You are on page 1of 16












 At one level MacKenzie (1987, p 2) sees mineral


 economics as ‘the application of economics in the study of
all aspects of the mineral sector’.
Economics, and the economic way of thinking, have had
More recently, Gordon and Tilton (2008, p 4) have
an important influence on business and government
suggested that:
affairs for at least the last two centuries. The Scottish
author Adam Smith espoused the foundations of Mineral economics is the academic discipline
modern economic thought in 1776. His famous volume that investigates and promotes understanding of
economic and policy issues associated with the
– The Wealth of Nations1 – ushered in a revolution in
production and use of mineral commodities.
economic thinking. His ideas formed the basis of the
new academic field of political economy, which writers To understand its focus more clearly it is useful to
such as Jevons (1879, p 8) renamed as economics some briefly consider the definition of economics, and its
one hundred years later. evolution2.

In the early pages of his book, The Worldly Philosophers, The ancient Greek scholar, Xenophon, first used the
term economics some 2500 years ago to describe the
Heilbroner (1972) traces the rise of economics to the
field of household management, known today as ‘home
emergence of the market system in the wake of the
economics’. By using the term political economy,
Industrial Revolution, which began in the middle of the
Smith and the classical economists who followed in his
eighteenth century. Prior to that time, the organisation
footsteps over the next century of so, sought to extend
and survival of society had largely depended on the study to the level of nations by focusing attention
tradition and authoritarian rule. on the production, distribution and consumption of
The discipline of economics developed strongly during wealth. As the nineteenth century proceeded, writers in
the 20th century, with economists applying its principles the field focused also on utility and the discussion of
to many areas and industries. One of these industries individual economic welfare.
was mining. For at least the last 50 years, undergraduate One of the most widely used early definitions of
students in mining engineering programs around economics was that of Alfred Marshall, in his influential
the world have taken one or more courses in mineral volume, The Principles of Economics (1890, p 1) which
economics, or engineering economics, as part of their notes that:
curriculum. Graduate coursework programs in mineral POLITICAL ECONOMY or ECONOMICS is
economics have also developed in a number of well- the study of man in the ordinary business of life; it
known universities.
 
   

 
 

examines that part of individual and social action Galbraithian mould. We consider why and how this
which is most closely connected with the attainment has happened in the third section of this chapter. Before
and with the use of the material requisites of doing so, we consider the place of mineral economics
wellbeing. in the broader context of the study of economics more
Thus it is on the one side a study of wealth; and on generally.
the other, and more important side, a part of the
study of man. 
This is a broad definition and, as such, it attracted The rise of economics during the twentieth century
debate. In seeking to clarify the nature of the economics occurred in several dimensions. At one level there has
discipline, Robbins (1932, p 16) offered an alternative been division of the discipline between microeconomics
perspective with his so-called scarcity definition as and macroeconomics.
opposed to Marshall’s materialist definition. This was Microeconomics is the study of economic decision-
that: making by consumers, households, firms and
Economics is the science which studies human government, and the way in which these relate to the
behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce operation of markets. Its focus has been on areas such
means which have alternative uses. as supply and demand, on the organisation of markets
Backhouse and Medema (2009, p 225) note that critics and on industry regulation. Microeconomics also
initially argued that the definition was too broad informs us about the decision-making activities, not
because: always benevolent, of government officials.
Macroeconomics, by contrast, is concerned with
social sciences ... the operations of national economies and the world
and too narrow because it: economy. Its focus has been on measures of economic
performance such as Gross Domestic Product (GDP),
... was too heavily tilted toward theory and left little,
inflation, investment, saving, economic growth, the
if any, room for empirical analysis, history, and
balance of payments and the distribution of income
institutions – and it essentially wrote ethics out of
and wealth. It is also concerned with the formulation of
economics.
fiscal, monetary and other areas of national economic
Yet most writers of modern principles economics policy to manage these variables.
textbooks have embraced this scarcity definition. There has also been strong interest in areas such as
Without scarcity, there would be no need for markets. international trade and finance, economic development,
Everything would be free and uncontested. It provides a financial markets and institutions, public finance,
reference point for new students to consider and digest labour markets, economic systems, urban and regional
the subsequent theories and models of classical and economics, natural resource economics, environmental
neoclassical economics, the two major schools of thought. economics, economic history, law and economics, and
They present it in a slightly extended version such as: the history of economic thought. Many economists
Economics is the study of how people and make their careers by specialising in one of these fields3.
society choose to employ scarce productive In a rather different way, there has also been a
resources to produce goods and services and growing interest in the economics of many major
distribute them among various groups in society. industries. Fields such as agricultural economics,
(Waud et al, 1996, p 6) transport economics, health economics, communication
This is, however, not the last word. Non-traditional economics, tourism economics, cultural economics,
economists, such as John Kenneth Galbraith, take an energy economics and mineral economics also are
even broader view. In his volume The New Industrial now distinct subdisciplines.
State (1978, p 417) Galbraith notes that: The study of these areas have emerged because of:
In economics, the overall size of these industries
Economic theory – the study which deals their importance to specific economies and regions
with the way prices, output and incomes of different specific characteristics, which make them
individuals, firms and the economy at large are worthy of separate analysis.
decided – is one area of specialisation. In 2010, the minerals and energy sectors accounted for
The corporation is another. around US$3000 B of world production. This was about
Decision theory – how decisions are reached five per cent of the world’s estimated GDP4. Importantly
in complex organisations – is yet another and
more modern field.  
 
Writers in the field of mineral economics such as  
MacKenzie (1987), and practitioners more generally,  
have tended to embrace a broader definition in the  

 
  

as well, international minerals trade has consistently economies such as Japan, Germany and Korea to more
accounted for more than ten per cent of the value of
world merchandise trade since 1960. During the past as well as economies such as Botswana and Papua New
decade it has exceeded 15 per cent in two or three years, Guinea. In several nations mineral exports account for
when mineral and energy prices were particularly high. well over half of total exports, while they are also key
Mineral production and trade is of great significance in imports in Japan, Korea and many European nations.
as many as fifty nations, and it is the dominant industry Another recent view of the importance of minerals and
in many sub-national regions around the world. Some energy on a ‘broad’ regional basis appears in Table 1.2,
indication of this importance for selected economies
which contains estimates of mineral and energy ‘value
can be seen in Table 1.1.
added’ for each of the world’s continental groupings
The contribution of the minerals and energy sector to for the years 2002 and 2007. This shows the importance
their GDP estimates for 2008 is reported in Table 1.1, as of Asia as the major source of minerals and energy in
is their contribution to exports and to total imports. recent years. The notable increase in magnitude for
Notice how the minerals and energy sector as every continent between 2002 and 2007 reflects the
a percentage of GDP varies from almost zero in minerals boom, which emerged after 2003.





     


    


     
     
     
     

     
     
     

     
     
     
     
     
     

     
     
     
     
     

     
     
     
     
     
     

 
 



 
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    

a. These estimates are derived from UN Statistics (unstats.un.org) by subtracting manufacturing (ISIC D) and estimated utilities (notionally

A difference between minerals and many other fixed in location (they may be discovered in remote
commodities is that they are factor inputs rather locations and need to be moved to intermediate- and
than final consumer goods. With one or two notable end-use markets).
exceptions, manufacturers demand them because of the Another supply-side matter of interest is recycling.
particular attributes they possess. Desirable qualities of While most energy minerals can be consumed only once,
different minerals may include things such as strength, metals and some non-metals can be profitably recycled
durability, chemical and thermal stability, ductility, using old-scrap and new-scrap sources. Recycling may
heat conductivity, resistance to corrosion, plasticity and also be more environmentally friendly.
lubricity. Garnaut (1995) adds a further perspective on the
Minerals differ widely in their physical and chemical special nature of minerals when he describes five
characteristics. The standard classification of metals, characteristics of mines that make them a special focus
non-metals and energy minerals provides one of government policy and administration. These are:
indication of these differences. An appreciation of 1. they can generate economic rent6
the diversity of minerals produced and consumed is
2.
possible by reviewing relevant webpages of the United
large scale
States Geological Survey5. Their analysts regularly
3. their development is often highly capital intensive
assess the status of at least 50 metals, 50 non-metals and
4. they have unusually large local, environmental,
seven or eight major energy minerals that are mined or
social and economic impacts
drilled on a regular basis around the world. They vary
widely in value with oil in 2010 being worth perhaps 5. their national economic impact varies greatly over
US$2 trillion, while some of the smaller minerals are relatively short periods of time.
worth perhaps as little as US$10 M each year. Another

useful classification of minerals – that used by the
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development While one can justify the study of mineral economics
(2007, p 84) – appears in Figure 1.1. in terms of the rise of the economics discipline,
the emergence of mineral economics has also been
MacKenzie (1987, p 6) argues that the main special
influenced by the development of parallel subdisciplines
characteristic of the minerals sector that justifies its
such as engineering economics. In their preface to a
study as a separate sub-branch of economics relates to
successful US textbook in the area, Riggs, Bedworth
the issue of geological endowment. The implications
and Randhawa (1996, xv) note that:
of a fixed endowment for economic analysis relate to
patterns of optimal use, the optimal timing of this use, The curriculums of most professional schools (of
increasing scarcity and conservation. engineering) include a course in applied economics
under such titles as engineering economy, financial
MacKenzie notes in particular that mineral deposits
management, managerial economics and economic
are:
decision-making.
initially unknown (they must be discovered)
These courses typically appear in the latter part of
fixed in size (they are non-renewable) the undergraduate curriculum. In mining schools, they
variable in quality (they often must be extracted
using new technologies)           
 
   

 


have often been called mineral economics. Though State University in 1946. Since that time the study of
hardly subdisciplines of economics, they have tended to mineral economics have moved around the world.
define the field of mineral economics in the eyes of many Several governments has established formal interests
mining professionals. Their emphasis has typically been in the field and there are a small number of university
on decision-making at the operational level, usually programs offered in the United States, Australia, Chile,
with a focus on minimising or optimising costs, in the South Africa and Europe. A group of consulting firms
context of investment decisions. Where they are taught also specialise in mineral economic issues.
well, mining professionals often rank such courses Many professionals who take mineral economics
among the more useful taken in their undergraduate courses are seeking to move into more senior
study. Students completing them also often then managerial roles. It seems desirable, therefore, that any
expect that subsequent study of mineral economics will comprehensive treatment of the area should address the
largely be focused on issues or project evaluation and strategic, operational and human resource management
related areas of applied financial analysis. While post- issues that relate specifically to resource sector
professional programs in mineral economics do tend to
companies, as well as providing a suitable overview
contain a strong emphasis on financial analysis, they
of the legal environment in which these firms operate.
combine this with study of mainstream economic issues,
These elements relate quite neatly to Galbraith’s broader
which arise from the special nature of mineral markets,
definition of economics, with its focus on economic
and the other features that the geological endowment
theory, the corporation and decision making.
constraint places on the study of the discipline.
It is instructive to complete this introductory
Gordon and Tilton (2008) trace the origins of the
discussion by making one further important point.
modern study of mineral economics to a collaborative
MacKenzie (1987, p 8) identifies two main requirements
effort between the Brookings Institution and the US
for the practice of mineral economics. They are:
Bureau of Mines in 1932. This led to the publication
of an edited volume by Tyron and Eckles (1932) titled 1. knowledge of the principles of economics and
Mineral Economics: Brookings Lectures. After World War associated analysis techniques
II there was growing concern over the implications 2. understanding of the technical characteristics of
of the geological endowment in the United States for
strategic mineral supply. A parallel development was economic viewpoint.
the foundation of the first mineral economics program The focus of discussion in this chapter has been on
at the College of Mineral Sciences at Pennsylvania the first of these issues, but the second point is also

 
 

important. It is often necessary to appreciate the What forces have been driving change in mining’s
technical issues relating to a mining or energy project interaction with local communities?
to apply economic and other principles to its analysis.
How important is international trade in minerals
Business, law and economics graduates will find it
and energy?
difficult to undertake the depth of analysis necessary to
analysis minerals sector issues unless they extend their What role has major changes in transport costs
technical knowledge in areas such as geology, mining played in international minerals trade?
methods and mineral processing. How does recent growth in mineral and energy
A well-trained mineral economist will apply economic trade compare with growth in other areas of
principles, in combination with suitable technical international trade?
knowledge, to analyse resources available in a fixed What are the sources of competitive advantage of
endowment. She, or he, will consider issues such as the Australian minerals sector?
how to use minerals, when to use them, how to mine
What are the key factors that influence the demand
them, when to recycle them and how to regulate them.
for different metals?
 How important are joint production issues in the
 analysis of mineral supply?
Writing about mineral economics in 1950, Gordon How has recycling affected the supply of major
and Tilton (2008) identified the key areas of interest metals in the recent past?
as mineral markets, project evaluation, depletion and
long-run availability of minerals, strategic minerals, 
monopoly policy with respect to aluminium and steel, In compiling this monograph, our aim is to provide a
and international commodity agreements. balanced and up-to-date view of the approaches and
In the ensuing 60 years, the mineral economics techniques that mineral economists use to appreciate
‘playing field’ has changed, but many of these topics the resources sector. While the bias of this volume is
remain of great interest and importance. Mineral towards the Australian mineral and energy sector, the
market analysis and project evaluation are both still discussion often takes a broader perspective. Mining is
central areas of focus. These have been joined by topics a global industry and if this volume is to provide value
such as the relationship between mineral exploitation to its readers, it must be internationally focused.
and development and the associated concepts of the The 16 chapters that follow this introduction are
‘resource curse’ and ‘Dutch disease’. Other important organised in five main sections. They are:
areas include mineral taxation and royalties; sustainable 1. minerals and the world economy (three chapters)
development and mining; minerals trade and transport;
2. minerals: consumption, production and markets
the issue of how mineral rents should be shared between
(three chapters)
local communities, regions, nations and companies;
3.
and the economics of innovation in the mining sector.
4. minerals and public policy (three chapters)
We address most of these areas in this volume and
5. mining and local communities (four chapters).
after reading it closely, you should be able to answer
Philip Maxwell has played the coordinating role
the following questions in a professional way.
with the first, second and fifth sections. Pietro Guj is
Does an abundance of mineral resources make a responsible for the Mineral Finance and Investment
country rich? section. The coordination of the minerals and public
What effects do mineral-based resource booms policy section has been shared. Our contributions
have on different economies? have emerged from our association with the Graduate
Coursework program in Mineral Economics at
What factors influence the discovery and exploi-
the Western Australian School of Mines7 at Curtin
tation of minerals around the world?
University.
What did the discovery of gold do to the Australian
One of the features that assisted the quality of our
economy?
program offerings over the past decade has been the
Why has the resources sector been important to contribution from colleagues from other institutions,
economies such as Australia, Canada and Chile in both in Australia and overseas. It is particularly
the recent past? Or has it been important? appropriate, therefore, that several of these visiting
What factors determine the contribution of mineral faculties, together with other selected colleagues, are
production to sustainable economic well-being? also contributing to this volume. They include Rod
What influence has greater environmental regula- Eggert (Colorado School of Mines), Phillip Crowson
tion had on the supply of minerals?
 

 
 

(University of Dundee), Peter Howie (Nazarbayev Jevons, W S, 1879. The Theory of Political Economy, second
University), Allan Trench (Curtin University and edition (Macmillan: London).
and the University of Western Australia) and Frank Kuznets, S, 1934. National Income, 1929-1932, 73rd US
Harman. Several others have acted as reviewers. Their Congress, second session, Senate document no 124, p 7.
insights enhance the quality of the pages ahead. We MacKenzie, B, 1987. Mineral Economics: Decision-Making
Methods in the Mineral Industry, 5-17 July, Adelaide:
thank them for their contributions.
Australian Mineral Foundation.
Marshall, A, 1890. Principles of Economics (Macmillan:
 London).
Backhouse, R and Medema, S, 2009. On the definition Riggs, J L, Bedworth, D B and Randhawa, S U, 1996. Engineering
of economics, Journal of Economic Perspectives, winter, Economics, fourth edition (McGraw-Hill: New York).
23(1):221-233. Robbins, L, 1932. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of
Galbraith, J K, 1978. The New Industrial State, third edition Economic Science (Macmillan: London).
revised (Houghton Mifflin: Boston). Tyron, E G and Eckles, E C (eds), 1932. Mineral Economics:
Garnaut, R, 1995. Dilemmas of governance, in Mining and Brooking Lectures (McGraw-Hill: New York).
Mineral Resource Policy in Asia-Pacific: Prospects for the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development
21st Century (eds: D Denoon, C Ballard, G Banks and (UNCTAD), 2007. World Investment Report: Trans-
P Hancock), p 61-66, Canberra. national Corporations, Extractive Industries and
Gordon, R and Tilton, J, 2008. Mineral economics: Overview Development, Geneva.
of a discipline, Resources Policy, 33(1):4-11. Waud, R, Maxwell, P, Hocking, A, Bonnici, J and Ward, I,
Heilbroner, R, 1972. The Worldly Philosophers, fourth edition 1996. Economics, third Australian edition (Longman:
(Simon and Schuster: New York). Melbourne).

 
















Several processes always occurring within any economy Some natural resource economists have included the
determine the economic wellbeing of its citizens. They environment (or environmental services) in their group
include production, distribution, consumption and of inputs.
trade. Our interest in this volume is with how minerals Recognising the value of each of these alternative
and energy exploitation impinge on these processes. specifications, let us hypothesise here that:
It is typical, initially at least, to think of the ways in
which people use minerals and energy in the process of Economic output = f (land, labour, capital,
producing goods and services. But the distribution of environment)
the proceeds of resource wealth and the consumption
of mineral and energy resources are very important as But what do economists mean by land, labour and
well. Furthermore, the sale and purchase of minerals capital?
and energy through interregional and international
Land refers to all of the natural resources used in
trade plays an important role in increasing people’s
production. As well as land itself it includes water,
welfare.
forests, fisheries, oil, gas and mineral deposits.
Let us begin by taking a production view of things.
Labour denotes the skills and capabilities used by
Over any given period, (eg a year), we can think of humans in the production process.
what an individual, a firm, a region, a nation or the
Capital describes all of the manufactured aids used
world produces in terms of a production function
in the process of production1.
in which the output generated is a function of the
The environment reflects the quality of the natural
economic resources used as inputs. Economists have
world around us. It is responsible for the quality of the
typically denoted these resources as land, labour and
air that we breathe and the water that we drink, and the
capital. The state of technology may also be included
way that we utilise it affects the food that we eat and
as an additional factor but in the short run, this will the materials that we use to build shelter for ourselves.
be reflected in the nature of the capital stock and the
quality of the labour force. In a similar vein, Alfred  
Marshall included organisation as a production factor.  

 

The services that the environment provides are also an The discovery and exploitation of minerals brings
input to production. It is also a ‘sink’ for our wastes major new activity to mining regions. Debates typically
and if this aspect is overused, the environment can arise as to:
adversely affect our ability to produce. How much should accrue to investors (often from
Critics argue that most mining and oil companies other places) who have risked their money to
neglected environmental issues until quite recently2. develop new oil wells or mines?
They did so because their main focus was on profits and How much of the windfall should be shared with
dividends to shareholders, and governments did not local and regional residents?
actively regulate pollution. These companies were not How much should government redistribute to
alone in their practices. Many manufacturing firms did citizens in other regions or states?
little to treat wastes, discharging them into the nearby These controversies are often the source of continuing
atmosphere, or into rivers, lakes or the sea with minimal uncertainty. When they are resolved in a satisfactory
treatment. In many parts of Australia and elsewhere, way, all stakeholders can share the returns from new
past and even present farming practices have resulted mineral and energy production.
in erosion and reduced soil fertility. This occurs even Hence one might argue that the great mineral
today in several developing nations. wealth of the Eastern Goldfields, the Pilbara, and the
Over the past 30 years there has been a major change other mining regions of Western Australia have been
in the position of corporations generally and mining distributed effectively over more than a century. It
companies particularly. They have embraced the has enhanced the income and general fortunes of the
principles of sustainable development and corporate average citizen of WA’s mining regions. A large royalty
social responsibility in their treatment of environmental stream, together with payroll tax receipts has assisted
issues and their relationships with the local communities the finances of the Western Australian government.
in which they operate3. Greater individual and company income taxes, as
well as resource rent royalties, have contributed to the
The following statement by McDivitt and Jeffrey, in
welfare of Australians more broadly.
Vogely (1976, p 16), reflects an interesting economic
perspective about the impact of mining on production: Even without the hand of government to redistribute
income and wealth through the fiscal system, many
… mineral development can contribute to the three
past mineral discoveries have brought a more even
major factors of production - land, through bringing
distribution of income. This was the case with the
into action otherwise dormant resources in the
Victorian, New South Wales and Western Australian
country; capital, both through attracting outside
gold rushes in the nineteenth century. Blainey (2003,
investment capital to the country and through p 62) notes that:
providing new money some of which can be used for
local investment; and labor, through upgrading local Gold checked, and for a time, reversed Australia’s
skills and implanting concepts of entrepreneurship. tendency to become a land that favoured the big
man. Whereas Australia’s first natural asset, the
That is, mining uses machines, labour, and minerals sheeplands, was grasped by a few thousand men, its
themselves to produce further capital (buildings,
second rich natural asset, the goldlands was divided
bridges, machinery, etc). In this process, worker skills among hundreds of thousands of men.
are upgraded and innovation takes place, enhancing
the labour pool for mining’s own use or for its use in Where mineral windfalls involve labour-intensive
other sectors. If they were rewriting this passage today, mining activity there is increased opportunity to share
income and wealth more equally4. But as minerals then
the two authors may also have included a reference
become less amenable to labour-intensive mining and
to environmental quality issues and to sustainable
require greater amounts of capital, there is the opposite
development.
tendency for the distribution of income and wealth to
In any economy, the issue of distribution – the way in become more unequal.
which different individuals or groups share production
A continuing issue regarding our future, concerns
– is also important. Issues relating to the fairness or
the way in which production and consumption relate
equity in the distribution of income and wealth usually
to one another. Consumption involves individuals and
generate controversy. This happens within families,
households (the private sector) and also government
smaller regions, states and provinces, and nations, and
using up goods and services.
also between nations on the world stage. Governments
use the proceeds of taxation and royalty collections to If a society consumes less than it produces, (ie spends less
redistribute this income and wealth. than its income) in any given time period, its members
(both the private and public sector) can save the residual
 
   
   

 
 

and invest it to ensure production continuing in the the Yabulu nickel refinery near Townsville, North
future. Saving and investment are important additional Queensland in Australia).
concepts in the economist’s lexicon. Saving refers to the As we saw in the final two columns of Table 1.1 and
amount generated from abstaining from consumption
in any given period, while investment is spending on and energy play an important part in increasing the
capital formation, both physical and human. economic and social welfare of many nations. Perhaps
New investment, that increases a nation’s or region’s fifty countries have significant mining industries and
physical and human capital, typically provides the many of these are significant international exporters.
basis for further economic growth and development. The remaining nations depend on key mineral and
If citizens consume what they produce, or more than energy imports to supply their factories, build their
they produce by borrowing against future expected general infrastructure and facilitate their housing and
production, their capital stock will fall and so will other building construction.
production, if other things are equal. We typically are Mineral exports were particularly important in
impressed with the ‘economic miracle’ nations whose Australia from the early 1840s until the beginning of
strong growth and development is attributable to World War I. Subsiding dramatically after 1914, mineral
domestic saving, which finances wise investment in new trade again rose dramatically after 1960. Sustained
physical and human capital. The economic performance international competitiveness in many parts of the
of Japan, Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, Hong Kong and industry underpinned Australia’s strong economic
now China in the latter part of the twentieth century performance in the last part of the twentieth century and
have drawn great praise from most commentators. in the first decade of the new millenium. This situation
Where nations have large mineral and energy seems certain to continue for many more decades.
resource endowments, much of which may have only In a complementary way, countries such as Japan and
recently been discovered, there also seems considerable Korea, that produce few minerals, depend on a secure
potential to invest the profits from its exploitation. and reasonably priced minerals and energy supply.
Such endowments form part of a natural capital base. This is critical to the downstream industries on which
Some natural capital is renewable, while some is these nations depend for the prosperity of their citizens.
not. It is normal to think of agricultural land, forests,
fisheries and solar, wind and tidal energy as renewable 
resources, and to classify minerals and many other 
energy sources as non-renewable resources. Despite Following the widespread adoption and use of national
their finite nature, and as we have already noted, it is accounting frameworks throughout the world after
possible to recycle many minerals in a profitable way. 1950, it has become standard practice to measure
If minerals are produced, and consumed, and they economic production by estimating Gross Domestic
cannot be recycled, their stock will decline5. As we shall Product, commonly known as GDP.
see, how the citizens of a country or region allocate the
First suggested in 1933 by the Harvard University
proceeds of mineral exploitation to current consumption
professor, Simon Kuznets, Gross Domestic Product is a
and investment is an issue, which is of interest to many
measure of the market value of final goods and services
people. We typically see such debate in discussions
produced in an economy during a given period6. It is
about minerals and sustainable development.
most usual to discuss GDP estimates for a year.
The final key concept in this section is trade. Trade Each nation’s central statistical agency computes
takes place because it makes individuals, companies official estimates of its GDP, typically in terms of
and nations better off. By specialising in the things they its national currency. In the case of Australia, this
can do best, these groups can exchange part of their organisation is the Australian Bureau of Statistics.
production for a variety of goods and services that will Australia’s officially estimated GDP in the 2010 - 11
enable them to reach a higher standard of living than financial year was around $A1300 B. This meant that
without trade. Trade takes place: GDP per capita for each of Australia’s 22.3 million
within regions (eg a nickel miner in the Western inhabitants in that year was a little more than $A58 000.
Australian Goldfields town of Laverton sells ore or
concentrate to the Kalgoorlie nickel smelter)
between nations, the established practice is to convert
between regions (eg a silver, lead and zinc mining estimates in terms of national currencies into $US,
company operating in Broken Hill, New South using prevailing exchange rates. These estimates appear
Wales, rails zinc concentrate for refining to the Port again in Table 2.1 for 2008.
Pirie smelter in South Australia)
between nations (eg a mining company operating  
in New Caledonia ships its lateritic nickel ore to  
 
   
   

 

Notice the dramatic differences in the size of the community organisations. For example in a study
economies in Table 2.1 as shown in their GDP estimates. using 1997 data, the Australian Bureau of Statistics
The United States accounted for more than 20 per cent of (2000) estimated that unpaid work in Australia could be
the world’s GDP – which was more than $US60 trillion valued at about 48 per cent of GDP.
in 2008. Australia’s GDP was about six per cent of the Estimates of actual GDP per capita, and GDP per
US total, and it was about 100 times the size of the GDP capita at Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) for our
of Papua New Guinea. selected economies also appear in Table 2.1. GDP per
 capita gives one measure of the standard of living of
 the average citizen of each nation. With an average

citizen in oil rich Norway appears dramatically better
    off than citizens of any other nation in the table. The
   average Ghanaian, with per capita income of $739 in
 2008, seems the poorest. Citizens of the US, Germany,
    Australia, Canada and Japan all did well in terms of this
    measure.
    The PPP adjustment in GDP per capita takes account
    of cost of living differences between nations. It is based
on continuing activities associated with the work of the

International Comparison Program of the World Bank.
   
The benchmark for the PPP measure is the cost of living
    in the USA. GDP per capita in the US was $US47 393
    in 2008. Its GDP per capita at PPP was, of course, also
 $US47 393.
    Compare this with the situation in Australia. Over the
    past two decades, most would judge that the cost of
living in Australia has been higher than in many other
   
nations. While estimated GDP per capita in Australia in
   
2008, at $US48 950, was higher than in the US, it fell to
    $US38 396 after PPP adjustment. This was well below
    the US figure. On this basis, the standard of living of the
 average US citizen seemed considerably higher than his
    or her Australian colleagues.
    In the case of countries such as Chile and South Korea,
living costs in 2008 were lower than in the United States.
   
This shows up in higher GDP/ capita at PPP levels with
   
these nations, than their GDP per capita estimates. For
   
 capita at PPP was $14 592. In South Korea, GDP per
    capita was $19 162 and GDP per capita at PPP was
    $27 681. Low living costs in developing nations may
double or even triple the GDP per capita estimate at
   
PPP. Notice how GDP per capita at PPP is higher than
    GDP per capita for each of the small developing mineral
    economies in Table 2.1.
    Notwithstanding the significant contributions to
overall production of volunteer groups and stay at
The GDP measure has several limitations. Importantly home partners in a country such as Australia, the size of
it does not include adjustments for capital consumption, the informal economy is of considerably greater relative
depreciation of natural capital, or environmental importance in developing nations. Hence, even after
degradation. It fails, also, to include estimates of the adjusting for Purchasing Power Parity, it is still likely
value of non-market goods such as work at home. that any comparison of living standards using GDP per
Hence the contributions to production of women and capita at PPP between an affluent developed nation,
men who are homemakers and raise families are not such as Australia or Japan, and a poorer developing
included. Also excluded is the work of volunteers mineral economy in Africa will overstate the difference
who contribute generously to the functioning of many between them.

 
 

While it is clear, therefore, that the average citizen of



a nation such as Ghana is poor, his or her production
will in reality exceed the estimate of $1518 in Table 2.1 

by a higher percentage than it does for the average
Australian citizen. GDP per capita at Purchasing Power    
Parity comparisons between nations are at best only an   
approximate indicator of economic welfare differences.   
The limitations of GDP and its associated measures  
have stimulated a number of alternative approaches 
and adjustments to reflect a country’s economic size    
and stage of development in a more effective manner7.    
But this statement itself begs the question of what
   
development really means.
   
 
When commentators discuss the economic growth of a    
nation, a region or the world, they usually are referring    
to the percentage rate of growth in total production    
over a given period such as a year (or a quarter).

On some occasions, however, they may alternately
   
refer to:
   
the percentage rate of growth in per capita production
   
of the average citizen over a given time period, and
more recently    
the rate of growth of productivity, or output per    
worker.    
Yet, since about 1960 it has become standard practice 
to measure economic growth by computing percentage    
changes in real Gross Domestic Product. We use the
   
term ‘real’ to indicate that the GDP has been adjusted
for changes in the rate of inflation. National statistical    
agencies use the GDP deflator, based on the level of    
prices of all new domestically produced final goods    
and services in an economy in a given period to make 
this adjustment.
   
Some estimates of average annual growth rates, based
   
on simple averages, for the periods 1981 to 1999 and
2000 to 2009, appear in Table 2.2.    

Todaro (1989, pp 86 - 87) points to traditional views    
that development or economic development takes    
place over an extended period (of say ten years or    
more) when an economy is able, following a period of
mediocre economic performance, to: But the Todaro view also seems implicitly to assume
bring about annual rates of growth exceeding that, during a significant development period,
five per cent the structure of an economy will change, with the
generate consistent growth in its real GDP per capita. emergence of major new and competitive industry
Hence, according Table 2.2, we might argue that, sectors (eg mining, manufacturing, services, etc). The
between 1980 and 1999, nations such as China, South achievements over a longer period of Japan, China,
Korea, India, Indonesia, as well as the two mineral South Korea and Singapore, and more recently of
rich nations of Botswana and Chile all experienced Thailand, India, Indonesia and Vietnam provide
significant economic development. examples of significant economic development taking
China, India, Ghana, Russia and Nigeria all met this place. Nations such as the United States, Britain,
criterion between 2000 and 2009. Germany, France, Canada and Australia have also
 
experienced economic development surges in this way.
  In each of these later cases, the mineral sector made a
  significant contribution to this development.

 

During the 1970s, a broader view emerged concerning 


the dimensions of the concept of economic development. 
Writers began to consider economic development in 
terms of reducing poverty, income inequality and
      
unemployment when an economy was experiencing 
consistently strong real GDP growth over an extended 
period.

In his extended definition, Todaro (1989, p 88) argues
      
that:
      
Development must … be conceived as a
      
multidimensional process involving major changes
in social structures, popular attitudes and national       
institutions, as well as the acceleration of economic 
growth, the reduction of inequality, and the       
eradication of absolute poverty.
      
Associated with this interest in a broader definition
      
of economic development, several economists have
proposed the use of socioeconomic indicators to 
measure development. One of the notable early       
measures in this area was Morris’s Physical Quality       
of Life Index (based on life expectancy at age one,       
infant mortality and literacy). Following this approach,
      
the United Nations Development Programme began
reporting estimates of the Human Development Index       
(HDI) in its annual Human Development Report8, which       
first appeared in 1990. The HDI measure is based 
equally on:       
… a country’s average achievements in three basic       
aspects of human development: health, knowledge,
      
and income (United Nations Development
Programme, 2011).       

It can range between zero and one. The UNDP provides       
further details concerning the recent computation of 
this measure on its web site. Estimates of the Human       
Development Index for our selected economies in 2010       
appear in Table 2.2 and movements in the HDI from
      
1980 to 2010 are reported in Table 2.4.
      
       

      
 
   Indonesia, Botswana, Chile, Peru and Saudi Arabia
after 1980. With the exception of South Korea, each of
 
these nations is a significant minerals producer. Mineral
  exploitation was apparently consistent with increasing
   life expectancy9, better education and higher incomes in
these countries over this three-decade period. By contrast,
In its Human Development Report 2010, the UNDP the significance of HDI increases in countries such as
classified 169 countries as shown in Table 2.3. South Africa, Russia, Papua New Guinea, Zambia and
It is notable that Norway (a major oil and gas exporter) Venezuela was less impressive. South Africa and Zambia
had the highest HDI value of any nation in 2010, while faced particular difficulties with the HIV/AIDS epidemic
Australia (a major mineral exporter) ranked second. that adversely affected life expectancy, while Russia
Another key minerals and energy exporter, Canada, was struggled with its transition to the free enterprise system.
the eighth ranked nation. Major change in HDI levels In an era when the minerals and energy sector has
occurred in nations such as China, South Korea, India, become a more global industry, the HDI is a useful initial

   
   

 
 

measure to assess the likely operating environment a dominated the world’s political, social and economic
mining company might face if it commences operations evolution. For 5000 years they have been the major
in a new nation. Recent increases in a country’s HDI factor in the flowering of a people’s culture, the key
may also indicate greater potential for the profitability to their industrial power and their influence in world
of new mineral projects in a previously difficult affairs.
jurisdiction. There seems much to this argument, though modern
Other things being equal, it should be more attractive oil and gas producers would also associate themselves
to invest in a more developed nation, but making with these views.
a judgment about development should involve A brief review of ancient history illustrates how
assessing several other issues. Consistent with the members of the prominent civilisations effectively used
Todaro definition above, such things as social and new technologies in processing metals such as copper,
institutional stability and honesty, income and wealth iron, gold, silver and tin as a basis for enhancing both
distribution trends, and poverty levels interact with the the quality of life of their citizens, as well as their
status of mineral policy and the extent of a country’s military strength.
mineral endowment in doing this in an effective and
The emphasis on the latter area seems to have
professional way.
been of central importance in the domination of
surrounding populations. This applied in varying ways

to the Sumerian, Babylonian, Assyrian, Persian, Greek,
Minerals and energy have played a major role in the Carthaginian, Roman and Chinese civilisations. With
history of the world. This is apparent simply by noting the fall of the Roman Empire around 450 AD, the use of
that many periods have been characterised by material metals dwindled as the world of Europe and the Middle
or energy names. Reflecting the role of changing East descended into the ‘Dark Ages’ period.
technology, the use of key minerals as a principal
Though new uses of minerals and energy began
ingredient of tools, or power, in periods bearing their
slowly emerging after 1500, it was the arrival of the
names brought improvement in terms of human
Industrial Revolution in the United Kingdom from
wellbeing, as measured by population growth and
about 1750 that heralded the widespread modern
other indicators. uses of minerals and energy. The establishment of
This shows up clearly in Table 2.5, a summary table heavy industry, the widespread use of coal and more
adapted from Wilson (1994, p xi). Wilson (1994, p xiii) recently oil and gas as its major energy sources, and
also argues that: the rise of materials such as steel, aluminium and a
The history of metals is the history of civilisation. range of more exotic metals, have all been part of this
The two are inseparable; each depends on the other picture. The Industrial Revolution has led to consumer
for its development; when one stumbles the other societies in which minerals and energy are used in
falters. Ever since Neolithic man learned the secret of ways and at levels that were previously unimaginable.
winning metals from ore-bearing rock, metals have Associated with this have been major technological
advances in exploration, mining and particularly
 mineral processing. Advances in transport technology
 have also created a global minerals economy, and as
we shall see in the next chapter, this has hastened the
  economic development of nations such as Australia in
  a dramatic way.
 
  
 

 As economic development has proceeded there has
  been a significant rise in mineral consumption. This has
  been particularly the case over the past half century.
  With world population and real GDP now standing
 
at or near their highest levels, the production and
consumption of most minerals are now also at record
 
levels.
 
Some estimates of the consumption of key minerals
 
for selected years between 1960 and 2009 appear in
  Table 2.6. The ratios shown in the final row indicate
  the extent of change in mineral consumption since

 

 key minerals in index terms are reported in Table 2.7 on


 a decade by decade since 1960.
 As any nation becomes more developed it initially uses
        minerals with higher degrees of intensity. Poor nations
       use minerals and energy at relatively low rates. But as
        they emerge in a major development push, they build
        roads, airports, railways, houses, public buildings and
factories and their citizens buy new cars, televisions,
       
air conditioners, computers, refrigerators and many
       
other goods. Their intensity of use of minerals expands
        dramatically. By the time they become developed
        economies, they derive larger amounts of income
 from service industries, which do not use minerals so
      
 intensively, and their minerals intensity of use tends to
decline slightly. Sometimes posited as an ‘inverted U’,
1960. Notice that aluminium has easily the greatest Figure 2.1 describes the likely shape of the curve relating
rate of increase, followed by copper and nickel. The a nation’s (or region’s) stage of economic development
rate of increase in steel, oil and zinc has been relatively to its minerals and materials intensity of use.
more subdued. Yet with the emergence of China and
Intensity
India as leading economic powers, the growth of iron of use
and steel use has been notably strong since 2000. Even
unfashionable lead, which is now used much less than
previously in paint and gasoline, increased by more that
150 per cent over the period, with its major application
now being in motor vehicle batteries.
In considering the relationship between mineral
consumption and economic development the concept
of intensity of use has been used by several authors.
Suggested by Wilfred Malenbaum in 1975, its formula
is:
Stage of economic development



It is possible to compute the intensity of use of all Developed nations have climbed a steep intensity of
minerals. To facilitate comparisons between minerals use hill and then their intensity of minerals use tends
IU, it is useful to state each in index form, setting the gradually to subside. Western Europe, the USA, Canada,
value to 100 in a selected base year. So, using data Japan, Australia and New Zealand have experienced
from Table 2.6, while the actual IU of steel moved from that phase. The United Kingdom, Germany and France
(347 Mt/$US13 440 B = 0.0258 Mt/$US B in 1960) to began the process during the 19th century and are now
595 Mt/$US$18 960 = 0.0314 Mt/$US B in 1970, this shows well past their peaks. The United States started a major
up as an increase in intensity of use from 100 in 1960 development surge in the latter part the 19th century
to 121.6 in 1970. By comparison aluminium grew from and is now also well beyond its IU summit. South Korea
100 to 174.7 over the same period, while lead moved began a major development surge after 1970 and has
only from 100 to 103.1. Estimates of IU movements if recently reached a peak. Australia experienced an initial
development surge after its Gold rushes in the latter
 half of the 19th Century and then after 1945. The recent
 surge in the Gulf States (UAE, Qatar, etc) is another

example of nations experiencing the climb.
        China has been undergoing the climb since 1978 but
        still does not seem to have reached the top of its ‘hill’.
        India is also ascending but is at a lower point. The
dramatic rise in mineral consumption over the past
       
decade has been linked to the major populations in these
       
nations. The position of the IU-development curve may
        also shift between different time periods because of the
        effects of technology on mineral use.

 
 

 the competitive behaviour of mineral producers and


 purchasers
effects of mineral development on indigenous
  populations
  the environmental impact of mining and its

 mitigation.
 We discuss the relevance of each of these issues in the
  coming chapters – often on more than one occasion.
  Table 2.8 provides a brief guide, should you require it.
 
 

Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2000. Unpaid work and the
 
Australian Economy, 1997, Catalogue no 5240.0, Canberra.
Blainey, G, 2003. The Rush that Never Ended, fifth edition
(Melbourne University Press: Melbourne).

Hilson, G, 2012. Corporate social responsibility in the
 extractive industries: Experiences from developing
A variety of factors make the study of mineral countries, Resources Policy, 37(2):131-137.
production, mineral consumption and mineral International Council on Mining and Metals, 2012. Available
economics generally more complex but also more from: <www.icmm.com>.
interesting. As we have noted already in this chapter, McDivitt, J and Jeffrey, W, 1976. Minerals and the developing
one of these is the non-renewable nature of minerals economies, in Economics of the Mineral Industries, third
edition, pp 3-32 (AIME: New York).
and energy resources. Others include:
Todaro, M, 1989. Economic Development in the Third World,
the fixed locations of deposits (often in remote areas) fourth edition (Longman: New York).
the economic rent that they generate United Nations Development Programme, 2011. The human
the impact of technological change on both the development index [online]. Available from: <http://hdr.
undp.org/en/statistics/hdi/>.
supply and demand side
Wilson, A J, 1994. The Living Rock (Cambridge: Woodhead).

 

You might also like