You are on page 1of 26

American Economic Association

The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies


Author(s): Robert Shimer
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No. 1 (Mar., 2005), pp. 25-49
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4132669
Accessed: 07/07/2010 11:56

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://dv1litvip.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://dv1litvip.jstor.org
The CyclicalBehaviorof Equilibrium
Unemploymentand Vacancies
By ROBERT SHIMER*

Thispaper argues that the textbooksearch and matchingmodel cannot generate the
observed business-cycle-frequencyfluctuations in unemploymentand job vacancies
in response to shocks of a plausible magnitude.In the United States, the standard
deviation of the vacancy-unemploymentratio is almost 20 times as large as the
standard deviation of average labor productivity,while the search model predicts
that the two variables should have nearly the same volatility.A shock that changes
average labor productivityprimarily alters the present value of wages, generating
only a small movementalong a downward-slopingBeveridge curve (unemployment-
vacancy locus). A shock to the separation rate generates a counterfactuallypositive
correlation between unemploymentand vacancies. In both cases, the model exhibits
virtually no propagation. (JEL E24, E32, J41, J63, J64)

In recent years, the Mortensen-Pissarides cyclical behaviorof two of its centralelements,


search and matching model has become the unemployment and vacancies, which are both
standardtheory of equilibrium unemployment highly variable and strongly negatively corre-
(Dale Mortensen and Chris Pissarides, 1994; lated in U.S. data. Equivalently,the model can-
Pissarides, 2000). The model is attractivefor a not explain the strong procyclicality of the rate
number of reasons: it offers an appealing de- at which an unemployed worker finds a job.
scriptionof how the labormarketfunctions;it is I focus on two sources of shocks: changes in
analytically tractable;it has rich and generally laborproductivityand changes in the separation
intuitive comparative statics; and it can easily rate of employed workers from their job. In a
be adaptedto study a number of labor market one-sector model, a change in labor productiv-
policy issues, such as unemploymentinsurance, ity is most easily interpretedas a technology or
firing restrictions,and mandatoryadvancedno- supply shock. But in a multi-sector model, a
tification of layoffs. Given these successes, one preference or demand shock changes the rela-
might expect that there would be strong evi- tive price of goods, which induces a change in
dence that the model is consistent with key real labor productivity as well. Thus these
business cycle facts. On the contrary,I arguein shocks represent a broad set of possible
this paper that the model cannot explain the impulses.
An increase in labor productivityrelative to
the value of nonmarketactivity and to the cost
* of advertisinga job vacancy makes unemploy-
Department of Economics, University of Chicago,
1126 East 59th Street, Chicago IL 60637 (e-mail: ment relatively expensive and vacancies rela-
shimer@uchicago.edu).A previous version of this paper
was entitled "EquilibriumUnemployment Fluctuations."I tively cheap.' The market substitutes toward
thank Daron Acemoglu, Robert Barro, Olivier Blanchard, vacancies, and the increased job-finding rate
V. V. Chari, Joao Gomes, Robert Hall, Dale Mortensen, pulls down the unemploymentrate, moving the
ChristopherPissarides, two anonymous referees, the editor economy along a downwardsloping Beveridge
Richard Rogerson, and numerous seminar participantsfor curve (vacancy-unemploymentor v-u locus).
comments that are incorporatedthroughoutthe paper. This
material is based upon work supported by the National
But the increase in hiring also shortens unem-
Science Foundation under grants SES-0079345 and SES- ployment duration,raising workers'threatpoint
0351352. I am grateful to the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation in wage bargaining, and therefore raising the
for financial support,to the Federal Reserve Bank of Min-
neapolis for its hospitality while I worked on an early
1
version of this paper, and to Mihai Manea, and especially The interpretationin this paragraph and its sequel
SebastianLudmer,for excellent researchassistance. builds on discussions with Robert Hall.
25
26 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

expected present value of wages in new jobs. choice of whetherto open a new vacancy. The
Higher wages absorb most of the productivity equilibriumvacancy rate depends on the unem-
increase, eliminating the incentive for vacancy ploymentrate,on labormarkettightness,and on
creation. As a result, fluctuationsin labor pro- the expected present value of wages in new
ductivity have little impact on the unemploy- employment relationships.Wages, in turn, are
ment, vacancy, and job-finding rates. determinedby Nash bargaining,at least in new
An increase in the separationrate does not matches. In principle, the wage in old matches
affect the relative value of unemploymentand may be rebargainedin the face of aggregate
vacancies, and so leaves the v-u ratioessentially shocks or may be fixed by a long-termemploy-
unchanged. Since the increase in separations ment contract.Section II A describes the basic
reduces employment duration, the unemploy- model, while Section II B derives a forward-
ment rate increases, and so thereforemust va- looking equation for the v-u ratio in terms of
cancies. As a result, fluctuations in the model parameters.
separationrate induce a counterfactuallyposi- Section II C performssimple analyticalcom-
tive correlation between unemployment and parative statics in some special cases. For ex-
vacancies. ample, I show that the elasticity of the v-u ratio
Section I presents the relevantU.S. business with respect to the difference between labor
cycle facts: unemploymentu is strongly coun- productivityandthe value of nonmarketactivity
tercyclical,vacancies v are equally stronglypro- or "leisure"is barely in excess of 1 for reason-
cyclical, and the correlation between the two able parametervalues. To reconcile this with
variables is -0.89 at business cycle frequen- the data, one must assume that the value of
cies. As a result, the v-u ratio is procyclical and leisure is nearly equal to labor productivity,so
volatile, with a standarddeviation around its marketwork provides little incrementalutility.
trend equal to 0.38 log points. To provide fur- The separationrate has an even smaller impact
ther evidence in supportof this finding,I exam- on the v-u ratio, with an elasticity of -0.1
ine the rate at which unemployed workers find accordingto the comparativestatics. Moreover,
jobs. If the process of pairingworkerswith jobs while shocks to labor productivity at least in-
is well-described by an increasing, constant duce a negative correlationbetween unemploy-
returns-to-scalematching function m(u,v), as in ment and vacancies, separation shocks cause
Pissarides (1985), the job finding rate is f = both variables to increase, which tends to gen-
m(u,v)/u,an increasingfunctionof the v-u ratio. erate a positive correlation between the two
I use unemployment-durationdata to measure variables. Similar results obtain in some other
the job-finding rate directly. The standarddevi- special cases.
ation of fluctuations in the job-finding rate Section II D calibratesthe stochasticmodel to
aroundtrend is 0.12 log points and the correla- match U.S. data along as many dimensions as
tion with the v-u ratio is 0.95. Finally I look at possible, and Section II E presents the results.
the two proposed impulses. The separationrate The exercise confirms the quantitativepredic-
is less correlatedwith the cycle and moderately tions of the comparativestatics. If the economy
volatile, with a standarddeviation about trend is hit only by productivity shocks, it moves
equal to 0.08 log points. Average labor produc- along a downward-slopingBeveridge curve, but
tivity is weakly procyclical and even more sta- empirically plausible movements in labor pro-
ble, with a standarddeviation about trend of ductivity result in tiny fluctuations in the v-u
0.02 log points. ratio. Moreover, labor productivityis perfectly
In Section II, I extend the Pissarides's (1985) correlatedwith the v-u ratio, indicatingthat the
search and matching model to allow for aggre- model has almost no internalpropagationmech-
gate fluctuations. I introduce two types of anism. If the economy is hit only by separation
shocks: labor productivity shocks raise output shocks, the v-u ratio is stable in the face of
in all matchesbut do not affect the rate at which large unemploymentfluctuations,so vacancies
employed workerslose theirjob; and separation are countercyclical. Equivalently, the model-
shocks raise the rateat which employed workers generatedBeveridge curve is upward-sloping.
become unemployed but do not affect the pro- Section II F explores the extent to which the
ductivity in surviving matches. In equilibrium, Nash bargaining solution is responsible for
there is only one real economic decision: firms' these results. First I examine the behavior of
VOL.95 NO. 1 AND VACANCIES
SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT 27

wages in the face of labor productivity and productivity shocks. This distinguishes the
separationshocks. An increase in labor produc- present model from those based upon intertem-
tivity encouragesfirms to create vacancies. The poral labor supply decisions (Robert E. Lucas,
resulting increase in the job-finding rate puts Jr., and LeonardRapping, 1969). Thus this pa-
upwardpressureon wages, soaking up virtually per explores the extent to which a combination
all of the shock. A decrease in the separation of search frictions and aggregate shocks can
rate also induces firmsto createmore vacancies, generate plausible fluctuations in unemploy-
again putting upward pressure on wages and ment and vacancies if labor supply is inelastic.
minimizing the impact on the v-u ratio and It suggests that search frictions per se scarcely
job-findingrate. On the other hand, I examine a amplify shocks. The paper does not examine
version of the model in which only workers' whether a search model with an elastic labor
bargaining power is stochastic. Small fluctua- supply can provide a satisfactory explanation
tions in bargaining power generate realistic for the observed fluctuations in these two
movements in the v-u ratio while inducing only variables.
a moderatelycountercyclicalreal wage, with a
standarddeviation of 0.01 log points around I. U.S. Labor Market Facts
trend.
Section III provides another angle from This section discusses the time series behav-
which to view the model's basic shortcoming.I ior of unemployment u, vacancies v, the job
consider a centralizedeconomy in which a so- finding ratef, the separationrate s, and labor
cial planner decides how many vacancies to productivity p in the United States. Table I
create in orderto maximize the presentvalue of summarizesthe detrendeddata.
market and nonmarketincome net of vacancy
creation costs. The decentralized and central- A. Unemployment
ized economies behave identically if the match-
ing function is Cobb-Douglasin unemployment The unemployment rate is the most com-
and vacancies and workers'bargainingpower is monly used cyclical indicatorof job-search ac-
equal to the elasticity of the matching function tivity. In an average month from 1951 to 2003,
with respect to the unemploymentrate, a gen- 5.67 percent of the U.S. labor force was out of
eralization of Arthur Hosios (1990). But if work, available for work, and actively seeking
unemploymentand vacancies are more substi- work. This time series exhibits considerable
tutable,fluctuationsare amplifiedin the central- temporalvariation,falling to as low as 2.6 per-
ized economy, essentially because the shadow cent in 1953 and 3.4 percent in 1968 and 1969,
wage is less procyclical. Empirically it is but reaching 10.8 percent in 1982 and 1983
difficult to measure the substitutabilityof un- (Figure 1). Some of these fluctuations are al-
employment and vacancies in the matching most certainly due to demographic and other
function, and thereforedifficult to tell whether factors unrelated to business cycles. To high-
observed fluctuationsare optimal. light business-cycle-frequency fluctuations, I
Section IV reconciles this paper with a num- take the difference between the log of the un-
ber of existing studies that claim standard employment level and an extremely low fre-
search and matchingmodels are consistent with quency trend, a Hodrick-Prescott(HP) filter
the business cycle behavior of labor markets. with smoothing parameter105 using quarterly
Finally, the paper concludes in Section V by data.2 The difference between log unemploy-
suggesting some modificationsto the model that ment and its trend has a standarddeviation of
might deliver rigid wages and thereby do a 0.19, so unemploymentis often as much as 38
betterjob of matchingthe empiricalevidence on percent above or below trend.Detrendedunem-
vacancies and unemployment. ployment also exhibits considerablepersistence,
It is worth emphasizing one important-but with quarterlyautocorrelation0.94.
standard-feature of the search and matching
frameworkthat I exploit throughoutthis paper:
2 use the level of unemploymentratherthan the rate to
workersarerisk-neutraland supply laborinelas- keep the units comparableto those of vacancies. A previous
tically. In the absence of search frictions, em- version of this paper used the unemploymentrate, with no
ployment would be constanteven in the face of effect on the conclusions.
28 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

TABLE 1-SUMMARY STATISTICS, QUARTERLY U.S. DATA, 1951-2003

u v v/u f s p
Standarddeviation 0.190 0.202 0.382 0.118 0.075 0.020
Quarterlyautocorrelation 0.936 0.940 0.941 0.908 0.733 0.878
u 1 -0.894 -0.971 -0.949 0.709 -0.408
v - 1 0.975 0.897 -0.684 0.364
Correlationmatrix v/u - - 1 0.948 -0.715 0.396
f 1 -0.574 0.396
s - 1 -0.524
p - - -- - 1

Notes: Seasonally adjusted unemploymentu is constructedby the BLS from the CurrentPopulation Survey (CPS). The
seasonally adjusted help-wanted advertising index v is constructedby the Conference Board. The job-finding rate f and
separationrate s are constructedfrom seasonally adjustedemployment, unemployment,and mean unemploymentduration,
all computedby the BLS from the CPS, as explained in equations(1) and (2). u, v,f, and s are quarterlyaverages of monthly
series. Average labor productivityp is seasonally adjustedreal average output per person in the non-farmbusiness sector,
constructed by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) from the National Income and Product Accounts and the Current
Employment Statistics. All variables are reportedin logs as deviations from an HP trend with smoothing parameter105.

12 participationare distinct economic conditions.


ChinhuiJuhnet al. (1991) show that almost all
10 of the cyclical volatility in prime-aged male
nonemploymentis accountedfor by unemploy-
ment. ChristopherFlinn and James Heckman
(1983) show that unemployed workers are sig-
nificantlymore likely to find a job than nonpar-
ticipants, although Stephen Jones and Craig
Riddell (1999) argue that other variables also
help to predictthe likelihood of finding a job. In
2 any case, since labor force participationis pro-
cyclical, the employment-populationratio is a
more cyclical measure of job-search activity,
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
worsening the problems highlighted in this
FIGURE 1. QUARTERLY U.S. UNEMPLOYMENT (IN MILLIONS) paper.
AND TREND, 1951-2003 It is also conceivable that when unemploy-
Notes: Unemploymentis a quarterlyaverage of the season- ment rises, the amountof job-searchactivity per
ally adjusted monthly series constructedby the BLS from unemployed worker declines so much that ag-
the CPS, survey home page http://www.bls.gov/cps/.The gregate search activity actually falls. There is
trend is an HP filter of the quarterlydata with smoothing both direct and indirect evidence against this
parameter105.
hypothesis. As direct evidence, one would ex-
pect that a reductionin searchintensitycould be
observed as a decline in the number of job-
There is some question as to whether unem- search methods used or a switch toward less
ployment or the employment-populationratio is time-intensive methods. An examination of
a better indicator of job-search activity. Advo- CurrentPopulationSurvey (CPS) data indicates
cates of the latter view, for example Harold no cyclical variationin the number or type of
Cole and Richard Rogerson (1999), argue that job-search methods utilized.3 Indirectevidence
the number of workers moving directly into comes from estimates of matching functions,
employment from out-of-the-laborforce is as which universally find that an increase in un-
large as the numberwho move from unemploy- employment is associated with an increase in
ment to employment (Olivier Blanchard and
Peter Diamond, 1990). On the otherhand, there
is ample evidence that unemploymentand non- 3 Shimer (2004b) discusses this evidence in detail.
VOL.95 NO. 1 AND VACANCIES
SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT 29

the numberof matches (BarbaraPetrongoloand .3


1.6. JOLTS Conference Board
Pissarides,2001). If job-searchactivity declined - r CD

sharply when unemployment increased, the 1.3 .0


matching function would be measured as de- 014

creasing in unemployment.I conclude that ag-


gregate job search activity is positively 1.2 .1
correlatedwith unemployment.
-.2
• 1.1
10
-.3
B. Vacancies
0
.9
2001:1 2001:3 2002:1 2002:3 2003:1 2003:3
The flip side of unemploymentis job vacan-
cies. The Job Openings and Labor Turnover FIGURE2. Two MEASURESOF U.S. JOB VACANCIES,
Survey (JOLTS) provides an ideal empirical 2000Q4-2003Q4
definition: "A job opening requires that 1) a Notes: The solid line shows the logarithmof the numberof
specific position exists, 2) work could start job openings in millions, measured by the BLS from the
within 30 days, and 3) the employer is actively JOLTS, survey homepage http://www.bls.gov/jlt,quarterly
averaged and seasonally adjusted. The dashed line shows
recruitingfrom outside of the establishmentto the deviation from trend of the quarterlyaveraged, season-
fill the position. Included are full-time, part- ally adjusted Conference Board help-wanted advertising
time, permanent, temporary, and short-term index.
openings. Active recruitingmeans that the es-
tablishmentis engaged in currentefforts to fill
the opening, such as advertisingin newspapers that help-wanted advertisingis subject to low-
or on the Internet, posting help-wanted signs, frequency fluctuationsthat are related only tan-
accepting applications, or using similar meth- gentially to the labormarket.In recentyears, the
ods."4Unfortunately,JOLTSbegan only in De- Internet may have reduced firms' reliance on
cember 2000 and comparable data had never newspapersas a source of job advertising,while
previously been collected in the United States. in the 1960s, newspaper consolidation may
Although there are too few observationsto look have increasedadvertisingin survivingnewspa-
systematically at this time series, its behavior pers and Equal Employment Opportunitylaws
has been instructive. In the first month of the may have encouraged firms to advertise job
survey, the non-farm sector maintained a sea- openings more extensively. Fortunately,a low-
sonally adjusted4.6 million job openings. This frequency trend should remove the effect of
number fell rapidly during 2001 and averaged these and other secular shifts. Figure 3 shows
just 2.9 million in 2002 and 2003. This decline the help-wantedadvertisingindex and its trend.
in job openings, depicted by the solid line in Notably, the decline in the detrended help-
Figure 2, coincided with a period of rising un- wanted index closely tracks the decline in job
employment, suggesting that job vacancies are openings measureddirectly from JOLTSduring
procyclical. the period when the latter time series is avail-
To obtain a longer time series, I use a stan- able (Figure 2).
dardproxy for vacancies, the ConferenceBoard Figure 4 shows a scatterplot of the relation-
help-wantedadvertisingindex, measuredas the ship between the cyclical component of unem-
number of help-wanted advertisements in 51 ployment and vacancies, the Beveridge curve.
major newspapers.5A potential shortcomingis The correlationof the percentage deviation of
unemployment and vacancies from trend is
-0.89 between 1951 and 2003.6 Moreover, the
4 This definition comes from the Bureau of Labor Sta-

tistics news release, July 30, 2002, available at http://


6
www.bls.gov/jlt/jlt_nrl.pdf. Abrahamand Katz (1986) and Blanchardand Diamond
5 Abraham(1987) discusses this measurein detail. From (1989) discuss the U.S. Beveridge curve. Abrahamand Katz
1972 to 1981, Minnesota collected state-wide job vacancy (1986) argue that the negative correlationbetween unem-
data.Abrahamcomparesthis with Minnesota's help-wanted ployment and vacancies is inconsistentwith Lilien's (1982)
advertisingindex and shows that the two series track each sectoral shifts hypothesis, and instead indicates that busi-
other very closely through two business cycles and ten ness cycles are driven by aggregatefluctuations.Blanchard
seasonal cycles. and Diamond (1989) conclude that at business cycle
30 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

110 0.6

100 ..........
90
.
0.o2-------
70
60
0.4
50

40-
30 0
@i
~d _
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
-0.6
U.S. HELP-WANTEDADVERTISING
FIGURE3. QUARTERLY
INDEXANDTREND,1951-2003 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6
Notes: The help-wantedadvertisingindex is a quarterly
averageof the seasonallyadjustedmonthlyseries con- Unemployment
structedby the ConferenceBoard with normalization
FIGURE 4. QUARTERLY U.S. BEVERIDGE CURVE,
1987 = 100.The dataweredownloaded fromthe Federal
ReserveBank of St. Louis databaseat http://research. 1951-2003
The trendis an HP
stlouisfed.org/fred2/data/helpwant.txt. Notes:Unemployment is constructed
by the BLS fromthe
datawithsmoothingparameter
filterof the quarterly 105. CPS.Thehelp-wanted indexis constructed
advertising by
the ConferenceBoard.Botharequarterlyaveragesof sea-
sonallyadjustedmonthlyseriesandareexpressedas devi-
ationsfroman HP filterwithsmoothingparameter 105.
standarddeviation of the cyclical variation in
unemployment and vacancies is almost identi-
cal, between 0.19 and 0.20, so the product of
unemploymentand vacancies is nearly acyclic. Gross worker flow data can be used to mea-
The v-u ratio is thereforeextremelyprocyclical, sure the job-finding rate directly, and indeed
with a standard deviation of 0.38 around its both the unemployment-to-employment and
trend. nonparticipation-to-employment transitionrates
are strongly procyclical (Blanchard and Dia-
C Job-Finding Rate mond, 1990; Hoyt Bleakley et al., 1999; Ka-
tharineAbrahamand Shimer, 2001). There are
An implication of the procyclicality of the two drawbacksto this approach.First, the req-
v-u ratio is that the hazard rate for an unem- uisite public use datasetis available only since
ployed worker of finding a job, his job-finding 1976, and so using these data would require
rate, should be lower during a recession. As- throwingaway half of the available time series.
sume that the numberof newly hired workersis Second, measurement and classification error
given by an increasing and constantreturns-to- lead a substantialoverestimateof gross worker
scale matching function m(u,v), depending on flows (John Abowd and Arnold Zellner, 1985;
the number of unemployed workers u and the James Poterbaand Lawrence Summers, 1986),
numberof vacancies v. Then the probabilitythat the magnitudeof which cannot easily be com-
any individual unemployed worker finds a job, puted. Instead,I infer the job-finding rate from
the average transitionrate from unemployment the dynamic behavior of the unemployment
to employment,is f m(u,v)/u = m(1,0), where level and short-termunemployment level. Let
0 v/u is the v-u ratio. The job-finding ratef ut denote the number of workers unemployed
should therefore move together with the v-u for less than one month in month t. Then as-
ratio. suming all unemployedworkersfind a job with
probabilityft in month t and no unemployed
worker exits the labor force,
frequencies, shocks generally drive the unemploymentand
vacancy rates in the opposite direction. Ut+1 =
Ut(1 -ft) + Us+1.
VOL.95 NO. 1 SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT
AND VACANCIES 31

0.70 0.3
0.65
00
0 .2 9 o ........................
0.60
i I 0
0.55 o
0.50
o
0.00.
o

0.45 0.1 0
D
o
0.40
0.0 I
0.35
-0.2
0.30
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

FIGURE 5. MONTHLY JOB-FINDING PROBABILITY FOR -1.2 -0.8 -0.4 0.0 0.4 0.8 1.2
UNEMPLOYED
WORKERS,1951-2003
Notes: The job-finding rate is computedusing equation(1),
with unemployment and short-term unemployment data Vacancy-Unemployment
Vacancy-Unemployment RaRatio
tio
constructedand seasonally adjusted by the BLS from the
FIGURE 6. MONTHLY U.S. MATCHING FUNCTION,
CPS, survey home page http://www.bls.gov/cps/. It is ex- 1951-2003
pressed as a quarterlyaverage of monthly data. The trend
is an HP filter of the quarterlydata with smoothing param- Notes: The v-u ratio is constructedby the BLS from the
eter 105. CPS and by the Conference Board. The job-finding rate is
constructedusing equation (1) and BLS data from the CPS.
Both are quarterlyaverages of seasonally adjustedmonthly
series and are expressed as deviationsfrom an HP filterwith
Unemployment next month is the sum of the smoothing parameter105.
numberof unemployedworkersthis monthwho
fail to find a job and the number of newly
unemployed workers. Equivalently, One can use the measured job-finding rate
and v-u ratio to estimate a matching function
Ut+I - /t+ m(u,v). Data limitationsforce me to impose two
(1) f, = 1- restrictionson the estimatedfunction. First, be-
Ut
cause unemploymentand vacancies are strongly
I use the unemploymentlevel and the numberof negatively correlated,it is difficult to tell em-
workers unemployed for 0 to 4 weeks, both pirically whether m(u,v) exhibits constant, in-
constructedby the BLS from the CPS, to com- creasing, or decreasing returnsto scale. But in
putef from 1951 to 2003.7 Figure 5 shows the their literature survey, Petrongolo and Pissar-
results. The monthly hazardrate averaged 0.45 ides (2001) conclude that most estimates of the
from 1951 to 2003. After detrendingwith the matchingfunctioncannotrejectthe null hypoth-
usual low-frequency HP filter, the correlation esis of constantreturns;I thereforeestimatef =
between f, and 0, at quarterly frequencies is f(O8),consistent with a constantreturns-to-scale
0.95, although the standarddeviation of ft is matchingfunction. Figure 6 shows the raw data
about 31 percent that of O,. Given that both for the job-finding rateft and the v-u ratio 0,, a
measures are crudely yet independently con- nearly linear relationship when both variables
structed, this correlation is remarkable and are expressed as deviations from log trend.Sec-
strongly suggests that a matching function is a ond, I impose that the matching function is
useful way to approachU.S. data. Cobb-Douglas, m(u,v) = Ctu?v1-a, for some
unknown parametersa and /,. Again, the data
are not very informativeas to whetherthis is a
7 Abrahamand Shimer (2001) argue that the redesign of reasonablerestriction.BI estimate the matching
the CPS in January1994, in particularthe switch to depen-
dent interviewing,reducedmeasuredshort-termunemploy-
ment. They suggest some methods of dealing with this
discontinuity.In this paper, I simply inflate short-termun- 8 Consider the CES matching function logf, = log Ii +
employment by 10 percent after the redesign took effect. 1/p log (a + (1 - a)O,). Cobb-Douglas correspondsto
32 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

functionusing detrendeddataon the job-finding 0.050


rate and the v-u ratio. Depending on exactly
how I control for autocorrelationin the residu- 0.045.
als, I estimate values of a between 0.70 and
0.75. With a first-orderautoregressiveresidual,
I get a = 0.72 with a standarderrorof 0.01.
0.035
One particularlycrude aspect of this measure
of the job-finding rate is the assumptionthat all
0.030
workersare equally likely to find a job. Shimer
(2004a) proves that when the unemployed are 0.025
heterogeneous,f, measuresthe meanjob-finding
rate in the unemployed population.That paper 0.020 .......... ......... .............
also comparesmy preferredmeasureof the job- 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
findingrate with two alternatives.The first uses FIGURE
7. MONTHLY PROBABILITY
SEPARATION FOR
the unemployment level and mean unemploy-
WORKERS, 1951-2003
EMPLOYED
ment durationto obtain a weighted average of
Notes: The separationrate is computed using equation (2),
the job-finding rate in the unemployed popula- with employment, unemployment, and short-term unem-
tion, with weights proportionalto each individ- ployment data constructedand seasonally adjusted by the
ual's unemployment duration.9 The second BLS from the CPS, survey home page http://www.bls.gov/
follows Robert Hall (2004) and measures the cps/. It is expressed as a quarterlyaverage of monthly data.
The trendis an HP filter of the quarterlydata with smooth-
job-finding rate of workers with short unem-
ing parameter105.
ployment duration using the ratio of workers
with 0 to 4 weeks of unemploymentto workers
with 5 to 14 weeks of unemployment.Since the
job-finding rate declines with unemployment bias. When a worker loses her job, she has on
duration,I find that my preferredmeasureof the average half a month to find a new job before
job-finding rate lies between these two alterna- she is recordedas unemployed. Accounting for
tives. Hall measures an averagejob-findingrate this, the short-termunemploymentrate the next
of 0.48 per month, while unemploymentdura- month is approximatelyequal to
tion data yield a job-finding rate of 0.34 per
month. Nevertheless, all three measures are =
ut+ l stet(1 - ft).
highly correlated, and so the choice of which
measureto use does not qualitativelyaffect the
conclusions of this study. Ignoring the probabilityof finding anotherjob
within the month leads one to understatethe
D. Separation Rate separation rate. This problem is particularly
acute when the job-finding rate is high, i.e.,
I can also deduce the behaviorof the separa- duringexpansions. I thereforemeasurethe sep-
tion rate from data on employment, short-term arationrate as
unemployment, and the hiring rate. Suppose
first that whenever an employed worker loses
her job, she becomes unemployed. Then the (2) s, = et (1ut+ 1
t
st=
separationrate could simply be computedas the ti
If

ratio of short-term unemployed workers next


month, us+1, to employed workers this month, Figure 7 shows the monthly separation rate
e,. But this masks a significanttime-aggregation thus constructed.It averaged 0.034 from 1951
to 2003, so jobs last on average for about 2.5
years. Fluctuationsin the deviation of the log
limiting case of p = 0. When I estimate the CES function separationratefrom trendare somewhat smaller
using nonlinear least squares and correct for first-order than in the hiringrate, with a standarddeviation
autocorrelation,I get a point estimate of p = 0.06 with a of 0.08, and separationsare countercyclical, so
standarderrorof 0.38.
9 A previous version of this paperrelied on that measure the correlationwith the detrended v-u ratio is
of f, This had little effect on the results. -0.72.
VOL.95 NO. 1 AND VACANCIES
SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT 33

130 1.2 .06


120 o 0.8 ------------------------------
--------- .04
rr(D
110 0.4 .02
100
-a 0
90 E
e(-0.4. -.02 -0
80
8
-.06
70
> -1.2.0
- Vacancy-UnemploymentRatio
60 AverageLaborProductivity
-1.6 08
50 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

40 FIGURE9. QUARTERLY
U.S. VACANCY-UNEMPLOYMENT
RATIO AND AVERAGE LABOR PRODUCTIVITY, 1951-2003

U.S. AVERAGELABOR
FIGURE8. QUARTERLY Notes: Unemployment is constructedby the BLS from the
ANDTREND,1951-2003
PRODUCTIVITY CPS. The help-wanted advertisingindex is constructedby
the Conference Board. Both are quarterlyaverages of sea-
Notes: Real output per person in the non-farm business
sonally adjustedmonthly series. Labor productivityis real
sector, constructedby the BLS Major Sector Productivity average outputper worker in the non-farmbusiness sector,
and Costs program,survey home page http://www.bls.gov/ constructed by the BLS Major Sector Productivity and
lpc/, 1992 = 100. The trendis an HP filter of the quarterly Costs program. The v-u ratio and labor productivity are
data with smoothing parameter105.
expressed as deviations from an HP filter with smoothing
parameter105.

The strong procyclicality of the job-finding Product Accounts, while employment is con-
rate and relatively weak countercyclicality of structedfrom the BLS establishmentsurvey, the
the separationrate might appear to contradict CurrentEmployment Statistics. This series of-
Blanchard and Diamond's (1990) conclusion fers two advantagescomparedwith total factor
that "the amplitude in fluctuationsin the flow productivity: it is available quarterly since
out of employmentis largerthanthatof the flow 1948; and it bettercorrespondsto the concept of
into employment." This is easily reconciled. labor productivity in the subsequent models,
Blanchardand Diamond look at the numberof which do not include capital.
people entering or exiting employment in a Figure 8 shows the behaviorof labor produc-
given month,fu, or se,, while I focus on the tivity and Figure 9 compares the cyclical com-
probability that an individual switches employ- ponents of the v-u ratio and labor productivity.
ment states,f, and st. Although the probability There is a positive correlationbetween the two
of entering employmentf, declines sharply in time series and some evidence that labor pro-
recessions, this is almost exactly offset by the ductivity leads the v-u ratio by about one year,
increase in unemploymentut, so that the num- with a maximum correlationof 0.56.10 But the
ber of people exiting unemployment is essen- most importantfact is that labor productivityis
tially acyclic. Viewed through the lens of an stable, never deviating by more than 6 per-
increasing matching function m(u,v), this is cent from trend. In contrast, the v-u ratio has
consistent with the independent evidence that twice risen to 0.5 log points aboutits trendlevel
vacancies are strongly procyclical. and six times has fallen by 0.5 log points below
trend.
E. Labor Productivity

The final importantempirical observation is 10From 1951 to


1985, the contemporaneouscorrelation
the weak procyclicality of labor productivity, between detrendedlabor productivityand the v-u ratio was
measuredas real outputper workerin the non- 0.57 and the peak correlationwas 0.74. From 1986 to 2003,
farm business sector. The BLS constructs this however, the contemporaneousand peak correlations are
negative, -0.37 and -0.43, respectively. This has been
quarterlytime series as part of its Major Sector particularlynoticeableduringthe last threeyears of data.An
Productivity and Costs program. The output exploration of the cause of this change goes beyond the
measure is based on the National Income and scope of this paper.
34 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

It is possible that the measuredcyclicality of tivity and the separation rate are common
labor productivityis reduced by a composition knowledge.
bias, since less productive workers are more Next I turn to the economic agents in the
likely to lose theirjobs in recessions. I offer two economy, a measure1 of risk-neutral,infinitely-
responses to this concern. First, there is a com- lived workers and a continuumof risk-neutral,
position bias that points in the opposite direc- infinitely-livedfirms.All agents discountfuture
tion: labor productivity is higher in more payoffs at rate r > 0.
cyclical sectors of the economy, e.g., durable Workers can either be unemployed or em-
goods manufacturing.And second, a large lit- ployed. An unemployedworkergets flow utility
erature on real wage cyclicality has reached a z from non-market activity ("leisure") and
mixed conclusion aboutthe importanceof com- searches for a job. An employed worker earns
position biases (Abraham and John Haltiwan- an endogenous wage but may not search. I
ger, 1995). Gary Solon et al. (1994) pro- discuss wage determinationshortly.
vide perhaps the strongest evidence that labor Firms have a constant returns-to-scalepro-
force composition is importantfor wage cycli- duction technology that uses only labor, with
cality, but even they argue that accounting labor productivity at time t given by the sto-
for this might double the measured variability chastic realization p(t). In order to hire a
of real wages. This paper argues that the worker, a firm must maintainan open vacancy
search and matching model cannot account at flow cost c. Free entry drives the expected
for the cyclical behavior of vacancies and un- present value of an open vacancy to zero. A
employmentunless laborproductivityis at least worker and a firm separate according to a
ten times as volatile as the data suggest, so Poisson process with arrival rate governed
composition bias is at best an incomplete by the stochastic separation rate s(t), leaving
explanation. the worker unemployed and the firm with
nothing.
Let u(t) denote the endogenous unemploy-
II. Searchand MatchingModel ment rate,11 v(t) denote the endogenous mea-
sure of vacancies in the economy, and 0(t)
I now examine whethera standardsearchand v(t)/u(t) denote the v-u ratio at time t. The flow
matchingmodel can reconcile the strongprocy- of matches is given by a constant returns-to-
clicality of the v-u ratio and the job-findingrate scale function m(u(t), v(t)), increasing in both
with the weak procyclicalityof laborproductiv- arguments. This implies that an unemployed
ity and countercyclicalityof the separationrate. worker finds a job according to a Poisson pro-
The model I consider is essentially an aggregate cess with time-varying arrival rate f(O(t))
stochastic version of Pissarides (1985, or 2000, -
m(1,0(t)) and that a vacancy is filled according
Ch. 1). to a Poisson process with time-varying arrival
rate q(0(t)) - m(0(t)', 1) = f(0(t))/0(t).
A. Model I assume that in every state of the world,
labor productivityp(t) exceeds the value of lei-
I start by describing the exogenous vari- sure z, so there are bilateralgains from match-
ables that drive fluctuations. Labor productiv- ing. There is no single compelling theory of
ity p and the separation rate s follow a first- wage determinationin such an environment,
order Markov process in continuous time. A and so I follow the literatureand assume that
shock hits the economy according to a Pois- when a workerand firm first meet, the expected
son process with arrival rate A, at which point gains from tradeare split accordingto the Nash
a new pair (p',s') is drawn from a state de- bargainingsolution. The workercan threatento
pendent distribution. Let Ep,X,p,s,denote the become unemployed and the firm can threaten
expected value of an arbitrary variable X to end the job. The present value of surplus
following the next aggregate shock, condi-
tional on the current state (p,s). I assume that
this conditional expectation is finite, which is i1 With the populationof workers constant and normal-
ized to one, the unemployment rate and unemployment
ensured if the state space is compact. At every level are identical in this model. I thereforeuse these terms
point in time, the current values of produc- interchangeably.
VOL.95 NO. 1 AND VACANCIES
SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT 35

beyond these threats is divided between the the pair is matched, they produce p units of
worker and firm, with the worker keeping a output.If they were to breakup the match, free
fraction f3 E (0, 1) of the surplus,her "bargain- entry implies the firm would be left with noth-
ing power." I make almost no assumptions ing, while the worker would become unem-
about what happens to wages after this initial ployed, getting flow utility from leisure z and
agreement, except that the worker and firm from the probability of
f(Op,s) contacting
a firm,
manage to exploit all the joint gains from trade. in which event the worker would keep a fraction
For example, the wage may be re-bargained 0 of the match value Vp,s.Next, there is a flow
whenever the economy is hit with a shock. probabilitys that the worker and firm separate,
Alternatively,it may be fixed at its initial value destroying the match value. Finally, an aggre-
until such time as the firm would prefer to gate shock arrives at rate A, resulting in an
fire the worker or the worker would prefer expected change in match value p,sVp,s -
to quit, whereuponthe pair resets the wage so p,s.
as to avoid an unnecessary and inefficient Anothercritical equationfor the match value
separation. comes from firms' free entry condition. The
flow cost of a vacancy c must equal the flow
probabilitythat the vacancy contacts a worker
B. Characterizationof Equilibrium times the resulting capital gain, which by Nash
bargainingis equal to a fraction 1 - 3 of the
I look for an equilibrium in which the v-u match value
ratio depends only on the current value of p Vp,s:
and s, Given the state-contingent
v-u
Op,s.12 (5) c = q(Op,s)(1- ) Vp,s.
ratio, the unemploymentrate evolves according
to a standard backward-looking differential
equation, Eliminating current and future values of Vp,s
from (4) using (5) gives
(3) ui(t) = s(t)(l - u(t)) --f(Op(t),s(t))u(t)
r+s+A
(6) +
+
where (p(t), s(t)) is the aggregatestate at time t. q(O~ p,,
A flow s(t) of the 1 - u(t) employed workers
become unemployed, while a flow f(O) of the = (1 - p) p-z 1
+ AE
u(t) unemployed workers find a job. An initial c ' q(Op,,)
conditionpins down the unemploymentrate and
-the aggregate state at some date to.
I characterizethe v-u ratio using a recursive which implicitly defines the v-u ratio as a func-
equationfor the joint value to a workerand firm tion of the current state (p,s).13 This equation
of being matched in excess of breakingup as a can easily be solved numerically, even with a
function of the currentaggregate state, large state vector. This simple representationof
Vp,s.
the equilibrium of a stochastic version of the
Pissarides (1985) model appears to be new to
(4) rVp,s=p - (z + f(Op,,)PVp,s)- sVp,s the literature.
+ (EsV,,,-V
C. ComparativeStatics
Appendix A derives this equation from more
primitive conditions. The first two terms repre- In some special cases, equation (6) can
sent the currentflow surplus from matching. If be solved analytically to get a sense of the

12
It is straightforwardto show in a deterministicversion
13
of this model that there is no other equilibrium,e.g., one in A similar equation obtains in the presence of aggre-
which 0 also depends on the unemploymentrate. See Pis- gate variationin the value of leisure z, the cost of a vacancy
sarides (1985). c, or workers' bargainingpower P3.
36 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

quantitative results implied by this analysis. -s


First,supposethereare no aggregateshocks, A = + -
(r s)(1 -q(O,,s))+ Pf(O3,s)"
0.14 Then the state-contingent
v-u ratio satisfies
Substitutingthe same numbersinto this expres-
r+s sion gives -0.10. Doubling the separationrate
p-z
would have a scarcely discernibleimpacton the
+
q(O,~,)q p,O, = (1 - p) c v-u ratio.
Finally, one can examine the independent
The elasticity of the v-u ratio 0 with respect to behavior of vacancies and unemployment. In
"net labor productivity"p - z is steady state, equation (3) holds with t = 0.
If the matching function is Cobb-Douglas,
r+ s + m(u,v) = LU'•v1-a , this implies
Of(Op,,,)
(r + s)(1 - + Of(Op,s) - -
Ups) 1/(1 a)
r(p,,s))
where -r(0) E [0,1] is the elasticity of f(0). This
VP'S
(S 1
pt
P'
is large only if workers' bargainingpower P3is OuPa"

small and the elasticity ri is close to one. But For a given separationrate s, this describes a
with reasonableparametervalues, it is close to decreasingrelationshipbetween unemployment
1. For example, think of a time period as equal and vacancies, consistent with the Beveridge
to one month, so the averagejob-finding rate is curve (Figure 4). An increase in labor produc-
approximately0.45 (Section I C), the elasticity tivity raises the v-u ratio which lowers the un-
rq(0)is approximately0.28 (Section I C again), employment rate and hence raises the vacancy
the average separation probability is approxi- rate. Vacancies and unemployment should
mately 0.034 (Section I D), and the interestrate move in opposite directionsin response to such
is about 0.004. Then if workers' bargaining shocks. But an increase in the separationrate
power 0 is equal to 1 - Tr(0),the so-called scarcely affects the v-u ratio. Instead,it tends to
Hosios (1990) condition for efficiency,15 the raise both the unemploymentand vacancy rates,
elasticity of the v-u ratio with respect to net an effect that is likely to produce a counterfac-
labor productivity is 1.03. Lower values of P tually positive correlation between unemploy-
yield a slightly higher elasticity, say 1.15 when ment and vacancies.
/3 = 0.1, but only at 3 = 0 does the elasticity of I can perform similar analytic exercises by
the v-u ratio with respect to p - z rise appre- makingothersimplifying assumptions.Suppose
ciably, to 1.39. It would take implausible pa- that each vacancy contacts an unemployed
rameter values for this elasticity to exceed 2. worker at a constant Poisson rate .t, indepen-
This implies that unless the value of leisure is dent of the unemploymentrate, so q(O) = t .
close to laborproductivity,the v-u ratiois likely Given the risk-neutralityassumptions, this is
to be unresponsive to changes in the labor equivalent to assuming that firms must pay a
productivity. fixed cost c/4Lin order to hire a worker. Then
I can similarly compute the elasticity of the even with aggregateshocks, equation (6) yields
v-u ratio with respect to the separationrate: a static equation for the v-u ratio:

r+s p-z
--- + p =
14 /x p,s (1 - 3) c
Shimer (2003) performscomparativestatics exercises
undermuch weaker assumptions.For example, in thatpaper In this case, the elasticity of the v-u ratio with
the matching function can exhibit increasing or decreasing
returnsto scale and there can be an arbitraryidiosyncratic respect to net labor productivityis
process for productivity, allowing for endogenous separa-
tions (Mortensen and Pissarides, 1994). I show that the
results presentedhere generalize to such an environmentif
r + s + (P30
workers and firms are sufficiently patient relative to the
search frictions.
15 Section III shows that the Hosios condition carries
over to the stochastic model. and the elasticity of the v-u ratio with respect to
VOL.95 NO. 1 AND VACANCIES
SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT 37

the separationrate is -s/P3otO.Sincef(O) = /10, y is mean reverting.The stochasticvariablesare


one can again pin down all the parametervalues then expressed as functions of y.
except workers' bargainingpower P3.Using the Although I use the discrete state space model
same parametervalues as above, including/3 = in my simulations as well, it is almost exactly
0.72, I obtain elasticities of 1.12 and -0.105, correct and significantly easier to think about
almost unchangedfrom the case with no shocks. the behavior of the extrinsic shocks by discuss-
More generally,unless P is nearlyequal to zero, ing a related continuous state space model.16I
both elasticities are very small. express the state variables as functions of an
At the opposite extreme, suppose that each Ornstein-Uhlenbeckprocess (see Howard Tay-
unemployed worker contacts a vacancy at a lor and Samuel Karlin, 1998, Section 8.5). Let y
constantPoisson rate pt, independentof the va- satisfy
cancy rate, so f(O) = pt and q(O) = p/0. Also
assume that the separationrate s is constantand dy = - yydt + rdb
average labor productivity p is a Martingale,
Epp'= p. With this matchingfunction,equation where b is a standardBrownian motion. Here
(6) is linear in currentand future values of the y > 0 is a measure of persistence, with higher
v-u ratio: values indicating faster mean reversion, and
a > 0 is the instantaneousstandarddeviation.
(r+s+A
- +[0
This process has some convenient properties:y
is conditionally and unconditionallynormal; it
is mean reverting,with expected value converg-
p-z A ing asymptotically to zero; and asymptotically
=(1 - 3) E,. its variance converges to o2/2y.
c I consider two differentcases. In the first, the
It is straightforwardto verify thatthe v-u ratiois separationrate is constant and productivitysat-
linearin productivity,
andtherefore = isfies p = z + eY(p* - z), where y is an
IEp, OP,i.e., Ornstein-Uhlenbeckprocess with parametersy
r ++
s \ p -z and o, and p* > z is a measure of long-run
HPIH
1J p= =(I- p-z
c averageproductivity.Since ey > 0, this ensures
p > z. In the second case, productivityis con-
so the elasticity of the v-u ratio with respect to stant and separations satisfy s = eYs*, where
net labor productivityis 1, regardlessof work- again y follows an Ornstein-Uhlenbeckprocess
ers' bargaining power. I conclude that with a and now s* > 0 is a measure of the long-run
wide range of parameterizations,the v-u ratio 0 average separationrate. In both cases, the sto-
should be approximatelyproportionalto net la- chastic process is reduced to three parameters,
bor productivityp - z. y, a, and eitherp* or s*.
I now proceed to explain the choice of the
other parameters,startingwith the case of sto-
D. Calibration chastic productivity.I follow the literatureand
assume that the matching function is Cobb-
This section parameterizes the model to Douglas,
match the time series behavior of the U.S. un-
employment rate. The most importantquestion = =
is the choice of the Markov process for labor f(O) Oq(O) tO'1.
productivity and separations. Appendix C de-
velops a discrete state space model which builds This reduces the calibrationto ten parameters:
on a simple Poisson process correspondingto
the theoreticalanalysis in Section II B. I define
an underlying variable y that lies on a finite 16
I work on a discrete grid with 2n + 1 = 2001 points,
ordered set of points. When a Poisson shock which closely approximateGaussian innovations. This im-
plies that Poisson arrivalrate of shocks is A = ny = 4 times
hits, y either moves up or down by one point. per quarterin the model with labor productivityshocks and
The probabilityof moving up is itself decreas- A = 220 in the model with (less persistent) separation
ing in the currentvalue of y, which ensures that shocks.
38 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

the productivityparameterp*, the value of lei- TABLE 2-PARAMETER VALUES IN SIMULATIONS OF THE
MODEL
sure z, workers' bargainingpower 0, the dis-
count rate r, the separation rate s, the two
Source of shocks
matching function parametersa and p, the va-
Parameter
cancy cost c, and the mean reversion and stan- Productivity Separation
dard deviation of the stochastic process, y Productivityp stochastic 1
and o-. Separationrate s 0.1 stochastic
Without loss of generality, I normalize the Discount rate r 0.012 0.012
Value of leisure z 0.4 0.4
productivityparameterto p* = 1. I choose the Matching function q(O) 1.3550-0.72 1.3550-0.72
standarddeviation and persistence of the pro- Bargainingpower 3 0.72 0.72
ductivity process to match the empiricalbehav- Cost of vacancy c 0.213 0.213
ior of labor productivity. This requires setting Standarddeviation o- 0.0165 0.0570
Autoregressiveparametery 0.004 0.220
a- = 0.0165 and y = 0.004. An increase in the Grid size 2n + 1 2001 2001
volatility of productivityao-has a nearly propor-
tional effect on the volatility of other variables, Note: The text provides details on the stochasticprocess for
while the persistenceof the stochasticprocess y productivityand for the separationrate.
scarcely affects the reportedresults. For exam-
ple, suppose I reduce y to 0.001, so productivity
is more nearly a random walk. Because it is reported results are insensitive to the value of
difficult to distinguish small values of y in a that parameter,I show in Section III that if a =
finite dataset, after HP filtering the model- 3, the "Hosios (1990) Rule," the decentralized
generated data, the persistence and magnitude equilibrium maximizes a well-posed social
of the impulse is virtuallyunchangedcompared planner's problem.
with the baseline parameterization.But reassur- I use the final two parameters,the matching
ingly, the detrendedbehaviorof unemployment function constant g and the vacancy cost c, to
and vacancies is also scarcely affected by in- pin down the average job-finding rate and the
creasing the persistence of labor productivity. average v-u ratio. As reportedin Section I C, a
I set the value of leisure to z = 0.4. Since worker finds a job with a 0.45 probabilityper
mean labor income in the model is 0.993, this month, so the flow arrival rate of job offers
-'
lies at the upper end of the range of income pt01 should average approximately1.35 on a
replacementrates in the United States if inter- quarterlybasis. I do not have a long time series
preted entirely as an unemploymentbenefit. with the level of the v-u ratio, but fortunately
I normalize a time period to be one quarter, the model offers one more normalization.Equa-
and thereforeset the discount rate to r = 0.012, tion (6) implies that doublingc and multiplying
equivalentto an annualdiscountfactorof 0.953. pkby a factor 21-" divides the v-u ratio 0 in
The analysis in Section I D suggests a quarterly half, doubles the rate at which firms contact
separationrateof s = 0.10, so jobs last for about workers q(O), but does not affect the rate at
2.5 years on average. This is comparable to which workers find jobs. In other words, the
Abowd and Zellner's (1985) finding that 3.42 average v-u ratio is intrinsicallymeaningless in
percent of employed workers exit employment the model.I chooseto targeta meanv-u ratioof 1,
during a typical month between 1972 and 1982, which requiressetting[L = 1.355 and c = 0.213.
after correcting for classification and measure- In the case of shocks to the separationrate, I
ment error. It is also comparableto measured change only the stochastic process so as to
turnover rates in the JOLTS, although some match the empiricalresultsdiscussed in Section
separationsin that surveyreflectjob-to-job tran- I D. Productivity is constant and equal to 1,
sitions, a possibility that is absent from this while the mean separationrate is s* = 0.10. I
model. set a = 0.057 and -y = 0.220, a much less
Using the matching function estimates from persistent stochastic process. This leaves the
Section I C, I set the elasticity parameterto a = average v-u ratio and average job-finding rate
0.72. This lies towardthe upperend of the range virtually unchanged. Table 2 summarizes the
of estimates that Petrongolo and Pissarides parameterchoices in the two simulations.
(2001) report. I also set workers' bargaining I use equation(6) to find the state-contingent
power 3 to the same value, 0.72. Although the v-u ratio Oand then simulate the model. That
VOL.95 NO. 1 AND VACANCIES
SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT 39

TABLE3-LABOR PRODUCTIVITY
SHOCKS

u v v/u f p
Standarddeviation 0.009 0.027 0.035 0.010 0.020
(0.001) (0.004) (0.005) (0.001) (0.003)
Quarterlyautocorrelation 0.939 0.835 0.878 0.878 0.878
(0.018) (0.045) (0.035) (0.035) (0.035)
u 1 -0.927 -0.958 -0.958 -0.958
(0.020) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012)
v 1 0.996 0.996 0.995
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Correlationmatrix v/u 1 1.000 0.999
(0.000) (0.001)
f 1 0.999
(0.001)
p - - - - 1

Notes: Results from simulatingthe model with stochastic labor productivity.All variables are reportedin logs as deviations
from an HP trendwith smoothing parameter105. Bootstrappedstandarderrors-the standarddeviation across 10,000 model
simulations-are reportedin parentheses.The text provides details on the stochastic process for productivity.

is, starting with an initial unemployment rate although the difference is insignificant. It is
and aggregate state at time 0, I use a pseudo- worth emphasizingthat the negative correlation
random number generator to calculate the ar- between unemployment and vacancies is a re-
rival time of the first Poisson shock. I compute sult, not a direct target of the calibrationexer-
the unemploymentrate when that shock arrives, cise. The model also generates the correct
generatea new aggregatestateusing the discrete- autocorrelationfor unemployment,althoughthe
state-space mean-reverting stochastic process behaviorof vacancies is somewhatoff target.In
describedin Appendix C, and repeat.At the end the data, vacancies are as persistentand volatile
of each period (quarter),I record the aggregate as unemployment,while in the model the auto-
state and the unemploymentrate. correlation of vacancies is significantly lower
I throw away the first 1,000 "quarters"of than that of unemployment,while the standard
data. I then use the model to generate 212 data deviation of vacancies is three times as large as
points, corresponding to quarterly data from the standarddeviation of unemploymentfluctu-
1951 to 2003, and detrendthe log of the model- ations around trend. It is likely that anything
generateddata using an HP filter with the usual that makes vacancies a state variable, such as
smoothing parameter105. I repeat this 10,000 planning lags, an adjustmentcost, or irrevers-
times, giving me good estimates of both the ibility in vacancy creation,would increase their
mean of the model-generateddata and the stan- persistence and reduce their volatility, bringing
darddeviation across model-generatedobserva- the model more in line with the data along these
tions. The latter provides a sense of how dimensions. Shigeru Fujita (2003) develops a
precisely the model predicts the value of a par- model that adds these realistic features.
ticular variable. But the real problem with the model lies in
the volatility of vacancies and unemployment
E. Results or, more succinctly, in the volatility of the v-u
ratio 0 andthe job-findingratef In a reasonably
Table 3 reports the results from simulations calibratedmodel, the v-u ratio is less than 10
of the model with labor productivity shocks. percent as volatile as in U.S. data. This is ex-
Along some dimensions, notably the co- actly the result predictedfrom the deterministic
movement of unemploymentand vacancies, the comparativestatics in Section II C. A 1-percent
model performsremarkablywell. The empirical increase in laborproductivityp from its average
correlation between these two variables is value of 1 raises net laborproductivityp - z by
-0.89, the Beveridge curve. The model actually about 1.66 percent. Using the deterministic
producesa strongernegative correlation,-0.93, model, I arguedbefore that the elasticity of the
40 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

TABLE 4---SEPARATION RATE SHOCKS

u v v/u f s
Standarddeviation 0.065 0.059 0.006 0.002 0.075
(0.007) (0.006) (0.001) (0.000) (0.007)
Quarterlyautocorrelation 0.864 0.862 0.732 0.732 0.733
(0.026) (0.026) (0.048) (0.048) (0.048)
u 1 0.999 -0.906 -0.906 0.908
(0.000) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017)
v 1 -0.887 -0.887 0.888
(0.020) (0.020) (0.021)
Correlationmatrix v/u -- 1 1.000 -0.999
(0.000) (0.000)
f - - - 1 -0.999
(0.000)
s - - - - 1

Notes: Results from simulating the model with a stochastic separationrate. All variables are reportedin logs as deviations
from an HP trend with smoothingparameter105. Bootstrappedstandarderrors-the standarddeviation across 10,000 model
simulations-are reportedin parentheses.The text provides details on the stochastic process for the separationrate.

v-u ratiowith respectto net laborproductivityis dard deviations is about 0.08 and the two vari-
about 1.03 with this choice of parameters,giv- ables are strongly negatively correlated.
ing a total elasticity of 0 with respect to p of One might be concerned that the disjoint
approximately1.66 X 1.03 = 1.71 percent. In analysis of labor productivity and separation
fact, the standard deviation of log 0 around shocks masks some important interaction be-
trend is 1.75 times as large as the standard tween the two impulses. Modeling an endoge-
deviation of log p. Similarly, the job-finding nous increase in the separationrate due to low
rate is 12 times as volatile in the data as in the labor productivity,as in Mortensen and Pissar-
model. ides (1994), goes beyond the scope of this pa-
Not only is therelittle amplification,but there per. Instead, I introduce perfectly negatively
is also no propagationof the labor productivity correlated labor productivity and separation
shock in the model. The contemporaneouscor- shocks into the basic model. More precisely, I
relation between labor productivity,the v-u ra- assume p = z + eY(p* - z) and s = e-"Ys*,
tio, and the job-finding rate is 1.00. In the data, both nonlinearfunctionsof the same latentvari-
the contemporaneous correlation between the able y. The parameter > 0 permitsa different
first two variables is 0.40 and the v-u ratio lags os
volatility for p and s.
labor productivityby about one year. The em- I startwith the parameterizationof the model
pirical correlation between labor productivity with only labor productivity shocks and intro-
and the job-finding rate is similar. duce volatility in the separation rate. Table
Table 4 reports the results from the model 5 shows the resultsfrom a calibrationwith equal
with shocks to the separationrate. These intro- standarddeviations in the deviation from trend
duce an almost perfectly positive correlation of the separation rate and labor productivity
between unemploymentand vacancies, an event (o-s = 1 - z). The behavior of vacancies in the
that has essentially never been observed in the model is now far from the data, with an auto-
United States at business cycle frequencies(see correlation of 0.29 (compared to 0.94 empiri-
Figure 3). As a result, separationshocks pro- cally) and a correlationwith unemploymentof
duce almost no variabilityin the v-u ratio or the -0.43 (-0.89). The difference between model
job finding rate. Again, this is consistent with and datais highly significantboth economically
the back-of-the-envelope calculations per- and statistically. Moreover, although cyclical
formed in Section II C, where I arguedthat the fluctuationsin the separationrate boost the vol-
elasticity of the v-u ratio with respect to the atility of unemployment considerably, they
separationrate should be approximately-0.10. have a small effect on the cyclical volatility of
According to the model, the ratio of the stan- the v-u ratio andjob-findingrate, which remain
VOL.95 NO. 1 AND VACANCIES
SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT 41

TABLE 5-LABOR PRODUCTIVITY AND SEPARATION RATE SHOCKS

u v v/u f s p
Standarddeviation 0.031 0.011 0.037 0.014 0.020 0.020
(0.005) (0.001) (0.006) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003)
Quarterlyautocorrelation 0.933 0.291 0.878 0.878 0.878 0.878
(0.020) (0.085) (0.035) (0.035) (0.035) (0.035)
u 1 -0.427 -0.964 -0.964 0.964 -0.964
(0.068) (0.011) (0.011) (0.011) (0.011)
v - 1 0.650 0.650 -0.649 0.648
(0.042) (0.042) (0.042) (0.042)
Correlationmatrix v/u 1 1.000 - 1.000 0.999
(0.000) (0.000) (0.001)
f - 1 -1.000 0.999
(0.000) (0.001)
s - - - - 1 -0.999
(0.001)
p - - - - - 1
Notes: Results from simulating the model with stochastic but perfectly correlatedlabor productivity and separations.All
variables are reported in logs as deviations from an HP trend with smoothing parameter 105. Bootstrapped standard
errors-the standarddeviation across 10,000 model simulations-are reportedin parentheses.The text providesdetails on the
stochastic process.

at around 10 percent of their empirical values. ing solution, as would be the case if wages were
Smaller fluctuationsin the separationrate natu- renegotiated following each aggregate shock.
rally have a smaller effect, while realistically This strongerrestrictionpins down the wage as
large fluctuationsin the separationrate induce a a function of the aggregate state, w,s,. This
strong positive correlationbetween unemploy- facilitates a more detailed discussion of wages,
ment and vacancies, even in the presence of which serves two purposes. First, modeling
correlatedproductivityshocks. wages illustrates that flexibility of the present
To summarize, the stochastic version of the value of wage payments is critical for many of
Pissarides (1985) model confirms that separa- the results emphasized in this paper. And sec-
tion shocks induce a positive correlation be- ond, it enables me to relate this paper to a
tween unemployment and vacancies. It also literaturethat examines whether search models
confirms that, while labor productivity shocks can generate rigid wages. Appendix B proves
are qualitatively consistent with a downward- that a continually renegotiatedwage solves
sloping Beveridge curve, the searchmodel does
+ +
w,,, = (1 - P)z 3(p cO,,s).
not substantially amplify the extrinsic shocks (7)
and so labor productivity shocks induce only
very small movements along the curve. This generalizes equation (1.20) in Pissarides
(2000) to a stochastic environment.
F. Wages Considerfirstthe effect of a separationshock
on the wage. An increasein the separationrates
Until this point, I have assumed that the sur- inducesa slightdeclinein the v-u ratio(see Table
plus in new matches is divided according to a 4), which in turn,by equation(7), reduceswages
generalized Nash bargaining solution but have slightly. Althoughthe direct effect of the shock
made no assumptionabout the division of sur- lowers firms'profitsby shorteningthe durationof
plus in old matches. Although this is sufficient matches,the resultingdecline in wages partially
for determiningthe response of unemployment offsets this, so the dropin the v-u ratiois small.
and vacancies to exogenous shocks, it does not Second, consider a productivity shock. A
pin down the timing of wage payments. In this 1-percentincrease in net labor productivityp -
section, I introduce an additional assumption, z raises the v-u ratio by about 1 percent (see
that the surplus in all matches, new or old, is Table 3). Equation (7) then implies that the
always divided according to the Nash bargain- net wage w - z increases by about 1 percent,
42 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

TABLE6-BARGAINING POWERSHOCKS

u v v/u f w
Standarddeviation 0.091 0.294 0.379 0.106 0.011
(0.018) (0.086) (0.099) (0.028) (0.015)
Quarterlyautocorrelation 0.940 0.837 0.878 0.878 0.864
(0.023) (0.046) (0.036) (0.036) (0.047)
u 1 -0.915 -0.949 -0.949 0.818
(0.045) (0.032) (0.032) (0.112)
v - 1 0.995 0.995 -0.827
(0.001) (0.001) (0.128)
Correlationmatrix v/u - - 1 1.000 -0.838
(0.000) (0.124)
f - - - 1 -0.838
(0.124)
w - - - - 1

Notes: Results from simulatingthe model with stochastic bargainingpower. All variablesare reportedin logs as deviations
from an HP trend with smoothing parameter105. Bootstrappedstandarderrors-the standarddeviation across 10,000 model
simulations-are reportedin parentheses.The text provides details on the stochastic process for the workers' bargaining
power.

soaking up most of the productivityshock and driving force, wages are counterfactuallycoun-
giving firms little incentive to create new va- tercyclical (Abraham and Haltiwanger, 1995).
cancies. Hence there is a modest increase in Nevertheless, it seems plausible that a model
vacancies and decrease in unemploymentin re- with a combinationof wage and labor produc-
sponse to a large productivityshock. tivity shocks could generate the observed be-
To understandfully the importanceof wages havior of unemployment, vacancies, and real
for the v-u ratio, it is useful to consider a ver- wages. Of course, the unansweredquestion is
sion of the model in which labor productivity what exactly a wage shock is.
and the separationrate are constantat p = 1 and If wages are bargained in new matches but
s = 0.1, but workers' bargaining power /3 then not continually renegotiated,this analysis
changes stochastically.An increasein 0 reduces is inapplicable.Nevertheless,one can prove that
the profit from creating vacancies, which puts the frequency of wage negotiation does not af-
downwardpressure on the v-u ratio. It is diffi- fect the expected present value of wage pay-
cult to know exactly how much variabilityin 01 ments in new matches, but only changes the
is reasonable,but one can ask how much wage timing of wage payments. An increase in pro-
variability is requiredto generate the observed ductivity or decrease in separationsraises the
volatility in the v-u ratio. I assume 3 is a func- presentvalue of wage paymentsin new jobs and
tion of the latent variable y, 03 = (y + therefore has little effect on the v-u ratio. An
S'-l(a)), where D is the cumulative standard increased workers' bargainingpower in a new
normal distribution.If y were constant at zero, employmentrelationshipinduces a large reduc-
this implies 3 = a, but more generally 0 is tion in vacancies and in the v-u ratio.
simply bounded between 0 and 1. I set the
standarddeviation of y to o- = 0.099 and the III. OptimalV-U Fluctuations
mean reversion parameterto -y = 0.004. Al-
though this implies very modest fluctuationsin Another way to highlight the role played by
wages-the standarddeviation of detrendedlog the Nash bargainingassumptionis to examine a
wages, computed as in equation (7), is just centralized economy in which it is possible to
0.01-the calibrated model generates the ob- sidestep the wage-setting issue entirely.17 Con-
served volatility in the v-u ratio, with persis-
tence similar to that in the model with labor
productivity shocks. Table 6 shows the com- 17 A
number of papers examine a "competitive search
plete results. Since bargainingpower is the only economy," in which firms can commit to wages before
VOL.95 NO. 1 AND VACANCIES
SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT 43

sider a hypotheticalsocial plannerwho chooses a special case of equation (6), with workers'
a state-contingentv-u ratioin orderto maximize bargaining power P equal to the elasticity a.
the present discounted value of output net of This generalizes the Hosios (1990) condition
vacancy creation costs. The planner's problem for efficiency of the decentralizedequilibrium
is representedrecursively as to an economy with stochastic productivityand
separationrates. Since the numericalexample in
rW(p, s, u) = max(zu + p(l - u) - cuO Section II E assumes a Cobb-Douglasmatching
0 function with a = /, the equilibriumallocation
described in that section solves the social plan-
+ - - ner's problem. Conversely, if those parameter
Wu(p,s, u)(s(l u) uf(O))
values describe the U.S. economy, the observed
s',u)- W(p,
+ AEP,S(W(p', s,u))). degree of wage rigidity is inconsistentwith out-
put maximization.
Instantaneous output is equal to z times the With other matching functions, the link be-
unemploymentrate u plus p times the employ- tween the equilibrium with wage bargaining
ment rate minus c times the number of vacan- and the solution to the planner's problem is
cies v uO.The value changes graduallyas the broken. At one extreme, if unemploymentand
unemployment rate adjusts, with tu = s(1 - vacancies are perfect substitutes, i.e., f(O) =
u) - uf(O), and suddenly when an aggregate a, + aO, then the output-maximizingv-u ratio
shock changes the state from (p,s) to (p',s') at is infinite whenever a,(p - z) > c(r + s +
au)
rate A. andis zero if the inequalityis reversed.Withnear-
It is straightforwardto verify that the Bell- perfectsubstitutability,the output-maximizing v-u
man value Wis linearin the unemploymentrate, ratio is very sensitiveto currentproductivity.On
W,(p,s,u) = -c/f'(Op,s), and the v-u ratio satis- the other hand, if unemploymentand vacancies
fies areperfectcomplements,f(O) = min(au,aO), the
v-u ratio never strays from the efficient ratio
With imperfectcomplements,the impact
r+ s + A f( o,s) a,/av.
, of productivityshocks on the v-u ratio is muf-
f' O ( fled but not eliminated.
(Op,s) , Opsf' Os) The economics behind these theoreticalfind-
p +-•z Is ings is simple. An increase in laborproductivity
c f'p~(6, ,s,,)
relative to the value of non-marketactivity and
the cost of advertising a vacancy induces a
switch away from the expensive activity, unem-
This implicitly defines the optimal indepen- ployment, and toward the relatively cheap ac-
dent of the unemploymentrate. Op,s, tivity, vacancies. The magnitude of the switch
With a Cobb-Douglas matching function depends on how substitutable unemployment
m(u,v) = -I, this reduces to and vacancies are in the matching function. If
uAuvI they are strong complements, substitution is
r+s+A + p+s + nearly impossible and the v-u ratio barely
+ 'ps changes. If they are strong substitutes,substitu-
q(O,s) tion is nearlycostless, and the v-u ratiois highly
procyclical.
= - ) c + AEs In the decentralizedeconomy, the extent of
q(Op,,S,) substitutionbetween unemploymentand vacan-
cies is governed not only by the matchingfunc-
tion but also by the bargaining solution, as
hiring workers and can increase their hiring rate by prom- shown by the comparative statics exercises in
ising higher wages (Peters, 1991; Montgomery, 1991; Section II C. The Nash bargainingsolution ef-
Moen, 1997; Shimer, 1996; Burdett et al., 2001). It is by fectively correspondsto a moderate degree of
now well-known thata competitive searchequilibriummax-
imizes output, essentially by creating a market for job substitutability, the Cobb-Douglas case. If
applications.This discussion of output-maximizingsearch wages were more rigid, an increase in produc-
behavior therefore also pertainsto these models. tivity would induce more vacancy creation and
44 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

less unemployment,analogous to a centralized mond (1989) also focus on the negative corre-
environmentwith a high elasticity of substitu- lation between unemployment and vacancies,
tion in the matching function. but they do not model the supply of jobs and
The substitutabilityof unemploymentand va- hence do not explain why there are so few
cancies is an empirical issue. Blanchard and vacancies during recessions. Instead, they as-
Diamond (1989) use nonlinearleast squares to sume the total stock of jobs follows an exoge-
estimate a Constant Elasticity of Substitution nous stochastic process. This paper pushes the
(CES) matching function on U.S. data. Their cyclicality of the v-u ratio to the front of the
point estimate for the elasticity of substitutionis picture. Likewise, Cole and Rogerson (1999)
0.74, i.e., slightly less substitutable than the argue that the Mortensenand Pissarides (1994)
Cobb-Douglascase, althoughthey cannotreject model can match a variety of business cycle
the Cobb-Douglas elasticity of 1. As footnote 8 facts, but they do so in a reduced form model
describes, my data suggest an elasticity slightly thattreatsfluctuationsin the job-findingrate,and
in excess of 1, although my point estimate is hence implicitlyin the v-u ratio,as exogenous.
imprecise. Whetherthe observed movements in The second group of papers, including work
unemploymentand vacancies are optimal when by Michael Pries (2004), Gary Ramey and Joel
viewed throughthe lens of the textbook search Watson (1997), WouterDen Haan et al. (2000),
and matchingmodel, therefore,remainsan open and Joao Gomes et al. (2001), assumes that
question. employment fluctuations are largely due to
time-variationin the separationrate, minimiz-
IV. RelatedLiterature ing the role played by the observed cyclicality
of the v-u ratio. These papers typically deliver
There is a large literature that explores rigid wages from a search model, consistent
whetherthe search model is consistent with the with the findings in Section II E. Building on
cyclical behaviorof labormarkets.Some papers the ideas in Hall (1995), Pries (2004) shows that
look at the implications of the model for the a brief adverse shock that destroys some old
behavior of various stocks and flows, including employment relationships can generate a long
the unemploymentand vacancy rates,but do not transitionperiod of high unemployment,as the
examinethe implicitmagnitudeof the exogenous displaced workers move through a number of
impulses.Othersassume thatbusinesscycles are short-termjobs before eventually finding their
driven by fluctuationsin the separationrate s. way back into long-term relationships.During
These paperseitherimposeexogenouslyor derive this transition process, the v-u ratio remains
within the model a counterfactuallyconstantv-u constant, since aggregate economic conditions
ratio 0. A thirdgroupof papershas triedbut failed have returned to normal. Equivalently, the
to reconcilethe procyclicalityof the v-u ratiowith economy moves along an upward-slopingBev-
extrinsicshocks of a plausiblemagnitude. eridge curve during the transition period, in
Papers by Abraham and Lawrence Katz contradiction to the evidence. Ramey and
(1986), Blanchard and Diamond (1989), and Watson (1997) arguethattwo-sided asymmetric
Cole and Rogerson (1999) fit into the first cat- information generates rigid wages in a search
egory, matching the behavior of labor market model. But in their model, shocks to the sepa-
stocks and flows by sidesteppingthe magnitude rationrate are the only source of fluctuationsin
of impulses. For example, Abraham and Katz unemployment.The job-finding ratef(O) is ex-
(1986) argue that the downward-slopingBever- ogenous and constant, which is equivalent to
idge curve is inconsistentwith models in which assuming that vacancies are proportionalto un-
unemployment is driven by fluctuationsin the employment.This is probablyan importantpart
separationrate, notably David Lilien's (1982) of the explanationfor why theirmodel produces
sectoral shifts model. That leads them to advo- rigid wages. Den Haan et al. (2000) show that
cate an alternative in which unemployment fluctuationsin the separationrate amplify pro-
fluctuations are driven by aggregate distur- ductivity shocks in a model similar to the one
bances, e.g., productivity shocks. Unfortu- examined here; however, they do not discuss
nately, they fail to examine the magnitude of the cyclical behaviorof the v-u ratio. Similarly,
shocks needed to deliver the observed shifts Gomes et al. (2001) sidestep the v-u issue by
along the Beveridge curve. Blanchardand Dia- looking at a model in which the job-finding rate
VOL.95 NO. 1 AND VACANCIES
SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT 45

is exogenous and constant, i.e., vacancies are by Nash bargainingcannot generate substantial
proportional to unemployment. Again, this movements along a downward-slopingBever-
helps keep wages relatively rigid in theirmodel. idge curve in response to shocks of a plausible
Mortensen and Pissarides (1994) have prob- magnitude. A labor productivity shock results
ably the best known paper in this literature.In primarilyin higher wages, with little effect on
their three-state "illustrative simulation," the the v-u ratio. A separationshock generates an
authorsintroduce,without comment, enormous increase in both unemploymentand vacancies.
productivityor leisure shocks into their model. It is importantto stress that this is not an attack
Average labor productivityminus the value of on the search approach to labor markets, but
leisure p - z is approximatelythree times as rather a critique of the commonly-used Nash
high in the good state as in the bad state.'8 This bargainingassumptionfor wage determination.
paper confirms that in response to such large An alternativewage determinationmechanism
shocks, the v-u ratio should also be about three that generates more rigid wages in new jobs,
times as large in the good state as in the bad measured in present value terms, will amplify
state, but argues that there is no evidence for the effect of productivity shocks on the v-u
these large shocks in the data. Even if one ratio, helping to reconcile the evidence and the-
accepts the magnitudeof the implied impulses, ory. Countercyclical movements in workers'
Mortensen and Pissarides (1994) still deliver bargainingpower provide one such mechanism,
only a correlationof -0.26 between unemploy- at least in a reduced-formsense.
ment and vacancies, far lower than the empiri- If the matching function is Cobb-Douglas,
cal value of -0.88. This is probablybecause of the observed behavior of the v-u ratio is not
the tension between productivityshocks, which socially optimal for plausible parameterizations
put the economy on a downward-slopingBev- of the model, but this conclusion could be over-
eridge curve, and endogenousmovementsin the turned if the elasticity of substitutionbetween
separationrate, which have the opposite effect. unemployment and vacancies in the matching
Monika Merz (1995) and David Andolfatto function is sufficiently large. Estimates of a
(1996) both put the standardsearch model into CES matching function are imprecise, so it is
a real business cycle frameworkwith intertem- unclearwhetherobserved wages are "toorigid."
poral substitutionof leisure, capital accumula- One way to generate more rigid wages in a
tion, and other extensions. Neither paper can theoreticalmodel is to introduceconsiderations
match the negative correlationbetween unem- whereby wages affect the workerturnoverrate.
ployment and vacancies, and both papers gen- For example, in the Burdett and Mortensen
eratereal wages that are too flexible in response (1998) model of on-the-job search, firms have
to productivity shocks. Thus these papers en- an incentive to offer high wages in order to
counter the problem I highlight in this paper, attractworkers away from competitors and to
although they do not emphasize this shortcom- reduce employees' quit rate. The distributionof
ing of the search model. Finally, Hall (2003), productivity affects an individual firm's wage
building on an earlier version of this paper, offer and vacancy creationdecisions in complex
discusses some of the same issues. Hall (2005) ways, breakingthe simple link between average
proposes one possible solution: real wages are labor productivityand the v-u ratio in the Pis-
determined by a social norm that does not sarides (1985) model. In particular,a shift in the
change over the business cycle. productivitydistributionthat leaves average la-
bor productivity unchanged may appreciably
V. Conclusion affect average wages and hence the equilibrium
v-u ratio.
I have argued in this paper that a search and Another possibility is to drop some of the
matchingmodel in which wages are determined informational assumptions in the standard
search model.19 Suppose that when a worker
18This calculation would be
easy in the absence of
heterogeneity,i.e., if their parametero- were equal to zero.
Then p - z would take on three possible values: 0.022, 19 Ramey and Watson (1997)
develop a search model
0.075, and 0.128, for a six-fold difference in p - z between with two-sided asymmetric information.Because they as-
the high and low states. sume workers' job finding rate is exogenous and acyclic,
46 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

and firm meet, they draw an idiosyncratic leisure z plus the probability she finds a job
match-specific productivity level from some times the resulting capital gain E - U
f(Op,s)
distributionF. Workers and firms know about plus the probabilityof an aggregateshock times
aggregate variables, including the unemploy- that capital gain. Equation(9) expresses a sim-
ment rate and the distributionF, but only the ilar idea for an employed worker, who receives
firm knows the realized productivitylevel. Bar- a wage payment but loses her job at rate s.
wp,,
gaining proceeds as follows: with probability Equation (10) provides an analogous recursive
3 E (0,1), a worker makes a take-it-or-leave-it formulationfor the value of a filled job. Note
wage demand, and otherwise the firm makes a that a firm is left with nothing when a filled job
take-it-or-leave-itoffer. Obviously the firm ex- ends.
tracts all the rents from the employment rela- Sum equations(9) and (10) and then subtract
tionship when it makes an offer. But if the equation(8), defining Vp,'s Jp,s + Ep, - Up,,:
uninformedworkermakes the offer, she faces a
tradeoffbetween demandinga higher wage and (11) rVp,,= p - z - f(Op,s)(Ep,s- Up,,)
reducingher risk of unemployment,so the wage
dependson the hazardrate of the distributionF. - sVp,,
+ X(EEV,,,
- V,,s).
This again breaks the link between average la-
bor productivityand the equilibriumv-u ratio. In addition, the Nash bargaining solution im-
Exploring whether either of these models, or plies that the wage is set so as to maximize the
some related model, deliver substantialfluctua- Nash product - Up,) p 1-, which gives
tions in the v-u ratio in response to plausible (Ep,s
impulses remains a topic for future research. Ep,s Up, Jp,s
(12) = V
p,
OFTHEEQUATION
A: DERIVATION
APPENDIX FOR
SURPLUS
(4) Substitutingfor E - U in equation (11) yields
equation (4).
For notational simplicity alone, assume the If I allow wages to depend in an arbitrary
wage payment depends only on the aggregate manneron the history of the match, this would
state, wp,s, not on the history of the match. I affect the Bellman values E and J; however, the
return to this issue at the end of this section. wage, and therefore the history-dependence,
Define Up,s, and to be the state- would drop out when summing the Bellman
Ep,,, Jp,,
contingent present value of an unemployed equationsfor E and J. In otherwords, the match
worker, employed worker, and filled job, re- surplus V is unaffected by the frequency of
spectively. They are linked recursively by: wage renegotiation.

(8) = z + f(O,,,)(E,,, - U,,,) OFTHEWAGE


B: DERIVATION
APPENDIX
rUp,,
EQUATION
+Aps Up,-Up)
Assume that wages are continually renegoti-
(9) rEp,s= Wp,s- s(Ep,s- Up,s) ated, so the wage depends only on the current
aggregate state (p,s). Eliminate currentand fu-
+ - Ep,s) ture values of J from equation (10) using equa-
A(EE-p,sEps,
tion (12):
(10) = - -
rJp,s p wp,s sJP,S
- (r + s + A)(1 -
- w,s = p 3)Vp,s
+
A(Ep,sJp',s' Jps). + AEp,s(1-
P)Vp,,s,.
Equation (8) states that the flow value of an
unemployed worker is equal to her value of Similarly,eliminatecurrentandfuturevaluesof
V using(5):

their results are not directly applicable to this analysis,


(r + s + A)c c
although their methodology may prove useful. Wp,s= p Ep,s
q(Op,s) p,s
VOL.95 NO. 1 SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT
AND VACANCIES 47

Finally, replace the last two terms using equa- Var[y(t + h) - y(t)ly(t)]
tion (6) to get equation (7).
= [E[(y(t+h)-y(t))2ly(t)]
APPENDIXC: THE STOCHASTIC
PROCESS

The text describes a continuous state space


- (E[y(t+ h) - y(t)ly(t)])2.
approximationto the discrete state space model
used in both the theory and simulations.Here I The first term evaluates to hAA2over a suffi-
describe the discrete state space model and ciently short time interval h, since it is equal to
show that it asymptotes to an Ornstein- A2 if a shock, positive or negative, arrives and
Uhlenbeck process. zero otherwise. The second term is (hyy(t))2,
Consider a randomvariabley that is hit with and so is negligible over a shorttime intervalh.
shocks according to a Poisson process with ar- Thus
rival rate A. The initial value of y lies on a
discrete grid,
Var[y(t+ h) - y(t)ly(t)]= hAA2= ho.
y E Y =- -nA, -(n- 1)A...,
Putting this together, we can representthe sto-
0,..., (n - 1)A, nA} chastic process for y as

where A > 0 is the step size and 2n + 1 3 is


the number of grid points. When a shock- hits, dy = - yydt + adx
the new value y' either moves up or down by
one grid point: where for t > 0, the expected value of x(t) given
x(O) is x(0) and the conditional variance is t.
This is similar to a Brownian motion, except
(yh) that the innovationsin x are not Gaussian,since
Py=1
y with probability 2

?2
1+Yny)
nA)
y is constrainedto lie on a discrete grid.
Now suppose one changes the three parame-
ters of the stochastic process, the step size,
arrivalrate of shocks, and numberof steps, from
Note that although the step size is constant, (A,A,n) to (A\V/, A/e, n/e) for any e > 0. It is
the probabilitythaty' = y + A is smaller when easy to verify that this does not change either
y is larger,falling from 1 at y = -nA to zero at the autocorrelationparameter y = /n or the
y = nA. instantaneous variance - = XA. But as
It is trivial to confirmthaty' E Y, so the state e -- 0, the distributionof the innovationprocess
space is discrete.To proceedfurther,define y - x converges to a normal by the Central Limit
A/nand ar \/A. For any fixed y(t), I examine Theorem. Equivalently, y converges to an
the behaviorof y(t + h) over an arbitrarilyshort Omstein-Uhlenbeck process.20 This observa-
time period h. For sufficiently shorth, the prob- tion is also useful for computation.It is possible
ability that two Poisson shocks arrive is negli- to find a solution on a coarse grid and then to
gible, and so y(t + h) is equal to y(t) with refine the grid by decreasinge without substan-
probability 1 - hA, has increased by A with tially changing the results.
probability hA(1 - y(t)/nA)/2, and has de-
creased by A with probability hA (1 + y(t)/
nA)/2. Adding this together shows 20
Notably, for large n it is extraordinarilyunlikely that
the state variable reaches its limiting values of +nh. The
hA unconditionaldistributionof the state variable is approxi-
E[y(t + h) - y(t)ly(t)] = y(t) = -hyy(t). matel normal with mean zero and standard deviation
ofV2y = A-n/2. The limiting values of the state variables
n

thereforelie •n standarddeviations above and below the


mean. If n = 1000, as is the case in the simulations, one
Next, the conditionalvarianceof y(t + h) - y(t) should expect to observe such values approximatelyonce in
can be decomposed into 10436periods.
48 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2005

REFERENCES Joel. "Job Destruction and Propagation of


Shocks." AmericanEconomic Review, 2000,
Abowd, John M. and Zellner, Arnold. "Estimat- 90(3), pp. 482-98.
ing Gross Labor-Force Flows." Journal of Flinn, ChristopherJ. and Heckman, James J.
Business and EconomicStatistics, 1985, 3(3), "Are Unemployment and Out of the Labor
pp. 254-83. Force Behaviorally Distinct Labor Force
Abraham, Katharine G. and Katz, Lawrence F. States?"Journal of Labor Economics, 1983,
"Cyclical Unemployment:Sectoral Shifts or 1(1), pp. 28-42.
Aggregate Disturbances?"Journal of Politi- Fujita,Shigeru."TheBeveridge Curve,Job Cre-
cal Economy, 1986, 94(3), pp. 507-22. ation and the Propagationof Shocks." Un-
Abraham, Katherine G. "Help-Wanted Advertis- published Paper, 2003.
ing, Job Vacancies, and Unemployment." Gomes, Joao; Greenwood,Jeremy and Rebelo,
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Sergio. "EquilibriumUnemployment."Jour-
1987, 0(1), pp. 207-43. nal of MonetaryEconomics, 2001, 48(1), pp.
Abraham, Katharine G. and Haltiwanger, John 109-52.
C. "Real Wages and the Business Cycle." Hall, Robert E. "Lost Jobs." Brookings Papers
Journal of Economic Literature,1995, 33(3), on EconomicActivity,1995, 0(1), pp. 221-56.
pp. 1215-64. Hall, RobertE. "ModernTheory of Unemploy-
Abraham, Katharine G. and Shimer, Robert. ment Fluctuations:Empirics and Policy Ap-
"Changes in Unemployment Duration and plications." American Economic Review,
Labor-Force Attachment," in Alan B. 2003, 93(2), pp. 145-50.
Krueger and Robert M. Solow, eds., The Hall, Robert E. "Employment Efficiency and
roaring nineties: Can full employment be Sticky Wages: Evidence from Flows in the
sustained? New York: Russell Sage Founda- Labor Market."UnpublishedPaper, 2004.
tion, 2001, pp. 367-420. Hall, RobertE. "EmploymentFluctuationswith
Andolfatto, David. "Business Cycles and Labor- Equilibrium Wage Stickiness." American
Market Search." American Economic Re- Economic Review, 2005, 95(1), pp. 53-69.
view, 1996, 86(1), pp. 112-32. Hosios,ArthurJ. "On the Efficiency of Match-
Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Diamond, Peter. ing and Related Models of Search and Un-
"The Beveridge Curve." Brookings Papers employment." Review of Economic Studies,
on Economic Activity, 1989, 0(1), pp. 1-60. 1990, 57(2), pp. 279-98.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Diamond, Peter. Jones,StephenR. G. and Riddell,W. Craig."The
"TheCyclical Behaviorof the Gross Flows of Measurementof Unemployment:An Empir-
U.S. Workers." Brookings Papers on Eco- ical Approach."Econometrica, 1999, 67(1),
nomic Activity, 1990, 0(2), pp. 85-143. pp. 147-61.
Bleakley, Hoyt; Ferris, Ann E. and Fuhrer, Jef- Juhn, Chinhui; Murphy, Kevin M. and Topel,
frey C. "New Data on WorkerFlows during Robert H. "Why Has the Natural Rate of
Business Cycles." New England Economic Unemployment Increased over Time?"
Review, 1999, 0(0), pp. 49-76. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
Burdett, Kenneth and Mortensen, Dale. "Equilib- 1991, 0(2), pp. 75-126.
riumWage Differentialsand EmployerSize." Lilien, David M. "Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical
InternationalEconomic Review, 1998, 39(2), Unemployment."Journal of Political Econ-
pp. 257-74. omy, 1982, 90(4), pp. 777-93.
Burdett, Kenneth; Shouyong, Shi and Wright, Lucas, Robert E., Jr. and Rapping,LeonardA.
Randall. "Pricing and Matching with Fric- "Real Wages, Employment, and Inflation."
tions." Journal of Political Economy, 2001, Journal of Political Economy, 1969, 77(5),
105(5), pp. 1060-85. pp. 721-54.
Cole, Harold L. and Rogerson, Richard. "Can the Merz,Monika."Searchin the LaborMarketand
Mortensen-Pissarides Matching Model the Real Business Cycle." Journal of Mone-
Match the Business-Cycle Facts?" Interna- tary Economics, 1995, 36(2), pp. 269-300.
tional Economic Review, 1999, 40(4), pp. Moen, Espen R. "Competitive Search Equilib-
933-59. rium." Journal of Political Economy, 1997,
den Haan, Wouter J.; Ramey, Garey and Watson, 105(2), pp. 385-411.
VOL.95 NO. 1 SHIMER:UNEMPLOYMENT
AND VACANCIES 49

Montgomery,James. "EquilibriumWage Dis- Pries, Michael J. "Persistence of Employment


persion and Interindustry Wage Differen- Fluctuations: A Model of Recurring Job
tials." QuarterlyJournal of Economics, 1991, Loss." Review of Economic Studies, 2004,
106(1), pp. 163-79. 71(1), pp. 193-215.
Mortensen,Dale T. and Pissarides,Christopher Ramey, Garey and Watson, Joel. "Contractual
A. "Job Creation and Job Destructionin the Fragility, Job Destruction, and Business Cy-
Theory of Unemployment."Review of Eco- cles." QuarterlyJournal of Economics, 1997,
nomic Studies, 1994, 61(3), pp. 397-415. 112(3), pp. 873-911.
Peters, Michael. "Ex Ante Price Offers in Shimer,Robert."Contractsin a FrictionalLabor
Matching Games: Non-Steady States." Market."UnpublishedPaper, 1996.
Econometrica, 1991, 59(5), pp. 1425-54. Shimer, Robert. "The Cyclical Behavior of
Petrongolo,Barbaraand Pissarides,Christopher EquilibriumUnemployment and Vacancies:
A. "Lookinginto the Black Box: A Survey of Evidence and Theory." National Bureau of
the Matching Function." Journal of Eco- Economic Research, Inc., NBER Working
nomic Literature,2001, 39(2), pp. 390-431. Papers:9536, 2003.
Pissarides,ChristopherA. "Short-RunEquilib- Shimer, Robert. "Search Intensity." Unpub-
rium Dynamics of Unemployment, Vacan- lished Paper, 2004.
cies, and Real Wages." American Economic Solon, Gary; Barsky, Robert and Parker,
Review, 1985, 75(4), pp. 676-90. Jonathan A. "Measuring the Cyclicality of
Pissarides, ChristopherA. Equilibrium unem- Real Wages: How ImportantIs Composition
ployment theory, 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: Bias?" Quarterly Journal of Economics,
MIT Press, 2001. 1994, 109(1), pp. 1-25.
Poterba,James M. and Summers,LawrenceH. Taylor, Howard, and Samuel Karlin. An intro-
"ReportingErrorsand LaborMarketDynam- duction to stochastic modeling. San Diego:
ics." Econometrica,1986, 54(6), pp. 1319-38. Academic Press, 3rd ed., 1998.

You might also like