You are on page 1of 9

Small Ruminant Research 49 (2003) 97–105

Economic profitability and typology of Ripollesa


breed sheep farms in Spain
M.J. Milán a,∗ , E. Arnalte b , G. Caja a
a Departamento de Ciencia Animal y de los Alimentos, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Edifici V. 08193, Bellaterra, Spain
b Departamento de Economı́a y Ciencias Sociales, Universidad Politécnica de Valencia, Valencia, Spain

Accepted 5 April 2002

Abstract
The aim of this work was to study the economic results of Ripollesa breed sheep farms in Spain, and to establish a typology
which would clarify the characteristics of the different types of existing farms. Data was collected using a survey of 52 farm
owners, from which the mean economic results of the farms were calculated. To establish a typology, the data were treated
using a multivariate statistical analysis (principal component analysis). Subsequently, a hierarchy analysis (cluster analysis) of
the coordinates of the farms with the first five factors was applied. The results indicate that, in general and under our working
conditions, the most diversified farms obtain higher income and higher net added value at factor cost (NAVfc). At the same
time, public subsidies make up an average of 27% of total income and 52% of NAVfc. It was possible to typify four groups
of farms.
© 2003 Published by Elsevier Science B.V.
Keywords: Sheep; Farm management; Principal component analysis; Ripollesa breed; Spain

1. Introduction ments to producers. Among the effects of these pay-


ments have been increases in flock size and aging of
The 1999 census showed Catalonia with 1,046,634 the flocks (Cahn, 1990; Manrique et al., 1992). In ad-
head of sheep (Departament d’Agricultura Ramaderia dition, Boutonnet (1993) asked whether or not meat
i Pesca, 2000), which is approximately 5% of the to- had become a subproduct for sheep producers, since
tal for Spain. Among native sheep breeds in Catalo- subsidies made up more than a third of the total in-
nia, the Ripollesa is the most common. It is found come on French sheep farms dedicated to meat pro-
mainly in the provinces of Barcelona and Gerona and duction. In similar vein, Bazin (1994) observed that in
is currently characterized as a meat-producing breed. 1991 subsidies were equivalent to 100% of the profit
The sheep sector was one of the first whose produc- on French sheep farms, that is to say, income from
ers received direct subsidies to compensate for falls in the sale of products was the same as their production
income. The Common Market Organization from its costs.
beginning anticipated the need for compensation pay- At the moment, as well as compensating income,
there are other reasons which justify maintaining these
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +93-581-2152; bonuses: these are the so-called “non-productive”
fax: +93-581-14-94. functions associated with this type of farming. They
E-mail address: mariajose.milan@uab.es (M.J. Milán). have been observed by various authors (Blanchemain

0921-4488/03/$ – see front matter © 2003 Published by Elsevier Science B.V.


doi:10.1016/S0921-4488(03)00058-0
98 M.J. Milán et al. / Small Ruminant Research 49 (2003) 97–105

and Flamant, 1983; Blanchemain, 1989; Zorita, 1990; A multivariate statistical analysis was used to treat
Accounts Tribunal of the EC, 1995). Among these the data for the typological analysis. A principal com-
functions the following are of some importance: ponent analysis (PCA) was made using 41 variables.
This analysis synthesizes data which can be dispersed
• The majority of autonomous sheep breeds in the
and heterogeneous for some variables and factors; this
community are able to make use of resources which
explains most of the total variability of the sample
would otherwise remain unused.
(Johnson and Wichern, 1982; Judez, 1989). The in-
• Sheep production is often the only significant ac-
terpretation of the factors is helped by the use of the
tivity in areas where it is difficult to promote other
rotated matrix, varimax. Subsequently, a hierarchical
types of economic activity: it therefore contributes
analysis (cluster analysis) was performed on the co-
to the continuance of human activity in areas which
ordinates of the farms against the first five factors.
would otherwise be abandoned.
This analysis differentiates and groups farms accord-
• Sheep farming contributes to the maintenance of
ing to their homogeneity using Euclidean distance
certain ecosystems and thus reduces the risk of for-
(Hair et al., 1987). Finally, the mean structural, tech-
est fires, soil erosion and loss of biodiversity.
nical and economic indicators that define each group
The fact that sheep farming, as it occurs with farm- were calculated. The differences between groups were
ing practices that are extensive or semi-intensive, is checked using a one-way ANOVA analysis with a
characterized by a diversity of productive systems Student–Newman–Keuls mean comparison test. All
(Capillon, 1985; Caja and Such, 1991; Liénard et al., calculations were made using the (6.1.2) version of
1992; Manrique et al., 1992, 1994), making it diffi- the SPSS statistical package (SPSS, 1998).
cult to understand the situation of these farms and
the effects of agricultural policies together with the
strategies needed to adapt to these policies. This lack 3. Results and discussion
of knowledge was the main reason for the current
work, the aim of which was to describe the situation 3.1. Income from the farm
as well as to study the economics of Ripollesa sheep
farms in Catalonia and to evaluate the degree to which On 35% of the farms studied, all family income
community subsidies affect them. At the same time, came directly from the farm while, 17% of cases in-
the work was planned to establish a typology which come was supplemented with some type of pension.
is effective in helping to understand the diversity of In the rest, there were additional external sources of
existing farming practices. income. Income from the farm was defined as income
from the flock, from other agricultural activities, from
the sale of agricultural products and from agrarian sub-
2. Materials and methods
sidies. In the farms studied, the mean incomes from
the farm amounted to 49,387 (Table 1). Farm in-
The data used refers to 1993 and was obtained in comes correlated positively and significantly with the
1994 from surveys returned by 52 farm owners ded-
icated to meat production. The surveyed farms com-
prised approximately 15% of the total of the official Table 1
census of Ripollesa breed sheep farms in Catalonia. Total income and income from sheep farming on “Ripollesa” breed
The sample of farms was obtained using a stratified farms
sampling by provinces. Two zones were defined: Mean ± S.D.∗
Gerona and Barcelona provinces, which are the main Income from sheep farming ( ) 29109 ± 15365
areas of Ripollesa breed farming. Amortizations were Income from sheep farming per sheep ( ) 78.4 ± 12.4
calculated using the linear amortization method, with Total subsidies/total income (%) 26.9 ± 7.0
a residual value of zero and a useful life of 25 years Sheep subsidies/sheep income (%) 27.6 ± 6.2
for buildings, 20 years for farm machinery and 10 Total income ( ) 49387 ± 52739
years for fencing. ∗ Standard deviation.
M.J. Milán et al. / Small Ruminant Research 49 (2003) 97–105 99

number of sheep in the flock (r = 0.48; P < 0.01) but Table 2


correlated negatively with the percentage represented Mean expenditure per sheep on “Ripollesa” breed farms
by income from sheep farming over total income (r = Expenditure ( ) Mean ± S.D.∗ (%)
−0.42; P < 0.01). This indicates that the most diver- Feed 14.1 ± 5.1 (69.2)
sified farms earn more income than those which deal Veterinary 2.6 ± 1.4 (12.6)
exclusively with sheep. One of the most significant Land rent 1.5 ± 2.3 (7.4)
sources of income was the public subsidies. These sub- Sheds 1.4 ± 1.2 (6.9)
sidies comprise a mean of 27% of the total income, Shearing 0.8 ± 0.3 (3.8)
with a maximum value of 39%. The amount of spe- Total livestock 20.4 ± 6.3 (100)
cific subsidies given to sheep farmers represented a ∗ Standard deviation.
mean of 73% of total subsidies.
Mean income from sheep farming (sale of meat, the dependency on external products for feed. Sheep
wool and sheep subsidies) was 29,109 per farm or related expenditure was 20.4 per sheep (Table 2)
78.4 per sheep. The “bonus” played an important part and had a mean percentage of 51% of total exter-
in the income derived from sheep farming (27.6%). nal expenditure. Farming expenditure per sheep cor-
The mean for sheep related income was 71% of total related significantly (P < 0.01) and inversely with the
farm income. Only on five farms did the total income AA of the farms (r = −0.39). Logically, as AA de-
derived from sheep farming. On 54% of the farms, creases farmers have to rely more heavily on bought
sheep farming generated more than 75% of income, feed and rented pastures. Mean feed expenditure per
while on 19% of farms this figure was below 50%. The sheep (which included everything bought to feed both
latter cases were farms with a small flock where other sheep and lambs) was 14.1 per sheep, with high vari-
livestock rearing was important or where a large area ability, depending on the availability of feed on the
was given over to the production and sale of cereals. farm. The mean health expenditure per sheep (includ-
Significant correlations were obtained (P < 0.01) be- ing medicines, reproductive treatment and veterinary
tween income from sheep farming and numerical pro- costs) was 2.6 per sheep. The wide dispersion in-
ductivity (number of saleable lambs per ewe joined) dicates the differences in health care that the flocks
(r = 0.96) and productivity index (weight of saleable receive. No correlation was found between this index
lambs per ewe joined) (r = 0.92) of the flocks, in and the productivity of the flocks. On some farms, the
spite of the seasonal nature of meat prices and the fact renting of pastures is an important part of expendi-
that these farms use continuous mating, with lambing ture on the flock (Table 2). Expenditure on rented pas-
taking place all the year round. ture had a mean of 6.6% of the farming expenditure.
No significant correlation was found between expen-
3.2. Farm expenditure diture on rented pastures per sheep and the AA of the
farm. Another type of cost to be taken into account
The items of expenditure that have been taken into is the group called “shedding costs” which included
account to obtain external expenditure were those re- electricity, water, cleaning products and disinfectants.
lated to sheep farming, expenditure related to other These costs had an inverse correlation with flock size
livestock rearing, the cost of renting buildings and the (r = −0.48; P < 0.01), which indicates the working
cost of crops. Labor costs and the rent of farms not of economies of scale.
owned by the farmer, were not included. Mean exter-
nal expenditure on the farm was 21,930 . Expenditure 3.3. Economic results
on crops had a mean percentage of 34% of the ex-
ternal expenditure of the farm. As would be expected Table 3 shows the mean economic results of the sur-
these costs correlated positively (P < 0.01) with agri- veyed farms. Gross agrarian production (GAP) of the
cultural area (AA) (r = 0.73) and negatively with farm was obtained by adding all forms of income from
farming costs (r = −0.43) and feed per sheep (r = the sale of farm products. The great importance of
−0.36). These correlations were due to the fact that subsidies on the economic results of the farms can be
an increase in crop production on the farm decreased observed. These subsidies comprised a mean of 52%
100 M.J. Milán et al. / Small Ruminant Research 49 (2003) 97–105

Table 3 farm expenditure over total expenditure and the per-


Mean economic results on “Ripollesa” breed sheep farms centage of income from sheep over total income. This
Parameter ( ) Mean ± S.D.∗ factor was indicative of the distribution and orienta-
Gross agrarian sales 37673 ± 48309
tion of the AA and characterizes farms which were
External expenditure 21930 ± 42249 relatively more specialized in cereal cultivation, with
Gross added value (mp)a 15743 ± 10276 recent investment in machinery and a higher relative
Subsidies 11714 ± 7321 importance of expenditure on crops, as opposed to
Gross added value (fc)b 27456 ± 16681 farms with a higher relative specialization in forage
Amortization 3077 ± 2416
Net added value (fc) 24378 ± 15891
and in which income from sheep and sheep farming
Wages and salaries paid 4647 ± 6302 costs were preponderant. The second principal com-
Net farm surplus 19731 ± 14620 ponent, which explained 15% of the variance, was a
Net farm surplus/family AWUc 16300 ± 12689 dimensional factor and characterized farms according
Net farm surplus without subsidies/family 6374 ± 7719 to the size of their flock. The third principal compo-
AWU
a
nent, which explained 10% of variance, was a fac-
Market prices.
b tor of economic dimension. These were farms with a
Factor cost.
c Annual work unit. high GAP and high costs, in which income from sheep
∗ Standard deviation. with respect to total income was not very important.
The fourth principal component, explaining 8% of
of the net added value at factor cost (NAVfc). Table 3 the variance, characterized farms with little AA, high
also reflects the net farm surplus (NFS) of the family livestock costs, high AA productivity and a high de-
annual work unit (AWU), which may be considered as gree of mechanization per hectare. These were farms
an indication of the economic sustainability of these on which expenditure on grazing land per sheep was
farms. The mean value is not high, given that theo- important. The fifth principal component, which ex-
retically it should remunerate the opportunity costs of plained 7% of the variance, typified farms with high
the factors (land, labor and capital) of the farm family. labor and sheep productivity; this value increased in
In order to appreciate the effect of direct subsidies on relation to increases of AA with total labor.
the NFS of the farm, the value of these subsidies was
subtracted, giving very low mean values. The overall 3.5. Establishment of typologies
results of the farm expressed in NAVfc correlate pos-
itively (P < 0.01) with flock size (r = 0.68) and with Four groups were obtained from the cluster analy-
AA (r = 0.47). They also have a negative correla- sis. Two groups of 20 farms each were the most sig-
tion with farming expenditure per sheep (r = −0.28; nificant. The other two groups were composed of four
P < 0.05). However, they have no correlation with the and two farms each. A total of six farms remained in-
numerical or productivity index of the flock. dividualized. Table 4 shows details of the mean val-
ues of land use of the farms for each group. Table 5
3.4. Characterizing factors of the farms shows the mean values of the availability of labor for
each group. The characteristics of each of the groups
The results of the PCA indicated that there were are discussed below.
11 factors with values higher than the unit, these ex-
plained 84% of the variance. The first five components 3.5.1. Group 1: farms with a strong bias to cereal
explained 60% of the variance. The first principal com- production
ponent explained 20% of the variance and had high Group 1 farms had a mean total surface (TS) of
and positive correlation coefficients with the percent- 214 ha and a mean AA of 56 ha, practically all of
age of cultivated cereal land over AA, the amortiza- which were cultivated. The farms had a high per-
tion of machinery, the percentage of crop costs with centage of woodland, occasionally used for grazing.
respect to total expenditure and with total labor costs. Nearly half of the AA was cultivated with winter cere-
The coefficients were high and negative with the per- als, the rest of the AA was given over mainly to forage
centage of forage land over AA, the percentage of (alfalfa and ryegrass predominated) and usually had
M.J. Milán et al. / Small Ruminant Research 49 (2003) 97–105 101

Table 4
Mean values of land distribution according to groups
Group 1 Group 2 Group 3 Group 4 P<

Number of farms 20 20 4 2 –
Total surface (ha) 214.2a 138.5a 125.0a 1738.0b <0.00
Agricultural area (ha) 55.8 43.4 26.5 86.0 NSa
Forage surface (ha) 25.3 39.5 24.8 68.5 NS
Natural pasture surface (ha) 0.4a 19.2b 3.7a,b 0.0a,b <0.05
Winter cereal surface (ha) 26.4a 3.6b 1.8b 17.5a,b <0.00
Arable land/AAb (%) 99.4a 73.5b 75.0a,b 100.0a,b <0.03
Cereal surface/AA (%) 47.6a 9.7b 5.8b 18.6b <0.00
Forage surface /AA (%) 45.5a 89.9b 94.2b 81.4b <0.00
Owned surface/TSc (%) 73.2a 47.3a,b 0.8b 17.3a,b <0.02
Power/AA (hpd /ha) 3.3 3.3 1.3 1.4 NS
Different letters in the same row indicate significant differences (P < 0.05).
a Not significant.
b Agricultural area.
c Total surface.
d Horse power; 1 hp = 0.7457 kW.

some irrigated land. The flocks were medium sized This helped certain reproductive and feeding practices.
and the livestock rate was the lowest (Table 5). On The majority (16) could also undertake mechanical
these farms sheep were not usually farmed together cleaning in the sheds. Nine farms had a race-way and
with other livestock. Total mean labor employed was four farms had a sheep dip. As well as having the
2.2 AWU, with a mean percentage of salaried workers most specialized installations for sheep production,
of 32.6%; these workers usually carried out shepherd- this group had the most modern installations. Nine
ing tasks. In this group, the owner usually worked full farms in the group had some type of fencing to control
time on the farm. With respect to flock management, grazing. Sheep farming costs were only 39% of total
on eight farms in this group discontinuous mating was farm costs (Table 6) as a consequence of the impor-
the usual practice while the rest preferred to have a tance of cropping activity on these farms. However,
more uniform production of lambs over the year since income from sheep was 61% of the total income, due
the product was sold directly to local butchers. to the fact that a large proportion of other agricultural
This was the group of farms which had invested production was given over to feed for the sheep (both
most heavily in recent years, both in buildings and in concentrates and forage). At the same time, sheep
machinery. In nearly all cases (19) they had installa- farming costs per sheep were low (compared to other
tions that allowed the sheep to be separated into pens. groups), due, above all, to the low cost of bought feed

Table 5
Mean Values of the availability of labor according to groups
Group 1 Group 2 Group 3 Group 4 P<

TotalAWUa 2.2a 1.5b 1.6a,b 2.2a,b <0.04


Family AWU 1.4 1.3 1.0 1.1 NSb
Salaried work/total AWU(%) 32.6a 9.6b 33.7a,b 50.0a,b <0.01
AAc /total AWU (ha) 24.9 30.0 17.6 39.1 NS
Sheep/total AWU 170a 200a 452b 402b <0.00
Age of owner (years) 44a 45a 61b 49a,b <0.03
Different letters in the same row indicate significant differences (P < 0.05).
a Annual work unit.
b Not significant.
c Agricultural area.
102 M.J. Milán et al. / Small Ruminant Research 49 (2003) 97–105

Table 6
Mean flock size, units of other livestock types, livestock rate and productivity according to group
Group 1 Group 2 Group 3 Group 4 P<

Sheep 367a 273b 667c 886c <0.00


Total LUa 85.2 53.5 139.0 141.5 NSb
LU ruminants/AAc 1.3a 1.8a 5.4b 1.7a <0.00
Lambs sold 361a 315a 683b 910b <0.00
Numerical productivityd 0.98 1.11 1.02 1.02 NS
Ponderal productivitye 22.9 26.1 23.0 24.5 NS
Different letters in the same row indicate significant differences (P < 0.05).
a Livestock unit.
b Not significant.
c Agricultural area.
d Lambs per sheep and year.
e kg per sheep and year.

and the rent for grazing land. As has been mentioned, bonuses and subsidies for arable crops. The mean eco-
these were farms with low livestock activity, on which nomic productivity (NAVfc/AA) of the land was the
the sheep used woodland grazing and stubble from lowest of the groups; although the mean economic
cereal production as well as forage produced on the productivity of the flock (NAVfc/LU sheep) was high.
farm, so that they had less need for grazing land out- NFS per family employee AWU was on average to
side the farm. The subsidies received were 29% of the low. If the subsidies to the farm are not taken into ac-
total income of the farms with a mean of 12,590 . count this group had the lowest NFS per family AWU
On these farms, subsidies came mainly from sheep (Table 7).

Table 7
Mean expenditure and economic results according to group
Group 1 Group2 Group 3 Group 4 P<

Pasture rent per sheep ( ) 0.7a 1.4a 3.5b 0.8a,b <0.01


Feed costs per sheep ( ) 11.3a 15.6b 19.3b 11.8a,b <0.00
Livestock expenditure per sheep ( ) 16.5a 22.4b 25.9b 16.8a,b <0.00
Sheep income per sheep ( ) 73.7 82.5 75.8 76.4 NSa
Livestock expenditure/TEb (%) 38.8a 63.6b 80.7c 58.5a,b,c <0.00
Agrarian gross sales (× 103 ) 33.2a 20.2b 39.0a 54.0a <0.00
Subsidies (× 103 ) ( ) 12.6a 6.5b 17.2a,c 22.0c <0.00
NAVfc (× 103 ) ( ) 24.5a 14.9b 32.8a,c 47.2c <0.00
Net farm surplus (× 103 ) ( ) 17.5a,b 13.0a 28.0b,c 35.2c <0.00
Sheep income/total income (%) 61.1a 85.6b 91.0b 91.0a,b <0.00
Subsidies/total income (%) 28.5 25.4 31.0 28.5 NS
Subsidies/NAVfc (%) 58.3 48.3 53.3 48.3 NS
NAVfcc /AA ( ) 470.0a 623.3a 1289.2b 535.5a,b <0.00
NAVfc/AWUd ( ) 11089a 10710a 21150b 20939b <0.00
NAVfc/Lue sheep ( ) 435.1 350.4 320.9 336.6 NS
NFSf /family AWU ( ) 13475a 10530a 35610b 30976b <0.00
NFS subsidy/family AWU ( ) 3577 4987 13656 11317 NS
Different letters in the same row indicate significant differences (P < 0.05).
a Not significant.
b Total expenditure.
c Net added value at factor cost.
d Annual work unit.
e Livestock unit.
f Net farm surplus.
M.J. Milán et al. / Small Ruminant Research 49 (2003) 97–105 103

3.5.2. Group 2: farms with a bias towards forage 1, which confirms that there was more reliance on
These farms were relatively small compared to those public subsidy than group 1.
in group 1 (Table 4). The mean arable land was approx-
imately 75% of the AA; the non-worked AA consisted 3.5.3. Group 3: farms with high livestock activity
mainly of natural pasture (19 ha). Ninety percent of These were farms with hardly any stable territorial
the AA was for forage (approximately 40 ha) for an- base. Most of the AA was grazing land (94%) with
imal feed. Rented land was more common than in a mean area of 11.3 ha under Italian ryegrass. The
group 1 and consisted of the whole farm or plots of area given over to winter cereals was correspondingly
land near the farm. Flock size was the smallest and small. In all cases, the land was almost entirely rented.
the farming of other livestock was unusual. The mean The mean size of flocks was high. The mean total la-
labor force was 1.5 AWU, with very few salaried bor force was 1.6 AWU and the mean percentage of
workers. Compared to group 1 it was more likely that salaried workers was 34%. This was the group with
the owner had some other gainful activity of external the highest number of family members, excluding the
work income and more likely that family members owner, working outside the farm. The mean age of
worked off the farm. A high percentage of “individ- the owner was the highest. This group had the high-
ual farms” as defined by Blanc (1987) were observed. est number of sheep and least AA per AWU. Having
The amount of investment in buildings and farm ma- less AA, the available labor worked almost completely
chinery was less than for group 1. All farms had in- with the sheep. Investment in buildings was the aver-
stallations for separating sheep into lots, but only 14 age, although if the number of sheep was taken into
farms could clean the sheds mechanically. In general, account, this was the lowest value together with group
these farms were less innovative than those in group 4. Mean investment in machinery was also the lowest
1, although fencing for grazing was more common in comparison to the other groups, with a mean mech-
(11 farms). Being farms with more of their own for- anization index which was lower than groups 1 and 2
age land and less labor, investment was made pri- (Table 4). They turned to outside help for a number
marily in improving working efficiency. The practice of tasks more than the other groups, especially when
of discontinuous mating was less frequent than in these required heavy machinery (for example, com-
group 1. bined harvesters). Mechanical cleaning of sheds was
Livestock expenditure (Table 7) per sheep was available in three of the four farms and on only two
higher than group 1. The mean cost per sheep de- could sheep be divided into pens. None of the farms
rived from renting grazing land was higher, as was had a race-way, sheep dip or hoof dip, which indicates
the mean cost for bought feed. This was due to the the low degree of specialization of the installations.
bias towards livestock on these farms and a greater This group had the highest proportion of farms with
dependence on outside factors, especially bought con- fencing for grazing (three farms), which meant a great
centrates. Livestock expenditure had a mean of 64% saving in labor costs in the group with the highest
of total expenditure and income from sheep were number of sheep per AWU. Only one farm undertook
86% of total income. This group was characterized discontinuous mating.
by having the highest numerical and mean productiv- This group had the highest mean livestock expen-
ity index of the flocks. Public subsidies were 25% of diture per sheep. As the livestock rate was high, they
total income. In absolute terms, this group received had to resort to buying feed products more than the
the least public subsidy, which was due to the smaller other groups, and to renting grazing land. Mean sheep
size of the flocks and smaller area of arable crops expenditure was 81% of total expenditure, and in-
eligible for subsidy. The mean economic productivity come from sheep was 91% of total income. In this
of the labor force (NAVfc/AWU) was the lowest of group of farms subsidies were 31% of total income,
the groups studied (Table 7), while flock productivity and these came almost entirely from the bonus for
was average (NAVfc/LUsheep) and land productiv- sheep. NFS per family AWU was the highest although
ity (NAVfc/AA) was higher than group 1. NFS per subsidies were not taken into account. Finally, these
family AWU was the lowest, although if this was cal- farms had the highest economic productivity of land
culated omitting subsidies it was higher than group (NAVfc/AA) and work (NAVfc/AWU) (Table 7).
104 M.J. Milán et al. / Small Ruminant Research 49 (2003) 97–105

3.5.4. Group 4: farms with a strong territorial of the dependence of the farms on these subsidies.
base and large flocks As an average, the total received subsidies reached
Although this group was composed of only two 27% of the total income of the farms, and 52% of the
farms, it represented a type of farm which was clearly NAVfc, which places them below the values described
differentiated from the rest of the sample surveyed. for sheep farms from other countries.
These were farms with a very high mean TS and a Four different groups can be formed depending on
mean AA of 86 ha, which was wholly cultivated. The the structural characteristics and economic results of
majority of land was grazing, principally Italian rye- the farms.
grass with a mean of 17 ha. Both farms had a high
• Group 1: Farms with a strong bias to cereal produc-
percentage of rented land. The flocks were large but
tion. These were diversified farms (fundamentally
the livestock rate was medium to low. Mean employed
sheep and cereal) in which, the income proceeding
labor was 2.2 AWU, with 50% of salaried workers.
from sheep activity reached 61% of the total in-
Neither the owner nor the family had work outside
come. NFS per family AWU was average to low,
the farm. Both the AA and the number of sheep per
and if the subsidies are taken away they represent
labor AWU were high. Investment in buildings was
the lowest value of the set of analyzed farms.
low. The annual amortization of agricultural machin-
• Group 2: Farms with a bias towards forage. These
ery was high in absolute terms. However, the relative
were smaller farms that use the land for the pro-
value was the lowest of all the groups, which indi-
duction of forages to feed the flock. They are more
cates that having a larger cultivated area the farm ob-
specialized. The mean NFS per family AWU was
tained higher profitability from these investments. On
the lowest.
both farms, animals could be separated into lots and
• Group 3: Farms with high livestock activity. These
the sheds could be cleaned mechanically. Neither farm
were farms with a small area and large flocks, with
had fencing for grazing. Livestock expenditure per
a greater dependence on buying feed and renting
sheep was one of the lowest values of all the groups.
grazing land. NFS per family AWU was the highest
Fifty-nine percent of the external expenditure corre-
although subsidies were not taken into account.
sponded to the sheep. Sheep farming brought in 91%
• Group 4: Farms with a strong territorial base and
of total income. A large part of agricultural production
large flocks. These were farms specializing in sheep
was destined as animal feed. Subsidies were 28.5% of
production in which a large part of agricultural pro-
total income and as an absolute value they were the
duction was destined to be animal feed. The mean
highest. They came from bonuses for sheep and sub-
NFS per family AWU was high. The profitability of
sidies for arable crops. This group of farms had the
labor was high.
highest mean NAVfc of the sample studied. NFS per
family AWU was high. The profitability of the land Groups 3 and 4 secured higher profitability due to
and the flock was average, while the economic pro- the fact that they had the largest flocks with approxi-
ductivity of labor was high (Table 7). mately the same utilization of labor. In both, the prof-
itability of labor was high.

4. Conclusion
References
From the obtained results, it is possible to conclude
Accounts Tribunal of the EC, 1995. Informe especial no. 13/95
that the economic sustainability of the studied farms sobre la aplicación de las medidas de intervención previstas
is not assured. The average value of the net farm sur- para la organización de mercados en el sector de las carnes de
plus of the family annual work unit is 16,300 . It ovino y caprino (Special report no. 3/95 on the application of
must be taken into account that this should remuner- the ways of foreseeable interventions for the organization of
ate the opportunity costs of the factors (land, labor markets in the sector of sheep and goat meat). DOCE N1285/1,
28 October 1995, 38 pp.
and capital) of the farm family. If this index is calcu- Bazin, G., 1994. Aides directes et disparites des revenus agricoles
lated without taking into account the direct subsidies a (Deficiency payments and disparities of agricultural revenues).
very low average value is obtained, that gives an idea Econ. Rurale 220–221, 192–196.
M.J. Milán et al. / Small Ruminant Research 49 (2003) 97–105 105

Blanc, M., 1987. Family and employment in agriculture: recent Hair, J.F., Anderson, R.E., Tatham, R.L., 1987. Multivariate Data
changes in France. J. Agric. Econ. 38, 289–301. Analysis with Readings. MacMillan, New York, USA.
Blanchemain, A., 1989. The diversity of sheep production systems Johnson, R.A., Wichern, D.W., 1982. Applied multivariate
in France: a first analysis. Etudes et Recherches sur les Systèmes statistical analysis. 594 pp.
Agraires et le développement 16, 47–53. Judez, L., 1989. Técnicas de análisis de datos multidimensionales
Blanchemain, A., Flamant, J.C., 1983. Voies et impasses du (Technologies for the analysis of multidimensional infor-
développement de l’élevage ovin et caprin en zones difficiles mation). MAPA. Madrid, 301 pp.
(The development of ovine and caprine breeding in difficult Liénard, G., Cordonnier, P., Boutonnet, J.P. Exploitations et
zones). In: 10 Journées pour la Recherche ovine et caprine. systèmes de production d’herbivores INRA. Importance, évolu-
INRA-ITOVIC-SPEOC, Paris, pp. 3–26. tion, questions (Farms and productin systems of herbivores.
Boutonnet, J.P., 1993. Les revenus des éleveurs ovins (Revenues Importance, evolution, questions). Prod. Anim. 5, 1, 59–85.
of sheep farmers). SFER. Session sur les revenus agricoles. Manrique, E., Maza, M.T., Olaizola, A.M., 1992. Adaptación
Montpellier, 12 pp. de los sistemas de producción ovina de carne a un mercado
Cahn, A., 1990. The EC sheep meat regime, the political competitivo y a una PAC reformada (Adjustment of the meat
dimension. In: Slade, C.F.R., Lawrence, T.L.J., Davies, H., sheep production systems for a competitive market and for
Pitkethly, M.C. (Eds.), New Developments in Sheep Production. a reformed CAP). In: I Congreso Nacional de Economı́a y
British Society of Animal Production, Edinburgh, pp. 1–5. Sociologı́a Agraria, Zaragoza.
Caja, G., Such, X., 1991. Situación de la producción de leche Manrique, E., Sáez, A., Olaizola, A.M., 1994. La economı́a de
de oveja en el mundo y clasificación de los principales la producción ovina: de las rentas de la explotación a la
sistemas de producción de ovino lechero (The situation of milk gestión medioambiental (The economy of sheep production:
production of sheep throughout the world and classification of from farming revenues to environmental management). In:
the principal production systems of sheep milk). Ovis 14, 11– Gallego, L., Pérez, J.I. (Eds.), Producción Ovina y Caprina,
27. pp. 59–88.
Capillon, A., 1985. Connaı̂tre la diversité des exploitations: un SPSS Inc., 1998. SPSS statistical package (6.1.2) for Windows.
préalable à la recherche de réferences techniques regionales Chicago, IL, USA.
(Knowing the variety of the farms: a preliminary research of Zorita, E., 1990. Hacia una nueva estructura de la ganaderı́a
regional technical references). Agriscope 6, 31–40. ovina en España, armonizando recursos alimenticios y objetivos
Departament d’Agricultura, Ramaderia i Pesca (DARP), 2000. medioambientales (Towards a new structure of sheep livestock
Estadı́stica i conjuntura agrària (Agrarian conjuncture and in Spain, harmonizing feeding resources and environmental
statistics), vols. 150–151, Barcelona, 125 pp. objectives). Ovis 11, 9–42.

You might also like