You are on page 1of 20

World Development Vol. 32, No. 9, pp.

1525–1544, 2004
Ó 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/$ - see front matter
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.05.004

Foreign Direct Investment, Vertical Integration,


and Local Suppliers: Evidence from the Polish
Dairy Sector
LIESBETH DRIES
Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium

and

JOHAN F. M. SWINNEN *
The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA
Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium
Available online
Summary. — Studies argue that foreign investment has negative implications for small local
suppliers, as they cannot comply with higher standards or they are laid off to reduce transaction
costs. We analyze the impact of FDI in the Polish dairy sector, a sector dominated by small
suppliers and of crucial importance for poor rural households. The analysis shows that FDI does
not cause a rapid consolidation of the supply base. Instead, foreign companies introduce farm
assistance programs to overcome market imperfections. Through vertical and horizontal spillover
effects, this leads to improved access to finance, increased investments, product quality
improvements, and growth of small local suppliers.
Ó 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — Central Eastern Europe, Poland, dairy sector, vertical coordination, FDI

1. INTRODUCTION yet other studies conclude that the impact on


local firms is negative (Aitken & Harrison,
The public debate on globalization has 1999). The difference in the findings comes from
renewed interest in the effects of foreign direct two opposing effects of FDI. On the one hand,
investment (FDI). Some see foreign investment FDI can introduce new products and technol-
as a beneficial factor that can be an important ogies, and domestic companies can benefit from
source of much needed capital, technology, this through personnel turnover, demonstration
knowledge etc. for poorer countries. Others
point at the dangers of multinational compa-
nies crowding out local companies as well as * The authors thank Hamish Gow for discussions on the
introducing imperfect competition. issues addressed here and for collaboration in part of the
There is a growing empirical literature on the data collection. Furthermore we are grateful to Ewa
impact of FDI, which can be separated into Maciag, Mr. Klekotka, Dr. Uminski and students from
two strands. A first group of studies focuses on the University of Gdansk for their help with the survey.
horizontal spillover effects of foreign invest- This research was supported by the European Com-
ment on domestic firms. The conclusions from mission under its Phare/ACE Research Program (P98-
these studies are mixed: some studies find 1007-R). The opinions expressed in this paper are those
positive effects (Hu & Jefferson, 2002; Liu, of the authors only, and do not necessarily reflect those
2002), and others, no significant effect (Kokko, of the institutions with which they are affiliated. Final
Tansini, & Zejan, 1996; Konings, 2001), and revision accepted: 12 May 2004.
1525
1526 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

effects and knowledge spillovers. These hori- The second objective of this paper is to
zontal spillovers are however, only important if analyze and understand the mechanism and
the technology gap between the foreign and process of how FDI affects the local economy,
domestic firms is not too large (Kokko, 1994). and in particular (small) suppliers. A major
A negative FDI effect can come from FDI problem in transition countries is the break-
cutting into the local companies’ market share. down of exchange systems and contract
Hence, the different findings of the studies enforcement mechanisms (Blanchard, 1999;
reflect the relative importance of these two Konings & Walsh, 1999). Private institutional
factors in the various countries and sectors. innovations have solved these problems in
A second group of studies focuses on vertical some countries (Johnson, McMillan, &
spillover effects. Studies find that foreign firms Woodruff, 1999; Mcmillan & Woodruff, 1999).
facilitate the adoption of new technologies and Case studies suggest that foreign investors have
can solve contract enforcement problems (Gow played an important role in this process
& Swinnen, 1998; Key & Runsten, 1999). Yet through vertical integration (Foster, 1999;
most studies conclude that the impact on local Gow, Streeter, & Swinnen, 2000). At least in
suppliers is mostly negative, in particular for some cases such FDI-induced vertical integra-
small suppliers in developing countries (Dolan tion has contributed to improved access to
& Humphrey, 2000; Weatherspoon & Reardon, finance and inputs, and productivity growth of
2003). The latter often cannot comply with the suppliers (Gow & Swinnen, 2001). But, so far
higher standards and grading requirements for there is no representative statistical evidence on
the supplied products (Farina & Reardon, these effects. This paper will be the first to
2000; Henson, Loader, & Brouder, 2000; provide representative evidence on these effects,
Reardon, Codron, Busch, Bingen, & Harris, and to estimate econometrically the effect of
1999). Moreover, foreign investors prefer to these institutional innovations on the survival
deal with a few large suppliers to minimize and growth of small suppliers.
transaction costs, forcing consolidation of the Our empirical analysis uses data from Poland
supplier base and hence separating many small and specifically from the Polish dairy sector. To
suppliers from their traditional outlets (Hollo- identify both the effects of FDI and the process
way, Nicholson, Delgado, Staal, & Ehui, 2000; through which these effects occur, we collected
Runsten & Key, 1996; Winters, 2000). Reardon data at several levels. More specifically, we
and Berdegue (2002) show, in the case of retail collected data through a series of in-depth
investors in Latin America, how this process interviews with domestic and foreign owned
can lead to the rapid exclusion of thousands of companies at the level where the foreign
small suppliers. investment took place (dairy processing and
The first objective of this paper is to study the marketing) as well as through a random survey
impact of foreign direct investment on suppli- of (potential) local suppliers (dairy farms) to
ers, and in particular small suppliers, in tran- these companies. We also interviewed some
sition countries. Many companies in transition dairy equipment suppliers. In combination the
countries are (or were) in severe need of collected information constitutes a unique
restructuring and upgrading of capital, tech- dataset on the impact of FDI on (small) sup-
nology, and management. This holds across the pliers.
transition world, but is especially pronounced We selected the Polish dairy sector for several
in those countries which are now most open to reasons. First, Poland is the largest of the EU
external competition, either because trade accession countries, yet a small economy in the
restrictions were liberalized in the transition world market. Poland produced around 12
process, or, for several Central and Eastern million tons of milk in 2000, which represents
European countries, because they will soon be 2.5% of total production in the world. The
integrated in a single EU market in which they accession of Poland alone would increase total
will have to compete with other EU companies. milk output in the EU with 10% (FAO, 2003).
At the same time, transition countries, and in Yet milk production and the dairy sector have
particular those closer to the EU, have received been severely affected by the economic and
a large inflow of FDI over the past years. For institutional reforms over the past ten years.
these reasons, studying the impact of FDI in Milk production and the number of dairy cows
transition countries can provide very useful fell by almost 30% during 1989–96. Productiv-
insights. ity also declined initially but has turned around
FDI VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS 1527

since 1992 and since 1997 yields are above their search for new markets, and allowed foreign
pre-reform level. 1 companies to invest in the Polish dairy sec-
Second, agriculture is a very important sector tor. 5 By 1999 there had been a total inflow of
in the Polish economy and characterized by US$4.6 billion of foreign investments into the
unfavorable structures and low incomes. Polish agri-food sector, 5% of which has gone
Almost 20% of the population is employed in to dairy processing and dairy equipment
agriculture, mostly on small farms. Poland is companies.
unique among the transition countries in that it The combined impact of privatization and
had a mixed institutional structure in agricul- FDI on the structure of the dairy sector has
ture under the Communist regime. Small pri- been modest (see Table 2): the total number of
vate family farms survived the Communist dairy processing companies with more than 50
collectivization and occupied 76% of total employees decreased by 22% during 1993–99.
agricultural land. 2 The remaining land was The decrease was mainly in the number of
used by large-scale state farms. 3 Hence, in cooperatives, as the number of (noncoopera-
contrast to other Communist countries where tively-owned) private companies doubled. Yet,
small farms resulted from the fragmentation cooperatives still controlled 70% of the dairy
and decollectivization of the former collective market by 1999. Twenty of the 50 privately-
farms, both small farms and large farms have a owned dairies had majority foreign investor
strong historical and institutional basis in ownership.
Poland. In combination, these characteristics make
Third, dairy plays an important role in Polish the Polish dairy sector a very interesting case
rural areas since many of the small farms have and potentially a rich source of insights for the
at least some milk production. Out of approx- study of FDI impacts, in particular regarding
imately 1.3 million dairy farms, 89% had only vertical spillover effects and the impact on small
1–4 cows in 1996 (see Table 1). Farms with suppliers. Moreover, continued FDI in the
fewer than 10 cows produced 75% of Poland’s Polish dairy sector could have very significant
milk. Less than 60% of total milk production repercussions for the sector, for the many small
was delivered to dairies; the rest was used for supplying farms, and obviously for rural
self-consumption or directly sold on the local welfare and development more generally.
market. By 2000, 85% of Polish dairy farms still Therefore understanding the impacts is useful
had fewer than five cows (GUS, 2001). both for the study of Poland and for more
Fourth, the dairy sector––both the process- general lessons.
ing companies and the farms––were (and still The paper is organized as follows. In Section
are) in need of substantial restructuring in 2, we discuss the data that were collected both
order to be competitive on the international at the dairy-processing level and through a
market. In the early 1990s Polish milk pro- unique survey of local milk producers. Next, we
duction was generally characterized by low discuss qualitative evidence on the impact of
productivity and low quality. While the situa- foreign direct investments and vertical integra-
tion has improved importantly since the mid tion in the dairy sector on supplier restructur-
1990s, even in 1999 only 20% of the 450,000 ing. In Section 4, we present an econometric
producers delivering milk to dairies delivered analysis of the impact of FDI on survival and
exclusively milk of the highest quality (Swedish growth of local milk producers. Finally, Sec-
Board of Agriculture, 2001). The small scale of tion 5 draws conclusions.
the family farms creates specific investment
problems for upgrading milk quality, as well as
problems for investors in the dairy processing
companies, because of transaction costs of milk 2. DATA
collection.
Fifth, Poland has attracted significant FDI To identify both the effects of FDI and the
in the dairy sector, 4 yet at the same time local process through which these effects occur,
companies continue to have a large share of we collected data through a series of in-
the market. The liberalization of the Polish depth interviews with domestic and foreign-
trade system and the privatization of the owned dairy-processing companies and
processing industry in the 1990s opened the through a random survey of local dairy farms
Polish dairy sector to increased competition which are potential suppliers to these compa-
from abroad, allowed Polish exporters to nies.
1528
Table 1. Structure of private farms in the Polish dairy sector, 1996–2000
Total Herd size (number of cows per farm)
1 2 3–4 5–9 10–19 20–29 30–49 50–99 100–199 >200

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
Number of 1,307,320 547,122 363,004 249,714 126,579 19,281 975 246 218 141 40
farms (1996)
As a percentage of total number of farms
1996 100 41.9 27.8 19.1 9.7 1.5 0.1 0 0 0 0
1998 100 40.6 26.9 19.3 10.6 2.5 0.1 0 0 0 0
1999 100 42.8 26.1 17.8 10.0 2.9 0.3 0.1 0 0 0
2000 100 44.6 24.6 16.9 10.0 3.4 0.4 0.1 0 0 0
% Change +2.7 )3.2 )2.2 +0.3 +1.9 +0.3 +0.1
1996–2000
Source: GUS (2001).
FDI VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS 1529

Table 2. Number of dairy companies with more than 50 employees in Poland, 1993–1999
1993 1994 1995 1996 1999 Change 93–99 (%)
Total 410 332 318 321 320 )22
Cooperatives 352 309 284 280 270 )24
Public companies 30 12 0 0 0 )100
Commercial law companies 28 11 34 41 50 +79
Source: Majewski and Dalton (2000).

(a) Small suppliers Around 45% of the households in the survey


supplied milk to foreign-owned dairies, 55% to
The farm-level data collection focused on domestically-owned.
small suppliers and the data were collected in a Most of the so-called farms listed in the
2001 survey of 290 dairy-producing rural official Polish statistics as dairy farms are
households in the Warminsko-Mazurskie merely households producing for home con-
region in the North-East of Poland. Warmin- sumption. They account for the vast majority
sko-Mazurskie is an interesting region for this of the one- and two-cow ‘‘farms’’ which make
analysis because it is an important dairy region up 70% of the total number of dairy farms in
in Poland and because it has a mixture of large- Poland (Table 1), and 36% of dairy farms in
scale and small-scale farms––unlike some other Warminsko-Mazurski (Table 4). Because of the
regions in Poland. At the start of transition focus of our analysis, i.e., to understand how
large-scale state farms (cooperatives were the changes in the processing sector introduced
almost nonexistent in Poland) farmed between by FDI affected the suppliers, our survey con-
30% and 50% of agricultural land in the centrated on those households which delivered
region. 6 at least some milk to dairies at the start of the
We interviewed 290 rural households who period covered by the survey (1995). As a
had at least had some dairy production in the consequence, households with 1–2 cows repre-
past six years. Specifically, only households sent a smaller group in our survey sample: 3%
were selected which produced and delivered in 1995 and 10% in 2000.
milk to a dairy processor in 1995. The survey Even with this selection focus however, the
therefore also covers households that have vast majority of the farms in the sample are
stopped producing and/or delivering milk to a very small by (West or East) European stan-
processor since 1995. By using this methodol- dards. The majority of farms in the sample
ogy we have tried to minimize sample selection (57%) had less than 10 cows and 96% of the
bias due to exits. farms had less than 20 cows in 1995 (Table 4).
This survey was performed in the fall of 2001 The average size of dairy farms in the sample
and included retrospective questions on chan- was 8.8 cows in 1995 and 10.5 cows in 2000.
ges that had occurred over the previous six
years––more or less the period after the arrival
of foreign investors in dairy companies in the (b) Dairy companies
region. The households were selected randomly
in certain municipalities. As in the rest of We selected six dairy companies for in-depth
Poland, domestic dairies still far outnumber interviews with the management. Key charac-
foreign-owned dairies. To ensure that the teristics of the companies are summarized in
sample included a considerable number of Table 5. The selection of the dairy companies
farmers that had been in contact with foreign- was based on three criteria: FDI, ownership
owned dairy companies and their policies, we structure, and size. In terms of foreign invest-
overrepresented municipalities in the vicinity to ment, two of the selected companies are
the three foreign-owned dairies in the region majority foreign-owned, two have important
(ICC––Paslek; Warmia Dairy; Kraft/Bel–– links to foreign companies, and two are purely
Chorzele). 7 domestic. Four are medium-size companies
Table 3 shows how the 290 households in the (50–70 million liters of milk), one large (420
survey deliver (or delivered) milk to 24 different million liters) and one small (2.5 million liters).
dairy companies, which greatly vary in size. Three are cooperatives, two private, and one a
1530 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 3. Dairy companies in the survey


Dairy Actual # farmers # Farmers in the sample # Farmers in the sample
delivering to this delivering to this dairy in delivering to this dairy in
dairy in 2001 1995 2001
OSM Elblag n.a. 30 20
Nowy Dwor n.a. 0 6
ICC Paslek 461 42 25
Olsztyn 232 4 3
Warmia Dairy 2,600 58 56
Lukta 130 13 7
Ostroda n.a. 4 0
Morag n.a. 3 10
Mostkowo n.a. 1 0
Marowieckie n.a. 1 2
Milejewoa n.a. 1 0
Lecza n.a. 1 0
Mazowsze, Chorzelea 2,500 26 25
Szczytno 500 9 2
Gizycko 2,200 19 26
Nidzicki 540 0 1
Mragowob (2,300) 34 0
Olecko 1,500 28 25
Mlekpol, Grajewo 14,000 1 26
Ostrolecka n.a. 0 5
Kurpie, Baranowo 3,450 3 7
Jezioranya n.a. 2 0
Gdansk n.a. 1 1
Other n.a. 2 1
# % # %
FDI processors total 126 45 106 43
No-FDI processors total 157 55 143 57
Total (%) 283 100 249 100
a
Kraft/bel––Chorzele.
b
Bankrupt in 2001. Mragowo dairy merged with Mlekpol in Grajewo.

Table 4. Share of farms in our survey by size classes and processor


Number of cows per farm
1 2 3–4 5–9 10–19 20 Total
Sample 1995 1.7 1.4 12.8 40.7 39.3 4.1 100
Sample 2000 5.1 5.9 10.3 26.9 35.9 12.4 100
W-Ma 2000 22 13.8 19.1 29.1 13.1 2.9 100
No-FDIb 1995 1.3 1.3 12.1 40.1 42 3.2 100
No-FDI 2000 6.4 3.8 10.2 29.9 31.8 12.7 100
FDI 1995 0.8 0.8 12.7 42.1 38.1 5.6 100
FDI 2000 3.2 5.6 10.3 23.8 42.9 12.7 100
a
Warminsko-Mazurskie region.
b
No-FDI is the group of farmers that were delivering to a domestic dairy company in 1995; FDI includes farmers
delivering to a foreign owned dairy in 1995.

joint venture of a cooperative and a private cies vis-


a-vis their suppliers based on the
company. information collected in both the interviews
In the next section we discuss how the foreign and the surveys. Later on we develop an
investments have affected dairy company poli- econometric model to assess how these changes
Table 5. Fact sheet on selected Polish dairy companies
Mlekpol Mleczarnia Kurpie Mazowsze ICC Paslek Warmia Dairy
Location Grajewo Paslek Baranowo Chorzele Paslek Lidzbark-Warminski

FDI VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS


Legal structure Cooperative Private company Cooperative Cooperative Joint venture Private company
private and coop
Main products Drinking milk, Yoghurt Cheese, butter Drinking milk, Cheese, butter, Skimmed milk pow-
cream, butter, butter, cheese, drinking milk, der (85% of output)
milk powder, cream, milk for yoghurt powder,
cheese, yoghurt further processing whey powder
Foreign owner No No No No Yes Yes
Since when? 1994 1995
Foreign share (%) 70 100
Home country USA NL
Supply to foreign dairy Hochland (2000) Bel/Kraft (1995)
Number of employees 900 10 200 240 250 310
Annual milk supply (ltr.) 420 mio 2.5 mio 65 mio 55 mio 52.5 mio 70 mio
Does company offer the
following programs?
Credit program Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Input supply program Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Agricultural extension Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Veterinary service No No No No No Yes
Bank loan guarantee Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes
Since when? 1994 1992 1991 1992 1995 1995
Since when do you apply 1994 1999 1999 1995 1995 1999
EU standard classification
system?

1531
1532 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

have affected the survival and growth of small markets, while it ensures timely delivery and
suppliers to the dairy companies. high-quality supplies for the company.

(b) Spillover effects


3. FOREIGN INVESTMENT, VERTICAL
INTEGRATION, AND SUPPLIER These initiatives by foreign investors not only
RESTRUCTURING had important direct vertical spillover effects on
their own suppliers, but also much wider spill-
(a) Foreign investment and vertical integration over effects. Local dairy companies quickly
learned about the change in company policies
Foreign companies played an important role implemented by foreign owners and they star-
in demonstrating the importance of supplier ted to copy the successful programs and adjust
assistance programs and quality improvement their own company policies. Our interviews
strategies. For example, when Land O’ Lakes show that by 2001 all the interviewed dairies
invested in ICC Paslek in 1994, milk quality of have programs that assist their supplying
its supplying farms––as everywhere in the farms:
region––was poor. From the start, the foreign ––All companies have an input supply pro-
investor set out a clear strategy to increase the gram: the companies provide suppliers ac-
quality of delivered milk. The strategy included cess to feed and to inputs for on-farm feed
basic changes and investments. One of the first production, such as seed and fertilizer.
changes was to invest in cooling tanks in col- Farmers purchase the inputs through com-
lection points where small suppliers delivered pany shops and the inputs are paid from
their milk. 8 Furthermore, they invested in the milk checks.
agricultural extension to raise small farmers’ ––Five out of six companies assist farms in
awareness of the importance of milk quality investing through credit and investment assis-
and to teach farmers about basic hygienic rules tance programs. Investment assistance takes
in handling the milk. From the beginning, the the form of leasing of milk equipment and
foreign investor also required germ count and leasing of cows, as well as loans for buying
cell count tests (in accordance with EU stan- new or second hand cooling and milking
dard tests for milk quality classification). equipment. Payments are deducted from fu-
Farmers were also allowed to have their milk ture payments for milk deliveries.
tested for antibiotic residues free of charge in ––Five of the dairies provide bank loan guar-
the dairy’s laboratory. This was especially antees for bank loans to farmers. Almost all
helpful for farmers who had had a cow disease bank loans for farm investments have prefer-
at their farm and who needed to make sure that ential interest rates (subsidized interest rates
no antibiotics residue was left in the milk. around 5% compared to commercial loans
Faced with small suppliers unable to make with interest rates often above 20%). In or-
basic investments and restricted in their access der to obtain such a loan, the farmer needs
to basic inputs (such as feed, working capital, collateral. In many cases, however land or
etc.) due to a variety of market imperfections, buildings are not accepted as a bank guaran-
foreign investors also introduced other farm tee. Therefore, most interviewed dairies pro-
assistance programs, such as input (feed) sup- vide an additional service to their suppliers
ply programs, trade credit, investment assis- by co-signing the bank loan. In this way
tance programs, etc. (see below). Payments for the dairy provides the bank loan guarantee
this supplier assistance and the loans is done and facilitates its farmers’ access to bank
typically through deductions of the ‘‘milk credits.
check’’ at the time of payment for the milk. ––The companies also provide extension ser-
Enforcement of the payments is done by vices to their suppliers. The only dairy that
effectively interlinking output and input mar- did not provide credit assistance programs
kets: assistance programs are restricted to or agricultural extension services to its sup-
farms supplying to the company and part of an pliers was the small dairy, Mleczarnia, prob-
(implicit) contract between the farm and the ably because it did not have sufficient means
company. 9 In other words, if successful, 10 this (size).
process of FDI-induced vertical integration The conclusion that horizontal spillover
between supplier and company enhances the effects have caused a rapid replication of these
farms’ access to basic inputs, credit, and output programs by domestic companies is confirmed
FDI VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS 1533

Table 6. Foreign ownership and financial assistance programs (% of farms delivering)


Total Foreign owned Domestic
Credit program on-farm investments 71.5 71.6 71.4
Credit program cows 72.1 73.9 70.7
Input supply program 78.1 78.9 77.5
Loan guarantee program 37.2 46.2 29.8
Average 71.5 71.6 71.4

by data from our farm survey, as summarized dairies. As explained above, assistance also
in Table 6. By 2001, more than 70% of the includes guarantees for bank loans. Hence, part
farms deliver to companies with input supply of the loans given by the banks is indirectly due
and credit programs, and there is no significant to these loan guarantee programs of dairies.
difference between foreign and local companies. The importance of the loan guarantee pro-
The only difference is in access to bank loan grams should not be underestimated. Almost
guarantees, which is significantly higher for half (45%) of the households who could not
those delivering to foreign companies (46%) obtain preferential bank loans identified lack of
than for those delivering to local dairies (30%). sufficient collateral as the main reason.
Third, the programs which assist farms in
accessing inputs (mainly feed) enhance invest-
(c) Impact on farm investments ment indirectly by lowering input costs, or
reducing transaction costs in accessing inputs,
The assistance programs had an important and consequently, through improved profit-
impact on dairy farm investments in the region. ability.
More than three-quarters (76%) of all farms in
the survey made investments in the past 10
years, and 92% of all farms with more than 10 (d) Impact on quality
cows (see Table 7). Of those that invested, 58%
used loans, almost half of which came from the The combined impact of these programs is
dairies . also reflected in the quality of the milk deliv-
These numbers however, underestimate the ered. Figure 1 illustrates how the quality of the
impact of the dairy company programs on farm milk delivered to the six interviewed dairy
investment for three reasons. First, dairy loans companies improved dramatically over 1996–
are more important for dairy-related invest- 2001. While in 1996 only around 30% of the
ments than bank loans which are more gener- milk delivered to the dairies was, on average, of
ally used: 86% of all loans from dairy the highest (extra) class of milk quality (the
companies are used for investments in enlarg- highest quality by EU standards), this share has
ing and upgrading the livestock herd (30%) and increased to more than 80% by 2001.
cooling tanks (56%). In contrast, only 29% of
all bank loans are used for these types of (e) Dynamics of spillover effects
investments.
Second, loans from dairies are only a partial The evidence suggests that foreign invest-
indicator of the financial assistance offered by ment has played a more important role early on

Table 7. Investments and loans of farm households


Size Invests Uses loan to Uses dairy Uses bank Uses dairy loan Uses bank loan
(# of (% of invest (% of A) loan (% of B) loan (% of B) (% of A) (% of A)
cows) total)
A B C D E F
1–5 52 54 41 50 21 26
6–10 78 51 43 70 22 36
>10 92 74 43 75 31 54
All 76 58 43 69 25 40
1534 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Share of Extra Class Milk in Total (%)


100
90
80
70 Mlekpol
60
Mleczarnia
50
Kurpie
40
Mazowsze
30
ICC Paslek
20
10 Warmia Dairy
0
1996 1998 2001

Figure 1. Change in share of highest quality milk (EU standard) by dairy company.

in the transition as an initiator of change and companies we interviewed had on-farm cooling
institutional innovation. We found no signifi- tanks: the share of suppliers with on-farm
cant difference in 2001 between assistance pro- cooling tanks was 3% on average for the four
grams provided by foreign-owned companies domestic companies and only 9% on average
and domestic dairies, except for the loan even for the two foreign-owned companies. By
guarantee programs, which were more exten- 2001, the share had grown to 51% on average
sively provided by the foreign dairies. for the foreign-owned companies, while only to
The survey data confirm that important 22% on average for the domestic companies.
convergence has occurred in milk quality
between domestic and foreign-owned dairies (f) Impact on survival and growth of small
and their suppliers as spillover effects in com- suppliers
pany programs have multiplied. In 1995 the
supply of extra class milk was significantly How did the opening of the dairy sector to
larger among farmers delivering to foreign- foreign investment, competition and increased
owned dairies (58%) than among farmers quality requirements affect the survival and
delivering to domestic dairies (38%). By 2000 growth of dairy farms? Were small dairy
however this gap had almost disappeared: 83% farmers forced out of the market or did they
of foreign versus 79% of domestic dairy sup- manage to survive and upgrade their farms
pliers (see Figure 2). with the assistance of the programs discussed
Adjustments and convergence are slower above?
when they require important investments. In Our survey data show that of the 283
1996 very few of the suppliers to the six dairy households delivering milk to dairy companies

90
Share of farms with Extra class milk

80 FDI
70 no-FDI
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1995 2000

Figure 2. Change in share of highest quality milk (EU standard) in the farm survey.
FDI VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS 1535

35
1995
30
2000
25

Frequency
20

15

10

0
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25
Herd size

Figure 3. Size distribution of dairy farms in total survey sample. Each data point gives the average frequency of farms in
three consecutive size classes of which the data point itself is the size class in the middle. For example, the data point for
herd size three signifies the average number of farms with herd sizes 2, 3 and 4.

in 1995, 36 (13%) stopped delivering milk dur- In the next section we further analyze this
ing 1995–2000. Ten of them (4%) stopped restructuring process. We econometrically esti-
producing altogether while the rest (9%) kept mate the impact of various factors, among
some cows for home consumption. Hence, 87% which the ownership structure of the dairy
continued delivering to dairies despite radical company and assistance programs offered to
restructuring of the dairies and tightened suppliers, on the survival and growth of local
quality demands. Moreover, most of those who suppliers.
stopped delivering may have stopped anyhow:
the average age of those who stopped is 56
years, compared to 45 years for the entire 4. ECONOMETRIC EVIDENCE
sample. In fact, the average annual decline in
delivering farms in our sample ()2.6%) is less (a) Model and variables
than the average annual decline in agricultural
employment in Poland over the same period To complement our qualitative insights and
()3.3%). econometrically to quantify the direct effect of
The size distribution changed importantly foreign investment and the assistance programs
(see Figure 3). Three-quarters of the house- on small suppliers, we estimate a model based
holds (211) had between four and 12 cows in on the firm growth literature. This literature
1995. The share of farms in the 4–12 cow cat- starts from the ‘‘law of proportionate effects’’
egory has reduced significantly with about the or Gibrat’s law, stating that firm growth rates
same amount upgrading to a larger size and are independent of initial firm size. Following
falling back to smaller, presumably subsistence, Evans (1987), Hart and Oulton (1996) and Hall
farms producing for home consumption. More (1997) the supplier growth relationship is
specifically, of the 211 household farms, 135 specified as follows.
(65%) had still between four and 12 cows in
2000; 35 (17%) had less than four cows in 2000, d
Si;t ¼ ½F ð:; Si;t0 Þ ðSi;t0 Þð1 þ ei;t Þ ð1Þ
while 41 (19%) had more than 12 cows in 2000.
Farmers with growing farms were significantly where Si;t and Si;t0 denote the size of supplier i
younger (42 years on average) than those whose respectively at time t, the current period and t0 ,
farm size declined (51 years on average). the initial period. ½F ð:; Si;t0 Þ is a function of size
In summary, these data suggest that most and some other variables and d is the time
small dairy farms have survived this restruc- interval over which growth is measured or in
turing process well. They have not been cut out, other words, d ¼ t  t0 . Finally, et is the pro-
made important investments, upgraded their portionate rate of growth between t0 and t. If d
farm business, and improved quality. Those is small and we express Eqn. (1) in logarithms,
who fell out were mostly older farmers that we obtain the following general growth func-
may have gone out of business anyhow. tion.
1536 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

lnðSi;t Þ  lnðSi;t0 Þ 1995, divided by the number of years between


¼ ln½F ð:; ðSi;t0 ÞÞ þ ui;t ð2Þ the two points of observation, i.e., five.
d
The first set of explanatory variables mea-
Using (2), we estimate the impact of foreign sures the impact of dairy company character-
investment and supplier assistance programs on istics, including its ownership structure.
supplier growth with the following model: FDI is a dichotomous variable, which takes
the value of one if the household delivered its
lnðSi;t Þ  lnðSi;t0 Þ Xk Xl
milk to a foreign-owned dairy company in
¼ a0 þ aa Ai;a;t0 þ bb Bi;b;t
d 1995, and takes the value of zero otherwise.
a¼1 b¼1
The expected impact of FDI on survival and
Xm
þ vc lnðSi;c;t0 Þ þ ni;t ð3Þ growth of local suppliers is uncertain ex ante.
c¼1
Most studies in the literature suggest that the
impact is negative, especially for small suppli-
where A is a vector of k variables related to the ers. But our evidence, as discussed in the pre-
dairy company, including firm ownership and vious section, indicates that FDI has
assistance programs; B is a vector of l variables contributed to access to finance, inputs, and
controlling for differences on the level of the technology of small suppliers and as such may
farm household and farm operator; S is a vec- have contributed to the survival and growth of
tor of m variables that measure differences in the farms.
initial farm size, and finally ni;t is the errorterm. FDISIZE is an interaction term of FDI and
Estimating Eqn. (3) using ordinary least SIZE95, an indicator of initial herd size. This
squares (OLS) regression techniques will only interaction term is included to test the
take into account the growth of farms that still hypothesis of foreign investors’ bias toward
exist at the end of the period that we consider. large suppliers. If foreign investors prefer to
Such analysis based on a sample of surviving deal with large suppliers, this may have a neg-
farms only, may be biased due to sample ative survival, and possibly also growth, effect
attrition. Instead, we use a two-step Heckman for small producers that initially supplied to the
model of firm survival and growth (Weiss, foreign-owned dairy company. On the other
1999). First, a selection equation is estimated hand, this bias can lead to an additional posi-
by maximum likelihood as an independent tive growth effect for large suppliers that deliver
probit model to determine which farms have to foreign-owned companies. We therefore
survived using information from the whole expect FDISIZE to have a positive effect on
sample of suppliers. A vector of inverse Mills survival and growth.
ratios (estimated expected error) can be gener- PROGRAM measures the number of dairy
ated from the parameter estimates. Supplier assistance programs that are offered by the
growth is observed only when the selection dairy company. Assistance programs include
equation equals 1. Then, for the surviving extension, veterinary assistance, credit pro-
suppliers, growth is regressed on the explana- grams either for buying cows or for making
tory variables and the vector of inverse Mills other on-farm investments, input supply pro-
ratios from the selection equation by least gram, bank loan guarantees, and on-farm milk
squares. Therefore, the second stage reruns the collection. PROGRAM takes a value between
regression with the estimated expected error zero and seven with seven indicating that the
included as an extra explanatory variable, dairy offers all seven possible assistance pro-
removing the part of the error term correlated grams.
with the explanatory variables and avoiding the From the information gathered in our inter-
bias. 11 views it was clear that foreign-owned dairy
The dependent variables in the two estima- companies had initiated and were the first to
tions are SURVIVAL and GROWTH, respec- implement such assistance programs. Hence,
tively. SURVIVAL is a dichotomous variable the variables FDI and PROGRAM may not be
that takes the value of one if the household is independent. But the correlation between both
still delivering milk to a dairy in 2000 and it variables in the sample is very small: the cor-
takes the value of zero if the household stopped relation coefficient is 0.08. Still, to test for the
delivering milk. GROWTH is defined as the impact of possible multicollinearity problems in
difference between the natural logarithm of the the estimation, we also ran restricted models
number of cows owned in 2000 and the natural (Models B and C) where FDI and PROGRAM
logarithm of the number of cows owned in are excluded, respectively.
FDI VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS 1537

A final variable related to the dairy company HHMEMBER is the number of household
to which the household delivers is COOP. members and is expected to have a positive
COOP is a dichotomous variable, which takes effect on survival.
the value of one if the household head is Finally, farm size is proxied by the natural
delivering to a cooperative and takes the value logarithm of the number of cows owned by the
zero otherwise. We expect COOP to have a household in 1995 (SIZE95). To capture pos-
positive effect on survival as it is more compli- sible nonlinear effects of this relationship we
cated for a cooperative dairy company to include a variable SIZE95SQ, the squared
exclude suppliers, which are typically members value of SIZE95 and SIZE95CU, the cubic
of the cooperative, than for a noncooperative form of SIZE95.
private company.
The next group of explanatory variables in (b) Regression results
the analysis includes characteristics of the
household head. AGE measures the age of the Table 8 shows the estimation results for 283
household head. AGE may capture two differ- households that delivered milk to a dairy in
ent effects. As a proxy for experience one 1995 and for which the relevant data were
should expect a positive effect on growth. available. 12
Younger people are however typically more The estimated coefficients for FDI and FDI-
dynamic and entrepreneurial and age may SIZE are insignificant for both the survival and
therefore have a negative impact, especially the growth models. These results imply, first,
since previous management experience may be that suppliers delivering to foreign companies
less relevant in a transition environment. are equally likely to survive than those deliv-
EDU is the education level of the household ering to domestic companies––and hence that
head and takes a value between one and seven we find no evidence that foreign companies are
where one stands for the lowest level of edu- more likely to cut down their supplier base.
cation and seven the highest. Better educated Moreover, our results indicate also that foreign
farmers are also more likely to survive and companies are not more likely to cut off small
grow, hence, EDU is expected to have a positive suppliers from their supplier base than domes-
coefficient. tic companies. This result is contrary to most
PENSION is defined as a dichotomous var- arguments in the literature that suggest that
iable that takes the value of one if the house- foreign investment causes companies to cut
hold receives income from pensions and zero if small suppliers from their supply base to min-
not. PENSION is assumed to have a negative imize transaction costs and because small
impact on survival and growth because it farmers cannot make the necessary investments
reflects lack of incentives to invest. to reach enhanced standards.
COMMUNITY is an indicator of the activity One criticism on this interpretation is that the
in the community of the household head, and variable FDI could be endogenous because
thus his social capital, and is measured as the foreign firms may decide their investment
number of times per year that the household location based on the structure of the local
head takes part in meetings concerning the supplier base. In other words, foreign firms
village. Social capital is expected to have a may prefer to invest in dairy companies with
positive impact on the likelihood of farm sur- larger suppliers. In our sample however, this is
vival and growth. not the case. The initial size distributions of
WAGE is defined as a dichotomous variable farms delivering to domestic dairy companies
that takes the value of one if the household and farms delivering to foreign companies are
receives income from off-farm employment and not significantly different (see Table 9; Pear-
zero in the other case. WAGE may capture two son’s v2 ¼ 4:72).
opposing effects. Employment in other sectors Assistance programs that dairy companies
can offer extra sources of finance for the provide for their supplying farms have a highly
household to invest in the farm operation. With significant and positive impact both on the
important rural credit constraints, the effect likelihood of farm survival and on growth.
would be positive on farm survival and growth. Dairies that provide more programs to their
On the other hand, with rural labor market suppliers have fewer suppliers dropping out,
constraints, access to off-farm employment can and their suppliers grow more. We know from
act as a stepping-stone to leave the agricultural our interviews that foreign investors started
sector. first with these programs, beginning in 1993–95.
1538
Table 8. Regression results
Model A Model B Model C
Survival Growth Survival Growth Survival Growth
Coefficient jz-valuej Coefficient jz-valuej Coefficient jz-valuej Coefficient jz-valuej Coefficient jz-valuej Coefficient jz-valuej
Dairy company
FDI )0.497 (0.48) 0.047 (0.99) 0.271 (0.35) 0.042 (0.87) – – – –
FDISIZE 0.456 (0.80) )0.017 (0.79) )0.098 (0.23) )0.015 (0.68) – – – –
PROGRAM 0.541 (6.03) 0.006 (1.83) – – – – 0.520 (6.06) 0.006 (1.78)
COOP 0.933 (2.39) )0.001 (0.05) 0.666 (2.34) )0.011 (0.86) 0.912 (2.34) )0.001 (0.10)

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
Farm characteristics
SIZE95 0.788 (2.75) )0.336 (3.61) 1.131 (4.79) )0.406 (4.92) 0.943 (3.85) )0.351 (3.79)
SIZE95SQ – – 0.134 (2.95) – – 0.149 (3.53) – – 0.136 (2.99)
SIZE95CU – – )0.017 (2.32) – – )0.018 (2.54) – – )0.017 (2.36)

Household characteristics
AGE )0.020 (1.60) )0.001 (2.33) )0.007 (0.71) )0.001 (1.97) )0.020 (1.55) )0.001 (2.26)
EDU )0.032 (0.27) 0.009 (2.11) 0.116 (1.21) 0.008 (1.63) )0.013 (0.11) 0.010 (2.19)
WAGE )0.929 (2.84) )0.038 (2.36) )0.689 (2.83) )0.023 (1.34) )0.860 (2.72) )0.039 (2.40)
PENSION 0.245 (0.76) )0.019 (1.48) 0.057 (0.24) )0.020 (1.50) 0.250 (0.79) )0.019 (1.51)
COMMUNITY 0.073 (0.87) 0.003 (1.65) 0.031 (0.53) 0.003 (1.59) 0.062 (0.77) 0.003 (1.66)
HHMEMBER )0.006 (0.07) 0.005 (1.47) 0.101 (1.63) 0.004 (1.18) )0.010 (0.13) 0.005 (1.52)

Constant )0.695 (0.73) 0.262 (3.19) )1.577 (1.92) 0.390 (5.42) )0.894 (0.98) 0.287 (3.64)
Log likelihood 193.3 163.0 191.8
Rho 0.176 (0.595) )0.687 (4.10) 0.107 (0.35)
Observations 283 283 283 283 283
*
Significant at 10%.
**
Significant at 5%.
***
Significant at 1%.
FDI VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS 1539

Table 9. Initial size distribution of farms delivering to domestic and foreign-owned dairy companies (1995)
Number of cows Farms delivering to:
per farm
Foreign owned dairy companies Domestic dairy companies
# % # %
<2 1 0.8 2 1.3
2–3 6 4.8 11 7.0
4–5 27 21.4 25 15.9
6–7 18 14.3 26 16.6
8–9 19 15.1 22 14.0
10–11 24 19.1 27 17.2
12–13 15 11.9 19 12.1
14–15 6 4.8 15 9.6
>15 10 7.9 10 6.4
Total 126 100 157 100
2
Pearson’s v ¼ 4:72 ðp ¼ 0:787Þ

But over the time period covered by our survey least part of the exits from the sector were
(1995–2001) we found no statistical interaction involuntary.
between the programs and foreign ownership of While we found no size effect of suppliers
the companies. The correlation coefficient concerning foreign investment, the significant
between FDI and PROGRAM is 0.08, and coefficient of SIZE1995 indicates that in gen-
leaving out the respective variables, did not eral larger farms were more likely to survive
significantly affect the results. This suggests that 1995–2000 and the associated restructuring
domestic companies have rapidly replicated the process.
successful programs and have been equally The size-growth relationship is complex with
successful in assisting and upgrading their all three SIZE variables significant. A first
suppliers. implication is that initial farm size does have a
COOP has a significant impact, but only on significant effect on farm growth, which is
the survival of suppliers. This confirms our inconsistent with ‘‘Gibrat’s law,’’ which
hypothesis that suppliers delivering to cooper- states that firm growth is independent of the
atives are more likely to survive because it is initial size. Second, the significant coefficients
more difficult for cooperatives to refuse to take for SIZE95SQ and SIZE95CU indicate
milk from their suppliers, which are typically that the size-growth relationship has two turn-
cooperative members. This suggests that at ing points. On the basis of the estimated

150
Change in number of cows

-150
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24
Herd size

Figure 4. Change in number of cows by farm size, 1995–2000. Each data point gives the average change in number of
cows in three consecutive size classes of which the data point itself is the size class in the middle. For example, the data
point for herd size three signifies the average change in number of cows in all farms with herd sizes 2, 3 and 4.
1540 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

coefficients, one can calculate that the turning affected the likelihood of the farms continuing
points occur at a herd size of eight cows (min- to deliver milk to companies despite increased
imum) and 24 cows (maximum). Figures 3 and demands, farms run by younger households are
4 illustrate the developments behind these esti- more likely to increase their herd size and to
mation results. Eight cows was approximately grow. Similarly, while education does not affect
the median herd size in 1995 (see Figure 3) and the likelihood of survival, better educated farm
more than 97% of our observations had a herd managers are associated with more growth. The
size smaller than 24 cows. The group of result is the same for the indicator of social
smallest farms (1–4 cows) has grown and also capital. Playing an active role in the community
the group of larger farms (more than 16 cows). does not seem to have a relationship with
The medium group (5–15 cows) has reduced in farmers’ survival over the past five years, but it
size. Part of the farms in this group has reduced is positively correlated with farm growth. The
their size and others have increased their size. results are robust for different model specifica-
Several of these farms have increased their herd tions.
size to more than 15 cows. The regression The WAGE variable has a significantly neg-
results indicate that this is mostly the case for ative impact both on farm survival and growth.
farms already having more than eight cows in Households with household members that earn
1995. Some very small suppliers (1–4 cows) income from wages in other sectors are more
have grown (since growth was relatively larger likely to quit their dairy operation. Households
in the 1–4 group than in the 5–8 group). The with off-farm employment also have slower
group of very small suppliers has grown mostly growing farms. These results suggest that
because of suppliers of the medium group households with off-farm income sources are
(especially those with 5–8 cows) have cut down more likely to leave the sector, while house-
their herd. Figure 4 illustrates how this trans- holds that depend solely on the agricultural
lates itself in the herd distribution. While in sector as a source of income tend to stay in the
numbers of farms the smallest farms have sig- sector. Weiss (1999) also finds a significantly
nificant growth rates, in terms of livestock the negative relationship between off-farm
important growth occurred in the group of employment of Austrian farming households
farms with more than 13 cows. and farm survival. These findings confirm the
It is unclear whether these developments view that part-time farming is a stepping-stone
over 1995–2000 reflect a ‘‘normalization’’ of a out of the agricultural sector and that part-time
farm distribution which was distorted by the farming promotes the restructuring of the farm
Communist legacy––the 2000 farm distribu- sector (Pfeffer, 1989; Roe, 1995).
tion appears less distorted than the 1995 dis- This estimation result also suggests that
tribution, as illustrated in Figure 3––or access to credit for the farms in the sample may
whether it is only one stage in a further be less constraining than is often argued (e.g.,
development toward a bimodal farm size dis- European Commission, 1998; World Bank,
tribution in the dairy sector. There is mixed 2001). Other studies find that in regions where
evidence whether such bimodal distribution, rural credit market imperfections are a very
with both small part-time farmers on the one important constraint for farms, households’
hand, and large full-time commercial farmers access to off-farm income sources has an
on the other hand, has emerged in Western important positive impact on farm develop-
market economies. Some studies confirm such ment (e.g. Rizov, Gavrilescu, Gow, Mathijs, &
development of a ‘‘disappearing middle’’ Swinnen, 2001). Hence, our result confirms that
(Edwards, Smith, & Peterson, 1985; Garcia, the vertical integration process and the farm
Offutt, & Sonka, 1987; Weiss, 1999). A recent assistance programs by the dairy farms, in
study by Wolf and Sumner (2001) finds, combination with the general progress in the
however, that farm size distributions for US Polish rural finance system, have a very signif-
dairy farms are not bimodal. icant positive impact on access to credit for the
Some other characteristics of the farms also farms, and on mitigating their credit con-
affect their growth and/or survival. The indi- straints.
cators of human and social capital character- This conclusion is consistent with the insig-
istics do not have an impact on the survival of nificant result of PENSION. The negative
farms, but only on the growth of the farms. Age coefficient of PENSION in the growth equa-
has a significantly negative effect on farm tions, suggests that, if anything, access to pen-
growth. Hence, while age has not significantly sions reduces farm growth. Finally, the size of
FDI VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS 1541

the household does not affect the survival or for the suppliers. Our estimations show that the
growth of the farms. assistance programs had a significant effect
both on the survival and the growth of suppli-
ers.
5. CONCLUSIONS The second step is that of horizontal spill-
overs. When domestic companies observe these
Previous studies argue that foreign invest- successful vertical integration strategies, they
ment leads to a rapid consolidation of the local start copying the strategies. Our analysis shows
supplier base with negative implications for that these horizontal spillover effects are strong
those suppliers who cannot comply with higher and rapid. For several of the effects, after five
standards and grading requirements, or who years there is no longer a significant difference
are cut out by the company in order to reduce between foreign owned and domestic compa-
transaction costs. Studies argue that this effect nies, and their suppliers. Only in some aspects,
can be especially dramatic for small suppliers in such as medium term investments, convergence
developing countries. had not yet occurred.
The conclusions of our analysis are different. In combination, these effects have caused
We do not find that foreign investment leads to significant improvements in small suppliers’
either a rapid consolidation of the local sup- investments, productivity and product quality
plier base or to small suppliers being cut out. In over the five-year period studied here. More
other words, we do not find the negative direct than 85% of all suppliers continued supplying
effects for local suppliers that are often attrib- despite restructuring of the dairy companies
uted to foreign direct investments in the liter- and strong tightening of quality requirements.
ature. On the contrary, our evidence shows that The reduction in suppliers over the period is
the indirect effects of foreign investment––or its less than the average reduction in agricultural
spillover effects––lead to improved access to employment in Poland, and most of those who
finance, increased investments, and (dramatic) stopped supplying were older farmers who
quality improvements by small local suppliers. might have stopped delivering milk anyhow.
The mechanism through which this happens Younger and better educated managers were
consists of two steps. First, after foreign associated with stronger supplier growth. The
investment, processing companies start a pro- average size of the farms increased, but rela-
cess of vertical coordination through contract- tively little, and the vast majority of suppliers
ing with local suppliers in which input and remain small.
output markets are interlinked. The contracting In summary, our study finds that foreign
is associated with enhanced standards require- investment through this process of vertical
ments of supplies while at the same time the integration did not result in the negative direct
companies provide assistance programs to effects for local suppliers that are often attrib-
improve supplier management, and to enhance uted to foreign direct investments in the liter-
access to technology, credit and other inputs. In ature. On the contrary, our evidence shows that
combination, the contracts and assistance pro- there are significant positive effects on small
grams are designed to overcome market suppliers, but that the most important effect
imperfections. The contracts are enforced by was, over the period analyzed here, indi-
interlinking the various markets. This process rect through vertical and horizontal spillover
leads to important positive vertical spillovers effects.

NOTES

1. Important causes of the output decline were declin- the disruption of traditional exchange relationships
ing relative prices and subsidy cuts following liberaliza- between farms and up- and downstream companies
tion (terms of trade for milk producers declined by (Dries & Swinnen, 2002; Macours & Swinnen, 2000).
almost 90% during 1989–92). Both output and produc-
tivity were negatively affected by disruptions from 2. In the European former Communist countries, only
privatization and restructuring, as well as contracting in former Yugoslavia private farming also survived to a
problems in the absence of enforcement mechanisms and large extent.
1542 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

3. Poland had very few collective farms. 8. Formally, the foreign investor was in a joint venture
with a local cooperative and leased the collection
4. FDI has resulted from several company strategies: stations from the cooperative. It was the cooperative
to serve the local market when trade constraints limit which, under strong pressure from the foreign investor,
imports, to use the Polish economy advantages for made the investments in the cooling equipment at its
exporting to the home market or to third markets, etc. collection stations.
Poland performed well in FDI inflows because of its
stable political and institutional system, advanced 9. The process of interlinking markets is traditionally
reform strategy, and cheap but relatively well educated studied extensively in the development economics liter-
labor force. The EU accession process has further ature, typically focusing on landlord-tenant or trader-
stimulated FDI because it reinforced the institutional farmer relationships in developing countries (see e.g.,
and economic stability, the prospect of a large single Bardhan & Udry, 1999).
market, growth in Polish incomes and food demand,
and––in some cases––expectations of EU subsidies 10. Success of these programs and contract enforce-
(Walkenhorst, 2001). ment is not obvious. Gow and Swinnen (2001) discuss
several cases of failure.
5. Poland is a net exporter of dairy products. The main
buyers of Polish dairy products in 1998 were the former 11. As the regression results in the next section will
Soviet Union countries (FSU). Imports of dairy products show, Rho (the estimated correlation coefficient
in Poland mainly originate from the EU. Although the between the residuals in the survival and growth
total value of imports was halved during 1992–98, the equations) is insignificant in our model. This indicates
share of imports from the EU has increased. Poland that there are actually no unobserved characteristics
exports mostly lower value products to the EU, and that make surviving farms grow faster than farms that
imports mostly higher value cheese and other products. In have quit. This means that the Heckman model that we
1999, 59% of all imports were yogurts, almost all have estimated would give the same results as estimat-
imported from Germany. Only licensed dairies are ing a probit model of farm survival and a least-squares
allowed to export their products to the EU. In 2000, only model for growth separately. Since both estimation
19 out of the approximately 400 dairy processing compa- methods will give the same results, we have opted to
nies have obtained such an export license. Although in keep the Heckman procedure as it is the standard
numbers these firms make up only 5% of the sector, in methodology used in the literature on firm survival and
terms of total milk procurement they account for 25% growth.
(Kaspersson, Rabinowicz, & Schwaag Serger, 2002).
12. On top of models A, B and C in Table 8, we have
6. Estimate on the basis of data on old voivodship also run restricted models to test the potential impact
classifications (Wies I Rolnictwo, 1999). of correlation between AGE and PENSION, because
older household heads are more likely to receive
7. Using a list of supplying farmers from the foreign- pensions. We find that the results are robust across
owned dairy companies would create a selection bias these different model specifications and for simplicity
since a list of current suppliers will exclude any farmers we have not included the results of these models in
that have stopped supplying over the past years. Table 8.

REFERENCES

Aitken, B. J., & Harrison, A. E. (1999). Do domestic Dries, L., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2002). Institutional
firms benefit from foreign direct investment? Evi- reform and labor reallocation during transition:
dence from Venezuela. American Economic Review, evidence from Polish agriculture. World Develop-
89(3), 605–618. ment, 30(3), 457–474.
Bardhan, P., & Udry, C. (1999). Development microeco- Edwards, C., Smith, M. G., & Peterson, R. N. (1985).
nomics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. The changing distribution of farms by size: a Markov
Blanchard, O. (1999). The economics of post-communist analysis. Agricultural Economics Research, 37(4), 1–
transition. Oxford: Clarendon. 16.
Dolan, C., & Humphrey, J. (2000). Governance and European Commission (1998). Agricultural situation
trade in fresh vegetables: the impact of UK super- and prospects in the Central and Eastern European
markets on the African horticulture industry. Journal countries. Poland, Brussels: European Commission,
of Development Studies, 37(2), 147–176. Directorate General Agriculture.
FDI VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND LOCAL SUPPLIERS 1543

Evans, D. (1987). Tests of alternative theories of firm Swedish Institute for Food and Agricultural Eco-
growth. Journal of Political Economy, 95, 657–674. nomics.
FAO (2003). FAOSTAT Agriculture Data [online]. Kokko, A. (1994). Technology, market characteristics
FAO. Available at http://www.FAO.org. and spillovers. Journal of Development Economics,
Farina, E. M. M. Q., & Reardon, T. (2000). Agrifood 43(2), 279–293.
grades and standards in the extended Mercosur: their Kokko, A., Tansini, R., & Zejan, M. C. (1996). Local
role in the changing agrifood system. American technological capability and productivity spillovers
Journal of Agricultural Economics, 82(5), 1170–1176. from FDI in the Uruguayan manufacturing sector.
Foster, C. (1999). The impact of FDI in the upstream Journal of Development Studies, 32(4), 602–611.
and downstream sectors on investment in agriculture Konings, J. (2001). The effects of foreign direct invest-
in the NIS. In Agricultural Finance and Credit ment on domestic firms. Evidence from firm-level
Infrastructure in Transition Economies. Paris: OECD. panel data in emerging economies. Economics of
Garcia, P., Offutt, S. E., & Sonka, S. T. (1987). Size Transition, 9(3), 619–633.
distribution and growth in a sample of Illinois cash Konings, J., & Walsh, P. P. (1999). Disorganization in
grain farms. American Journal of Agricultural Eco- the process of transition. Firm-level evidence from
nomics, 69(2), 471–476. Ukraine. Economics of Transition, 7(1), 29–46.
Gow, H., & Swinnen, J. (1998). Agribusiness restruc- Liu, Z. (2002). Foreign direct investment and technology
turing, foreign direct investment, and hold-up prob- spillover: evidence from China. Journal of Compar-
lems in agricultural transition. European Review of ative Economics, 30(3), 579–602.
Agricultural Economics, 25(4). Macours, K., & Swinnen, J. (2000). Causes of output
Gow, H., & Swinnen, J. (2001). Private enforcement decline during transition: the case of Central and
capital and contract enforcement in transition coun- Eastern European agriculture. Journal of Compara-
tries. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, tive Economics, 28(1), 172–206.
83(3), 686–690. Majewski, E., & Dalton, G. (2000). The strategic options
Gow, H., Streeter, D., & Swinnen, J. (2000). How for the Polish agro-food sector in the light of economic
private contract enforcement mechanisms can suc- analyses. Warsaw: FAPA.
ceed where public institutions fail: the case of Mcmillan, J., & Woodruff, C. (1999). Interfirm relation-
Juhosucor A. S. Agricultural Economics, 23(3), 253– ships and informal credit in Vietnam. Quarterly
265. Journal of Economics (November), 1285–1320.
GUS (2001). Statistical Yearbook. Warsaw: Central Pfeffer, M. J. (1989). Part-time farming and the stability
Statistical Office. of family farms in the Federal Republic of Germany.
Hall, B. H. (1997). The relationship between firm size European Review of Agricultural Economics, 16(4),
and firm growth in the US manufacturing sector. 425–444.
Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 583–606. Reardon, T., & Berdegue, J. A. (2002). The rapid rise of
Hart, P. E., & Oulton, N. (1996). Growth and size of supermarkets in Latin America: challenges and
firms. Economic Journal, 106(438), 1242–1252. opportunities for development. Development Policy
Henson, S. J., Loader, R. J., & Brouder, A. (2000). Food Review, 20(4), 317–334.
safety standards and exports of perishable products Reardon, T., Codron, J.-M., Busch, L., Bingen, J., &
from developing countries: fish exports from East Harris, C. (1999). Global change in agrifood grades
Africa to the European Union. American Journal of and standards: agribusiness strategic responses in
Agricultural Economics, 82(5), 1159–1169. developing countries. International Food and Agri-
Holloway, G., Nicholson, C., Delgado, C., Staal, S., & business Management Review, 2(3), 421–435.
Ehui, S. (2000). Agroindustrialisation through insti- Rizov, M., Gavrilescu, D., Gow, H., Mathijs, E., &
tutional innovation. Transaction costs, cooperatives Swinnen, J. (2001). Transition and enterprise restruc-
and milk-market development in the East-African turing: the development of individual farming in
Highlands. Agricultural Economics, 23, 279–288. Romania. World Development, 29(7), 1257–1274.
Hu, A. G. Z., & Jefferson, G. H. (2002). FDI impact and Roe, B. (1995). A study of US farms exits with evidence
spillover: evidence from China’s electronic and from the panel study of income dynamics: 1968–
textile industries. The World Economy, 25(8), 1063– 1989. Paper presented at the AAEA annual meeting,
1076. Indianapolis, August 6–9, 1995.
Johnson, S., McMillan, J. & Woodruff, C. (1999). Runsten, D. & Key, N. (1996). Contract farming in
Contract Enforcement in Transition. EBRD Work- developing countries: theoretical issues and analysis
ing Paper No. 45. London: European Bank for of some Mexican Cases. Report LC/L.989. Santiago,
Reconstruction and Development. Chile: UN-ECLAC.
Key, N., & Runsten, D. (1999). Contract farming, Swedish Board of Agriculture (2001). A study of the
smallholders, and rural development in Latin Amer- milk sector in Poland, Hungary, the Czech Republic
ica: the organization of agroprocessing firms and the and Estonia. Market Regulations Division.
scale of outgrower production. World Development, Walkenhorst, P. (2001). The geography of foreign direct
27(2), 381–401. investment in Poland’s food industry. Journal of
Kaspersson, E., Rabinowicz, E., & Schwaag Serger, S. Agricultural Economics, 52(3), 71–86.
(2002). EU milk policy after enlargement––competi- Weatherspoon, D. D., & Reardon, T. (2003). The rise of
tiveness and politics in four candidate countries. Lund: supermarkets in Africa: implications for agrifood
1544 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

systems and the rural poor. Development Policy Wolf, C. A., & Sumner, D. A. (2001). Are farm size
Review, 21(3), 333–356. distributions bimodal? Evidence from kernel density
Weiss, C. (1999). Farm growth and survival: econometric estimates of dairy farm size distributions. American
evidence for individual farms in Upper Austria. Am- Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83(1), 77–
erican Journal of Agricultural Economics, 81, 103–116. 88.
Wies I Rolnictwo (1999). Warsaw. World Bank (2001). Poland: the functioning of the
Winters, A. L. (2000). Trade liberalisation and poverty. labor, land and financial markets: opportunities and
Available: http://www.worldbank.org/poverty/wdr- constraints for farming sector restructuring. Wash-
poverty/winters.htm. ington, DC: The World Bank.

You might also like