You are on page 1of 4

1/14/2020 Social dilemma - Wikipedia

Social dilemma
A social dilemma is a situation in which an individual profits from selfishness unless everyone chooses the selfish alternative, in which case the whole group loses.[1] Problems arise when too many group
members choose to pursue individual profit and immediate satisfaction rather than behave in the group's best long-term interests. Social dilemmas can take many forms and are studied across disciplines
such as psychology, economics, and political science. Examples of phenomena that can be explained using social dilemmas include resource depletion, low voter turnout, and overpopulation.

Game theory provides some mathematical models of social dilemmas, which can be experimentally tested by people playing them, through a computer or in-person.

Contents
Types
Public goods
Replenishing resource management
Tragedy of the commons
Social traps
Perceptual dilemma
In conflict
Theories
Game theory
Evolutionary theories
Psychological theories
Factors promoting cooperation in social dilemmas
Motivational solutions
Strategic solutions
Structural solutions
Conclusions
See also
References
Further reading
External links

Types
The prisoner's dilemma is a simple game that serves as the basis for research on social dilemmas.[2] The premise of the game is that two partners in crime are imprisoned separately and each are offered
leniency if they provide evidence against the other. As seen in the table below, the optimal individual outcome is to testify against the other without being testified against. However, the optimal group
outcome is for the two prisoners to cooperate with each other.

Prisoner B does not confess (cooperates) Prisoner B confesses (defects)


Prisoner A: 3 years
Prisoner A does not confess (cooperates) Each serves 1 year
Prisoner B: goes free
Prisoner A: goes free
Prisoner A confesses (defects) Each serves 2 years
Prisoner B: 3 years

In iterated games, players may learn to trust one another, or develop strategies like tit-for-tat, cooperating unless the opponent has defected in the previous round.

Asymmetric prisoner's dilemma games are those in which one prisoner has more to gain and/or lose than the other.[3] In iterated experiments with unequal rewards for co-operation, a goal of maximizing
benefit may be overruled by a goal of equalizing benefit. The disadvantaged player may defect a certain proportion of the time without it being in the interest of the advantaged player to defect.[4] In more
natural circumstances, there may be better solutions to the bargaining problem.

Related games include the Snowdrift game, Stag hunt, the Unscrupulous diner's dilemma, and the Centipede game.

Public goods
A public goods dilemma is a situation in which the whole group can benefit if some of the members give something for the common good but individuals benefit from “free riding” if enough others
contribute.[5] Public goods are defined by two characteristics: non-excludability and non-rivalry—meaning that anyone can benefit from them and one person's use of them does not hinder another person's
use of them. An example is public broadcasting that relies on contributions from viewers. Since no single viewer is essential for providing the service, viewers can reap the benefits of the service without
paying anything for it. If not enough people contribute, the service cannot be provided. In economics, the literature around public goods dilemmas refers to the phenomenon as the free rider problem. The
economic approach is broadly applicable and can refer to the free-riding that accompanies any sort of public good.[6] In social psychology, the literature refers to this phenomenon as social loafing. Whereas
free-riding is generally used to describe public goods, social loafing refers specifically to the tendency for people to exert less effort when in a group than when working alone.[7]

Replenishing resource management


A replenishing resource management dilemma is a situation in which group members share a renewable resource that will continue to produce benefits if group members do not over harvest it but in which
any single individual profits from harvesting as much as possible.[8]

Tragedy of the commons


The tragedy of the commons is a type of replenishing resource management dilemma. The dilemma arises when members of a group share a common good. A common good is rivalrous and non-excludable,
meaning that anyone can use the resource but there is a finite amount of the resource available and it is therefore prone to overexploitation.[9]

The paradigm of the tragedy of the commons first appeared in an 1833 pamphlet by English economist William Forster Lloyd. According to Lloyd, "If a person
puts more cattle into his own field, the amount of the subsistence which they consume is all deducted from that which was at the command, of his original
stock; and if, before, there was no more than a sufficiency of pasture, he reaps no benefit from the additional cattle, what is gained in one way being lost in
another. But if he puts more cattle on a common, the food which they consume forms a deduction which is shared between all the cattle, as well that of others
as his own, in proportion to their number, and only a small part of it is taken from his own cattle".[11]

The template of the tragedy of the commons can be used to understand myriad problems, including various forms of resource depletion. For example,
overfishing in the 1960s and 1970s led to depletion of the previously abundant supply of Atlantic Cod. By 1992, the population of cod had completely collapsed
because fishers had not left enough fish to repopulate the species.[10]

Social traps
A social trap occurs when individuals or groups pursue immediate rewards that later prove to have negative or even lethal consequences.[12] This type of Atlantic cod stocks were severely overexploited in
dilemma arises when a behavior produces rewards initially but continuing the same behavior produces diminishing returns. Stimuli that cause social traps are the 1970s and 1980s, leading to their abrupt
called sliding reinforcers, since they reinforce the behavior in small doses and punish it in large doses. collapse in 1992.[10]

An example of a social trap is the use of vehicles and the resulting air pollution. Viewed individually, vehicles are an adaptive technology that have
revolutionized transportation and greatly improved quality of life. But their current widespread use causes negative externalities. In many places air pollution continues unabated because the convenience of
driving a car is immediate and the environmental costs are distant and often do not become obvious until much later.

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Social_dilemma 1/4
1/14/2020 Social dilemma - Wikipedia
Perceptual dilemma
A perceptual dilemma arises during conflict and is a product of outgroup bias. In this dilemma, the parties to the conflict prefer cooperation while simultaneously believing
that the other side would take advantage of conciliatory gestures.[13]

In conflict
The prevalence of perceptual dilemmas in conflict has led to the development of two distinct schools of thought on the subject. According to deterrence theory, the best
strategy to take in conflict is to show signs of strength and willingness to use force if necessary. This approach is intended to dissuade attacks before they happen.
Pollution in the sky of Athens,
Conversely, the conflict spiral view holds that deterrence strategies increase hostilities and defensiveness and that a clear demonstration of peaceful intentions is the most
Greece. effective way to avoid escalation.[14]

An example of the deterrence theory in practice is the Cold War strategy (employed by both the United States and the Soviet Union) of mutually assured destruction
(MAD). Because both countries had second strike capability, each side knew that the use of nuclear weapons would result in their own destruction. While controversial, MAD succeeded in its primary purpose
of preventing nuclear war and kept the Cold War cold.

Conciliatory gestures have also been used to great effect, in keeping with conflict spiral theory. For example, Egyptian President Anwar El Sadat's 1977 visit to Israel during a prolonged period of hostilities
between the two countries was well-received and ultimately contributed in the Egypt–Israel Peace Treaty.

Theories

Game theory
Social dilemmas have attracted a great deal of interest in the social and behavioral sciences. Economists, biologists, psychologists, sociologists, and political scientists alike study behavior in social dilemmas.
The most influential theoretical approach is economic game theory (i.e., rational choice theory, expected utility theory). Game theory assumes that individuals are rational actors motivated to maximize their
utilities. Utility is often narrowly defined in terms of people's economic self-interest. Game theory thus predicts a non-cooperative outcome in a social dilemma. Although this is a useful starting premise there
are many circumstances in which people may deviate from individual rationality, demonstrating the limitations of economic game theory.

Evolutionary theories
Biological and evolutionary approaches provide useful complementary insights into decision-making in social dilemmas. According to selfish gene theory, individuals may pursue a seemingly irrational
strategy to cooperate if it benefits the survival of their genes. The concept of inclusive fitness delineates that cooperating with family members might pay because of shared genetic interests. It might be
profitable for a parent to help their off-spring because doing so facilitates the survival of their genes. Reciprocity theories provide a different account of the evolution of cooperation. In repeated social
dilemma games between the same individuals, cooperation might emerge because participants can punish a partner for failing to cooperate. This encourages reciprocal cooperation. Reciprocity serves as an
explanation for why participants cooperate in dyads, but fails to account for larger groups. Evolutionary theories of indirect reciprocity and costly signaling may be useful to explain large-scale cooperation.
When people can selectively choose partners to play games with, it pays to develop a cooperative reputation. Cooperation communicates kindness and generosity, which combine to make someone an
attractive group member.

Psychological theories
Psychological models offer additional insights into social dilemmas by questioning the game theory assumption that individuals are confined to their narrow self-interest. Interdependence Theory suggests
that people transform a given pay-off matrix into an effective matrix that is more consistent with their social dilemma preferences. A prisoner's dilemma with close kin, for example, changes the pay-off
matrix into one in which it is rational to be cooperative. Attribution models offer further support for these transformations. Whether individuals approach a social dilemma selfishly or cooperatively might
depend upon whether they believe people are naturally greedy or cooperative. Similarly, goal-expectation theory assumes that people might cooperate under two conditions: They must (1) have a cooperative
goal, and (2) expect others to cooperate. Another psychological model, the appropriateness model, questions the game theory assumption that individuals rationally calculate their pay-offs. Instead many
people base their decisions on what people around them do and use simple heuristics, like an equality rule, to decide whether or not to cooperate. The logic of appropriateness suggests that people ask
themselves the question: "what does a person like me (identity) do (rules/heuristics) in a situation like this (recognition) given this culture (group)?" (Weber et al., 2004) [15] (Kopelman 2009)[16] and that
these factors influence cooperation.

Factors promoting cooperation in social dilemmas


Studying the conditions under which people cooperate can shed light on how to resolve social dilemmas. The literature distinguishes between three broad classes of solutions—motivational, strategic, and
structural—which vary in whether they see actors as motivated purely by self-interest and in whether they change the rules of the social dilemma game.

Motivational solutions
Motivational solutions assume that people have other-regarding preferences. There is a considerable literature on social value orientations which shows that people have stable preferences for how much they
value outcomes for self versus others. Research has concentrated on three social motives: (1) individualism—maximizing own outcomes regardless of others; (2) competition—maximizing own outcomes
relative to others; and (3) cooperation—maximizing joint outcomes. The first two orientations are referred to as proself orientations and the third as a prosocial orientation. There is much support for the idea
that prosocial and proself individuals behave differently when confronted with a social dilemma in the laboratory as well as the field. People with prosocial orientations weigh the moral implications of their
decisions more and see cooperation as the most preferable choice in a social dilemma. When there are conditions of scarcity, like a water shortage, prosocials harvest less from a common resource. Similarly
prosocials are more concerned about the environmental consequences of, for example, taking the car or public transport.[17]

Research on the development of social value orientations suggest an influence of factors like family history (prosocials have more sibling sisters), age (older people are more prosocial), culture (more
individualists in Western cultures), gender (more women are prosocial), even university course (economics students are less prosocial). However, until we know more about the psychological mechanisms
underlying these social value orientations we lack a good basis for interventions.

Another factor that might affect the weight individuals assign to group outcomes is the possibility of communication. A robust finding in the social dilemma literature is that cooperation increases when
people are given a chance to talk to each other. It has been quite a challenge to explain this effect. One motivational reason is that communication reinforces a sense of group identity.[18]

However, there may be strategic considerations as well. First, communication gives group members a chance to make promises and explicit commitments about what they will do. It is not clear if many
people stick to their promises to cooperate. Similarly, through communication people are able to gather information about what others do. On the other hand, this information might produce ambiguous
results; an awareness of other people's willingness to cooperate may cause a temptation to take advantage of them.

Social dilemma theory was applied to study social media communication and knowledge sharing in organizations. Organizational knowledge can be considered a public good where motivation to contribute is
key. Both intrinsic and extrinsic motivation are important at individual level and can be addressed through managerial interventions.[19]

Strategic solutions
A second category of solutions are primarily strategic. In repeated interactions cooperation might emerge when people adopt a Tit for tat strategy (TFT). TFT is characterized by first making a cooperative
move while the next move mimics the decision of the partner. Thus, if a partner does not cooperate, you copy this move until your partner starts to cooperate. Computer tournaments in which different
strategies were pitted against each other showed TFT to be the most successful strategy in social dilemmas. TFT is a common strategy in real-world social dilemmas because it is nice but firm. Consider, for
instance, about marriage contracts, rental agreements, and international trade policies that all use TFT-tactics.

However, TFT is quite an unforgiving strategy and in noisy real-world dilemmas a more forgiving strategy has its own advantages. Such a strategy is known as Generous-tit-for-tat (GTFT).[20] This strategy
always reciprocates cooperation with cooperation, and usually replies to defection with defection. However, with some probability GTFT with forgive a defection by the other player and cooperate. In a world
of errors in action and perception, such a strategy can be a Nash equilibrium and evolutionarily stable. The more beneficial cooperation is, the more forgiving GTFT can be while still resisting invasion by
defectors.

Even when partners might not meet again it could be strategically wise to cooperate. When people can selectively choose who to interact with it might pay to be seen as a cooperator. Research shows that
cooperators create better opportunities for themselves than non-cooperators: They are selectively preferred as collaborative partners, romantic partners, and group leaders. This only occurs however when
people's social dilemma choices are monitored by others. Public acts of altruism and cooperation like charity giving, philanthropy, and bystander intervention are probably manifestations of reputation-based
cooperation.

Structural solutions

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Social_dilemma 2/4
1/14/2020 Social dilemma - Wikipedia
Structural solutions change the rules of the game either through modifying the social dilemma or removing the dilemma altogether. Field research on conservation behaviour has shown that selective
incentives in the form of monetary rewards are effective in decreasing domestic water and electricity use. Furthermore, numerous experimental and case studies show that cooperation is more likely based on
a number of factors, including whether or not individuals have the ability to monitor the situation, to punish or "sanction" defectors, if they are legitimized by external political structures to cooperate and
self-organize, can communicate with one another and share information, know one another, have effective arenas for conflict resolution, and are managing social and ecological systems that have well-defined
boundaries or are easily monitorable.[21][22] Yet implementation of reward and punishment systems can be problematic for various reasons. First, there are significant costs associated with creating and
administering sanction systems. Providing selective rewards and punishments requires support institutions to monitor the activities of both cooperators and non-cooperators, which can be quite expensive to
maintain. Second, these systems are themselves public goods because one can enjoy the benefits of a sanctioning system without contribution to its existence. The police, army, and judicial system will fail to
operate unless people are willing to pay taxes to support them. This raises the question if many people want to contribute to these institutions. Experimental research suggests that particularly low trust
individuals are willing to invest money in punishment systems.[23] A considerable portion of people are quite willing to punish non-cooperators even if they personally do not profit. Some researchers even
suggest that altruistic punishment is an evolved mechanism for human cooperation. A third limitation is that punishment and reward systems might undermine people's voluntary cooperative intention.
Some people get a "warm glow" from cooperation and the provision of selective incentives might crowd out their cooperative intention. Similarly the presence of a negative sanctioning system might
undermine voluntary cooperation. Some research has found that punishment systems decrease the trust that people have in others.[24] Other research has found that graduated sanctions, where initial
punishments have low severity, make allowances for unusual hardships, and allow the violator to reenter the trust of the collective, have been found to support collective resource management and increase
trust in the system.,[25][26]

Boundary structural solutions modify the social dilemma structure and such strategies are often very effective. Experimental studies on commons dilemmas show that overharvesting groups are more willing
to appoint a leader to look after the common resource. There is a preference for a democratically elected prototypical leader with limited power especially when people's group ties are strong.[27] When ties are
weak, groups prefer a stronger leader with a coercive power base. The question remains whether authorities can be trusted in governing social dilemmas and field research shows that legitimacy and fair
procedures are extremely important in citizen's willingness to accept authorities. Other research emphasizes a greater motivation for groups to successfully self-organize, without the need for an external
authority base, when they do place a high value on the resources in question but, again, before the resources are severely overharvested. An external "authority" is not presumed to be the solution in these
cases, however effective self-organization and collective governance and care for the resource base is.[28]

Another structural solution is reducing group size. Cooperation generally declines when group size increases. In larger groups people often feel less responsible for the common good and believe, rightly or
wrongly, that their contribution does not matter. Reducing the scale—for example through dividing a large scale dilemma into smaller more manageable parts—might be an effective tool in raising
cooperation. Additional research on governance shows that group size has a curvilinear effect, since at low numbers, governance groups may also not have the person-power to effectively research, manage,
and administer the resource system or the governance process.[28]

Another proposed boundary solution is to remove the social from the dilemma, by means of privatization. This restructuring of incentives would remove the temptation to place individual needs above group
needs. However, it is not easy to privatize moveable resources such as fish, water, and clean air. Privatization also raises concerns about social justice as not everyone may be able to get an equal share.
Privatization might also erode people's intrinsic motivation to cooperate, by externalizing the locus of control.

In society, social units which face a social dilemma within are typically embedded in interaction with other groups, often competition for resources of different kinds. Once this is modeled the social dilemma
is strongly attenuated.[29]

There are many additional structural solutions which modify the social dilemma, both from the inside and from the outside. The likelihood of successfully co-managing a shared resource, successfully
organizing to self-govern, or successfully cooperating in a social dilemma depends on many variables, from the nature of the resource system, to the nature of the social system the actors are a part of, to the
political position of external authorities, to the ability to communicate effectively, to the rules-in-place regarding the management of the commons.[30] However, sub-optimal or failed results in a social
dilemma (and perhaps the need for privatization or an external authority) tend to occur "when resource users do not know who all is involved, do not have a foundation of trust and reciprocity, cannot
communicate, have no established rules, and lack effective monitoring and sanctioning mechanisms." [31]

Conclusions
Close examination reveals that social dilemmas underlie many of the most pressing global issues, from climate change to conflict escalation. Their widespread importance warrants widespread understanding
of the main types of dilemmas and accompanying paradigms. Fortunately, the literature on the subject is expanding to accommodate the pressing need to understand social dilemmas as the basis for real-
world problems.

Research in this area is applied to areas such as organizational welfare, public health, local and global environmental change. The emphasis is shifting from pure laboratory research towards research testing
combinations of motivational, strategic, and structural solutions. It is encouraging that researchers from various behavioral sciences are developing unifying theoretical frameworks to study social dilemmas
(like evolutionary theory; or the Social-Ecological Systems framework developed by Elinor Ostrom and her colleagues). For instance, there is a burgeoning neuroeconomics literature studying brain correlates
of decision-making in social dilemmas with neuroscience methods. The interdisciplinary nature of the study of social dilemmas does not fit into the conventional distinctions between fields, and demands a
multidisciplinary approach that transcends divisions between economics, political science, and psychology.

See also
Collective action Prisoner's dilemma
Coordination game Rationality
Decision theory Social trap
Elinor Ostrom Strategic games
Game theory Superimposed Schedules of Reinforcement
Identity politics Tragedy of the anticommons
Moral economy Tragedy of the commons
Nash equilibrium Voting paradox
Non-zero-sum Zero-sum game

References
10. Kenneth T. Frank; Brian Petrie; Jae S. Choi; William C. Leggett (2005). "Trophic Cascades in a
1. Allison, S. T.; Beggan, J. K.; Midgley, E. H. (1996). "The quest for "similar instances" and Formerly Cod-Dominated Ecosystem". Science. 308 (5728): 1621–1623.
"simultaneous possibilities": Metaphors in social dilemma research". Journal of Personality and doi:10.1126/science.1113075 (https://doi.org/10.1126%2Fscience.1113075). PMID 15947186 (http
Social Psychology. 71 (3): 479–497. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.71.3.479 (https://doi.org/10.1037%2F
s://pubmed.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/15947186).
0022-3514.71.3.479).
11. W F Lloyd - Two Lectures on the Checks to Population (1833)
2. Van Vugt, M., & Van Lange, P. A. M. (2006). Psychological adaptations for prosocial behavior: The
altruism puzzle. In M. Schaller, J. A. Simpson, & D. T. Kenrick (Eds.), Evolution and Social 12. Platt, J (1973). "Social traps". American Psychologist. 28 (8): 641–651. doi:10.1037/h0035723 (htt
Psychology (pp. 237–261). New York: Psychology Press. ps://doi.org/10.1037%2Fh0035723).
3. Robinson, D.R.; Goforth, D.J. (May 5, 2004). "Alibi games: the Asymmetric Prisoner' s Dilemmas" 13. Wallace, M.D. (1979). Arms races and escalations: some new evidence. In J.D. Singer (Ed.),
(https://economics.ca/2004/papers/0359.pdf) (PDF). Meetings of the Canadian Economics Explaining war: Selected papers from the correlates of war project (pp. 24-252). Beverly Hills, CA:
Association, Toronto, June 4–6, 2004. Sage.
4. Beckenkamp, Martin; Hennig-Schmidt, Heike; Maier-Rigaud, Frank P. (March 4, 2007). 14. Tetlock, P. E. (1983). "Policy-makers' images of international conflict". Journal of Social Issues. 39:
"Cooperation in Symmetric and Asymmetric Prisoner's Dilemma Games" (http://homepage.coll.mp 67–86. doi:10.1111/j.1540-4560.1983.tb00130.x (https://doi.org/10.1111%2Fj.1540-4560.1983.tb00
g.de/pdf_dat/2006_25online.pdf) (preprint link). Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective 130.x).
Goods. 15. Weber, M.; Kopelman, S.; Messick, D. (2004). "A conceptual Review of Decision Making in Social
5. Allison, S. T.; Kerr, N.L. (1994). "Group correspondence biases and the provision of public goods". Dilemmas: Applying the Logic of Appropriateness". Personality and Social Psychology Review. 8
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 66 (4): 688–698. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.66.4.688 (3): 281–307. doi:10.1207/s15327957pspr0803_4 (https://doi.org/10.1207%2Fs15327957pspr080
(https://doi.org/10.1037%2F0022-3514.66.4.688). 3_4). PMID 15454350 (https://pubmed.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/15454350).
6. Baumol, William (1952). Welfare Economics and the Theory of the State. Cambridge, MA: Harvard 16. Kopelman, S (2009). "The effect of culture and power on cooperation in commons dilemmas:
University Press. Implications for global resource management". Organizational Behavior and Human Decision
Processes. 108: 153–163. doi:10.1016/j.obhdp.2008.06.004 (https://doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.obhdp.2
7. Karau, Steven J.; Williams, Kipling D. (1993). "Social loafing: A meta-analytic review and 008.06.004). hdl:2027.42/50454 (https://hdl.handle.net/2027.42%2F50454).
theoretical integration". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 65 (4): 681–706.
doi:10.1037/0022-3514.65.4.681 (https://doi.org/10.1037%2F0022-3514.65.4.681). The reduction 17. Van Vugt, M.; Meertens, R. & Van Lange, P. (1995). "Car versus public transportation? The role of
in motivation and effort when individuals work collectively compared with when they work social value orientations in a real-life social dilemma" (https://web.archive.org/web/201107151202
individually or coactively 38/http://www.professormarkvanvugt.com/files/CarVersusPublicTransportation-JournalofAppliedSo
cialPsychology-1995.pdf) (PDF). Journal of Applied Social Psychology. 25 (3): 358–378.
8. Schroeder, D. A. (1995). An introduction to social dilemmas. In D.A. Schroeder (Ed.), Social CiteSeerX 10.1.1.612.8158 (https://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/summary?doi=10.1.1.612.8158).
dilemmas: Perspectives on individuals and groups (pp. 1–14).
doi:10.1111/j.1559-1816.1995.tb01594.x (https://doi.org/10.1111%2Fj.1559-1816.1995.tb01594.x).
9. Brechner, K. C. (1977). "An experimental analysis of social traps". Journal of Experimental Social Archived from the original (http://www.professormarkvanvugt.com/files/CarVersusPublicTransporta
Psychology. 13 (6): 552–564. doi:10.1016/0022-1031(77)90054-3 (https://doi.org/10.1016%2F002 tion-JournalofAppliedSocialPsychology-1995.pdf) (PDF) on 2011-07-15.
2-1031%2877%2990054-3).

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Social_dilemma 3/4
1/14/2020 Social dilemma - Wikipedia
18. Orbell, John M.; Dawes, Robyn M. & van de Kragt, Alphons J. C. (1988). "Explaining discussion- 25. Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons.
induced cooperation". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 54 (5): 811–819. 26. Poteete; et al. (2010). Working Together.
doi:10.1037/0022-3514.54.5.811 (https://doi.org/10.1037%2F0022-3514.54.5.811). 27. Van Vugt, M. & De Cremer, D. (1999). "Leadership in social dilemmas: The effects of group
19. Razmerita, Liana; Kirchner, Kathrin; Nielsen, Pia (2016). "What factors influence knowledge identification on collective actions to provide public goods" (https://pure.uvt.nl/ws/files/654858/JPS
sharing in organizations? A social dilemma perspective of social media communication" (https://re P1999_MarkDave_.pdf) (PDF). Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 76 (4): 587–599.
search-api.cbs.dk/ws/files/45013819/liana_razmerita_what_factors_influence_postprint.pdf) doi:10.1037/0022-3514.76.4.587 (https://doi.org/10.1037%2F0022-3514.76.4.587).
(PDF). Journal of Knowledge Management. 20 (6): 1225–1246. doi:10.1108/JKM-03-2016-0112 (h 28. Ostrom, Elinor (24 July 2009). "A General Framework for Analyzing Sustainability of Social-
ttps://doi.org/10.1108%2FJKM-03-2016-0112). Ecological Systems". Science. 325 (5939): 419–422. doi:10.1126/science.1172133 (https://doi.org/
20. Nowak, M. A.; Sigmund, K. (1992). "Tit for tat in heterogeneous populations" (https://web.archive.o 10.1126%2Fscience.1172133). PMID 19628857 (https://pubmed.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/19628857).
rg/web/20110616192929/http://www.ped.fas.harvard.edu/people/faculty/publications_nowak/Natur 29. see for example Gunnthorsdottir, A. and Rapoport, A. (2006). "Embedding social dilemmas in
e92b.pdf) (PDF). Nature. 355 (6357): 250–253. doi:10.1038/355250a0 (https://doi.org/10.1038%2 intergroup competition reduces free-riding". Organizational Behavior and Human Decision
F355250a0). Archived from the original (http://www.ped.fas.harvard.edu/people/faculty/publication Processes. 101 (2): 184–199, also contains a survey of the relevant literature.
s_nowak/Nature92b.pdf) (PDF) on 2011-06-16.
doi:10.1016/j.obhdp.2005.08.005 (https://doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.obhdp.2005.08.005).
21. Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons:The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. 30. Ostrom, Elinor (25 September 2007). "A diagnostic approach for going beyond panaceas" (https://
Cambridge University Press. www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC2000497). Proceedings of the National Academy of
22. Poteete, Janssen, and Ostrom (2010). Working Together: Collective Action, the Commons, and Sciences. 104 (39): 15181–15187. doi:10.1073/pnas.0702288104 (https://doi.org/10.1073%2Fpna
Multiple Methods in Practice. Princeton University Press. s.0702288104). PMC 2000497 (https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC2000497).
23. Yamagishi, T. (1986). "The Provision of a Sanctioning System as a Public Good". Journal of PMID 17881578 (https://pubmed.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/17881578).
Personality and Social Psychology. 51 (1): 110–116. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.51.1.110 (https://doi.o 31. Poteete, Janssen, and Ostrom (2010). Working Together: Collective Action, the Commons, and
rg/10.1037%2F0022-3514.51.1.110). Multiple Methods in Practice. Princeton University Press. p. 228.
24. Mulder, L.B.; Van Dijk, E.; De Cremer, D.; Wilke, H.A.M. (2006). "Undermining trust and
cooperation: The paradox of sanctioning systems in social dilemmas". Journal of Experimental
Social Psychology. 42 (2): 147–162. doi:10.1016/j.jesp.2005.03.002 (https://doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.j
esp.2005.03.002).

Further reading
Axelrod, R. A. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books. ISBN 978-0-465-02122-2.
Batson, D. & Ahmad, N. (2008). "Altruism: Myth or Reality?" (https://web.archive.org/web/20080517041239/http://www.in-mind.org/issue-6/altruism-myth-or-reality.html). In-Mind Magazine. 6. Archived
from the original (http://www.in-mind.org/issue-6/altruism-myth-or-reality.html) on 2008-05-17.
Dawes, R. M. (1980). "Social dilemmas". Annual Review of Psychology. 31: 169–193. doi:10.1146/annurev.ps.31.020180.001125 (https://doi.org/10.1146%2Fannurev.ps.31.020180.001125).
——— & Messick, M. (2000). "Social Dilemmas". International Journal of Psychology. 35 (2): 111–116. doi:10.1080/002075900399402 (https://doi.org/10.1080%2F002075900399402).
Kollock, P. (1998). "Social dilemmas: Anatomy of cooperation". Annual Review of Sociology. 24: 183–214. doi:10.1146/annurev.soc.24.1.183 (https://doi.org/10.1146%2Fannurev.soc.24.1.183).
JSTOR 223479 (https://www.jstor.org/stable/223479).
Komorita, S. & Parks, C. (1994). Social Dilemmas. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. ISBN 978-0-8133-3003-7.
Kopelman, S., Weber, M, & Messick, D. (2002). Factors Influencing Cooperation in Commons Dilemmas: A Review of Experimental Psychological Research (http://www.nap.edu/catalog.php?record_id=1
0287). In E. Ostrom et al., (Eds.) The Drama of the Commons. Washington DC: National Academy Press. Ch. 4., 113–156
Kopelman, S. (2009). "The effect of culture and power on cooperation in commons dilemmas: Implications for global resource management" (https://deepblue.lib.umich.edu/bitstream/2027.42/50454/4/10
72r_08_Kopelman.pdf) (PDF). Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 108: 153–163. doi:10.1016/j.obhdp.2008.06.004 (https://doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.obhdp.2008.06.004).
hdl:2027.42/50454 (https://hdl.handle.net/2027.42%2F50454).
Messick, D. M. & Brewer, M. B. (1983). "Solving social dilemmas: A review". In Wheeler, L. & Shaver, P. (eds.). Review of personality and social psychology. 4. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. pp. 11–44.
Nowak, M. A.; Sigmund, K. (1992). "Tit for tat in heterogeneous populations" (https://web.archive.org/web/20110616192929/http://www.ped.fas.harvard.edu/people/faculty/publications_nowak/Nature92b.
pdf) (PDF). Nature. 355 (6357): 250–253. doi:10.1038/355250a0 (https://doi.org/10.1038%2F355250a0). Archived from the original (http://www.ped.fas.harvard.edu/people/faculty/publications_nowak/Nat
ure92b.pdf) (PDF) on 2011-06-16.
Palfrey, Thomas R. & Rosenthal, Howard (1988). "Private Incentives in Social Dilemmas: The Effects of Incomplete Information and Altruism". Journal of Public Economics. 35 (3): 309–332.
doi:10.1016/0047-2727(88)90035-7 (https://doi.org/10.1016%2F0047-2727%2888%2990035-7).
Ridley, M. (1997). Origins of virtue. London: Penguin Classics. ISBN 978-0-670-87449-1.
Rothstein, B. (2003). Social Traps and the Problem of Trust. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521612821.
Schneider, S. K. & Northcraft, G. B. (1999). "Three social dilemmas of workforce diversity in organizations: A social identity perspective". Human Relations. 52 (11): 1445–1468.
doi:10.1177/001872679905201105 (https://doi.org/10.1177%2F001872679905201105).
Van Lange, P. A. M.; Otten, W.; De Bruin, E. M. N. & Joireman, J. A. (1997). "Development of prosocial, individualistic, and competitive orientations: Theory and preliminary evidence" (https://research.vu.
nl/ws/files/570774/VanLange%20Journal%20of%20Personality%20and%20Social%20Psychology%2073(4)%201997%20u.pdf) (PDF). Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 73 (4): 733–746.
doi:10.1037/0022-3514.73.4.733 (https://doi.org/10.1037%2F0022-3514.73.4.733). hdl:1871/17714 (https://hdl.handle.net/1871%2F17714).
Van Vugt, M. & De Cremer, D. (1999). "Leadership in social dilemmas: The effects of group identification on collective actions to provide public goods" (https://pure.uvt.nl/ws/files/654858/JPSP1999_Mark
Dave_.pdf) (PDF). Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 76 (4): 587–599. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.76.4.587 (https://doi.org/10.1037%2F0022-3514.76.4.587).
Weber, M.; Kopelman, S. & Messick, D. M. (2004). "A conceptual review of social dilemmas: Applying a logic of appropriateness". Personality and Social Psychology Review. 8 (3): 281–307.
doi:10.1207/s15327957pspr0803_4 (https://doi.org/10.1207%2Fs15327957pspr0803_4). PMID 15454350 (https://pubmed.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/15454350).
Yamagishi, T. (1986). "The structural goal/expectation theory of cooperation in social dilemmas". In Lawler, E. (ed.). Advances in group processes. 3. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. pp. 51–87. ISBN 978-0-
89232-572-6.

External links
Homepage of the social-dilemma network (http://www.socialdilemma.com)

Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Social_dilemma&oldid=931040388"

This page was last edited on 16 December 2019, at 15:54 (UTC).

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc.,
a non-profit organization.

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Social_dilemma 4/4

You might also like