You are on page 1of 14

World Development 120 (2019) 76–89

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

World Development
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

The ‘New’ national development planning and global development goals:


Processes and partnerships
Admos O. Chimhowu a,⇑, David Hulme b, Lauchlan T. Munro c
a
The Global Development Institute, School of Environment Education and Development, University of Manchester, Arthur Lewis Building, Oxford Road, Manchester M13 9PL,
United Kingdom
b
School of Environment Education and Development, University of Manchester, Arthur Lewis Building, Oxford Road, Manchester M13 9PL, United Kingdom
c
School of International Development and Global Studies/École de développement international et mondialisation, Social Sciences Building/Pavillon des sciences sociales, FSS8006,
University of Ottawa/Université d’Ottawa, Ottawa, ON K1N 6N5, Canada

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: The number of countries with a national development plan has more than doubled, from about 62 in
Available online 16 April 2019 2006 to 134 in 2018. More than 80 per cent of the global population now lives in a country with a
national development plan of one form or another. This is a stunning recovery of a practice that had been
Keywords: discredited in the 1980s and 1990s as a relic of directed economies and state-led development. Several
National planning factors have fostered this re-emergence but from about 2015 the momentum for producing plans has
Sustainable Development Goals accelerated, driven in part by a need to plan for the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). Based on
Economic planning
an analysis of 107 national development plans, and drawing insights from 10 case study countries, this
Development planning
Development policy
paper analyses ‘new’ national development planning and identifies the types and content of the plans,
National strategy and their implications for the sustainable development agenda. The paper generates a typology of the
new national plans, analyses their characteristics and explores the ways in which the new national devel-
opment planning and the SDGs may interact. The study finds greater ownership and political control of
the processes leading to plan production. It also finds that the plans vary in terms of the evidence used,
the degree of internal consistency between different parts of the same plan, the process of developing the
plan (inclusive or elite-driven), and the extent to which they are clear on how they will be financed. In
contrast to 20th-century national development plans the new-generation plans are often underpinned
by theories of collaborative rationality rather than by linear rationality. This new generation of national
plans has been neglected by academic researchers and merits much greater examination, especially to
understand the ways in which their implementation can enhance the achievement of the SDGs.
Ó 2019 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Ltd. This is an open access article under the CC BY license (http://
creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

1. Introduction plan has more than doubled – from 62 to 134 – between 2006
and 2018, and that nearly 80 per cent of the global population
This paper looks at the recent return of national development now lives in a country with a national development plan of one
planning and its potential as a catalyst for achieving Agenda form or another. Parallel to this process, the UN-Habitat’s New
2030 for Sustainable Development. On September 25, 2015, all Urban Agenda emphasizes the need for municipalities to develop
193 UN member states committed themselves to a set of 17 Sus- territory-based plans. This has seen municipal authorities increas-
tainable Development Goals (SDGs). Unlike the Millennium Devel- ingly making their own detailed SDG plans. Clearly, substantial
opment Goals (MDGs), which were largely top-down in approach, state and civil society efforts are being devoted to the preparation
the SDGs are to be implemented through locally-generated and - and implementation of these plans at all levels of governance as
driven plans that reflect the ambitions, priorities and contexts of the role of the nation-state in promoting development is reimag-
respective UN member states. Work done by the University of ined in an era when the dominance of the International Financial
Manchester-based Strategic Network on New National Planning Institutions (IFIs) over development policy is more contested than
shows that the number of countries with a national development ever before. Yet little systematic work has been done to understand
the value of such pursuits.
⇑ Corresponding author. National development planning has had a chequered history
E-mail addresses: admos.chimhowu@manchester.ac.uk (A.O. Chimhowu), david. anchored in the failure of centrally planned economies in the
hulme@manchester.ac.uk (D. Hulme), lauchlan.munro@uottawa.ca (L.T. Munro). 1950s and 1960s. Many developing countries are now seeking to

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2019.03.013
0305-750X/Ó 2019 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Ltd.
This is an open access article under the CC BY license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89 77

guide their own development through a set of processes, policies a rational science, a plan becomes a blueprint document informed
and practices that can usefully be termed the ‘new national plan- by science and driven from the top by impartial experts (tech-
ning’. This new national planning has attracted little research nocrats) with access to all necessary data and almost infinite ana-
interest, yet there is growing evidence that it has implications lytical capacity. In its simplified form it involves a process in which
not only for how countries respond to the SDGs but also in terms the technocrats ‘survey things as they are, observe what needs to
of the global and local challenges that they confront. A common be done, study the means you have to do it with, and then work
response by governments to these challenges has been their out practical ways of going about it’ (Waterston, 2006, p. 430). It
reassertion of the necessity of national development planning to frames national development as a ‘problem’ that can be theoreti-
build institutions, resources and risk/shock-management capabili- cally and empirically understood by experts so that the outcomes
ties that are needed to achieve national development. This reasser- of public interventions can be predicted and optimal policies iden-
tion of the need for national development planning is a reaction to tified. Plans therefore pursue agreed and defined developmental
the dominant trend of the past three decades, namely that of eco- goals in the most technically efficient way – which minimizes costs
nomic liberalization, marketization and deregulation. While suc- and risks and which maximizes benefits and opportunities. To
cessful in some respects, this trend has created greater economic achieve this optimal position, a top-down approach is posited in
inequality, while socializing many of the risks and amplifying cer- which intellectual and professional elites apply the best techniques
tain shocks (e.g. the financial crisis of 2008) and increasing the fre- (such as linear modelling, input–output modelling, cost–benefit
quency and severity of economic, especially financial and currency, analysis and critical path analysis) to the best available data. This
crises (Polanyi-Levitt, 2013). Additionally, it is also a response to permits them to identify optimal policies and actions so that devel-
the possibilities offered by new flows of financing, especially new opment goals (from economic growth rates to human development
natural resource finds during a commodity boom, at a time when improvements) can be achieved. Although this framing of national
more policy space has been created by the decline of leverage of development planning has been used extensively in ‘mixed’ eco-
the IFIs and of the Washington Consensus, and by post-Highly nomic contexts, at the extreme it supports the idea of state-
Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC). based central planning rather than allowing the market to drive
The term ‘new’ national planning is used in this paper to cap- how economic development occurs.
ture the new context in which the current generation of national The second paradigm, based on more recent theories of commu-
development planning practices is emerging. It is adopted for nication and negotiation, uses collaborative or instrumental
two reasons. First, as the paper shows, ‘new’ national development rationality (Innes & Booher, 2010). In this way of thinking national
planning is largely a practice-led paradigm with a body of knowl- development is a ‘development mess’ which is understood differ-
edge, concepts and practices that relate both to state responses to ently by citizens and is only partially understood theoretically.
economic globalization and to how they plan to implement Agenda Data on which understandings are based are accepted as often
2030 for Sustainable Development. As shown later, ‘new’ national being patchy, partial and of poor quality and hence not susceptible
planning defines a new paradigm of ‘real’ ownership, in terms of to accurate predictions based on binary logic (cause and effect) but
the closer fit of plans with electoral cycles and nationally deter- rather only to fuzzy logic (Allmendinger, 2017), or what Johnston
mined priorities, albeit with reference to new global norms. and Clark (1982) called ‘dynamic logic’. Planning therefore is seen
Second, although there are certain elements of continuity, ‘new’ as a process of communication and negotiation about a desired
national development planning displays conceptual and method- future, involving interaction of numerous individuals who bargain
ological characteristics that are in some ways distinct from the and negotiate from varying power bases to achieve objectives that
planning practices of the 1950s through the 1980s. Third, ‘new’ at least partially reflect their self-interest built around shared val-
national planning frames an emerging epistemic community built ues (Innes & Booher, 2010).
around this study, and the unique database in particular offers Collaborative rationality therefore posits a quite different
insights into how development ideology and policy are being heuristic for decision making. It views planning as a process of
remade in a multipolar world. negotiating and communicating across communities and citizen-
The paper is structured as follows. After presenting its analyti- ries about shared values, cause–effect relationships and probable
cal framework and methodology, it traces the rise, fall and re- outcomes (see Forester, 1999; Sager 2002; Innes & Booher, 2010;
emergence of national development planning from the 1960s to Healey, 1992, 2010). The national development plan is a point of
the present. It then explores the factors driving the emergence of engagement about the future in the mould of Habermas’s (1987)
‘new’ national development planning; identifies the main charac- idea of communicative rationality. In effect, the national plan is
teristics and types of new national planning; and examines the not so much a set of decisions as an important and ongoing ele-
ways in which national planning and the SDGs may interact. The ment of social deliberation that involves constantly (re)negotiating
conclusion summarizes the argument and highlights the main goals and policies/actions so that choices are made that are techni-
findings. cally desirable and politically feasible. National plans are part of a
continuing social ‘conversation’ rather than the end of an objective
technico-analytical exercise: the process of planning is as impor-
2. Paradigms of planning and organising concepts tant as the eventual content of the plan. Such a framing of planning
has been criticized for its normative nature and also for its lack of
The central element of our conceptual framework focuses on engagement with power asymmetries in the planning process
the ways in which the process of planning and the ‘plan document’ (Hillier, 1993). Others like Fainstein (2000) raise concerns about
as an output contribute to results (national development) and cre- the time it can take to reach consensus and also the fact that
ates the typology we apply in Section 7. A review of the literature flawed alternative (top-down) approaches may also produce desir-
on national development plans identifies two competing para- able outcomes.
digms informing understandings and practices. The first, grounded In reality, it is important to realize that the understandings
in theories of linear rationality, is a classical planning paradigm described above probably represent ends of a spectrum, and the
that sees planning as ‘an organized, conscious and continual practical logic of planning for national development in most cases
attempt to select the best available alternatives to achieve specific involves more nuanced understandings and different shades of the
goals’ (Waterston, 1965, p. 26). Often called the rational compre- ends of the spectrum. For this paper the interest is in understand-
hensive model, where national development planning is seen as ing the approaches to planning for Sustainable Development and
78 A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89

the types of rationality that underpin practices embodied in the vision for national development’. A focus on the national meant
107 plans analysed. that sub-national plans were not included although, in the end,
the research sought to understand the many meanings of a
national development plan and embraced the findings emerging
3. Methodology from the trawl of plans. This search created a large repository of
plans from 134 countries. These formed the basis of a systematic
This study has adopted a multiple-methods design so that a content analysis. In the interests of fidelity and accuracy, content
comparison of what is happening globally (review and analysis of analysis was performed wherever possible on the original language
secondary data) is accompanied by more detailed insights into version of the plan (Arabic, English, French, Portuguese, Russian or
the state of national planning practices in 10 countries (primary Spanish) and not on the English translation. This paper is based on
research). This section discusses the secondary data used and the an analysis of 107 of the 134 national plans in the repository (see
analysis done. It also provides details of the primary case study Appendix 1). Those plans not analysed here are mostly from coun-
work carried out as part of this study. The secondary data and its tries with populations of one million people or fewer for which
analysis are discussed first, starting with bibliometric analysis. work is still ongoing. For this study conventional, directed and
The study uses bibliometric analysis (quantitative analysis of summative content analysis (Hsieh & Shannon, 2005) of each
written publications) to capture trends in the popularity of national development plan generated the data we report on. Fol-
national development planning over time and, in particular, how lowing conventional content analysis, and corroborating this with
the published literature reflects this. Google Ngram searches were detailed country case studies, we proceeded to directed content
conducted in English, French, German, Russian and Spanish, the analysis. This was based on coding, using 10 core themes and 90
major languages in which the national planning literature exists, variables derived from our literature review. The 10 themes were:
with a focus on key terms: central planning, economic planning,
(national) development planning, as well as on variants of those 1. Country profile;
terms, e.g. economic plan. A broadened search period from1925 2. Plan outlook (data on the plan itself, title, themes, duration,
(i.e. just before the first Soviet Five-Year Plan) until 2008 (the most language of publication, cost of producing the plan, main
recent year for which Ngram provided data) was used to capture actors in the planning process);
trends in the popularity of national development planning over 3. Quality of the plan’s evidence base, including assumptions,
time. As the data from all languages were broadly similar (with a level of evidence, use of economic modelling;
peak in discussions of national planning in the 1960s and 1970s), 4. Scenario snapshots (i.e. past plan achievements and current
the paper reports on and uses only the English language results. plan goals and targets; strategic focus);
In order to cross-check our Ngram results, content analysis of 5. Key objectives and targets, including priority sectors and/or
seminal textbooks in development economics that have multiple demographic groups;
editions was also carried out, to see how much attention these paid 6. Links to global agendas;
to national development planning. Meier’s (1964–2005) Leading 7. Financing of the plan and means of implementation;
Issues in Economic Development (eight editions) and Todaro’s 8. Keywords such as aid, economic growth, job creation,
(1977–2015) Economic Development (12 editions) met these crite- empowerment, human development, poverty reduction/
ria. The results are broadly similar; however, this paper reports pri- eradication, SDGs, social transformation, sustainable
marily from Meier, mainly because, in addition to being a seminal growth/development, competitiveness
text and a compendium with extended commentaries, it is broadly 9. Issues, including assessments of the quality of the data, evi-
representative of development economics discourse at its many dence and methods used in the plan, quality of scenarios, if
publication dates. any;
Next, the study conducted a systematic and comprehensive 10. Plan orientation (technocratic, transformational or with ele-
review of literature on national development planning published ments of both).
since the Millennium. Very little coverage of such planning was
found during this period apart from fleeting references in Poverty While items 2–8 largely involved noting and counting in an
Reduction Strategy Papers (PRSPs). A meticulous search of websites objective fashion, items 9 and 10 involved expert judgement. We
of key international organizations (the International Monetary applied an adaptation of the policy Delphi technique (Dunn,
Fund (IMF), the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and 2017). Originally used as a forecasting technique that relies on a
Development (OECD), the UN Department of Economic and Social panel of experts, for this study, we engaged economic policy and
Affairs, the UN Development Programme, the World Bank Group), planning experts, and developed the respective sets of variables
done in 2016 and 2017, sought to identify whether these organiza- (see Appendix 2) used for themes 9 and 10 above.
tions were aware of the apparent return of national development Apart from the secondary data described above, the study also
planning and whether they appeared to be promoting its return. uses primary data from 10 country case studies as a way to better
A key World Bank document was found (World Bank, 2007), which contextualize findings in the empirical realities of day-to-day pol-
reported on the results of the Bank’s survey looking for ‘results- icy making. The paper draws on insights from the 10 case studies of
oriented’ national development plans. The World Bank reported the new national planning in Bangladesh, Benin, Ghana, Indonesia,
finding 62 countries with such plans in 2006, which provided it Peru, Togo, Tunisia, Uganda, South Africa and Zimbabwe. These
with a baseline figure for national development plans a decade countries have a variety of linguistic, legal and cultural traditions,
before our study. are based on several continents and also reflect various levels of
Finally, an exhaustive web search to identify and download as development. Each national case study used causal process tracing
many national development plans as could be found was then con- (CPT) (Collier, 2011) of national development planning and imple-
ducted, with a focus mostly on government websites of member mentation. In the case studies CPT was used more in a deductive
countries of the United Nations. This created an archive of 134 sense to help identify which planning paradigm they fitted into
national development plans published between 2012 and 2018. and to build an understanding of the level of elite commitment
For this study a national plan document was defined as ‘any to plans. All 10 case studies used a common methodology and
time-bound national plan with a set of coherent economic and are written in a common format. The next section discusses the
socio-political objectives that transcends sectors and articulates a study’s findings.
A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89 79

4. The Rise, fall and return of national planning have a demonstrable strategy for reducing poverty, as well as the
means to measure and track anti-poverty investments and poverty
For many newly independent states in the 1950s and 1960s, a levels. At the same time James Wolfensohn, President of the World
national development plan was almost as important a symbol of Bank, was energetically proposing that all developing countries
national sovereignty as a flag, written constitution or seat at the should have a Comprehensive Development Framework (Mallaby,
UN. In those mid-20th century decades, economic theory tended 2004, pp. 232–260) as the newly liberalized economies had ‘the
to focus on market failures (e.g. Arrow, 1963; Coase, 1960; need for a more integrated approach to development based on a
Keynes, 1931, Keynes, 1936; Polanyi, 1957, Robinson, 1933; framework articulated and ‘‘owned” by the country itself’ (World
Samuelson, 1954) and prescribe an interventionist economic policy Bank, 2001).
on a Keynesian, dirigiste or socialist model. Economic theories of The PRSPs were the eventual result of these competing initia-
the big push (Rosenstein-Rodan, 1943), balanced growth (Nurkse, tives and were adopted by 63 countries starting in 2001 (IMF,
1955), two-gap models (Chenery & Strout, 1966) emphasised the 2016). In many ways, PRSPs resembled old-style national develop-
need for the state to coordinate national development efforts or, ment plans, with investment plans, output targets across a range of
at least, to coordinate national investment planning to ensure com- directly productive and social sectors, and results matrices. The
plementary investments. PRSP approach included ‘participatory assessments’ to ensure that
In ideological terms, the mid-20th century saw a broad consen- planning was integrated with ‘good governance’. After preparing
sus in favour of state intervention in the economy on both sides of PRSPs, governments (for example Bangladesh, Benin, Ghana,
the Cold War. The apparent success of Soviet industrialization after Malawi, Togo, Uganda, Vietnam and Zambia) began to think about
five-year plans started in 1928 was proclaimed as proof of the returning to national plans that would pursue the MDGs and other
superiority of planned over free market economies (Baran, 1962). goals. It was noted earlier that in some of the ex-HIPCC Phase II
The success of the Marshall Plan in promoting post-war recovery countries (for example Zambia) new-found confidence to craft
in Western Europe was also claimed as a triumph of interventionist their own plans came from a commodity boom that provided the
economic policy in a capitalist economy. Even the World Bank pub- fiscal space to be more imaginative about their futures.
lished a how-to book on national economic planning techniques Around the same time, the rise of complexity science (Colander
(Blitzer, Clark & Taylor, 1975). & Kupers, 2014; Ramalingam, 2013) argued for new forms of plan-
Over the 1970s, however, disappointment with national eco- ning, based on contingency, behaviour change, adaptation and con-
nomic planning began to set in. While some suggested that plan- stant learning (Swanson & Bhadwal, 2009; Earl, Carden & Smutylo
ning was failing because of a lack of political will or inadequate 2001). Especially in environmental science and policy, planning for
data and planning capacity (Faber & Seers, 1972), many critics con- complexity became increasingly mainstream. Planning increas-
cluded that planning itself was the problem. Planners distorted ingly aimed not for specific outcomes, but for increased ‘resilience’
government budgets by focusing too much on investment com- of individuals, organizations and systems in the face of emergent
pared to running costs (Caiden & Wildavsky, 1974) or by substitut- phenomena (Hummelbrunner & Jones, 2013).
ing failing state structures for more efficient market mechanisms From the 1990s onwards, economic theory became more
(Agarwala, 1983; Bauer, 1982). Following in the footsteps of public favourable to certain types of state intervention. The economics
choice theory, the concepts of government failure, rent-seeking of asymmetric information (Barr, 1992) and behavioural eco-
and directly unproductive profit-making activities (Krueger, nomics (Kahneman, 2011; Thaler & Sunstein, 2009) both pointed
1974, Krueger, 1990; Bhagwati, 1982) caused by government inter- out new flaws in the idea of self-regulating markets. Similarly,
ference came to dominate development thinking. the new institutional economics (North, 1990) provided justifica-
By the early 1980s, as a component of ‘structural adjustment’, tion for considerable government activity beyond the night watch-
the World Bank and the IMF had begun a full-scale assault on man state. Indeed, one prominent member of the 1980s liberal
national development planning and on the planning ministries counter-revolution warned that ‘an older generation (of scholars
and commissions that promoted it (World Bank, 1983). The col- and advocates) who had emphasised the importance of market
lapse of the Soviet bloc in 1989–91 and the spectacular growth failures in development economics finds in the new institutional-
of the liberalized Chinese economy created further doubts about ism new justification for their interventionist beliefs’ (Bates,
the desirability of national development planning. Most of the for- 1995, p. 27). Although none of these new economic theories sup-
mer Soviet republics scrapped their planning apparatuses in the ported old-style central economic planning, they suggested that
1990s and early 2000s (Yazlyyev, 2017). In aid-dependent coun- new forms of state intervention were in order, in sharp contrast
tries the processes were gradual but, over the 1980s and 1990s, to the liberal counter-revolution of the 1980s.
many national planning agencies and economic development min- Bibliometric research allows us to examine when and how
istries were abolished or merged into ministries of finance, where interest in national development planning rose and declined.
they became marginalized in terms of status, staffing, budget and According to Google Ngram searches in English and French, the lit-
relevance to policy. erature on economic planning peaked in the mid-1960s, coinciding
Nevertheless, national development planning never went away with the apogee of post-independence optimism regarding
completely. China, India and Malaysia kept their national planning planned, autonomous development in the ‘Third World’ (Fig. 1).
apparatus, even as they liberalized their economies. The World The peaks in the Russian, Spanish and German language literatures
Summit for Children in 1990 pushed dozens of countries to pro- occurred somewhat later, in the 1970s. There was a revival in the
duce ‘national plans of action for children’. This push was conso- use of the term ‘central planning’, especially in German, in the
nant with research showing that there was no one-to-one early 1990s as the countries of the former Soviet bloc transitioned
relationship between economic growth and the advance of human from centrally planned to market-based economies.
development – conscious effort by the state was needed to effec- Content analysis of all eight editions of Meier’s (1964–2005)
tively promote health, nutrition and education (Drèze & Sen, 1989). textbook, Leading Issues in Economic Development, reveals a marked
Starting in 1996, the Heavily Indebted Poor Country (HIPC) ini- decline in interest in economic planning over time (Fig. 2).1 Meier’s
tiative offered debt relief in exchange for commitments by benefi-
ciary states to invest in health, education, nutrition and poverty 1
As measured by the percentage of the pages mentioning ‘plan’, ‘planning’,
reduction. The creditors insisted, however, that HIPC beneficiaries ‘development planning’, ‘economic planning’, ‘central planning’, ‘decentralized plan-
ning’ or ‘plan implementation’.
80 A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89

Fig. 1. Mentions of development planning in books published in English 1925–2008. Source: Author’s analysis.

1% of the pages in Meier in the 1995, 2000 and 2005 editions and in
similar amounts in other development economics textbooks.
In 2007, after a quarter century of leading the drive toward eco-
nomic liberalization, the World Bank published a survey of ‘na-
tional results-based national development strategies’ or what an
earlier era would have called national development plans. The
Bank found 62 countries had such documents. In 2016–17, we
replicated that World Bank survey and located equivalent docu-
ments in 134 countries, almost a doubling in the number of coun-
tries having a national development plan or strategy between 2006
and 2016. Countries with a national development plan now once
again form the majority of countries on earth. Furthermore, most
people now live in a country with a national development plan.3
Countries with national development plans are found on all conti-
nents and regions, with all major metropolitan linguistic traditions
(Anglophone, Arabophone, Francophone, Hispanophone, Lusophone,
Fig. 2. Percentage of pages concerned with development planning in Meier’s Russophone), all levels of income and human development (includ-
Leading Issues in Economic Development, various editions. Source: Author’s analysis. ing the leading ‘emerging countries’), and with a wide variety of legal
and constitutional traditions and political regimes (including liberal
democratic market economies in the OECD). Countries with a
own comments on the prospects for planning also became markedly
national development plan include recent development ‘successes’
less optimistic between the early and middle editions. The same gen-
like China, India and Malaysia, as well as those that have been in
eral trend is found in Todaro’s Economic Development, as the propor-
decline like Zimbabwe.
tion of pages devoted to development planning declines from 6.2 per
The increasing number and spread of national development
cent in the second edition (1981) to 1.5 per cent in the 10th edition
plans over the past decade is an important policy trend that
(2009).
requires explanation and exploration. It might be tempting to
The decline in interest in development planning in the Meier
assume that, like so many trends in development, this one origi-
textbook is paralleled by a rising interest in government failure,
nated in the UN, in the IFIs, or in the Development Cooperation
rent seeking and other aspects of the liberal critique of state-
Directorate of the OECD (OECD-DAC). A search and analysis of
driven development.2 Discussions of government failure rise from
the UN,4 World Bank, IMF and OECD websites in July–August 2016
no pages in the 1964 edition to 6.5 per cent of the total pages in
and again in July–August 2017, however, found no evidence to sup-
the 2005 edition.
port such an assumption. On the contrary, these international bodies
By the mid-1990s, national development planning had virtually
disappeared from the development literature, appearing on under
3
This is largely because populous emerging countries like Bangladesh, China, India,
2
As measured by the percentage of pages mentioning ‘rent seeking’ (society), Indonesia, Nigeria and Vietnam have national development plans.
4
(vested) ‘interest groups’, ‘government failure’, ‘state failure’, (price) ‘distortion(s)’, Our search focused on the UN Development Programme, the UN Department of
‘directly unproductive profitable activities’, or ‘welfare loss’. Economic and Social Affairs and the UN Economic and Social Council.
A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89 81

seem barely aware of the recent return of national development some of the earlier plans from Turkmenistan and North Korea). A
planning. All their websites together contained fewer than a dozen few have objectives that diverge from the international consensus
documents related to national development planning and no recog- embodied in the MDGs and SDGs, promoting cultural purity (Bhu-
nition that such planning had made a return. The return of national tan), productivist development even if it is at the expense of the
development planning appears to be an initiative led by the coun- environment (North Korea and Uzbekistan) and a variety of nation-
tries of the global South and, recently, a result of mobilising to pur- alist themes. To some extent this third reason confirms a recurring
sue the SDGs (see Southernvoice.org). theme in the plans analysed, especially the way pluralist develop-
ment thinking is evolving in a multi-polar, post-financial crisis,
post-Washington Consensus World. The crucial point to this is that
5. Why has national development planning Re-emerged? national plans are providing a window into the nature of develop-
ment in a post-neoliberal world and views that run counter to glo-
This section draws on the evidence from a review of the litera- bal ideals are also reflected in the plans. For these ‘rebels’ there is
ture, an analysis of 107 plans, and detailed evidence from the 10 an element here of a desire to chart a course of development not
case study countries. While the broader development literature necessarily based on what the global consensus is.
provided a more global context for the production of plans, analy- A fourth reason for the return of national planning relates to the
sis of the plans and case study work in the 10 selected countries fears and opportunities presented by some of the forces of eco-
allowed a better grounding of the reasons for the re-emergence nomic globalisation. Rodrik (2011) has coined the term the ‘tri-
of national development planning. A majority of the plans analysed lemma’ to characterize the challenges of how to manage the
include a preamble explaining the reason for producing them, as tensions inherent in processes of economic globalization, national
well as any acknowledgements for their production. An analysis sovereignty and democratic governance. Evidence from the 107
of these sections helped to build a picture of why countries are pro- plans analysed suggests that some national development plans
ducing plans. In addition, the detailed case study analysis allowed are tools of virtue signalling – activist states trying at the same
this study to follow up on some of the reason why national devel- time to manage both upside and downside risks of liberal global-
opment planning has re-emerged in specific contexts. ization. In other words, national development plans are an attempt
Our analysis suggests four reasons why developing and other by emerging economies to build resilient and integrated national
emerging economies have created and published national develop- economies capable of facing the downside risks of globalization,
ment plans. First, the HIPC conditionalities meant that PRSPs led as seen in events such as the 1998 East Asian Crisis and the 2009
back to national development planning in many of those countries. Great Recession. At the same time evidence from some of the coun-
Of the 63 countries in the IMF database of PRSPs (IMF, 2017), 52 tries where deliberative bottom-up approaches to producing the
now have some kind of national development plan that goes plans was used suggests a clear effort to reclaim national sover-
beyond ‘poverty reduction’ and the remaining 11 have new- eignty and (re-)democratise the process of setting national goals.
generation PRSPs. There is evidence from our specific country case
studies of Ghana, Uganda, Benin and Togo that the tightly managed
HIPC and the PRSPs helped to build state capacity to plan as well as 6. New national plans: characteristics and types
orient state institutions and elites to learn to commit to plans. The
main impact of PRSPs was getting ministries of finance to look at 6.1. Duration of plans
poverty and human development as ‘their’ concern rather than just
passing them over to social sector ministries (Driscoll & Evans, Most national development plans have a planning horizon of
2005). four to six years, with 45 per cent of plans running for five years
Second, it is clear from reading the content of the 107 plans (Fig. 3). Many countries call these medium-term plans, which
analysed in this study that the new wave of national development may or may not be accompanied by a longer-term ‘vision’ docu-
plans (NDPs) are a response to the challenge posed by the MDGs of ment of 20 years or more. Five-year plans are the most common,
2000 and the SDGs of 2015; simply put, the existence of these especially in the ex-HIPC countries. For many of these countries
increasingly comprehensive sets of development goals required a the plans broadly map to the political calendar of elections (for
planning and monitoring framework. A majority of plans from example, the Ghana plan). This is longer than the three-year PRSPS
the global South make specific mention of the MDGs and SDGs in and their IFI-dominated schedules. Countries with longer-term
their content. The institutional support availed to countries signing plans will in some cases also produce more detailed sector plans
up to these has also spurred the practice of producing plans. Global or break the long-term plan into bite-sized segments. There are
goals affect NDPs in different ways. This is clear when one looks at some regional variations, however, with Eastern Europe and Latin
the structuring of planning and at whether a comprehensive or a America showing more significant variation. In trying to under-
sectoral approach (or both) are adopted. From the detailed case stand determinants of plan duration we find that that this is less
study work done as part of this study we learn that, in Indonesia, dependent on how long it actually takes to physically implement
the SDGs fostered a shift towards comprehensive planning while, plans and much more on other factors. Preliminary analysis sug-
by contrast, in Bangladesh the MDGs and SDGs have encouraged gests a strong association between plan duration and the political
both a set of sectoral strategies around specific, selected goals (that calendar of elections in countries. This is particularly true for coun-
ministers and sectoral ministries seek to control) and the continu- tries where democratic transitions are a common tradition through
ation of a national plan that seeks to be comprehensive. Global goal elections. There is also a strong association between those coun-
setting has fostered a professionalization of national development tries with long term plans (over five years) and 1) either the
planning, created more and better data and strengthened belief in absence of strong political contestation for power; or 2) political
technical monitoring and analysis. governance conditions that do not allow the possibility of change
A third and perhaps perverse reason for the return of national in government. This is particularly true in parts of the former
planning is that NDPs are seen as a counter-narrative to the global Soviet Union.
agreement embodied in the Agenda 2030 for Sustainable Develop- Another interesting dimension to the duration of plans is the
ment. This on the surface appears to contradict the preceding para- implication of the shorter planning horizon (five years and below)
graph but Munro (2017), argues that some of the country plans are for the more long-term SDGs that require sustained commitment
in fact rebelling against the MDG–SDG consensus (as in the case of across electoral cycles. Preliminary evidence from the more recent
82 A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89

Duraon of Naonal Plans(Years) Naonal Planning Agency


50
45
Unit Office of
40
President/Prime Minister
35
30
Ministry of Finance or
25 Economic Planning
Number of Plans
20 Related Ministry
15 No specific Owner
10
5
0 Polical Party
3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 15 18 20+

Fig. 3. Duration of plans. Source: Author’s analysis based on 99 plan documents. Fig. 4. Ownership and drivers of national development plans. Source: Author’s data
compiled from plans: n = 97.

plans suggests that, while many countries have begun to accom-


modate the SDGs, this has not necessarily changed the shorter the planning agency has meant that it is now much more directly
planning horizons, as focus remains on the political calendar, espe- aligned with the president/state house than with the ministry of
cially in democracies. There is evidence suggesting that, in some finance (seen as donor-captured). However, this has also meant
countries (e.g. Ghana and to some extent South Africa) where the that the agency is not as influential in sector ministries as it was
process of producing the plan has been inclusive and created some when it was more aligned with the finance ministry. These two
form of ‘elite consensus’ across the political divide, the longer-term cases suggest that individual country context and related political
planning horizon can survive a change in government. There is factors often determine how effective the agency can be, irrespec-
more evidence from the detailed case study work that national tive of where it is located. In 24 of the 107 plans there is no indi-
development plans more generally are more politically embedded cation of which government agency owns the plan, a factor that
and more a part of national political systems, and therefore more has been taken to mean a lack of serious effort to make the plan
nationally owned, than PRSPs ever were. This is particularly true work. Without a clear sponsor and multiple or conflicting owners,
for both the above countries, where deliberative bottom up plan implementation and monitoring may become quite confusing
approaches have been used to generate the plans. and there is evidence in such contexts that line ministries often
then do not take the national development plan seriously and will
often produce their own operational plan.
6.2. Who owns and produces the plans?
The content analysis also provides evidence of the return of
national planning agencies as independent quasi-state bodies.
Here ‘ownership’ of the plan refers to the agency or unit that
When countries moved away from national development planning
produces the plan, mobilises support and is ultimately responsible
in the late 1980s and 1990s national planning agencies were either
for supervising plan implementation, monitoring key results and
abolished, got whittled down or were absorbed by finance or eco-
reporting on progress. Ownership of national plans is important
nomic development ministries. They re-emerged in the form of
in that it sends a political signal about leadership, commitment
parastatals with the resurgence of new national planning and
and the importance attached to the plan. Information on owner-
now constitute the third most likely location for driving national
ship of a plan was extracted by content analysis of national plan
development plans (Fig. 4). There is no direct evidence that their
documents. Fig. 4 indicates that a majority of the plans and the
existence means plans will be of a better quality than before or that
offices responsible for them still sit in the traditional ministries
they will be more likely to be implemented. However, indications
of finance or economic planning. The fact that a majority of the
from the 10 case studies suggest that a country with a specialised
countries in this group are countries that went through the HIPC
agency is likely to have greater state capacity and better quality
programme suggests that this arrangement is a legacy of the insti-
national development plans. The existence of national planning
tutional arrangements from that time. There is no widespread evi-
agencies is more likely to indicate a commitment to driving
dence yet to suggest that merely being located in a finance
through a plan, as it can ensure that the process is run by specialist
ministry or a powerful political office like that of the president
technocrats rather than generalist bureaucrats. The latter point is
increases commitment or the possibility of plan implementation.
particularly important as some evidence from our detailed case
However, there is some evidence of an association between the
study work indicates that national development plans associated
location and ownership of a plan in a powerful political office
with ‘professionalised’ agencies are more likely to survive a change
and the likelihood that the plan will begin to influence how
in government than those housed in traditional ministries.
resources are allocated through the budget. For example, in coun-
tries where the National Planning Authority has constitutional
backing and is based or located in the most politically powerful 6.3. The content of plans and global goals
office in a country, there is closer alignment between the plan
and public expenditure allocations through the national budget. The content analysis, based on key search terms, revealed com-
We identified 27 such countries and have evidence from one of mon elements but also some regional variations in the content of
the 10 case study countries (Ghana) suggesting that having consti- national development plans (Table 1). Four findings merit atten-
tutional status raises its profile and independence, thereby giving it tion. First, all plans include a major focus on economic concerns
an ability to survive changes in government during elections. We and policies: growth rate, trade, investment, export earnings and
also learn from the Uganda case study, however, that achieving productivity growth. Second, plans from mainly natural resource-
constitutional status can reduce the operational effectiveness of rich countries have a distinct focus on the ‘structural transforma-
the planning authority. In this case, constitutional protection of tion’ of their respective economies by fostering economic diversifi-
A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89 83

Table 1
Bibliometric analysis of key phrases/words used in all national plans by region.

Region Aid Capacity Economic Investment Poverty Resilience Sustainable Socioeconomic SDGs
development/ growth reduction/ growth/ growth/devt./
building eradication development transformation
Sub-Saharan Africa1 732 1606 1335 3980 1194 175 531 282 100
Asia1 123 432 430 1967 251 182 188 92 24
Europe & CIS1 20 210 644 1757 147 8 284 135 18
Middle East & North Africa1 124 265 195 1197 500 25 557 45 56
Latin America1 137 656 361 1611 463 59 434 23 3
USSR1 0 7 2 13 0 0 2 22 0
Total 1136 3176 2967 10,525 2555 449 1996 599 201

Source: Author’s data compiled from NDPs.


1
The assumption that a data revolution is apolitical is extremely naïve. Much data has commercial value and is harvested and monopolised by very powerful corporations
(e.g. Amazon and Google). Other data, for example hydrological data (especially about dams), is classified as ‘top secret’ in many countries (e.g. China and India).

cation. In Middle East and North African (MENA) countries there is 7. Types of contemporary national development plans
a focus on reducing dependency on natural resources and on
employment creation, and young people are singled out as a group It is evident that the re-emergence of national planning has not
needing special attention (after the ‘Arab Spring’). produced a homogeneous set of plans. Instead, there are distinct
Third, plans from sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) often have an variants. Here we conduct a preliminary analysis based on a simple
emphasis on investment, economic growth and poverty reduction 22 matrix that sorts plans in terms of whether they are based
and they single out youth and women as special groups for atten- on a linear or a collaborative conceptualisation of rationality
tion. Reading through many of the plans from SSA shows the iner- (see Section 2) and whether they are strongly or weakly
tia created by years of externally managed programmes under the evidence-based and socially embedded (Fig. 5).
HIPC initiative and the PRSPs. Many of the key headings required Our 22 matrix yields four ‘types’ of plan:
under HIPC remain and it is also clear that many SSA countries Type A – Top-down, expert-led plans with a strong evidence
have economic content in their plans that map closely to World base but limited social embeddedness;
Bank-led country diagnostic studies. The social development prior- Type B – Bottom-up, collaboratively created plans with a strong
ities of SSA plans tend to strongly integrate the MDG and/or SDG evidence base and high social embeddedness;
agenda. A small sub-set of African national development plans Type C – Top-down plans, disjointed and with weak evidence
(e.g. Algeria, Eritrea, Zimbabwe) emphasises strongly nationalist and limited social embeddedness;
themes, such as indigenization of the economy, the maintenance Type D – Bottom-up plans with weak evidence base and limited
of national sovereignty, self-reliance and resistance to outside social embeddedness.
interference. Some 38 per cent of plans adopted the linear/top-down
A fourth observation that differentiates contemporary plans approach (A or C), as against 62 per cent adopting more collabora-
from an earlier generation is the attention paid to common global tive or communicative approaches. This suggests that the historical
issues, like climate change and the environment, and to global pub- domination of planning theory by linear thinking has not been con-
lic goods. Almost all plans mention climate change and the uncer- tinued by the new national development planning. In addition, 68
tainty it creates as a risk that plans must take into account. per cent of plans were strongly evidence-based and coherent,
Similarly, the SDGs are referenced in the newer plans with a partic- while 32 per cent were weakly evidence-based and/or disjointed
ular focus on social and human development issues. To a degree, it or incoherent. Thus, around one-third of contemporary national
is as if the national development plan is an opportunity for a coun- plans are either intellectually weak or purely ornamental.
try to show it is a ‘good global citizen’ responding to a common
agenda.
7.1. Type A: Top-down, expert-led, strong evidence base but limited
6.4. Financing of national development plans social embeddedness

A key consideration of the quality of any plan is whether it has Just over a quarter of the 107 plans are Type A. National plans
been properly costed and sources of financing worked out. Without produced in this way are usually led by technical teams in core
this, a plan will lack credibility and, though still useful in other economic and finance ministries or, in the case of many Persian
respects (for example, as political signalling), the extent to which Gulf countries, by global consulting companies. The content of such
it influences future spending decisions will diminish. Our content plans is tailored to a technical and economically literate audience.
analysis of the national plans shows that financing is the weakest Sometimes, simpler, less technical summaries are published for the
area in most plans. Of the 107 analysed, a majority (79) have no lay citizenry. Development plans in this mould show limited social
specific costing associated with plan implementation, save for embeddedness, in terms of being inclusive of views and ideas from
vague references to domestic and foreign sources. Of the 29 plans all social groups, but are shaped by the thinking of selected polit-
that explained how they would be financed, 14 mentioned govern- ical, bureaucratic and corporate elites. The weaknesses of such an
ment and donors while, 13 of them identified central government approach are now well known and include a lack of shared vision
and domestic sources as their main sources of finance. A majority and the effect this has on accountability and confidence in both
of the countries talk more generally about both domestic and inter- political and economic governance processes. The prevalence of
national financing as crucial for implementing plans. While there is such types of plans in countries without significant political power
great variability in the levels of detail, generally countries that contestation (especially the absolute monarchies) suggests a need
ascribe a greater role for domestic sources of funding provide more to test further an association between this type of plan and types of
certainty and precision about financing arrangements compared governance systems in a country.
with those that seek external investment and other external Plans tending towards Type A are generally technically compe-
receipts. tent and sophisticated in the forms of analysis and evidence base
84 A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89

easily accessible to a lay audience. Plans tending towards Type B


show a balancing of their economic and social content, being
couched in the language of ‘inclusive growth’ and often identifying
specific social groups (women, young people and the elderly) for
attention. Type B plans also relate local priorities to the regional
and global development contexts. This is especially true of the
more recent plans, whose content includes specific reference to
the SDGs and the Paris climate change agreement. Such plans have
relatively strong evidence bases (including economic modelling
and/or scenario building) but are written in a language accessible
to both lay and professional audiences. The language of new man-
agerialism is used to relate the different levels at which results are
to be achieved and there is usually a clear agency that owns the
plan.
Plans tending towards Type B match the spirit of the SDGs, in
Fig. 5. Functional classification of types of national development plans. Source: which the pursuit of SDG 16 (peace, justice and strong institutions)
Author’s analysis of plans from 103 countries. and SDG 17 (partnerships) make the planning process as important
as the plan itself. From an SDG perspective, Type B is probably the
closest fit to an ‘ideal–type’ national development plan. There is
used to arrive at decisions. The typical Type A plan includes some
some evidence from our detailed case study work – especially in
form of economic modelling, scenario building and/or the use of
Ghana and Uganda – that a Type B plan draws in commitment from
input–output models. The plans from Togo, China and Saudi Arabia
across the political elites and therefore improves its prospects of
are good examples of this approach. Such plans have limited social
implementation. Resource allocation (budget and staffing) closely
embeddedness, as there is little or no evidence that state-led pro-
resembles the priorities set in such plans and the political rhetoric
cesses have recognized or engaged the wider society about the
matches plan contents. This is not to suggest that plans tending
plan’s values and vision (beyond opaque public consultation exer-
towards Type A cannot draw commitment or mobilise implemen-
cises). Some plans will state that all stakeholders were ‘consulted’,
tation capacity. About half the countries in the B group are former
but it is not apparent what mechanisms have been used. In coun-
HIPC countries, appear on the DAC list of aid-eligible countries and,
tries with autocratic regimes the national developments plan usu-
in some cases, are still significantly dependent on aid donors.
ally reads like the ‘ruler’s world-view’ of what is good for the
Whether they have adopted a Type B approach through domestic
‘subjects’, rather than a collective vision. Plan documents tending
choice or following donor preferences is unclear from reading the
towards Type A are generally very well written and costed, and
plan document but the case studies of Uganda and Togo suggests
set clear goals and targets. The content is heavily skewed towards
a combination of both.
economics, finance, trade, business and productivity, although
some attention is paid to public administration and social issues.
7.3. Type C: Top-down plans, disjointed and with a weak evidence base
Although sustainability and climate change get mentioned, there
and limited social embeddedness
is limited emphasis on global goals, such as the SDGs and the Paris
climate change agreement. Monitoring mechanisms tend to be
Our content analysis identified only 10 plans of this type. Plans
clearly laid out using the language of new managerialism and the
tending toward Type C are premised on the linear rationality that
plan document has a clear ‘owner’ responsible for results.
underpins Type A plans but they lack competence, are disjointed
and use evidence poorly. Evidence from the content analysis sug-
7.2. Type B: Bottom-up, collaborative plans with a strong evidence gests that Type C is produced in a context of degraded state capac-
base and high social embeddedness ity. Zimbabwe’s original ZIMASSET 2013–18 plan is a typical
example of Type C plans. Such plans are driven from the top and,
Around 42 per cent of the 107 plans fall into this group. These rather than being evidence-led, they attempt to mimic elements
plans involve creating a broad-based social consensus about values of plans from successful countries. There is often little coherent
and actions towards a defined and shared future (see Section 2). examination and justification for the key priorities listed or of
The national development plan is therefore seen as a set of agreed how they relate to each other. The content tends to an eclectic col-
values, actions and pathways for achieving this common future, lection of topics, ranging from the economy, finance and business
and the process of building national consensus is as important as to the social and environmental, without a structured considera-
the content of the plan itself. However, it must be noted that it tion of how they support or undermine each other. Although key
may take a very long time to establish a consistent set of prefer- terms such as sustainability, climate change and SDGs appear in
ences for a society or may simply be impossible. In spite of these Type C plans, it is clear that these are used as sound-bites and
weaknesses, communicative rationality does appear to have are only superficially engaged and deployed. Often Type C docu-
become the default modus operandi for those working to plan for ments do not have a clear owner and monitoring mechanisms
the achievement of the SDGs. are not clearly articulated. There is no evidence of the plan being
National development plans tending towards type B are the socially embedded, although in some of them there is mention of
most common of the 107 plans analysed. The current plans for ‘consultations’ with society. Our detailed case study work suggests
Uganda and Ghana are examples. Typically, such plans have evi- that countries tending towards Type C have significant political
dence of the participation or involvement of groups other than just and economic governance deficits.
the bureaucratic, political and corporate elites. There is evidence of
wider social consultation on what constitutes national values and 7.4. Type D: Bottom-up plans with a weak evidence base and limited
priorities. Reading such plans gives an impression that the national social embeddedness
development plan is a document for communication and negotia-
tion with multiple stakeholders, both internal and external. Type When national development plans reflect broad-based and par-
B documents are usually publicly available and in forms that are ticipatory processes but produce a vision that is poorly translated,
A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89 85

they tend towards Type D. Some 20 per cent of the 107 plans we developing countries.5 This meant that the IFIs had a concrete
analysed fell into this category; Peru and Venezuela are clear mechanism to shape (critics would say ‘control’) plans in aid-
examples of the type. For such plans there is evidence that a recipient countries. In effect, plans and policies were often deter-
bottom-up process was attempted but there is a lack of credible mined by negotiations between the IFI ‘partners’ – with the World
and coherent analysis justifying the decisions and priorities Bank sometimes supporting pursuit of the MDGs (through increased
reached. Plans tending towards Type D are produced in a participa- public expenditure on health, education and gender projects) and
tory manner and are usually publicly available. In terms of the con- the IMF seeing the MDGs as threatening fiscal discipline.
tent, Type D plans engage with global issues such as the SDGs and The UN created two concrete mechanisms to ensure the MDGs
climate change but in a superficial way. The national–global links would have an impact on practice. First, a linear–rational, planning
to these issues is not clearly enunciated and evidence is weak or mechanism in the form of the Millennium Project (led by Jeffrey
inconsistent. Further, the scale of the issues and challenges identi- Sachs) and a social transformation mechanism, the Millennium
fied is not matched by the scale of response proposed and there are Campaign (led by Evelyn Herfkens). The Millennium Project took
usually unrealistic expectations about the availability of resources a ‘Type A’, top-down, technocratic frame: its MDG-based Poverty
for plan execution. Countries tending towards Type D have often Reduction Strategies would shape national plans such that vastly
gone through periods of political or economic instability or are in increased public expenditure and better technical analysis would
the process of emerging from conflict. Sometimes Type D plans achieve MDG targets across developing countries (Hulme 2007).
are part of mass political mobilisations meant to convey a message By contrast, the Millennium Campaign adopted a socio-political
of hope to citizens. Such plans convey a message that says: change approach that was bottom-up and sought to mobilise civil
although there are challenges, those with power know about them society and promote social action for poverty eradication. The
and are doing something through this plan. They can be seen as underlying principles and characteristics of the Project and the
part of ‘state theatre’, a performance by the state to calm a restive Campaign could not have been more different (see Table 2).
population or to win the trust and confidence of citizens but with In 2005 Sachs, and more than 100 expert colleagues from 13
little obvious intention of any meaningful achievement of stated working parties, published the UN Millennium Project’s main
objectives. report – Investing in Development: A Practical Plan to Achieve the
MDGs – which sought to identify the projects, policies and invest-
ments that would most rapidly tackle poverty and human develop-
8. The new national development planning and global ment deprivations. These teams had conducted vast and high-
development goals quality surveys of ‘what worked’ globally in anti-poverty pro-
grammes. Had the ambitious plans for rolling out this report been
We argued above that the emergence of global goals has in part supported by UN members, then an era of standardised Type A
spurred the emergence of new national planning. Internationally, plans would have been promoted across developing countries.
at least in terms of the public record, one of the most important But, after its grand launch, the main report and its detailed support
recent factors is the apparent consensus that all countries should documents rapidly faded from the agenda for international devel-
pursue global goals agreed through UN processes. These included opment. Technically, the UN’s Millennium Project may (or may
the MDGs, the SDGs and the Paris Agreement on Climate Change not) have been excellent, but the global South was not going to fol-
of 2015. While these agreements are sometimes presented as low the lead of ‘another middle-aged white man’ saving them.
‘technical’, all were the products of intensely political negotiations. Around the same time an increasing number of developing
The MDGs were driven by aid donors (OECD countries and countries became more assertive about how the IFIs’ PRSPs – and
international agencies) and sought to reduce (roughly ‘halve’) glo- plans more generally – should be prepared (Hulme 2015). The
bal poverty by 2015. They pursued income poverty reduction, drafting of PRSPs had partially rehabilitated the idea of compre-
human development and sustainability by setting goals and targets hensive planning. But the ways in which they had been drafted
whose achievement was to be assessed by objectively verifiable also had exposed the weaknesses of aid-led development. The first
indicators. This was straight from a results-based management ‘principle’ of PRSPs – they must be ‘Country-driven: involving
textbook. The SDGs were the product of much more complex nego- broad-based participation by civil society and the private sector. . .’
tiations from 2012 to 2015 about ‘what comes after the MDGs’. (see Hulme (2010, p. 133) for World Bank webpages) – had been so
They were arrived at by discussions among all UN member states deeply abrogated by foreign consultants that Uganda, Ghana, Viet-
and are much more ambitious in both depth and breadth – seeking nam and others began to think of taking control of planning.
to eradicate poverty (in income and human development dimen- From what has been discussed above one might judge the
sions) and promote sustainability, equality, human rights and good MDGs a failure in terms of their influence on national planning
governance. But, like the MDGs, the SDGs are non-binding: there processes. This would be incorrect. The MDGs helped to do three
are no sanctions for countries who do not honour the agreement. things. First, they rehabilitated the idea of systematic planning –
By contrast, the Paris Agreement on Climate Change sought to be market-based coordination by itself could not deliver national
binding but, after tortuous negotiations, took a relatively weak development goals; second, they heightened the focus on the
form: countries should voluntarily set their own targets (not adopt application of evidence for planning and policy choices; and third,
international targets) and these nationally determined targets they increased demand for good-quality data on poverty, depriva-
should be binding. tion and other issues. These achievements have had great signifi-
How has this international move to set and agree global goals cance for the successor to the MDGs – the SDGs of 2015.
affected the re-emergence of national planning? Evidence suggests
that the MDGs helped reignite national planning but in close asso- 8.1. The Sustainable development goals and new national planning
ciation with other elements of the ‘Millennium moment’, such as
HIPC and PRSPs, so exact effects are hard to confirm. The most The UN’s Sustainable Development Goals, agreed by all UN
obvious impact is that the MDGs ‘deal’, agreed by the UN member states in 2015, adopt the MDG format of goals, targets
Secretary-General and the IFIs (World Bank and IMF) in March and indicators based on results-based management thinking. But
2001, continued to grant oversight of national-level policy negoti-
ations to the IFIs through PRSPs. These documents required formal
Bank/IMF approval before IFI and donor funds could be released to 5
See Hulme (2007, 2010, 2015) for detailed discussions and evidence.
86 A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89

Table 2
A comparison of the main characteristics of the Millennium Project and Millennium Campaign.

Characteristics Millennium Project Millennium Campaign


Approach Top-down Bottom-up
Key actors Scientists and specialists Civil society organizations
Strategy Detailed plans and implementation Political mobilization
Interventions Focus on aid Pre-selected and tested Emergent through practice
More aid means less poverty All governments should be much more accountable for volume, quality and use of public finance
Goal Deliver basic needs to the poor Promote human rights and empowerment for all
Role of leader Lead from the front, take a high profile Let partners lead, stay in the background
View on MDGs Total acceptance Useful for ‘newcomers’ but experienced people and organizations need locally determined goals

Source: Adapted from Hulme (2010, p. 130).

the SDGs emerged from a quite different negotiating process. would be useless. In the end the Paris Agreement on Climate
Rather than being driven by OECD countries and aid agencies, Change was agreed: countries should pursue voluntary, national
the SDGs were produced after painstaking deliberation by all UN targets that would cap global warming at 2 °C and, if possible, at
members in an Open Working Group. This had two important con- 1.5 °C. As targets are voluntary, much of its ‘success’ was that it
sequences for the ways in which the SDGs have affected and may was not a public failure. Potentially, the Paris Agreement has pro-
make an impact on national planning. found implications for national planning as, in future, all national
First, the SDGs are much more numerous than the MDGs, with plans will need to consider the carbon footprint of their economic
17 goals and 169 targets. Technically this makes it much more dif- and human development programmes, ideally by carbon budget-
ficult to set priorities, as there is a much greater number of choices ing. In many countries this will be through liaison with a specialist
and potential trade-offs than with the MDGs. But the SDGs have ministry but there is a possibility that the need to assess the cli-
the great advantage that they now cover economic growth and mate impacts of all activities could more broadly strengthen the
related goals such as employment, infrastructure, urbanisation role of national planning in shaping public policy decisions.
and energy. The MDGs were always only partial goals, as they
did not include ‘economic development’, which had remained the 8.3. Global goals, state capacity and elite commitment to national
domain of the IFIs. development
Second, the SDGs explicitly recognise that they are global goals
and that individual countries need to select their own national As discussed earlier in this paper, the ways in which global goal-
goals and targets through national deliberation processes. The setting exercises affect national planning processes can be concep-
ambiguity that surrounded the MDGs – did countries have to adopt tualised in different ways. At a purely technical level of analysis,
them into national plans or could they be re-set – has been then, global goals can be seen as supportive of NDPs as they point
removed. This creates more opportunity for the SDGs to promote to the need for better technical analysis for public decision making.
national goal-setting and associated national planning initiatives, There is substantial evidence that the MDGs have led to more and
as the argument, or feeling, that goals are being imposed from better data being available for many important indicators.6 Not
above (by aid agencies or ‘middle-aged white men’) has gone. surprisingly, there has been much enthusiasm for promoting a ‘data
The role of leading international technical specialists is to advise, revolution’ which promises to strengthen the planning, managing
as Jeffrey Sachs now does through the Sustainable Development and monitoring of development interventions from a politically
Solutions Network, and not to direct through a New York-based non-partisan position.7 In Indonesia one can argue that global goals
mega-project. have moved well beyond ‘data’ and have directly shaped bureau-
In addition to these effects, two specific SDGs have implications cratic action: the National Planning Agency has been set the task
for the new national planning. Goal 16 (peace, justice and strong of planning for the country to fully achieve the SDGs by 2030.
institutions) potentially fosters the evolution of strengthened ana- But global goal-setting can also make an impact through com-
lytical capacities in government and of greater citizen participation municative and/or collaborative rationality redefining values and
in decision making. If it was seriously adopted, it would reduce the operating more ideologically. The UN Millennium Campaign
number of weak national plans (types C and D) and would encour- sought to activate this approach by mobilising civil societies, in
age type B processes based on collaborative rationality (see Sec- donor and emerging-power countries, to campaign against pov-
tions 2 and 7). Goal 17 (partnerships for the goals) would erty. Consciously or unconsciously, it focused on reshaping the
potentially foster stronger global, regional, national and sub- social norms of the middle classes by internationally diffusing
national partnerships but its lack of clear indicators suggests that, the MDGs (Fukuda-Parr & Hulme, 2011). More elite-focused frame-
as with the MDGs, partnership will be encouraged as an idea, yet works for understanding social change, such as the political settle-
with no practical plans-of-action. ments framework (Hickey et al., 2015), see global goals as a
potential path towards encouraging political and business elites
8.2. The Paris agreement on climate change to recognise that their fostering more effective state action (better
schooling and health services, etc.) could contribute to both social
In 2015, as tens of thousands of diplomats, politicians, civil soci- progress and greater commercial opportunities for themselves
ety activists and scientists were arguing into the early hours of the (self-interest).
morning on the final content of the SDGs, there was a much bigger
‘global goals game’ in the background – climate change. This was 6
For example, in 2000 the data available on maternal mortality in most low-
an even more contentious negotiation as first, it involved real income countries was weak or non-existent. By 2015 most low-income countries
trade-offs, in which some countries would have to agree to transfer (except those engaged in conflict) had usable data on maternal mortality. See http://
mics.unicef.org/ and https://www.dhsprogram.com/.
resources to other countries; and, second, it sought to be a binding 7
The assumption that a data revolution is apolitical is extremely naïve. Much data
agreement. If Paris failed, as an earlier summit in Copenhagen had, has commercial value and is harvested and monopolised by very powerful corpora-
then the idea of global goal-setting would have been greatly weak- tions (e.g. Amazon and Google). Other data, for example hydrological data (especially
ened. Indeed, some SDG veterans said that, if Paris failed, the SDGs about dams), is classified as ‘top secret’ in many countries (e.g. China and India).
A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89 87

The technical and elite commitment strands of analysis can require much attention going forward. A fourth conclusion is the
combine when national elites take actions that raise state capacity clear need for further detailed case study work to understand some
to plan and implement public programmes (see Fukuyama (2014) of the determinants of state capacity and commitment to national
on the crucial role of state capacity for development). While it is plans once they are developed, and to identify ways of raising both
difficult to separate the impacts of global goals from the many capacity and commitment. Making progress with the SDGs in
other factors operating on state capacity, a study by Evans (2013) many countries will depend to a large extent on the existence of
tracked the way in which the MDGs directly strengthened state credible plans, of the capacity to implement agreed plans and of
capacity in Zambia. The Minister of Health responded to regional a commitment to follow through with the plans. It is for this reason
MDG meetings at which data showed that Zambia was not making that this emergence of ‘new’ national planning must be seen as an
as much progress in reducing maternal mortality as were other opportunity for the global community to continue finding ways of
Southern African countries. Immediately afterwards he prioritised enhancing achievement of the SDGs by ensuring that there is
services for pregnant women and over time significantly improved capacity to produce credible plans.
health service delivery through better budgeting, motivation,
improved organization and staff management. Such clear examples Conflict of interest
are rare but they do point to the potential for global goals to have
an ideational impact on behaviour that strengthens both planning None.
and implementation.
Acknowledgements

9. Conclusions Work reported in this paper was done as part of the Strategic Net-
work on New National Planning-an 18 month project on funded
Our research has clearly shown that there is now a renewed glo- through a £130 585 GCRF-ESRC grant number ES/P007406/1.
bal interest in comprehensive national planning that we term the The authors would like to thank the following for their research
‘new’ national development planning. Surprisingly, this return to assistance in this project: Dr Olabimtan Adebowale, Ms Alexandra
national planning has received very limited academic or policy Garcia, Mr Gedeon Djissa, Mr Begench Yazlyyev, Ms Sarah Tal, Ms
analysis and yet it has implications for how SDGs can be opera- Mapenzie Tauzie, Dr Bala Yusuf, Dr Andrea Zinzani, Mr Pedro Lucas
tionalised and monitored within individual countries. The new Chagas Mendonca.
national planning has been stimulated by several factors: recogni-
tion that markets by themselves cannot coordinate development
Appendix A
activity and promote structural transformation; learning from
the experience of preparing PRSPs for the IFIs and concerns about
Appendix 1 and 2
the ways in which this weakened sovereignty; and the emergence
of agreements on global goals. It is important to highlight that this Appendix 1
era differs greatly from the 1950s to 70s era of national planning. It Countries whose national development plans were analysed for this paper.
sees the plan as a tool for development and not a guarantee of S/N Country Plan timeframe
development. While concepts of linear rationality inform the new
Sub-Saharan Africa
national planning, the paradigm also recognises uncertainty and 1 Angola 2013–17
contingency much more and concepts of communicative and/or 2 Benin 2011–15
collaborative planning now inform they way planning is carried 3 Botswana 2013–16
out in a majority of countries. 4 Burkina Faso 2011–15
5 Burundi 2010–25
Based on this analysis, four main observations on the ‘new’
6 Chad 2013–15
national development planning and its significance both in practice 7 Congo, DR 2011–15
and in theory can be made. First, there is little doubt that new 8 Ethiopia 2010–15
national development planning has ushered in a new era in which 9 Ghana 2014–17
10 Guinea 2013–15
plan documents are no longer an end in themselves but are seen as
11 Guinea-Bissau 2011–15
part of a process of communicating and negotiating national ideals 12 Ivory Coast 2012–15
with internal and external audiences. In an era of SDGs this shift 13 Kenya 2013–17
presents opportunities for ensuring more grounded responses to 14 Lesotho 2012–17
global ideals, especially in the SDG 16 call for more engaged state 15 Liberia 2012–17
16 Madagascar 2015–19
interaction with citizens in strategy, plans, policies and implemen-
17 Malawi 2011–16
tation. The typology introduced in this paper helps suggest which 18 Mali 2012–17
plans may be taken seriously and how far they represent elite or 19 Mauritania 2011–15
popular projects. In a way this enables local but perhaps more so 20 Mozambique 2015–35
21 Namibia 2012–17
external partners to understand ways of engaging with such docu-
22 Niger 2012–15
ments. Second, it is clear that the emergence of the ‘new’ national 23 Nigeria 2009–20
development planning has seen the return of ‘state-led develop- 24 Republic of Congo 2012–16
ment planning’ as an area where technical expertise has consider- 25 Rwanda 2013–18
able value. This has created (and is creating) new opportunities to 26 Senegal 2013–17
27 Sierra Leone 2013–18
raise state capacity, with implications for the effectiveness of the
28 Somaliland 2012–16
state, and elites, as the ‘owner’ of national development plans. 29 South Africa 2012–30
Third, our analysis suggests that, while many countries demon- 30 South Sudan 2011–13
strate an ability to better analyse, plan and monitor future activity 31 Swaziland 2013–18
32 Tanzania 2016–21
than before, the least convincing area is the way the plans will be
33 Togo 2013–17
financed. It is not clear from our analysis how far this is an issue of 34 Uganda 2015–20
low capacity to cost and finance plans, or of a more general lack of 35 Zambia 2011–16
access to finance for development. Clearly, this is an area that will 36 Zimbabwe 2013–18

(continued on next page)


88 A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89

Appendix 1 (continued) Appendix 2


Themes and variables for analysis.
S/N Country Plan timeframe
Theme Variables
Asia
37 Bangladesh 2016–20 1. Country profile Country, Region, Population
38 Bhutan 2013–18 2. Plan outlook Title of plan, Vision, Theme, Years covered,
39 Brunei 2012–17 Number of pages, Language, Duration, Total cost
40 China 2016–20 of preparing the plan, Driver of the plan, Funder,
41 India 2012–17 Preparation approach, Preparation context,
42 Laos 2011–15 Performance monitoring and evaluation
43 Malaysia 2016–20 3. Evidence base Level of evidence, Analysis assumptions,
44 Myanmar 2014 Econometric modelling
45 Pakistan 2013–18 4. Scenario snapshots Past plan achievements, Current plan goals and
46 Papua New Guinea 2008–50 targets, Planning underpinnings
47 Philippines 2011–2016 5. Strategic focus Key objectives (specific measurable targets),
48 Thailand 2012–16 Extent of integration, Order of precedence of
49 Timor Leste 2011–30 focus, Sectors targeted, Public sector reform
50 Vietnam 2015–35 agenda, Targeted public sectors for investment,
Europe and CIS Recognition of demographic groups
51 Albania 2014–20 6. Links to global agenda Climate change, Trade, Sustainable Development
52 Armenia 2014–25 Goals, Migration, Remittances, Agenda priorities
53 Azerbaijan 2013–20 (international)
54 Belarus 2015–30 7. Financing and means Estimated cost of plan, Estimated cost of plan as a
55 Bosnia & Herzegovina 2016–18 of implementation % of GDP
56 Estonia 2015–20 Expected share of domestic financing, Expected
57 Georgia 2014–20 share of government financing, Expected share of
58 Kazakhstan 2012–50 private financing, Expected share of donor/
59 Kosovo 2016–21 external financing/aid, Investment breakdown,
60 Kyrgyzstan 2013–17 Financing mechanisms, Expected role of private
61 Lithuania 2012–30 sector, Expected role of donors/aid partners,
62 Moldova 2012–20 Expected role of civil society, Implementation
63 Mongolia 2016–30 performance mechanism, Key success factors,
64 Montenegro 2013–16 Spatial/regional implementation of plan
65 Russia 2012–20 8. Key words Aid, Competitiveness, Economic growth,
66 Tajikistan 2016–30 Economic empowerment, Employment/job
67 Turkey 2014–18 creation, Empowerment, Export driven, Human
68 Turkmenistan 2011–30 capital, Capacity building, Capacity utilization,
69 Ukraine 2015–20 Inequality, Investment, Poverty reduction,
70 Uzbekistan 2017–21 Poverty eradication, Resilience, Risk reduction,
Middle East and North Africa SDGs, Sustainable Development goals, MDGs,
71 Algeria 2010–14 Millennium Development Goals, Social
72 Bahrain 2007–30 transformation, Socio-economic development,
73 Egypt 2015–30 Strategic advantage,Sustainable growth,
74 Jordan 2013–19 Sustainable development , Value addition,
75 Lebanon 2011–16 Wealth creation
76 Morocco 2015–20 9. Issues (Criteria Economic growth, Poverty rate, Poverty
77 Oman 2016–20 Judgement) reduction rate, Socioeconomic growth, Data/
78 Palestine 2014–16 Method/Evidence used, Level of assumptions,
79 Qatar 2011–16 Statistics and analysis used, Use of scenario
80 Republic of Iraq 2013–17 forecasting
81 Saudi Arabia 2015–19 10. Plan orientation Technocratic
82 Tunisia 2016–20 Transformational
83 UAE 2015–21
Latin America
84 Argentina 2012–16
85 Barbados 2013–20 Appendix B. Supplementary data
86 Belize 2010–30
87 Bolivia 2016–20 Supplementary data to this article can be found online at
88 Brazil 2016–19
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2019.03.013.
89 Chile 2014–18
90 Colombia 2014–18
91 Costa Rica 2015–18
92 Dominica 2014–18
93 Ecuador 2013–17
References
94 El Salvador 2014–19
95 Guatemala 2014–32 Agarwala, R. (1983). Planning in developing countries: lessons of experience. World
Bank staff working paper 576. Washington, DC: World Bank.
96 Guyana 2011–14
Allmendinger, P. (2017). Planning theory. London: Palgrave.
97 Haiti 2014–16
Arrow, K. (1963). Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. American
98 Honduras 2014–18
Economic Review, LIII, 941–973.
99 Jamaica 2009–30 Baran, P. A. (1962). The political economy of economic growth. New York: Monthly
100 Mexico 2013–18 Review Press.
101 Nicaragua 2012–16 Barr, N. (1992). Economic theory and the welfare state: A survey and interpretation.
102 Panama 2015–19 Journal of Economic Literature, XXX, 741–803.
103 Paraguay 2014–30 Bates, R. H. (1995). Social dilemmas and rational individuals. In J. Harris, J. Hunter, &
104 Peru 2011–21 C. M. Lewis (Eds.), The new institutional economics and third world development.
105 St Vincent and the Grenadines 2013–25 London: Routledge.
106 Trinidad and Tobago 2011–14 Bauer, P. (1982). Equality, the third world and economic delusion. London: Methuen.
107 Venezuela 2013–19 Bhagwati, J. N. (1982). Directly unproductive, profit-seeking (DUP) activities. Journal
of Political Economy, 90, 988–1002.
A.O. Chimhowu et al. / World Development 120 (2019) 76–89 89

Blitzer, C. R., Clark, P. B., & Taylor, L. (Eds.). (1975). Economy-wide models and Innes, J. E., & Booher, D. E. (2010). Planning with complexity: An introduction to
development planning. New York: Oxford University Press/World Bank. collaborative rationality for public policy. London: Routledge.
Caiden, N., & Wildavsky, A. (1974). Planning and budgeting in poor countries. New Johnston, B., & Clark, W. (1982). Redesigning rural development. Baltimore, MD:
York: Wiley. Johns Hopkins University Press.
Chenery, H. B., & Strout, A. M. (1966). Foreign assistance and economic Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
development. American Economic Review, 56, 679–733. Keynes, J. M. (1931). Essays in Persuasion. New York: W.W. Norton.
Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44. Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest and money. New
Colander, D., & Kupers, R. (2014). Complexity and the art of public policy. Princeton, York: Harcourt.
NJ: Princeton University Press. Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American
Collier, D. (2011). Understanding process tracing. PS Political Science & Politics, 44(4), Economic Review, 64, 291–303.
823–830. Krueger, A. O. (1990). Government failures in development. Journal of Economic
Drèze, J., & Sen, A. (1989). Political economy of hunger. Oxford: Clarendon. Perspectives, 4, 9–23.
Driscoll, R., & Evans, A. (2005). Second-generation poverty reduction strategies: Mallaby, S. (2004). The world’s banker: A story of failed states, financial crises, and the
New opportunities and emerging issues. Development Policy Review, 23, 5–25. wealth and poverty of nations. New York: Penguin Books.
Dunn, W. N. (2017). Public policy analysis: An integrated approach. London: Meier, G.M. (1964–2005). Leading Issues in Economic Development. Eight edns.
Routledge. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Earl, S., Carden, F., & Smutylo, T. (2001). Outcome mapping. Ottawa: IDRC. Munro, L.T. (2017). ‘The resurgence of national development planning: how did we
Evans, A. (2013). ‘Lessons from the Effective Promotion of Safe Motherhood in get back here?’ Paper presented at the International Studies Association, San
Zambia’. http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/africaatlse/files/2012/10/Lessons-from-the- Francisco, April 7.
effective-promotion-of-safe-motherhood-in-Zambia-Alice-Evans-Working- North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance.
Paper.pdf. Accessed 6 March 2019. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Faber, M., & Seers, D. (Eds.). (1972). The crisis in planning. London: Chatto & Windus. Nurkse, R. (1955). Problems of capital formation in underdeveloped countries. New
Fainstein, S. S. (2000). New directions in planning theory. Urban Affairs Review, 35, York: OUP.
451–478. Polanyi, K. (1957). The great transformation. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.
Fukuda-Parr, S., & Hulme, D. (2011). International norm dynamics and the ‘‘end of Polanyi-Levitt, K. (2013). From the great transformation to the great financialization:
poverty”: understanding the Millennium Development Goals. Global On Karl Polanyi and other essays. London: Zed Books.
Governance: A Review of Multilateralism and International Organizations, 17, Ramalingam, B. (2013). Aid on the edge of chaos. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
17–36. Robinson, J. (1933). The economics of imperfect competition. London: Macmillan.
Fukuyama, F. (2014). States and democracy. Democratization, 21, 1326–1340. Rodrik, D. (2011). The globalization paradox. New York: Norton.
Forester, J. (1999). Reflections on the future understanding of planning practice. Rosenstein-Rodan, P. N. (1943). Problems of industrialisation of eastern and south-
International Planning Studies, 4, 175–193. eastern Europe. Economic Journal, 53(210/211), 202–211.
Habermas, J. (1987). The theory of communicative action: Lifeworld and system – A Sager, T. (2002). Deliberative planning and decision making: An impossibility result.
critique of functionalist reason (Vol. 2) Boston, MA: Beacon. Journal of Planning Education and Research, 21, 367–378.
Healey, P. (1992). Planning through debate: The communicative turn in planning Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics
theory. Town Planning Review, 63, 143. and Statistics, 36, 387–389.
Healey, P. (2010). Making better places: The planning project in the twenty-first Swanson, D., & Bhadwal, S. (2009). Creating adaptive policies. New Delhi: Sage.
century. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2009). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth
Hickey, S., Sen, K., & Bukenya, B. (Eds.). (2015). The politics of inclusive development. and happiness. New York: Penguin.
Oxford: OUP. Todaro, M.P. (1978–2015). Economic Development. 12 ed. London: Pearson.
Hillier, J. (1993). To boldly go where no planners have ever. . .. Environment and Waterston, A. (1965). Development planning, lessons of experience. Baltimore: Johns
Planning D: Society and Space, 11, 89–113. Hopkins University Press.
Hsieh, H., & Shannon, S. E. (2005). Three approaches to qualitative content analysis. World Bank (1983). World development report 1983. Oxford: Oxford University
Qualitative Health Research, 15, 1277–1288. Press.
Hulme, D. (2007). A brief history of the world’s biggest promise. Brooks world World Bank (2007). Results-based national development strategies: Assessment and
poverty institute working paper 100. Manchester: Brooks World Poverty challenges ahead. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Institute. World Bank (2001). ‘What is CDF?’ Downloaded on 25/7/2017 from http://
Hulme, D. (2010). Global poverty (1st ed.). London: Routledge. www.worldbank.org/en/webarchives/archive?url=http%3A%2F%
Hulme, D. (2015). Global poverty (2nd ed.). London: Routledge. 2Fweb.worldbank.org%2Farchive%2Fwebsite01013%2FWEB%2F0__CON-3.
Hummelbrunner, R., & Jones, H. (2013). A guide for planning and strategy HTM&mdk=22201409.
development in the face of complexity. London: Overseas Development Institute. Yazlyyev, B. (2017). ‘National development planning in the Former Soviet Union’.
IMF (2016). Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers (PRSPs). December, 28. http://www. Paper presented at the Canadian Association for the Study of International
imf.org/external/np/prsp/prsp.aspx. (Accessed on 6 March 2019.) Development, Toronto, June 2.

You might also like