amount of analysis and theorizing - not to speak of the
experience and flair needed in every field of research. And we have suggested
that the study of development indicators can do with some improvements.
For one thing the very notion of development does not seem to have been
sufficiently analyzed. We should be able to answer in a precise manner ques-
tions like these: Development in which respects?, Development for whom?,
and Development at what price? For another thing the notion of development
should be made into the central concept of a number of alternative develop-
ment models, or explicit mathematical theories concerning developing
384 MARIO BUNGE

nations. This warning may sound pedantic but it does look necessary in view
o f the fact that development is often equated with industrial growth - which
should be just one aspect of a many sided process.
If development is conceived as an integral affair, one involving the biolo-
gical, economic, social and cultural aspects of a community, then the very
choice of development indicators is bound to differ from the usual set of
indicators. For one thing indicators of self reliance (or independence) and of
fairness (or equity) should be included among the dominant indicators of
development. Now, an indicator of equity or balance in the level or the distri-
bution of something, be it consumer goods or educational opportunities, is
not a descriptive indicator like, say, the GNP: it is a normative or prescriptive
indicator. As such it is unacceptable to anyone committed to the ideal of a
value free social science.
We have suggested that this ideal is wrong and dead anyway: that the
proper scientific attitude is not to ignore values but to reckon with them and,
whenever possible, to regard them as optima (not necessarily maxima). By so
doing we do not escape objectivity but rather on the contrary, and we come
to share the attitude of the biologist and the engineer, both of whom are
centrally interested in Finding or even prescribing the optimal values of
certain parameters, i.e. those corresponding to the most efficient functioning
of the system, be it organism or machine.
Accordingly we have proposed methods to construct quantitative
normative indicators, in particular development indicators, that should be
included in any formula for the overall development indicator. We have also
proposed an absolute indicator of the latter kind, i.e. one that does not
depend on any particular country chosen as a base line. This absolute
indicator, giving the overall development level D(p, t) of country p at time t,
allows one to compute the distance, in development level, between any two
countriesp and q at a given time t, namely thus: d(p, q, t) = ID(p, t) - D ( q , t) I.
The converse inference is of course impossible.) Finally we have sketched a
nonspeeifie model of the dynamics of development and stressed that all the
development indicators should participate in some such models, for otherwise
they bring little insight and they cannot be validated in a reliable matter.

McGill University, Montreal


DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS 385

NOTE

* An earlier version of this paper was presented to the UNESCO meeting on Indicators
of Social and Economic Change, Paris, 2 0 - 2 2 May 1974.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Bunge, Mario, and MLximo Garcia-Sucre: 1976, 'Differentiation, participation, and


cohesion', Quality and Quantity 10, pp. 171-178.
Unctad: 1970, Research Memo No. 41, Geneva, 5 November 1970.
Unesco: 1973, Study XXIV, Division of Methods and Analysis, 10 June 1973.

You might also like