You are on page 1of 7

Topic 1: R&D and Growth

3 R&D and Growth with both Variety Expansion


and Quality Improvements: Howitt (1999) Model

3.1 Introduction

• Scale effect: Larger population ⇒ More supply of potential


R&D workers and larger market ⇒ Faster technological progress
⇒ Faster growth.
• Jones (1995)’s model: (i) Fact: absence of scale effect. (ii) Model:
semi-endogenous growth.
• Young (1998)’s model without scale effect: An increase in the
reward to innovation resulting from a larger population will be
dissipated in the long run by the product proliferation it induces:
the larger economy will have to allocate a larger number of work-
ers to the innovation process in order to maintain a constant rate
of productivity growth because those workers must improve a
larger number of products. However, government policies such
as R&D subsidies do not affect long-run growth because prod-
uct proliferation will dissipate the increased reward to innovation
from a subsidy in the same way as it dissipates the increased re-
ward to innovation from a larger population.

16
3.2 The Model

There are two kinds of innovation: horizontal and vertical innovation.

• Preferences: Constant rate of time preference r > 0,


Z∞ −rt
U = E0 0
e Ct dt.

• A. Production Relations
Qt
AitxαitdiX 1−α
Z
Yt = Ct + Nvt + Nht = 0
(1)

where Yt is gross output, Ct is consumption, Nvt is vertical R&D


expenditure, Nht is horizontal R&D expenditure, Qt is the mea-
sure (number) of intermediate goods, xit is the quantity of inter-
mediate good i, Ait is a productivity parameter attached to the
latest version of intermediate good i and X = 1 is fixed factor.
Each intermediate good is produced using labor, according to
produced using skilled labor L.

xit = Lit, (2)

where Lit is the input of labor in sector i. The labor market-


clearing condition is
Qt
xitdi = Lt = egLt ,
Z

0
(3)

where gL is the exogenous population growth rate.


Vertical innovations are targeted at specific intermediate prod-
ucts. Each vertical innovation creates an improved version of
the existing product, which allows the innovator to replace an
incumbent monopolist until the next innovation in that sector.
17
Each horizontal innovation allows the innovator to monopolize a
newly created intermediate product until the first vertical inno-
vation arrives.
The final good producer’s demand for intermediate good i is
given by
pit = αAitxα−1
it

where pit is the price of intermediate good i in units of final out-


put. Intermediate good producer i’s profit maximization implies
that the producer supplies the quantity
1/(α−1)
w
 
t
xit =  2
 , (4)
Aitα
and earns the flow f profits
πit = Aitα(1 − α)xαit , (5)
where wt is the wage rate.

• B. Innovations

1. Vertical
The Poisson arrival rate of vertical innovations in any sector is
φt = λnt , λ > 0, (6)
λ > 0 is the productivity of vertical R&D, and
nt = Nvt/(Qt Amax
t ) is the productivity-adjusted expenditure
on vertical R&D, with Amax t = max{Ait, i ∈ [0, Qt]}. A
vertical innovator’s profit maximization gives the arbitrage
equation
1 − β = λνt, (7)
18
where β is the subsidy rate and νt = Vt /Amax
t (Vt is the value
of a vertical innovation). The value of a vertical innovation is
given by
Z ∞  Z τ 
Vt = 0
exp − t
(rs + φs)ds π̃tτ dτ, (8)
where rs is the instantaneous rate of interest at date s and π̃tτ
is the profit flow at date τ to any sector whose technology is of
vintage t.
2. Horizontal
The rate of new product innovation is
Ψ(Nht , Yt)
Q̇t = , (9)
Amax
t
where Ψ is a concave, constant-returns production function
with positive marginal products. The average product Q̇t/Nht
is a decreasing function of the fraction ht = Nht /Yt of GDP
allocated to horizontal R&D (also the fraction of labor force
engaged in horizontal R&D).
Each horizontal innovation results in a new intermediate
product whose productivity parameter is drawn randomly from
the distribution of existing intermediate products. As a result,
the expected value of a horizontal innovation is
 1/(1−α) 
Ait
E  Vt .
  

Amax
  

t

The arbitrage equation for a horizontal innovator is


 1/(1−α) 
Ait
1 − β = ψ 0(h)E  νt , (10)
  

Amax
  

t

where ψ(h) = Ψ(h, 1), with ψ 0 > 0 and ψ 00 < 0.


19
C. Spillover
It is assumed that Amax
t grows at a rate (σ/Qt) proportional
to the aggregate rate of vertical innovations.
max
Ȧt
gt = max = σλnt. (11)
At
Because the distribution of productivity parameters among new
products at any date is identical to the distribution across
existing products at any time, the distribution of relative
productivity parameters ait = Ait/Amaxt converges
monotonically to the invariant distribution

Pr{ait ≤ a} ≡ F (a) = a1/σ , 0 < a ≤ 1. (12)

In the long run,


 1/(1−α) 
Ait
E  = Γ−1, (13)
  

Amax
  

t

where Γ ≡ 1 + [σ/(1 − α)].

3.3 Steady-State Analysis

• In a steady state: Lt /Qt = l, Nvt/(Qt Amax


t ) = n and Nht /Yt =
h are all constant. From (11), we have

g = σλn. (G)

From (9), we have

gL = ψ(h)y, (Y)
20
where y = Yt/(Qt Amax
t ) is the productivity-adjusted level of
GDP per intermediate product. We also have
y = Γα−1lα (14)

ω ≡ wt /Amax
t = α2Γα−1 lα−1 (15)
α/(α−1)
g(τ −t)

max  ωe
π̃tτ = At α(1 − α)  
. (16)
α2

From (7), along with φ = λn, (14) and (16), we have the first
equilibrium condition:
λα(1 − α + σ)y
1−β = . (N)
r + λn + [α/(1 − α)]g
and from (7), (10) and (13), we have the second equilibrium
condition:

ψ 0(h) = Γλ. (H)

3.4 Properties of the Model

• The steady-state values of (n, y, g and h) are determined by (N),


(Y), (G) and (H).
• Equation (N): (i) Population growth does not create continual
scale effect. (ii) [α/(1 − α)]g appears because a successful in-
novator’s profits are subject to gradual “crowding out” by the
continual rise in wages at the steady state.
• Equation (G): The potential supply-side scale effect of a rising
number of R&D workers is nullified by the rise in the number of
products which reduces the spillover coefficient σ/Qt.
21
• Equation (H) (along with with equation(Y)): The growth rate
depends positively on population growth.
The system of equations can be reduced to two equations (V)
and (H) in the two R&D intensities (n, h).

Proposition 1: The steady-state growth rate g depends posi-


tively on β, gL, λ and σ and negatively on r.

3.4 Postwar Facts on R&D Inputs

• The input to R&D, as proxied by the number of scientists and


engineers engaged in R&D, has risen dramatically over the past
half century, with no visible tendency for growth in output per
person or in productivity to increase.
• The model predicts that the fraction (Nvt + Nht )/Yt = (n/y)+ h
should remain constant in the steady state.

3.5 Conclusions

• The Schumpeterian approach to growth theory can reconciled


with Jones’s evidence of the absence of scale effect.
• Population growth has a positive effect on growth, but it is not
the only determinant.
• Government policies can have long-run growth effects.

22

You might also like