You are on page 1of 25

2.

Portfolio Theory

Objectives:
Understanding of
• Return and risk of assets
• Return and risk of portfolios
• Efficient and optimal portfolios
• Market portfolio

Concepts:
• Perfect and perfect inverse correlated asset returns
• Covariance risk
• Mean-variance curve
• Mean variance frontier
• Capital market line

Contents:
2.1 Returns and Risks of Assets
2.2 Returns and Risks of Portfolios of Two Risky Assets
2.3 Portfolios of Many Risky Assets
2.4 Portfolios of Risk-free and Risky Assets
2.5 Efficient and Optimal Portfolios

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 18


2.1 Return and Risk of Assets
2.1.1 Rate of Return on Risky Assets
By assumption there are two assets X and Y, with the present values X , Y , the future values X
and Y and the random rate of returns
X − X , and Y − Y .
rX = rY =
X Y

Future values include future prices and all (intra-period) payments, such as dividends or
coupons. All statements and results apply to portfolios and their returns as well.

2.1.2 (Expected) Return and Risk of Assets


As a measure of the return of an asset X we use the expected value of the rate of return
( )
µ X ≡ E rX .

The variance and the standard deviation of the rate of returns serve as a measure of the risk of the
asset X:

( ) {
σ XX ≡ Var rX = E ⎡⎣ rX − E rX ⎤⎦ ( )
2

}
( )
σ X ≡ SD rX = Var rX ( )
These moments can be used for asset Y respectively.

2.1.3 Covariance of the Rate of Returns of Two Risky Assets


The covariance, σ XY , measures how the asset returns rX and rY move with each other:

( ) { ( )
σ XY ≡ Cov rX ,rY = E ⎡⎣ rX − E rX ⎤⎦ ⎡⎣ rY − E rY ⎤⎦( )}
Obviously the covariance of a random variable with itself is equal to its variance.

Instead of the covariance we use sometimes the correlation coefficient of the asset returns
σ XY
(
κ XY ≡ CC rX ,rY ≡) σ XσY .

The correlation coefficient is normalized to the interval [−1,1] . Depending on the covariance of
the returns the correlation coefficient takes the following values:
1. κ XY = +1 , i.e. the returns of two assets are perfectly correlated.

2. κ XY = −1 , i.e. the returns are perfectly inverse correlated.

3. −1 < κ XY < 1 , is the realistic range of the correlation coefficient.

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 19


2.2 Returns and Risks of a Portfolio of Two Risky Assets

2.2.1 Specification of the Portfolios


We form a portfolio P consisting a percent of the asset X and 1-a percent of the asset Y. (All
statements and results apply to portfolios of portfolios X and Y as well.) All results are based on
the properties of linear transformations of random variables. (For details see Appendix B).

Characterization of the assets


We assume that X has a higher return than Y and that X is riskier than Y:
( ) ( )
E rX > E rY > 0 (2.1)

Var ( r ) > Var ( r ) > 0


X Y
(2.2)

2.2.2 Return and risks of the portfolio

The rate of return of the portfolio P is a weighted average of the returns of the assets X and Y
( )
rP = arX + 1 − a rY .

Return of the portfolio


The (expected) return of the portfolio is defined the expectation of the rate of return of the
portfolio or the weighted returns of the assets:

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
µ P = E rP = E ⎡⎣ arX + 1 − a rY ⎤⎦ = aE rX + 1 − a E rY = aµ X + 1 − a µY ( ) (2.3)

Risk of the portfolio


The risk of a portfolio is measured by the variance or the standard deviation of the rate of return
of the portfolios:

{
σ PP = E ⎡ rP − E rP ⎤
⎣ ⎦ ( )
2

} ⎧
⎩ ⎣ ( ) ( (⎦
2
= E ⎨ ⎡ arX + 1 − a rY − E arX + 1 − a rY ⎤ ⎬


) )

{ ( )
2
( )
2
( )
2
( ) ( )
= E a 2 ⎡⎣ rX − E rX ⎤⎦ + 1 − a ⎡⎣ rY − E rY ⎤⎦ +2a 1 − a ⎡⎣ rX − E rX ⎤⎦ ⎡⎣ rY − E rY ⎤⎦ ( )}
( ) ( )
2
= a 2σ XX + 1 − a σ YY + 2a 1 − a σ XY

( ) ( )
2
= a 2σ XX + 1 − a σ YY + 2a 1 − a κ XY σ X σ Y (2.4)

Obviously the risk of the portfolio return is non-linear in the portfolio weights. Moreover, it
depends on the second order moments of the asset returns.

By definition, the standard deviation of the portfolio return amounts to

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 20


( ) ( )
2
σ P = a 2σ XX + 1 − a σ YY + 2a 1 − a κ XY σ X σ Y . (2.5)

2.2.3 Impact of the composition on the return and the risk of a portfolio
We investigate how an increase of the weight a influences the return and the risk of the portfolio.

Impact of the portfolio composition on the portfolio return


d µP
= µ X − µY > 0 (2.6)
da
The return increases proportionally to a:

+#

+"

+!

$ % &

Fig 2.1: Return of a portfolio of two assets

For a < 0 , the return of the portfolio is smaller than µY , for a > 1, greater than µ X .

Impact of the portfolio composition on the portfolio risk


dσ PP
da
( ) (
= 2aσ XX − 2 1 − a σ YY + 2 1 − 2a κ XY σ X σ Y ) (2.7)

or
dσ P 1 ⎡ 2 −1 2

( )
= a σ XX + 1 − a σ YY + 2a 1 − a κ XY σ X σ Y ⎤ ( )
2
(2.8)
da 2 ⎣⎢ ⎦⎥
( )
⋅ ⎡⎣ 2aσ XX − 2 1 − a σ YY + 2 1 − 2a κ XY σ X σ Y ⎤⎦ ( )
Obviously, the sign of the change of the risk of the portfolio depends on the covariance or the
correlation coefficient of the asset returns.
Sometimes it is useful to know the risk minimal portfolio. It can be derived from the first order
condition
dσ PP
da
( ) (
= 2aσ XX − 2 1 − a σ YY + 2 1 − 2a κ XY σ X σ Y = 0 , ) (2.9)

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 21


Since the radicand in the first line of (2.8) is not zero, the first order condition applies to the
second line of (2.8). From (2.9) follows the risk minimizing portfolio weight a* is

a* =
σ YY − κ XY σ X σ Y
=
σ Y σ Y − κ XY σ X (.
) (2.10)
σ XX + σ YY − 2κ XY σ X σ Y σ XX + σ YY − 2κ XY σ X σ Y

It is obvious that a* depends on the covariance or the correlation coefficient of the asset returns.
In order to discuss the shape of the curves (2.7) 0r (2.8) we distinguish three cases:
Case A: κ XY = 1 , i.e. perfectly correlated assets

Case B: κ XY = −1 , i.e. perfectly inverse correlated assets

Case C: −1 < κ XY < 1 , normal case

For didactical reasons we start with both extreme cases.

2.2.3.1 Case A: κ XY = 1

As the portfolio return is independent from the correlation of the assets return equations (2.3)
and (2.6) remain unchanged. Only the risk (variance and standard deviation) of the portfolio is
affected by the correlation coefficient.

Risk of the portfolio


For perfectly correlated assets the portfolio variance in equation (2.4) reduces to

( ) ( )
2
σ PP = a 2σ XX + 1 − a σ YY + 2a 1 − a σ X σ Y (2.11)

[
= aσ X + (1 − a )σ Y . ]
2

As long as we a ≥ 0 assume the expression in the squared bracket is positive, we would not be
short in X and thus the portfolio would be located North East of Y. In this case the standard
( )
deviation would be σ P = aσ X + 1 − a σ Y > 0 . In case of a sufficiently small a < 0 ,
( )
aσ X + 1 − a σ Y may become negative, and therefore, the standard deviation of the portfolio is
to be defined more generally as

(
σ P = aσ X + 1 − a σ Y ≥ 0 . ) (2.12)
From (2.12) we can derive the impact of the composition of the portfolio on its risk as

dσ P σY
da
(
= ± σ X − σY ≥ ≤ 0 ) () ⇔ a≥ ≤ − () σ X − σY .
(2.13)

The derivative is a constant with a alternating sign since it is σ X − σ Y > 0 if the weight of the
asset X is greater than the critical value, a > − σ Y (σ X ) ( )
− σ Y , and it is − σ X − σ Y < 0 if
a < −σY (σ X )
− σ Y . Obviously the critical value is itself negative.

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 22


Slope of the Mean Variance Curve
If we divide equation (2.6) by equation (2.13) we receive the slope of the so-called Mean
Variance Curve (MVC). This curve is also referred to as µ − σ curve. The slope of this curve tells
us how the Mean of the portfolio return changes if we change the risk of the portfolio by a small
change of a:
d µ P d µ P / da µ − µY σY
=
dσ P dσ P / da
=± X
σ X − σY
≥ ≤ 0 () ⇔ a≥ ≤ − () σ X − σY .
(2.14)

From equation (2.6) we know that the nominator of (2.14) is positive and constant. Thus, the
slope of the MVC must be a constant with an alternating sign. We can deduce from (2.13) and
(2.14)
⎛ dµ ⎞ ⎛ dσ P ⎞
sign ⎜ P ⎟ = sign ⎜ ⎟. (2.15)
⎝ dσ P ⎠ ⎝ da ⎠

Taking this into account we can distinguish different slopes in three different parts of the MVC:
σY d µ P µ X − µY
1. a > −
σ X − σY
⇒ (
σ P = aσ X + 1 − a σ Y > 0 ) ⇒ =
dσ P σ X − σ Y
>0

σY
2. a = −
σ X − σY
⇔ (
σ P = aσ X + 1 − a σ Y = 0 ) (2.16)

σY d µP µ − µY
3. a < −
σ X − σY
<0 ⇒ ( (
σ P = − aσ X + 1 − a σ Y > 0 ⇒ ) ) dσ P
=− X
σ X − σY
<0

The standard deviation and the MVC of this type are illustrated in the following graphs:

m# +#
! !
m! +!

m" "
" +"

$ % & $ m" m! m#

Fig 2.2a: STDV of a portfolio of perfectly corr. assets Fig 2.2b: MVC of a portfolio. of perfectly corr. assets

In the first range a > − σ Y (σ X )


− σ Y , the standard deviation and the MVC are increasing
straight lines, and in the third range a < − σ Y (σ X )
− σ Y decreasing straight lines.

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 23


The critical value a = − σ Y (σ X )
− σ Y creates the risk minimal portfolio, where the derivative of
the standard deviation curve and the MVC are not defined. We can confirm this by the first order
condition (2.10) for a risk minimizing portfolio weight a* if we respect κ XY = 1 :

a* =
σ YY − κ XY σ X σ Y
=
σ YY − σ X σ Y
=
−σ Y σ X − σ Y
=−
σY
< 0.
( ) (2.17)
σ XX + σ YY − 2κ XY σ X σ Y σ XX + σ YY − 2σ X σ Y (
σ X − σY )
2
σ X − σY

The risk of this portfolio equals zero since

σP = −
σY ⎛
σ X + ⎜1+
σY ⎞ σ σ
σY = − Y X + X
σ − σY + σY σY
=0.
( )
σ X − σY ⎟
σ X − σY ⎠ σ X − σY σ X − σY
(2.18)

We should keep in mind that the risk minimal portfolio is reached for an a* < 0 , i.e. a short
position in X. Such a portfolio generates negative (expected) returns. It is in any case inefficient.

2.2.3.2 Case B: κ XY = −1

Equations (2.3) and (2.6) remain unchanged. Only the portfolio risk is influenced by the
correlation coefficient.

Risk of the portfolio


For perfectly inverse correlated assets return the variance of the portfolio returns in equation
(2.4) simplifies to

( ) ( )
2
σ PP = a 2σ XX + 1 − a σ YY − 2a 1 − a σ X σ Y (2.19)

[
= aσ X − (1 − a )σ Y . ]
2

As the expression in the squared bracket may be negative, the standard deviation is defined as

( )
σ P = aσ X − 1 − a σ Y ≥ 0 . (2.20)
From (2.20) we can derive the impact of the portfolio composition on the risk of the portfolio as

dσ P σY
da
(
= ± σ X + σY ≥ ≤ 0 ) () ⇔ a≥ ≤ ( )σ + σY
. (2.21)
X

Again the derivative is constant with alternating sign. If a > σ Y (σ X )


+ σ Y the derivative is
positive, if a < σ Y (σ X )
+ σ Y the derivative is negative. At the critical value a = σ Y (σ X
+ σY )
the derivative is undefined.

Slope of the Mean Variance Curve

Dividing (2.6) by (2.21) yields the slope of the MVC:

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 24


d µ P d µ P / da µ − µY σY
=
dσ P dσ P / da
=± X
σ X + σY
≥ ≤ 0 () ⇔ ( )σ
a≥ ≤
+ σY
(2.22)
X

Again the nominator is positive. Thus the sign of the slope depends on the sign of (2.21). From
(2.21) and (2.22) follows
⎛ dµ ⎞ ⎛ dσ P ⎞
sign ⎜ P ⎟ = sign ⎜ ⎟. (2.23)
⎝ dσ P ⎠ ⎝ da ⎠

Moreover, the nominator and the denominator in (2.22) are constant. With these insights we can
distinguish three different ranges of the MVC:
σY d µ P µ X − µY
1. a >
σ X + σY
⇒ (
σ P = aσ X − 1 − a σ Y > 0 ) ⇒ =
dσ P σ X + σ Y
>0

σY
2. a =
σ X + σY
⇔ (
σ P = aσ X − 1 − a σ Y = 0 ) (2.24)

σY d µP µ − µY
3. a <
σ X + σY
⇒ ( (
σ P = − aσ X − 1 − a σ Y > 0 ⇒ ) ) dσ P
=− X
σ X + σY
<0

The standard deviation and the MVC are illustrated by the subsequent graphs:

m# +#
! !
m! +!

%&
m" "
" +"

$ % & $ m" m! m#

Fig 2.3a: STDV of a portfolio of perf. inverse corr. assets Fig 2.3b: MVC of a portfolio of perf. inverse corr. assets

In the first range a > σ Y (σ X )


+ σ Y the standard deviation and MVC are increasing straight
lines, and in the third range a < σ Y (σ X )
+ σ Y a decreasing straight lines. For the critical value
a = σY (σ X )
+ σ Y we receive the risk minimal portfolio. Again we can confirm this if we insert
κ XY = −1 into the first order condition (2.10) for the risk minimal portfolio a*:

a* =
σ YY − κ XY σ X σ Y
=
σ YY + σ X σ Y σ σ + σY
= Y X =
σY
>0.
( )
(2.25)
σ XX + σ YY − 2κ XY σ X σ Y σ XX + σ YY + 2σ X σ Y σ + σ ( )
2
σ +σ X Y
X Y

The risk of this portfolio equals zero since

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 25


σP =
σY ⎛
σ X − ⎜1−
σY ⎞
σY =
σ Yσ X σ + σY − σY σY
− X
(
=0.
) (2.26)
σ X + σY ⎟
σ X + σY ⎠ σ X + σY σ X + σY

( )
The risk minimal a* lies in the interval 0,1 . For a = 1 any (small) increase of a leads to a
proportional increase of the expected return and the risk as well. For a = 0 a small increase of a
causes an increase of the expected return and a decrease of the risk. Obviously, and we will
discuss this later in detail this portfolio is inefficient.

2.2.3.3 Case C: −1 < κ XY < 1

Equation (2.6) remains unchanged. However, the analysis of the influence of the portfolio
composition is more complex and complicated than the two previous cases. It is recommended to
start with a local analysis of the standard deviation and changes of the portfolio composition on
the standard deviation at a = 1 and a = 0 .

For a = 1 the portfolio consists only of X, and therefore the standard deviation of the portfolio
equals the standard deviation of X. In order to determine the impact of a change of the portfolio
composition on the standard deviation we have to evaluate (2.8) for a = 1 :
dσ P 1
= ⎡ 2σ − 2κ XY σ X σ Y ⎤⎦ = ⎡⎣σ X − κ XY σ Y ⎤⎦ > 0 (2.27)
da a=1
2σ X ⎣ XX

The risk of the portfolio increases with an increasing a.


For a = 0 the portfolio consists only of Y, and therefore the standard deviation equals the
standard deviation of Y. Moreover, we evaluate (2.8) for a = 0 in order to investigate the local
impact of a on the standard deviation.
dσ P 1
= ⎡ −2σ YY + 2κ XY σ X σ Y ⎤⎦ = − ⎡⎣σ Y − κ XY σ X ⎤⎦ (2.28)
da a=0
2σ Y ⎣

The sign of the reaction of the standard deviation on an increase of a depends on the size of the
two terms in the squared brackets. It depends on the size of the standard deviations of X and Y
and the correlation of the returns of the assets.
If the correlation coefficient is sufficiently close to 1, the difference in the brackets is negative,
and thus the derivative in (2.8) is positive. If on the contrary, the correlation coefficient is
sufficiently low the difference in the bracket is positive, and the derivative is negative.
However, it turns out that we can determine these relations more precisely. Therefore, it is
convenient to search for the portfolio composition a, which minimizes the standard deviation.
The risk minimizing a must satisfy the first order condition (2.9)
dσ P
da
( ) ( )
= ⎡⎣ 2aσ XX − 2 1 − a σ YY + 2 1 − 2a κ XY σ X σ Y ⎤⎦ = 0 . (2.9)

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 26


From (2.10) we have the value of the risk minimizing a* as

a* =
σ YY − κ XY σ X σ Y
=
(
σ Y σ Y − κ XY σ X ) (2.10)
σ XX + σ YY − 2κ XY σ X σ Y σ XX + σ YY − 2κ XY σ X σ Y .

The denominator of the fraction is positive because of

( )
2
σ XX + σ YY − 2κ XY σ X σ Y > σ XX + σ YY − 2σ X σ Y = σ X − σ Y >0. (2.29)

The sign of the risk minimizing a* is the same as the sign of the nominator. A comparison of the
equations (2.28) and (2.10) shows
⎛ dσ P ⎞
sign ⎜
⎝ da
a=0 ⎟

( )
= −sign a* . (2.30)

Thus we can conclude from these equations:


dσ P
1. σ Y < σ X κ XY ⇒ a=0
>0 ∧ a* < 0
da
dσ P
2. σ Y = σ X κ XY ⇒ a=0
=0 ∧ a* = 0 (2.31)
da
dσ P
3. σ Y > σ X κ XY ⇒ a=0
<0 ∧ 0 < a* < 1
da

Three possible shapes of the standard deviation are illustrated in the subsequent graphs:

m" m" m"


! ! !
m! m! m!

m#
m# m# #
# #

! $ ! $ ! $

Fig 2.4: Three possible shapes of the standard deviation curves of portfolios of two assets

Slope of the Mean Variance Curve

Dividing equation (2.6) by (2.8) results the slope of the MVC as


12

( ) ( )
⎡⎣ µ X − µY ⎤⎦ ⎡ a 2σ XX + 1 − a σ YY + 2a 1 − a κ XY σ X σ Y ⎤
2

d µ P d µ P da ⎢⎣ ⎥⎦
= = . (2.32)
dσ P dσ P da
⎣ (
⎡ aσ XX − 1 − a σ YY ) + (1 − 2a )κ σ σXY X

Y⎦

The nominator in (2.32) is positive since both factors are positive. Thus, the sign of the
derivative (slope of the MVC) in (2.32) is equal to the sign of the denominator.

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 27


From the curve sketched in (2.31) we can conclude derive three possible shapes of the MVC:
1. σ Y < κ XY σ X The MVC has a positive finite slope for all a ≥ 0 .

2. σ Y = κ XY σ X The MVC is vertical at a = 0 . The slope is positive for a > 0 ,


and negative for a < 0 .
3. σ Y > κ XY σ X The MVC is increasing in the neighborhood of a = 1 and decreasing
in the neighborhood of a = 0 .
Three possible shapes of the MVC are presented in the graphs below:

+# +# +# !
! !
+! +! +!

"
+" " +" " +"

! m" m! m# ! ! m" m! m#

Fig 2.5: Three possible shapes of the MVCs of portfolios of two assets

2.3 Portfolios of Many Risky Assets


We generalize the analysis to multiple assets and the market as a whole. This can be done easily
by the utilization of simple vector representation of the mean and the variance.

2.3.1 Return and Risk of the Portfolio


In a matrix presentation the return (2.3) and the risk (2.4) of a portfolio of two risky assets can be
written as:
⎡µ ⎤ (2.33)
µ P = ⎡⎣ a 1 − a ⎤⎦ ⎢ X ⎥
⎢⎣ µY ⎥⎦

⎡σ σ YX ⎤ ⎡ a ⎤ (2.34)
σ PP = ⎡⎣ a 1 − a ⎤⎦ ⎢ XX ⎥⎢ ⎥
⎢⎣ σ XY σ YY ⎥⎦ ⎣1 − a ⎦

Following this idea we can calculate easily the return and risk of a portfolio of n = 1,…,N risky
assets. In order to do this we have to introduce some useful notations. The returns of assets can
T
be presented by a N-dimensional vector of random variables, r = ⎡⎣ r1 r2 …rN ⎤⎦ , the expected
T T
returns by the vector, µ = ⎡⎣ µ1 µ2 … µ N ⎤⎦ , and a portfolio X by the vector x = ⎡⎣ x1 x2 …x N ⎤⎦ .
Usually portfolios are defined to satisfy x T e = 1 .

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 28


The pairwise covariance of the returns of different assets can be collected in a covariance matrix
∑ . The covariance of a random variable with itself equals the variance of the random variable.
Moreover, we should keep in mind that the covariance matrix is symmetric.

⎡ σ 11 σ 12  σ 1N ⎤
⎢ ⎥
⎢ σ 21 σ 22  σ 2 N ⎥
∑=⎢
   ⎥
⎢ ⎥
⎢⎣σ N 1 σ N 2  σ NN ⎥⎦

Return and Risk of a Portfolio


The rate of return of the portfolio can expressed as:
rX ≡ x T r (2.35)

The return of a portfolio X, denoted as µ X and its risk, denoted as σ XX can be expressed as:

( )
µ X ≡ E rX = x T µ (2.36)

σ XX ≡ Var ( r ) = x
X
T
∑x (2.37)

Covariance of the Returns of Two Portfolios X and Y


The covariance of the returns of the portfolios can be expressed as
( )
σ XY ≡ Cov rX ,rY = x T ∑ y = y T ∑ x . (2.38)

2.3.2 Concept of Mean Variance Frontier


The Mean Variance Frontier (MVF) is the envelope of all feasible risk return combinations
available by portfolios of elementary assets. The MVF is thus the convex hull of all possible
portfolios and all possible MVCs.

We will present two different ways to construct the MVF. The first one uses some tangential
properties of the MVF. This method is easy to apply. The disadvantage is that the method can’t
be applied straightforward in case of short sale restrictions. The second one uses quadratic
programming. This method is easy to understand, but it needs some calculation effort.

A third method uses an orthogonal decomposition. We will not discuss this method in this
lecture since it needs some more mathematical exposition.

2.3.3 Construction via the Tangential Property

The MVF will be constructed in two steps. At first we construct two elements of the MVF. At
second we will span the entire MVF from these two points.

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 29


2.3.3.1 Construction of Elements of the MVF
We define cX as an arbitrary constant associated with an envelope portfolio X. Moreover we
define e as a N-dimensional unit vector. The vector z X is the solution of the equation
µ − cX e = ∑ z X . (2.39)

As we will see the vector z X has already the composition of a MVF portfolio. However, it is not a
well-defined portfolio in the sense that the portfolio weights add up to one. Therefore, it has to
be normalized.

Theorem 1: Construction of an element of the MVF


A MVF portfolio has to satisfy both of the following conditions:

i) (
z X = ∑ −1 µ − c X e ) (2.40)

z Xi z Xi
ii) xi = N
= (2.41)
zXT e
∑z Xj
j=1

(2.40) we receive by pre-multiplying (2.39) by the inverse covariance matrix. The product eT z X
in (2.41) sums all elements of the vector z X . Therefore x is a normalization of z X to one.

Proof:
• A MVF portfolio has to lie on a tangent line to MVF running through a corresponding point
c X of the ordinate.

• Any tangential portfolio maximizes or minimizes the risk premium per unit of risk of the
portfolio. In other words λ has to attain an extreme value (maximum or minimum):

λ=
(
xT µ − cX e ) = x ( µ − c e)
T
X
(2.42)
σ XX x ∑x
T

The first order condition for such an optimal portfolio is


( µ − c e ) − 2 ∑ xλ = 0 .
X
(2.43)

In order to understand this we form in a first step the first order condition of λ with respect to
an arbitrary portfolio weight xh :

=
T T
( T
)
∂λ x ∑ x ∂ ⎡⎣ x µ − c X e ⎤⎦ ∂xh − ⎡⎣ x µ − c X e ⎤⎦ ∂ x ∑ x ∂xh
T

=0.
( ) ( ) (2.44)
∂xh
( )
2
xT ∑ x

As the denominator is not (and must not be) equal to zero the nominator has to be equal to
zero and therefore the first order condition (2.44) can be expressed as

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 30


(
⎡ xT µ − cX e ⎤ )
⎡ T
( ⎤ )
∂ ⎣ x µ − c X e ⎦ ∂xh − ⎣
x ∑x
T ( h )
⎦ ∂ x T ∑ x ∂x = 0. (2.45)

If we substitute the fraction in the second expression by λ and express the matrix products in
a more detailed way the first order condition can be rewritten as:

( ) ( ) ( ) (
∂ ⎡⎣ x1 µ1 − c X + x2 µ2 − c X …+ xh µ h − c X +…+ x N µ N − c X ⎤⎦ ∂xh )
− λ∂ ⎡⎣ x12σ 11 + x2 2σ 22 +…+ xh 2σ hh +…+ x N 2σ NN + (2.46)
+2x1 x2σ 12 +…+ 2x1 xhσ 1h +…+ 2x2 xhσ 2h +…+ 2x N xhσ Nh +…⎤⎦ ∂xh = 0

The derivation in (2.45) results the following first order condition for an arbitrary optimal
portfolio weight xh :

(µ h )
− c X − 2 ∑ h xλ = 0 (2.47)

In (2.47) µ h and ∑ h represent the lines h of µ and ∑ . If we apply this procedure to all assets
of the portfolio we receive a first order conditions for an optimal portfolio as in (2.43).
• The second order condition corresponding to (2.47) is

( )
∂ ⎡⎣ µ h − c X − 2 ∑ h xλ ⎤⎦ ∂ xh = −2σ hh λ (2.48)

If λ > 0 , the extremum is a maximum, if λ < 0 , it is a minimum. λ > 0 , implies


( ) ( )
x T µ − c X e > 0 (ascending tangent), and λ < 0 , implies x T µ − c X e < 0 (descending
tangent).
• Substituting 2λ x by z X and normalizing z X to one shows that any MVF portfolio that
maximizes or minimizes λ must fulfill the conditions (2.40) and (2.41).

2.3.3.2 Spanning of the MVF


All elements of the MVF can be constructed by the method of the above paragraph. Moreover,
the entire MVF can be spanned as a convex combination of two arbitrary elements of the MVF.

Theorem 2: Spanning of the MVF


The MVF can be spanned by a convex combination of two arbitrary elements of the MVF.
Proof:
• If the vectors x and y contain the weights of two MVF portfolios X and Y, it follows from
theorem 1 that there are vectors z X and zY and (vectors of) constants cX and cY that satisfy
the conditions (2.49a) - (2.50b):
zX
x= (2.49a)
zXT e

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 31


zY
y= (2.49b)
zY T e

( µ − c e) − ∑ z
X X
=0 (2.50a)

( µ − c e) − ∑ z
Y Y
=0 (2.50b)

• For any real number a, there is a constant cP = acX + (1 − a )cY and a portfolio P with the
composition zP = az X + (1 − a ) zY such that a is a solution of the equation (2.51):

( ) ( )
µ − cP e − ∑ z P = µ − ⎡⎣ acx + 1 − a c y ⎤⎦ e − ∑ ⎡⎣ az x + 1 − a z y ⎤⎦ = 0 (2.51)

• From this follows theorem 2.


The computation of the MVF by the spanning method is superior to the method we apply in the
next subsection 2.3.4 because solving of linear equations is much easier than solving quadratic
programs. However, the spanning method demands the absence of short sales restrictions.
Moreover, the latter gives some additional insights into portfolio theory.

2.3.4 Solution of a Quadratic Program


This method can also be applied in case of short sales. However, in that case we have to consider
the non-negativity constraint x ≥ 0 . In a first step we construct a single portfolio of the MVF,
and in a second step we construct the overall risk minimum portfolio, and in a third step we
develop the MVF.

2.3.4.1 Construction of a MVF Portfolio


Any portfolio of the MVF can be found as the solution of the following quadratic program:
Min Var rX
x
( ) ( )
s. t. E rX = µ X for all µ X ≥ 0 I

+#

&
%
$

"
m#

Fig 2.6: The MVF of many risky assets

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 32


The program can be written in the following way:
Min x T ∑ x
x

s.t. 1 = xT e (2.52)
µ X = xT µ (2.53)

In order to calculate an element of the MVF we minimize the variance of a portfolio which
assures a given expected portfolio return µ X .

In order to find a solution to the optimization problem we optimize the Lagrange function:

( ) (
L = xT ∑ x + λ 1 − xT e + ξ µ X − xT µ
x ,λ ,ξ
)
The solution has to satisfy the following first order conditions:
Lx = 2 ∑ x − λ e − ξµ = 0 (2.54a)

Lλ = 1 − x T e = 0 (2.54b)

Lξ = µ X − x T µ = 0 (2.54c)

If we pre-multiply (2.54a) by the inverse of the covariance matrix we receive


2 ∑ −1 ∑ x = λ ∑ −1 e + ξ ∑ −1 µ , (2.54’)

or
λ −1 ξ
x= ∑ e + ∑ −1 µ . (2.54’’)
2 2

Inserting (2.54’’) into (2.54b) and (2.54c) results


λ T −1 ξ
1 = xT e = e ∑ e + µ T ∑ −1 e (2.55a)
2 2
λ T −1 ξ
µ X = xT µ = e ∑ µ + µ T ∑ −1 µ (2.55b)
2 2
Equations (2.55a) and (2.55b) form a simultaneous equation system in the variables λ 2 and
ξ 2 that can expressed by the following matrix equation:

⎡ eT ∑ −1 e µ T ∑ −1 e ⎤ ⎡ λ 2 ⎤ ⎡ 1 ⎤
⎢ T −1 ⎥⎢ ⎥=⎢ ⎥ (2.56)
⎣e ∑ µ µ T ∑ −1 µ ⎦ ⎣ξ 2 ⎦ ⎣ µ X ⎦

Applying Cramer’s Rule yields the following solutions:


λ µ T ∑ −1 µ − µ X µ T ∑ −1 e
= (2.57a)
( )
2
2 eT ∑ −1 eµ T ∑ −1 µ − µ T ∑ −1 e

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 33


ξ µ X eT ∑ −1 e − eT ∑ −1 µ
= (2.57b)
( )
2
2 eT ∑ −1 eµ T ∑ −1 µ − µ T ∑ −1 e

Reinserting (2.57a) and (2.57b) into (2.54’’) yields the optimal portfolio:
µ T ∑ −1 µ − µ X µ T ∑ −1 e −1 µ X eT ∑ −1 e − eT ∑ −1 µ
x= ∑ e+ ∑ −1 µ (2.58)
( ) ( )
2 2
eT ∑ −1 eµ T ∑ −1 µ − µ T ∑ −1 e eT ∑ −1 eµ T ∑ −1 µ − µ T ∑ −1 e

Note that this is the general formula of MVF portfolios depending on the level of the a priori
given portfolio return µ X . As all MVF portfolios contains the expressions ∑ −1 e and ∑ −1 µ they
can be characterized as
x = φ ∑ −1 e + ϕ ∑ −1 µ , (2.59)
where φ and ϕ represent the fractions in the right hand side of (2.58). Envelope portfolios differ
because of different values of φ and ϕ .

The corresponding minimal risk of an envelope portfolio can be calculated as


σ XX = x T ∑ x = ⎡⎣φ eT ∑ −1 +ϕµ T ∑ −1 ⎤⎦ ∑ ⎡⎣φ ∑ −1 e + ϕ ∑ −1 µ ⎤⎦
= ⎡⎣φ eT + ϕµ T ⎤⎦ ⎡⎣φ ∑ −1 e + ϕ ∑ −1 µ ⎤⎦ (2.60)
= φ 2 eT ∑ −1 e + 2φϕµ T ∑ −1 e + ϕ 2 µ T ∑ −1 µ

It is recommended to simplify these expressions using some conventions. Therefore, we define


a = µ T ∑ −1 µ , b = µ T ∑ −1 e , and c = eT ∑ −1 e . Thus, a − bµ X represents the nominator of φ , and
cµ X − b the nominator of ϕ .

Equation (2.60) can be rewritten as


a 2 − 2abµ X + b2 µ X 2 2acµ X − 2bcµ X 2 − 2ab + 2b2 µ X c 2 µ X 2 − 2bcµ X + b2
σ XX = c+ b+ a
( ac − b ) ( ac − b ) ( ac − b )
2 2 2
2 2 2

=
a 2 c − b2 a − 2abcµ X + 2b3 µ X + ac 2 µ X 2 − b2 cµ X 2
=
( ac − b )( a − 2bµ
2
X
+ cµ X 2 ) (2.61)
( ) ( ac − b )
2 2
ac − b2 2

a − 2bµ X + cµ X 2
= .
ac − b2

2.3.4.2 The Risk Minimal Portfolio


As in the graphical presentation we will indicate the risk minimal portfolio with D . The risk
minimal portfolio is helpful for the construction of an explicit form of the MVF.

The risk minimal portfolio can be calculated as the solution of the following optimization
problem:
Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 34
Min x T ∑ x
x

s.t. 1 = xT e (2.62)
In order to find a single solution to the optimization problem we optimize the Lagrange function:

(
L = xT ∑ x + λ 1 − xT e
x ,λ
)
The solution has to satisfy the following first order conditions:
Lx = 2 ∑ x − λ e = 0 (2.63a)

Lλ = 1 − x T e = 0 (2.63b)

If we pre-multiply (2.51a) with the inverse covariance matrix we can receive


2 ∑ −1 ∑ x = λ ∑ −1 e , (2.63a’)

and
λ −1
x= ∑ e. (2.63a’’)
2

Inserting (2.63a’’) into (2.63b) results


λ T −1
1 = xT e = e ∑ e, (2.64)
2

and
λ 1 1
= T −1 = . (2.64’)
2 e ∑ e c

Reinserting (2.64’) into (2.63a’’) yields


1 1
xD = −1
∑ −1 e = ∑ −1 e (2.65)
e ∑ e
T
c

From (2.65) we can calculate the return of the risk minimal portfolio as
µ T ∑ −1 e b
µ D = x µ = µ x = T −1 = ,
T T
(2.66)
e ∑ e c

and its risk as


T
⎛ ∑ −1 e ⎞ ⎛ ∑ −1 e ⎞ eT ∑ −1 ∑ ∑ −1 e 1 1
σ DD = x ∑ x = ⎜ T −1 ⎟ ∑ ⎜ T −1 ⎟ =
T
= T −1 = . (2.67)
⎝ e ∑ e⎠ ⎝ e ∑ e⎠ ( )
e ∑ e c
2
eT ∑ −1 e

2.3.4.3 Construction of the MVF

We can construct an explicit form of the MVF. In order to do so we rewrite (2.61) in the
following way:

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 35


2
⎛ b b2 b2 a ⎞ ⎛ b⎞ ac − b2
c⎜ µX 2 − 2 µX + 2 − 2 + ⎟ c⎜ µX − ⎟ +
a − 2bµ X + cµ X 2 ⎝ c c c c⎠ ⎝ c⎠ c
σ XX = = =
ac − b2 ac − b2 ac − b 2

2
c ⎛ b⎞ 1
= µ − ⎟ +
2 ⎜ X
(2.68)
ac − b ⎝ c⎠ c

Obviously, the risk of any element of the MVF can be determined as

( )
2
σ XX = α µ X − µ D + σ DD , (2.69)

where the constant α is defined as α = c ac − b2 . ( )


We can derive an explicit form of the MVF from (2.68):

b 1⎛ 1⎞ b ac − b2 ⎛ 1⎞
µX = ± ⎜ σ − ⎟ = ± ⎜ σ XX − ⎟ (2.70)
c α⎝ XX
c⎠ c c ⎝ c⎠

Obviously the MVF is not an ordinary function, but a correspondence. The sign before the
square root causes the ascending and descending branch of the MVF. In a more explicit way we
can express (2.69) and (2.70) as
2
eT ∑ −1 e ⎛ µ T ∑ −1 e ⎞ 1
σ XX = µ
2 ⎜ X
− −1 ⎟
+ T −1 (2.69’)
( ) e ∑ e⎠ e ∑ e
T
µ T ∑ −1 µeT ∑ −1 e − µ T ∑ −1 e ⎝
1

⎡ T −1 T −1
( )
⎤2
2
µ ∑ e ⎢ µ ∑ µe ∑ e − µ ∑ e ⎛
T −1
T −1
1 ⎞⎥
µ X = T −1 ± ⎜⎝ σ XX − eT ∑ −1 e ⎟⎠ ⎥ (2.70’)
e ∑ e ⎢ eT ∑ −1 e
⎢⎣ ⎥⎦

2.3.5 The Market Portfolio


The universe of the capital market contains all assets. In the equilibrium of the capital market the
market portfolio contains all supplied and traded assets in the supplied proportions.
T
We define the vector of the total market values as V M = ⎡⎣V1 V2  VN ⎤⎦ , and the proportions
T
in the market portfolios as x M = ⎡⎣ x M 1 x M 2  x MN ⎤⎦ .

These vectors are related to each other as


Vi VM
x Mi = T
or xM = . (2.71)
e VM eT V M

If we assume that the vectors r , µ and the covariance-matrix Σ contain the universe of the
assets we can calculate the return rM , the expectation µ M and the risk σ MM or σ M of the entire
capital market:

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 36


rM = x M T r (2.72)

( )
µ M = E rM ≡ x M T µ (2.73)

σ MM = Var ( r ) ≡ x
M M
T
∑ xM (2.74)

σ M ≡ Var rM ( ) (2.75)

2.4 Portfolios of Risk-free and Risky Assets

The situation changes substantially if we take a risk free asset into account.

2.4.1 Portfolios of a Single Risky and a Risk-free Asset


Contrary to section 2.2 the asset Y is substituted by a risk-free asset with a fixed return r f . For
convenience we assume µ X − r f > 0 .

Returns and Risks of the Portfolio


The return and the risk of a representative portfolio which contains risky and risk-free assets in
proportions a and 1-a are
(
µ P = aµ X + 1 − a r f , ) (2.76)

σ PP = a 2σ XX , (2.77)

σP = a σX . (2.78)

The risk of the portfolio contains only the weighted risk of the asset X as the variance of r f is of
course zero as well as the covariance of r f with the return of X.

From the derivation of the equations (2.76) and (2.78) we learn about the impact of the
composition on the return and the risk of the portfolio:
d µP
= µ X − rf > 0 (2.79)
da
dσ P
da
= ±σ X ≥ ≤ 0 () ⇔ ()
a≥ ≤ 0 (2.80)

From the equations (2.79) and (2.80) we can calculate the slope of the risk-return-curve:
d µ P d µ P da µ X − rf
=
dσ P dσ P da

σX
≥ ≤ 0 () ⇔ ()
a≥ ≤ 0 (2.81)

Thus, we can distinguish three parts of the MVC:

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 37


d µ P µ X − rf
1. a > 0 ⇒ σ P = aσ X > 0 ⇒ = >0
dσ P σX

2. a = 0 ⇒ σP = 0 (2.82)

d µP µ X − rf
3. a < 0 ⇒ σ P = −aσ X > 0 ⇒ =− <0
dσ P σX

The MVF can be presented in the subsequent graph:

a >1
P
X
X
0<a<1

rf

a<0

0 mX mP

Fig 2.7: MVF of risky and a risk free asset

2.4.2 Portfolio of the Market Portfolio (of Many Risky Assets) and a Risk-Faree Asset
The tangent to the MVF starting from the risk-free interest rate r f is called the Capital Market
Line (CML). Its slope of the CML is defined as

tgα =
( )
E rM − r f
=
µ M − rf (2.83)
SD ( r )
M
σM

The slope determines the risk premium of the market per unit market risk.

+"

!
#
+#
+#$%$"&
'
"&

(
m# m"

Fig 2.8: Capital Market Line

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 38


Returns and Risk of the Portfolio
A portfolio of the risk-free and the market portfolio will be indexed with C as it represents the
entire Capital Market. Of course these assets are efficient. Their return ad risk amounts to:
(
µC = a µ M + 1 − a r f) (2.84)

σ CC = a 2σ MM (2.85)

σC = a σ M (2.86)

All results from section 2.4.1 apply mutatis mutandis to the return and the risk of portfolios out
of the market portfolio of risky and the risk free asset.

Returns and Risks of a Portfolio along the Capital Market Line


If investors select the portfolio weights for the market portfolio and the risk-free asset in the
interval 0 ≤ a ≤ 1 they can realize any portfolio along CML from r f to M. For a > 1 and
1 − a < 0 , any portfolio along CML northeast of M can be realized.

The (expected) risk premium of any portfolio along CML will be:
µ M − rf
( )
E rC − r f =
σM
( )
σ rC (2.87)

2.5 Efficient and Optimal Portfolios


Investments
In section 2.5.1 we restrict the investments in risky assets, short and long positions as well. In
section 2.5.2 we allow additionally an investment in a risk-free asset. There is again no
restriction on short positions.

2.5.1 Portfolios of Risky Assets

In a first step we derive the efficient portfolios, in a second one the optimal portfolios.

2.5.1.1 Efficient Portfolios of Risky Assets


As we already know, feasible portfolios can be found by the solution of the program:
Min Var rX
x
( ) ( )
s.t. E rX = µ X for all µ X ≥ 0 I

Of course, not all feasible portfolios are efficient. Each portfolio located at the lower branch of
the MVF is dominated by a portfolio located on the upper branch of the MVF.

Efficient portfolios are solutions of the program:

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 39


Max E rX
x
( ) s.t. Var rX ≤ σ XX ( ) for all σ XX ≥ σ DD > 0 II

+"
!

# &
'
%

$
m"

Fig 2.8: Efficient portfolios of risky assets

• All portfolios on the locus ADB are feasible as they are solutions to the program I.
• Portfolios on the locus AD are efficient as they are solutions of the program II.
• Portfolios on the locus DB are of course inefficient.

2.5.1.2 Optimal Portfolios of Risky Assets


As all investors are risk-averse we receive distinctive first order conditions of individual optima:
MRS µi = MRTµi ≠ MRS µj = MRTµj σ (2.88)
Pσ P Pσ P Pσ P P P

Obviously each investor realizes different MRS and MRT between returns and risks according to
his preferences and the opportunities of the capital market represented by the risk-return-curve.

+!
&'()*
!
&'()&

%
m# m"

Fig 2.9: Optimal portfolios of risky assets

Deviations in the MRS and MRT between return and risk always give an incentive for further
exchange as long as there is any possibility to equilibrate these entities.

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 40


2.5.2 Portfolios of many risky and one risk-free asset

If a risk free asset exists we can form portfolios of the risky assets and the risk free asset. We
will see that this option changes the entire situation significantly. In particular the set of efficient
portfolios will form a straight line. Therefore, the differences in the marginal rates of substitution
between return and risk, and thus the incentive for further exchange will disappear.

2.5.2.1 Efficient Portfolios


• All portfolios of the set Er f F are feasible.
• Portfolios on the straight line r f F are inefficient.

• Only portfolios on the line r f E are efficient. Portfolios along this line offer the maximal
return for each level of risk. We call this line the Capital Market Line.

+!
%
!

"

#
!$

&

' m!

Fig 2.10: Efficient portfolios of risky assets and a risk free asset

2.5.2.2 Optimal Portfolios

+"
'()*+
!
'()*'
+#
#

$
"%

&
m# m"

Fig 2.11: Optimal portfolios of risky assets and a risk free asset

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 41


Optimal portfolios are located at the Capital Market Line. The first-order condition of an optimal
portfolio is defined as:
µ M − rf
MRS µi = MRS µj = MRTµ = MRTµ = (2.89)
Pσ P Pσ P Pσ P MσM
σM

From (2.77) we can conclude some important properties of the capital market equilibrium:
• Despite any differences in the degree of risk-aversion risk investors choose always portfolios
along the Capital Market Line (CML).
• Obviously, there are no deviations in the marginal rates of substitution of return and risk
among the different investors and thus no incentives for further exchange.
• Moreover, the marginal rates of substitution of the investors equal the marginal rate of
transformation of the entire capital market. The latter equals to the slope of the CML.
• Obviously, all portfolios along the CML result as portfolios of the market portfolio and the
risk free asset.

Two fund separation theorem


• Optimal portfolios consist of the market portfolio and the risk-free asset.
• Preferences on risk determine the composition of the portfolio.

Financial Modeling I, js Returns and Risks of Portfolios 42

You might also like