You are on page 1of 16

Social Reproductiorl 1 59

labour', is defined as 'income-generating activity' , and can hence be bought


at much cheaper price than male labour.
2 . Moreover, by defining women universally as housewives, it is possible not
4 SOCIAL REPROD UCTION only to cheapen their labour, but also to gain political and ideological control
over them. Housewives are atomised and isolated, their work organisation
makes the awareness of a common work process ofproduction, very difficult.
Their horizon remains limited by the family. Trade unions have never taken
inte rest in women as housewives.
3. Due to this interest in women, and particularly in women in the colonies
as the optimal labour force, we do not observe a tendency towards the
The argument which began with the need t o break down bounded generalisatioi1 of the 'free' proletarian as the typical labourer, but of the
regions of economic discourse h as led to this chapter on social marginalised, housewifised, unfree labourer, most of them women. (Mies
reproduction. Here I will present in the first place some feminist and 1 986: 1 1 6)
Marxist approaches that can be seen as the prelude to the perspective By focusing on women's work, and bringing it to the foreground,
I want to propose: a theoretical framework of social reproduction. In this perspective questions the idea of the dominance of 'free' wage
the second section I develop this social reproduction framework, labour in capitalist relations of production. As housewives, women are
trying to show that the articulation ofmaterial and ideological realities invisible workers, as employed housewives they are marginalised
is part of a materialist tradition focusing on 'experience ' . The chapter because they are not considered the main 'breadwinner' in a family.
ends with the example of Catalan nationalism, in an attempt to show At the same time, housework, consumption work, increases constantly
how material relations have to be analysed within the larger framework in Western 'overdeveloped' countries, mostly in shopping and self­
of social reproduction, that is, the movement through which a concrete provisioning (Glazer 1 984; Mies 1 986: 1 26) which is to be related to
historical social reality sets the conditions for its continuity, and the cost-cutting strategies by marketing firms. In the realm of production,
way in which the concrete historical reality is embodied in agents women's work and employment (part-time workers, workers in the
through personal and collective identities. service sector) , both formal and informal, have also been increasing.
This situation, moreover, is not limited to Third World countries but
is a blatant fact of Western 'developed' labour markets. Several studies
PRODUCTION AND REPRODUCTION (Beechey and Perkins 1 987; J. Smith 1 984) show for the UK and the
USA how employment of women rests on the assumption that they
A JemiHist critique if the dichotomy; a dejiHitiotl if reproductiorl are subsidiary workers because their basic job is elsewhere (housework)
aHd because their income is not expected to reproduce the labour force
As I have tried to show in previous chapters, the attention feminists (neither present nor future generations), but is a mere 'complement'
have paid to domestic labour and to women's work more generally, to a full, male, 'family wage ' . Therefore the definition of women as
has been the major challenge to a production-centred view of economic eco nomically deperr'd ent on a male wage and as primarily non-wage
processes. Women's work, even when it is clearly 'production' work houseworkers for their family is a fundamental aspect of their being
as in sweatshops all around the world has suffered from what Mies terms employed in rapidly expanding low-wage sectors of the economy such
'housewifisation'. This concept stems from the awareness that: as servic es, and in low-paying forms ofemployment such as part-time
jobs. This paradoxical situation is highlighted by Joan Smith:
1 . Women are the optimal labour force because they are now being universally
defined as 'housewives' , not as workers; this means their work, whether in The refore, to the extent that the growth and relative importance of these
use value or commodity production, is obscured, does not appear as 'free wage- industries are central to the transformations in typical economic practices of

158
1 60 New DirectiotlS in Economic Arlthropology Social Reproduction 161
the nation, the set of social arrangements characterising women's lives as rep roduction , reproduction o f the labour force and biological
nonwage workers are incorporated into the very grounds of the economy. reproduction . SocialreprOductiorl woUld refer t6 i:he ' reproduction of
These social arrangements are precisely those that support the assumption that
the conditions of social production in the totality' (Edholm et al.
women are properly considered a cheaper and more dispensable labour force 1 977 : 1 05) . This in fact is a general expression of Marx's idea of social
reproduction of the capitalist mode of production, where productive
and are less dependent on their wages than male workers.
I

consumption, personal consumption , circulation, distribution and


In short, women's poverty and continued economic dependency are now

production are linked in a process that reproduces the material elements


the central operating premises of the most rapidly expanding sectors of the
US economy today and form the basis for the profound changes that have
characterised that economy over the past decade. ( 1 984:309) of capital, their value, and the social relations existing between capital
and labour which is the key to the capitalist character of the production
Moreover, the present situation in Western democracies, with the process conceived globally (Marx, Capital, Vol. II, 20 and 'Prologue'
financial crisis of the state and the drastic move away from the welfare in the Contribution to the Critique of Political ECMlOmy, Ch. 2) .
model, means an additional burden ofwork for many women. Services Reproductiotl of the labourJorce corresponds to the daily maintenance
such as the daily care of the very young and very old are being of the labourers- anerto the 'allocation of agents to positions within
transferred by the state to the ' community' , either the private individual the labour process over time' (Edholm et al. 1 977: 1 05). These two
family or volunteer associations organising 'community work'. In aspects should be clearly distinct: one can be thought of as including
either case, mostly women will be responsible for the additional non­ work such as domestic labour or the processing ofcommodities in order
wage caring jobs, increasing their usual load of reproductive, for them to be consumable use values. The other includes at least two
'domestic' work. slightly different ideas: first, that of socialisation, transfers ofknowledge
Feminism, then, has taken the lead in questioning the conceptual and introduction into social networks; and second, in a more general
dichotomy ofproduction/reproduction. Beyond the domestic labour sense, that of distribution, that is, the differential allocation of resources
debate, the issue of the inclusion of the reproduction of the labour (material and cultural) in a society as a whole, that positions people
force (waged and non-waged workers) in the structure of production in reference to means of production and means oflivelihood in a way
has emerged as a basic theme to be addressed. that sets the field for the relations of production. Socialisation can be
In a pathbreaking article Edholm et al. (1 977) argue against the seen as part of the process of resource allocation, one which, at least
'uncritical adoption of the term reproduction' and point to the danger in part, takes place in a realm ofrelationships often conceived as non­
of the analytical separation in the capitalist system of an 'economic' economic: those between kin , neighbours, friends, peers.
productive level and a 'reproductive' level, where different kinds of Biological reproduction refers to reproduction of human populations.
work are associated with human biological reproduction and assumed The question of human, biological reproduction is interesting to
to be autonomous from the 'productive' process set in motion directly analyse. Indeed, since Malthus, overpopulation has been one of the
by capital (1 977: 1 03-4) . The authors then question the general more powerful ideas because it was considered a 'natural' phenomenon.
assumption that 'human reproductive practices will be empirically similar Economists have used it uncritically to explain poverty, decreasing wages
in all modes ofproduction' (1977: 104); that control of the reproduction and generally the·worsenin g condition s of labourers worldwide.
oflabour force is identical with control over women, perceived as the Edholm et al. ask whether it is 'correct to assume that the normal
key elements in human (biological) reproduction; that sexual division c ondition of human populations is expansion ' ( 1 977 : 1 02). Other
of labour is a natural corollary of human reproduction as an feminist anthropologists (Tabet 1 985; MacCormack 1 982a) have also
unproblematic, female-centred function. argued against the assumption that ' natural' human fertility is high. I n
Therefore, in order to be operationalised the concept of reproduction fact i n human societies no fertility i s 'natural' and social practices
should be carefully disaggregated into distinct 'reproductions': social - forms ofmarriage, rituals, patterns offood allocation - influence fertility

L
1 62 New Directions in Economic Anthropology Social Reproduction 1 63
and the demography of human populations. On the other hand, the are moved by different 'logics'. The worker sells a commodity - labour
control of human reproduction should be studied in the context of a p ower - in order to get money that will enable her/him to buy the
society's complex means of controlling the resource oflabour power. use values for her/his own and her/his family's livelihood. And this
This disaggregation of the concept of reproduction is a necessary movement ofsimple commodity circulation in the market is completed
analytical device and a starting point. The theoretical aim, however, by a movement of 'simple commodity production' of the commodity
should be to integrate these 'reproductive' processes in the understanding labour power outside the market, within the domestic group. It is, in
of 'economic' processes. Thus, conflict and consent, material and its most basic form, the sale of a use value that cannot be put to use
ideological relations that help create and result from specific relations by its owner but can be exchanged in order to obtain the necessary
lise values for consumption. To live in order to work in order to live:
of production, might become clearer. The aim should be, it seems to
this chain of circumstances leads to the reproduction ofthe labour force
me, an integrative framework such as that of social reproduction.
and globally to social reproduction.
On the other hand, the capitalist is moved by his drive to accumulate,
because ownership of capital is what makes him a capitalist, what gives
Marxist perspective: the articulation if different economic 'logics '
him the power to control resources and results in his commanding
position in the social relations of production. This also leads to the
In order to integrate production and reproduction in a wider
reproduction ofagents allocated to specific controlling positions within
framework, an analysis of Marxist approaches to these 'domains' of
the labour process over time and globally to social reproduction. As
economic practice should also be undertaken. In Marxist analysis there Sweezy (1 964 [ 1 942J : 1 40) pointed out:
are two possible economic 'logics': one where the objective of
production is the final consumption of needed use values; the other The difference of behavior and motivation as between capitalist and worker
has, ofcourse, nothing to do with 'human nature'. It springs ... from the different
where the obj ective of production is accumulation. This occurs by
objective circumstances in which each is placed. Through failure to make
means of the appropriation of surplus value created within specific this distinction, orthodox economics has frequently been led into one or the
social relations of production and through the realisation of this value other of two opposite errors: the error ofsupposing that under capitalism every
in commodity circulation. In short, one stresses the production of olle is driven on by the desire to make profits, or the error of supposing that
use values to be obtained directly - as when a peasant works a every olle is interested only in use values and hence that all saving is to be regarded
subsistence plot - or indirectly as in simple commodity production in the light of a redistribution of income through time.
where exchange is limited, in theory, to the indirect acquisition of
Moreover, as Cook ( 1 984) has argued, we may find 'different
needed use values. The other stresses the production of exchange values: objective circumstances' within apparently 'homogeneous' groups of
commodities that circulate in order to enable the realisation and people, for example within households, following gender, age and status
accumulation of the surplus value embodied in them. While in the lines: among husband/wife, parent/child, brothers/sisters ,
first 'logic' exchange can only be a mere medium to the use value married/unmarried, heir/non-heir, etc . Within the broad distinction
motive; in the second 'logic' use value appears as a mere medium to of workers and ca,l?italists, then, different people will be placed in
the exchange value and accumulation motive. posi tions such as to be able to develop different economic 'logics'.
However, the degree to which these distinct logics are applicable The two 'logics' in capitalist social formations do not represent
to an economy as a whole is questionable. More likely, different different 'mQ(k��fproduction', societies or even homogeneous social
groups of people in a society will be motivated by different 'logics' groups. They appear as different aspects of the dynamics of social
according to their capacity to control and act upon resources - means reproduction. The element that concentrates this basic paradox of
of subsistence, land, instruments, raw material, people, information. conflicting 'logics' in capitalist social formations is hl!man .1ab9ur
In capitalist economies, for example, the labourer and the capitalist p ower. The reproduction of the labour force is the knot where
1 64 New DirectiotlS it! Ecot!omic Authropology Social Reproductiotl 1 65
different 'logics' come together and surplus value is potentially p roduction process was phased out in part (non-commodified
generated. Because the worker is in a position that makes her/him: h ousework) while other parts (biological reproducti on) became
independendy incapable of generating or getting hold of the necessaries relevant, paradoxically, in relation to the circulation approach to the
of life , he/she must put himself in a dependent position in respect to valu e oflabour power. The second Ricardian approach Was linked to
a different group of people who hold the obj ective means of everyday the market, circulation and the eventual balance ofsupply and demand.
maintenance. In the classical model of capitalist social relations of B oth approaches, which were presumed to be articulated - not
production, the worker sells his labour power in order to survive, but m erged - for all other commodities through competition between
his labour, then, produces exchange value in excess of the equivalent p roducers, thus eventually bringing together market and production
market value of the use values necessary for his reproduction. This processes, were more difficult to link in the case ofhuman labour power.
surplus value appears to belong to those having acquired the use of Here , Malthus's population theory presented a solution simply by
labour power. And the use to which they put this acquired value will postulating:
determine their economic 'logic' . It is precisely because both 'logics' That the power of population is indefinitely greater than the p ower in earth
become part of the same movement that something like 'surplus to produce subsistence for man. Population, when unchecked, increases in
value' can be theoretically (not to say materially!) generated. a geometrical ratio. Subsistence increases only in an arithmetical ratio . . . . By

The key position of the reproduction of the labour force can also the law of our nature which makes food necessary to the life of man, the
be seen in the main theoretical problems confronted by classical effects of these two unequal powers must be kept equal. This implies a strong
economists such as Ricardo and Malthus. The value oflabour power and constantly operating check on population from the difficulty of subsistence.
- that is within what 'logic' it is generated - has always produced ( 1 982 [1 798] :71)
theoretical uncertainty; paradoxically, this expresses its theoretical Malthus's theory is in fact a theory ofdistribution ofpeople and food,
significance. When thinking of the value of labour power classical where two different powers, the law of human generation regulated
economists came to confront two very simple but basic issues: first, by the institution ofmarriage and the law offood production, regulated
what sort of exchange value could human labouring capacities have, by the institution of property, are permanendy brought into balance
being, as they are, a mere corollary of human life? And, second, how by 'the law of our nature which makes food necessary t o the life of
to think theoretically about 'production' of human life? man' . As soon as property and marriage are institute d in society
Ricardo postulated a double approach (as for all commodities) : one (conceived as a unique and universal condition) 'inequality of conditions
relating to the production process, the other to the circulation process. must necessarily follow' (1 982: 1 42) in order that, paradOXically, those
The first, natural price, was historically grounded in concrete who suffer from want might claim 'the surplus product of others, as
circumstances in the production oflabour power such as, for example, a debt ofjustice' (1 982: 1 43). H owever:
acquired life standards in a specific place and moment, the cost or
availability of food and other necessities - market or non-market the number of these claimants would soon exceed the ability o f the surplus
prod uce to supply . . . . And it seems bo th natural and just that, except upon
(Ricardo 1 959 [ 1 82 1 ]:7 1-83) . This also pointed the way to a political
partic ular occasions, their choice should fall upon those who w ere able, and
dimension where better standards could be gained by confronting
pro fessed themselves willing, to exert their strength in procu ring a further
capitalist classes (Picchio 1 992). The natural price or value was meant su rplu s produce; and drus at once benefiting their community, a n d enabling
to express the value of the labour power incorporated in its production the prop rietors to afford assistance to greater numbers. ( 1 982: 1 4 3)
process, that is in the means of subsistence necessary to reproduce the
labour power. There remained always, however, a mysterious and rather Malthus's theory is attractive because of its mechanical simplicity
tautological aspect that stemmed from the fact that while labour power based on natural -. therefore unquestionable - laws and quantitative
was postulated as a commodity and as such was presumed to be values that are firmly tied in an equation by the axiom of nature that
produced in much the same way as any other commodity, the effective food is necessary to human life. The equation leads to a supply and
1 66 New Directiotls itl ECOtlOmic Atlthropology Social Reproductiotl 1 67
demand balance which in tum feeds back into the demanders (offood) th us can become a universal equivalent for exchange then revealing
side (that is, destitute labourers) mechanically influencing the production exchange value.
of people, the reproduction of the labour force. Thus the value (price) How people confront need in concrete social and historical contexts,
oflabour power appears to be mechanically set by quantitative variations a nd how they have to spend their physical and intellectual energies
in the proportions offood and people. However, this theory is strongly in order to live, produce economic social relations. Specific social and
dependent on a specific a priori social distribution ofproperty and power: political circumstances give some people more control over their Own
the distribution of food between people concerns only 'surplus fo�d' Jnd others' livelihood, further driving people into different positions
- that remaining after the owners' own consumption has been met ­ in their attempt to reproduce life.
and 'all who were in want offood'. Moreover, it is obvious to Malthus Ultimately, the degree to which the maintenance oflife is controlled
that 'the owners of surplus produce', who are the ones to distribute by oneself (as an individual or as a member of a group) affects the degree
it amongst the needy and supernumerary hordes of claimants, will discard to which life-producing energy might be conceived a separable,
'moral merit' as 'a very difficult distinguishing criterion' and will 'in alienable and consumable apart from the self The attempt to explain
general seek some more obvious mark of distinction' and thus it is how life is produced as labour and how labour can reproduce life is
'natural and just' that they select those willing 'to exert their strength the attempt to understand the particular way a society is reproduced
in procuring a further surplus produce' (1 982: 1 43) . What is important by its members materially and ideologically.
in Malthus and his followers is that they present their views as scientific
'laws of nature' and that they subsume the problem of the nature of
The tleedJor a wider theoreticalframework: toward social reproductiOtI
labour power to a simplistic supply and demand theory of value
formation in an ahistorical context. Where Ricardo tries to deal with
Going back to the standard division of the economic process into
the social and historical issues affecting the value of labourpower
production/distribution/ circulation/ consumption, it is interesting to
through the reproduction of the labour force, therefore leaving the
note the many relations between people that directly affect material
door open to the eventual analysis and theoretical integration of the livelihood and have consistently been left out of the picture or
reproduction of the labour force into the labour theory of value, reintroduced by forcing them to fit into old frameworks. Things get
Malthus ignores the problem by rendering a priori and universal the better when the whole movement of production and reproduction
relations ofproduction reproduced in distribution through the existence of the relations ofproduction is taken into account: to witness, Marx's
of groups of suppliers and groups of demanders (of food) and by chapter 2 in the 'Prologue' to the Cotltributiotl to the Critique if Political
shifting the attention to a further distribution between 'demanders' Economy (1 970l-: 247-68) where he points to the dialectical relationship
of a particular 'fund' of food. This view in fact obscures relations of between what he sees as different moments of a totality that he terms
production atld relations of distribution. 'production'. Production in this global sense, however, includes not
The reproduction of the labour force is the linchpin between the only production in its restricted sense as a particular moment of the
use value and exchange value 'logics' , between life and accumulation. en tire process, but also distribution, circulation and consumption as
Productive consumption and personal consumption, for example, distinct moments of the total process that are tied into reciprocal
come together in the reproduction of the labour force: what is personal relationships. In this �omplex web ofdialectical construction of a unit,
consumption for labourers is productive consumption for employers: nevertheless, the relationships between people in the moment of
income as costs. On the other hand, in the framework of any labour production deterrrllne the forms and the reciprocal relationships of the
theory of value (classical or Marxian) living labour is the ultimate use ?ifferent moments (1 970b:267). There is in Marx an idea that production
value, that which creates and is incorporated in all other produced use :s th e expression of the entire economic process. For example:
values, that which can be abstracted in a general exchange context and consumption as a need is an internal moment of the productive
1 68 New DirectiOtls iH Economic Anthropology Social Reproduction 1 69
activity, but the latter is the point of departure of its realisation and, relations and housework is the most salient, that relationships other
therefore, its foremost moment, the act in which the entire process is th an the labour/capital one must be explained as fundamental parts
resolved anew' (1970b:26o-1). 'But in society the relationship between of the social reproduction process of capitalist societies. What is now
the producer and the product, as soon as the latter is finished, is purely more and more obvious for Western capitalist societies has always been
external, and the comeback of the product to the individual depends perceived as present (by Marx and others) in pre-capitalist societies
on his relationships with other individuals' (1 970b:261 ). And these and capitalist social formations. It is then the spirit, but not the letter,
relationships are determined by the previous production processes. Social of Marx's social reproduction concept that I would like to make the
reproduction, for Marx, is the reproduction of the conditions necessary starting point of a useful, global, concept ofsocial motion in 'economic'
for a particular form of production to take place. anthropology.
In fact, social reproduction in this sense is close to his concept of
distribution (not so much ofproducts but of the means of production
and the allocation of people to different positions in production) SOC IAL REPRODUCTION
(1 970b: 263). This distribution is the basis of the process ofproduction.
But it is not a pre-given natural fact: it is the outcome of previous, The dialectics of the material atld the ideological
historical, production processes and the transformations within them
(1 970b:264). Social reproduction is perceived as the replacement of In a much quoted paragraph Marx (1 970c [1859] :37) states clearly that
things and people in a particular framework of relationships that the sum total of these relations of production constitute the economic
enables the production process to continue (Capital Vol. II, Ch. 20) . structure of society, the real base , on which rises a legal and political
Marx's view is interesting because of his historical formulation of superstructure and to which correspond definite forms of social consciousness.
the reproduction process and because he clearly ties the concept to The mode of production of material life, conditions the social, political and
the social relations instituting differential allocation of resources to intellectual life process in general. It is not the consciousness of men that
people. The problem for us, is that Marx studies social reproduction determines their being, but, on the contrary, their social being that determines
as the necessary movement of value and matter between the sectors their consciousness.
of capitalist production (production of means of production and This and other passages of his work have been used to construct
production of means of consumption) in order for the system to be the base/superstructure theoretical model, where the economic
able to continue at the same pace - simple reproduction - or at an structure determines consciousness and other social and institutional
increasing pace - enlarged reproduction. Production is very narrowly relations. While this interpretation has been advocated by orthodox
defined as industrial production where all workers sell their labour power Marxists, and, with some qualifications and a theoretical emphasis by
to the owners of the means ofproduction, and where only commodities Althusser and his school (Althusser 1 969, 1 974; Balibar 1 969; for a
are taken into account as values and matter being replaced . But this critique of these views see E.P. Thompson 1 978), a thorough and wide­
is not the capitalist world, at least not as we can perceive it nowadays. ranging reading of Marx's work (and that of Engels) puts his words
If 'classical' industrial labour/capital relationships may yet be in a different light. In his Philosophical WritiHgs of 1 844 (Marx 1 970a),
extrapolated to an ample (maybe dominant) part of the production his letter to Annenkov (1 846) and Theses Otl Feuerbach (1 845) (all in
process, it seems a fundamental flaw to present them as the only Marx and Engels 1 97 � , in The Germatl Ideology (Marx and Engels 1 992
relationships to be taken into account (together with capital/capital [1845-6]) The Misery of Philosophy (Marx 1 950 [1 846-7]), and in
relations) in capitalist social reproduction processes . We have seen, for En gels 's Ludwig Feuerbach atld the Erld of Classical Germatl Philosophy
example, that many resources do not circulate as commodities but are (1 886) and his letter to Bloch (1 890) (both in Marx and Engels 1 975) ,
nonetheless allocated in ways that are significant for the positions of but also in Marx's more 'mature' Grundrisse (1972 [1859]), in the 'Formen'
individuals within society. We have also seen, and the case of gender part (that on pre-capitalist social formations), we find a view that differs
1 70 New Directions in Economic Anthropology Social ReproductioH 171
widely from the orthodox rendering. In fact it is in this last work Feu erbach, I I ) and that historical materialism should go beyond
(Grundrisse) where, I think (unlike E.P. Thompson) , his idea becomes 'c ontemplative materialism', that is, beyond 'a materialism that does
clearest, in his discussion about the objective conditions of work and not con ceive the activity of the senses as practical activity . .' ( Theses
.

the subjective social being of the individual where he stresses the on Feu erbach, IX, in Marx and Engels 1 975:427-8). Marx's position is
separation of these aspects as a product of history which is only completed 'th at human essence is not something abstract inherent to each
in the relationship between wage labour and capital (1 972:35 1-8). If in dividual. It is, in its reality, the sum qf social relations' (Theses on
we add to this his constant emphasis on approaching real life as opposed Fet/ erbach, VI, my emphasis, Marx and Engels 1 975:427) . Social life is
to idealist positions (such as that ofProudhon) constructing society in /lIl/l1 ml practice and our objective is to understand this practice (Theses
the image of a previously constructed theoretical model and, foremost, 011 Feuerbach, VIII).

his refusal to separate being and consciousness (although dijferer!tiating Third, also, Marx puts forward the idea that in real social practice
them) (1 970a [1 844] : 1 43, 1 45-7) we get a slightly different picture. capitalism operates a separation between the subjective being and the
It is Marx's emphasis on the production and reproduction of real life '
objective conditions for the production oflife, as well as an alier!ation
and his struggle against idealist philosophers that we should recall. of consciousness from the process of production of life. Thus the
In the 1 844 manuscripts he presents a broad idea of human work separation of ideal and material appears not as 'natural' or inherent in
as 'vital activity': a conscious and material process that is the 'practical humanity, but instead as a product of an historical process ( Theses on
production of an objective world' which is 'the assertion of man as a Fwerbac/z, IV; Grundrisse 1 972:352-6, 368) .
conscious generic being' (1 970a: 1 1 1-12) and, further, he points out Fourth, stemming from this, it is argued that the ideologies of
that it is precisely the alienation of work in capitalist relations that capitalism tend to reify abstract categories whether in political economy
transfonns work into a mere medium to satisfy need instead of it being or religion, etc. And against this, in his study of a concrete social
the direct material and spiritual process of need satisfaction formation, there is an emphasis on the primacy of real social relations
(1 970a: 1 09-13). through the focus on the objective conditions for the production of
In the Grundrisse, this same problem is discussed i n a more elaborate life, now limited to bare material production, industrial production.
form in the Former! (a section on pre-capitalist social formations), In this light, the idea of a correspondence/determination between
where the presumed historical process of the 'freeing' oflabour from the production of material life and forms of social consciousness
social and material ties in turn is related to the use value/exchange appears as a (clumsy) way to stress the materiality of social life in an
value logics and to the dissolution of the social relations bound to use abstract model of a concrete capitalist social fonnation where work
value production. It is the same problem and the answer is in a similar has been alienated and social being divided into mere material practices
way tied to a historical, a real process, of separation of the 'objective (that is, work for wages as a medium to obtain subsistence) and 'other'
conditions' from the 'subjective social being' : the separation and spiritual practices necessary for the 'practical production of an objective
confrontation of the people involved in producing real life world'. Although in this famous passage of1 859 a sequence of causation
(1 972:368-74). We should then, I think, bear in mind that in the is clearly stated, there is a continuous reference to social relations as the
base/superstructure passage quoted at the beginning of this chapter, locus of movement and transformation, of process, that is, 'real life' .
several different statements are merged together. Productive forces are the result of previous social relations and not
First, Marx advances a theoretical debate against idealism and presents the autonomous forc� they appear to be in this passage. And social
historical materialism ('the production and reproduction of real life' , relations are the practical, real, materialist expression ofhuman activity
Engels 1 975 [1 890] :520) as the only way to approach human society. for the production and reproduction of real life.
Second, it is asserted that the process ofproduction includes 'social Moreover, in an interesting passage ofthe GruHdrisse on 'reproduction'
production' of consciousness and of ideologies such as religion ( Theses ( 1 972 :329-30), social relations (and, explicitly, rIOt products) appear
Ml Feuerbach, VII) . That thought is only real 'in practice' ( Theses OH as the main result of the production and valorisation process, namely
172 New DirectiotlS iH EcoHomic AHthropology Social ReproductioH 1 73
in capitalist formations, the relationship between the capitalist and the and again Gramsci fights mechanicism and monism both materialistic
worker. 'This social relation of production is a more important result and idealistic, whether he speaks ofthe 'relations offorce' and the various
of this process than its material fruits' (1972:330, see also 377-8). Marx, ec ono mic and political levels at which relations offorce are generated
in fact, criticises political economists for stressing the 'things produced' and expressed (1987 : 1 80--5) or whether he speaks of the philosophy
as opposed to the relationships produced. He highlights the production of praxis 'the identity of contraries in the concrete historical act, that
of relationships between people. That is, real lije, while the emphasis on is in human activity (history-spirit) in the concrete, indissolubly
things and relations among things appears very clearly defined in the connected with a certain organised (historicised) "matter" and with
chapter of'Commodity Fetishism' (Capital, Vol. I) as an ideal abstraction the transformed nature ofman' (1 987:372) . Gramsci's intent is, clearly,
of a specific human practice, an abstraction of concrete social relations to understand 'the real dialectical process' (1 987:36 6) in order to
between real people. 'j ustify a particular practical activity, or initiative of will' (1 987: 1 85),
For Marx, then, social relations, the result ofpractical activity which that is, in order to help in the construction of a self-aware political
includes consciousness, are the focus of his analysis. And it is only in (subaltern) force: 'the essential task is that ofsystematically and patiently
capitalism that matter and consciousness are confronted as different ens uring that this force is formed, developed, and rendered ever more
aspects of life. Marx is not clear, though, if this is an appearance or a homogeneous, compact and self-aware' (1987:185), ready for political
reality, and this is probably because, in his dialectical thinking, action when the moment arrives. And, for Gramsci, culture, together
mystification is both. with historical understanding which can be thought of as a different
expression of the same process, is the glue of 'practical (collective)
activity' and 'an historical act can only be performed by "collective
The Marxist tradition and 'economic aHthropology ': Gramsci, Williams, man" and this presupposes the attainment of a "cultural-social" unity
ThompsMl, Bourdieu, Godelier through which a multiplicity of dispersed wills, with heterogeneous
aims are welded together with a single aim' opera ting not only
Some writers in the Marxist tradition have tried to develop precisely intellectually, but also emotionally (1 987:349, c£ also p.4 13). What
this strand of Marx's thought: the tension between matter and ideas ' is interesting in Gramsci's thought is that it emerges from concrete,
which is resolved in human practice (material, historical, conscious). practical involvement with Italian politics, that is, with 'real life' and
Gramsci is perhaps the first to expand his thought in this direction. the struggle for change. It is his attempt to understand history from
His preoccupation is always related to history, to political action, to the viewpoint of the practical experience of real politics and present­
the role of the state as 'educator' , 'acting on economic forces, day strategies for action, that in a sense forces him to look at what in
reorganising and developing the apparatus of economic production, " effect moves people to action. In this light, material/ideal or
creating a new structure' (Gramsci 1 987 [1 929-35]:247). Although , structure/superstructure distinctions may be considered analytical
Gramsci maintains the analytical distinction of structure - that is, ' tools but can never be constructed, in real life, as a mechanistic
material forces and relations of production - and superstructure - '" projection of an external, abstract, linear, causal direction , but only as
political, juridical and political forces - his repeated statements are very a necessary reciprocity in a dialectical process, constantly (re)setting
clear as to the unity of structure and superstructure in history (that is, ' limits and producing-pressures from within the dynamics of process
'real life'). Time and again he expresses the concept of the 'historical , (Thompson 1978: 1 59-60).
bloc' where material and ideological forces are welded in practice which . Following and further developing a certain strand of Marx's and
is always political activity of different sorts: the fight for hegemonies Gramsci's thoughts, R. Williams and E.P. Thompson reintroduce into
in 'civil society' - cultural, moral, ethical; the struggle of a subaltern the academic disciplines of the social sciences and/or the humanities
group to press claims against the multiple coercions of 'political society' (cultural materialism, history, anthropology) the idea of real people as
- punitive force, law - (Gramsci 1 987 : 1 2 , 52, 1 80--3, 242-4) . Time ' SU bj ects /agents of history as opposed to the Althusserian abstract
174 New Directiorls in Economic Arzthropology Socia l Reproduction 1 75
notion of people as supports of functions determined by 'the structure points to (taking up Marx' s early writings) is that the separation of
of the relations of production' (Althusser 1 969: 1 94; Balibar 1 969:226). 'e c onomic' social relations and processes from the areas of' culture' and
In Williams and in Thompson human experierlce becomes the focus ' morality' , more generally of consciousness, as being something pre­
(as opposed to 'structure' or 'economy'), and within 'experience' the existing or preconscious is itselfpart of bourgeois utilitarian ideology.
objective and the subjective, matter and consciousness, are indivisible
Th e good old utilitarian notio n that all facts are quantifiable and measurable
and may obstruct knowledge when they appear as idealist reifications
(and hence can be ingested by a computer), and that whatever is not measurable
(Thompson 1 978:97, 1 7 1 , 1 75-6; Williams 1 977:75-82). Experience is not a fact, is alive and kicking and in possession of a large part of the Marxist
is a material process but one where we must think not only of the tra dition . And yet, what cannot be measured has had some very measurable
material production of maintenance but also of the material production material consequences. . . . Values are neither 'thought' nor 'hailed', they are
of a social and political order and of a cultural order without which li ved, and they arise within the same nexus of material life and material relations
the material production of life would be impossible. Experience is a as do our ideas. They are the necessary norms, rules, expectations, etc.,
process of forming and transforming social relations in the everyday learned (and 'learned' within feeling) within the 'habitus' of living; and
context of production, of politics, of culture and of the personal, learned, in the first place within the family, at work, and within the immediate
intimate, family environment. Experience is at once an individual process community. Without this learning social life could not be sustained, and all
and a social process and both are also indivisible in human societies. production would cease. ( 1 978: 1 75)
For Williams (1 984 [ 1 961] :55), communication of descriptions of the Bourdieu's concept of'habitus', that Thompson uses, is yet another
relationships between people and with the environment is fundamental attempt to understand the production of practice as a result of the
for human associative life, that is, life in a community. And this 'effort pressures and limitations that the structuration of previous experience
ofieaming, description and communication' (1 984:54) permeates the inflicts upon action. The 'habitus' is an interiorisation in the 'structures
whole social process with a creative drive: ofperception' ofthe exterior objective structures of ' concrete conditions
Communication is the process of making unique experience into common of existence'. It is then an individual but social structure, for it
experience, and it is, above ali, the claim to live. For what we basically say, incorporates individually what are social relations of (re)production
in any kind of communication is: 'I am living in this way because this is my ofmaterial life. As an individual 'scheme ofperception' it enables creative
experience' . . . . Since our way of seeing things is literally our way ofliving, practice, but as a social structure it sets limits and exerts pressures to
the process of communication is in fact the process ofcommunity: the sharing
conform to a certain 'logic' inscribed in 'reasonable' action:
of common meanings, and thence common activities and purposes; the
offering, reception and comparison of new meanings leading to the tensions A product of history, the 'habitus' produces individual and collective practices,
and achievements of growth and change. ( 1 984:55) and therefore history in accordance with the schemes engendered by history.
The 'habitus' assures the active presence of past experiences that, placed in
Consciousness here appears as a material expression of experience - every organism in the form of schemes ofperception, of thought and ofaction,
giving meaning to soc;ial relations in real life - and as a material force, better than any formal rule or explicit norm, tend to guarantee the conformity
exerting pressures leading to change. of practices and their continuity through time. (Bourdieu 1 980:91)
What is important in this view (and E.P. Thompson insists on it) is
that 'ideology', 'values', 'feeling', the realm of social consciousness as Once again, 'experience', 'practice' and 'process' in human societies
well as that ofmoral consciousness, are not some autonomous creation call for a dialectical understanding of matter and consciousness, of
of the mind, are not imposed upon material, necessary (that is, 'real life'.
'production') social relations, but are themselves materially produced But what, then, ofthe 'economy', ofthe pertinence ofhighlighting
in the various contexts of human life and all of it joins in a 'distinctive production from within the reproduction of 'real' , material life? In an
class experience' (1 978: 1 70-5) which is a fundamental part of the interesting article Godelier ( 1 978) attempts to free himself from
historical processes for reproducing human societies. What Thompson Althusserian structuralism and from vulgar economism (see also
176 New Directiorzs in Economic Arlthropology Social Reproductiorl 1 77
Godelier 1 984). He states very clearly that 'the distinction between eth nic identities, shadow work and informal circulatio n of resources,
base and superstructure is not one of levels or instances nor of . work vs. employment, etc.
institutions . . . . It is in its principle a distinction offunctions' (1978 : 157). More integrative explanations are then needed in order to drive our
However, there exists a 'hierarchy of functions' of social relations in
atte ntion toward social relations - that is, matter, ideas and
order to reproduce any society and: com munication in between real historical people - that produce and
reproduce real life. And in fact 'production' is j ust one more inroad
the social relations that are 'determinant in the last instance' are always those
that function as relations of production; because they function as relations of toward the understanding of the 'whole material social process'
production they dominate the reproduction of society and hence the repre­ constructed in an endless movement ofhuman practice and experience,
sentations that organise and express them also dominate. ( 1 978: 1 69) an d the struggle for change, which is history.
When we think, then, of a more integrative and processual model
Nevertheless, causality, determination, is not linear:
for 'economic anthropology', one that will help us confront what meets
the relation of causality that emerges is that of a hierarchy betweefljUflctiofls that our ethnographic experience and our empirical data, a model, moreover
exist sil1wltafleously afld presuppose each other. . . ( 1 978: 1 67) that remains resolutely attached to material matters, we think of a

In this same article Godelier very nicely detaches 'superstructure' concept of social reproduction in its full, complex and interlocking sense.

from the connotations of ideal construction and highlights the ideal


content of any material social relation and in particular of social
relations of production (1978: 1 57, 1 61-2). But why, then, should the Space, culture and capitalism: material relations irl cultural corltexts
social relations that function to produce objects (and, crucially, to
reproduce themselves as a social order of access to means and power) In thinking of social reproduction, we must be careful, however, not
have precedence over those that produce people? In his work, empirical to imply that the objective of a society is to reproduce itself, to maintain
and theoretical, Godelier solves the issue by stating that in most a certain order of things, to perpetuate a concrete form of organisation.
primitive societies kinship social relations have the function of social By personalising society we fall in fact into a functional organicist,
relations of production (this is close to Marx's view in the Grurzdrisse). harmonious image, where different limbs with different roles serve
The problem is that the analysis of what appears to occur in capitalist together a unique purpose decided by the head. In so doing we
social formations - the separation of an economic area of ,production' - obscure the possibility of dissent and conflict between groups. By
becomes reified here as a separate universal 'function' of social relations. presupposing perpetuation as the aim of the social body we also
They are no longer seen as a 'level' or 'instance' of material substance, preclude the viability of rupture, of radical change or the mere
for social relations are at once constituted in the material and the ideal, construction of alternative ways of life and of thinking within a
but still as a separate 'function' in theory. dominant hegemony. Counter-hegemonies, that is, cultural constructiorzs
We have seen, ho �ever, that in trying to explain 'economic' social · capable of creating cohesion among a large group of (dominated) people
relations - of production, distribution, circulation and consumption - and of supporting organised action in order to press claims and confront
we are time and again·driven toward power and culture, coercion and th e hegemonic (dominant) group, appear then as strange bodies that
hegemony, force and meaning. As Williams puts it, the production should either be 'assimilated' (that is, digested and incorporated) or
of a social, political and cultural order (together with [industrial] des troyed, with 'integration' as a middle term where a group is
production) are 'real practice s , elements of a whole material process' pe rmitted to keep some non-threatening identity signs as long as it
(1977:93-4) and hence they keep breaking the 'economic' orderfrom . fully submits to the basic hegemonic claims. Nationalism is a case in
withirl, introducing old issues in a new light, forcing in new questions p oint, where the cultural construction of a social body has a political
such as housework and the sexual division of labour, migrations and · ai m but is also tied to concrete relations of production. If we take the
178 New Directions in Economic Attthropology Social Reproductioll
179
example of Catalan nationalism we can see how capitalist relations of Sp anish seap�rts) , enabled Catalan merchants to directly engage
production relate to space and to cultural contexts in history. . in
c ommerce wah the Amen can colonies. Catalan industrial products
Although in the Catalan area one could trace back cultural, political (cotton and wool textiles) and commercial agricultural produce (spirits)
and economic historical processes that diverged from those of the gained most from the new market privileges, and capital began to
Castilian hegemonic rule, it would be an anachronism to speak of accumulate that was invested in the consolidation of industry (Soldevila
Catalan nationalism before the nineteenth century. Catalan nationalism 1978; Vilar 1 982 [1 962] ; Nadal 1 979). The loss of most of the colonies
is tied in with the surge of the German Romantic movement and the at the turn of the nineteenth century was a strong blow to the Catalan
search for roots in popular folklore, in history and in common law textile industry which exported around 20 per cent of its production.
(Prats 1 988). It appears as the search for a specific 'character' defining This focused the interests ofindustrial capitalists on the national market
Catalan nature and spirit. But Catalan nationalism is also very strongly
(Nadal 1 979; Vicens Vives 1 986). Against the ground of the nineteenth­
tied to the Enlightenment version of a nation of citizens, a free society
century political unrest (Napoleonic invasion, War of Indepen dence,
of men all of whom have equal rights within the boundaries of the
Absolutist Restora tion, Liberal and Conserv ative uprising s and
nation-space they have agreed to share. The idea of a free, voluntary,
constitutions, several Civil Wars, the First Republic, the Restorat ion,
cot/tract with a community of others that will then constitute a political
the loss of the last colonies in 1 898 . . . ) the Catalan bourgeoisie tried
body with power to govern itself is present in most strands of political
Catalanism although not with a consistent meaning. There is also a to further its interests, sometimes in conflicting ways. Generally,
very interesting economic component of the rise of Catalan nationalism, during the nineteenth century the aim of the Catalan bourgeoisie was
albeit not a simple obvious relationship but a complex one. to influence the central Spanish governments in two vital areas: with
The Catalan area emerged as a meaningful political unit with the regard to the resolution of the 'social problem' and to the preservation
first inroads gained to the south of the Pyrenees in Islamic Iberia in of the markets (the last colonies, the national market) . This is the
the ninth century. The territories rescued for Christendom in the name background of the emergence of nationalist ideologies in Catalonia.
of the Holy Emperor Charlemagne were under the jurisdiction ofstrong Here I will try to show the differences and similarities of the several
feudal lords, the Counts. Soon the Counts freed themselves from the nationalist ideologies, their bourgeois drive during the nineteenth
vassal link to the Frankish king while they consolidated and institu­ and early twentieth centurie s, their open confrontation with the
tionalised their feudal structure in the Usatges, a written code growing internationalist proletarian ideologies from the 1 870s to 1 936,
(Valls-Taberner 1 954). The following centuries saw the play of dynastic and the union of the left and bourgeois nationalist democrats under
alliances and military expansion that enabled Catalan merchants to a Catalan nationali st ideology during Franco's dictatorship.
control commerce in the Western Mediterranean. At the same time, The first move toward a nationalist cultural awareness was inspired
local political institutions were taking form. In the fifteenth century by German Romanti cism and addressed the recupera tion of the
a dynastic change gave the rule to a Castilian king and henceforth the Catalan language, folklore and literature and the construction of a
Catalan polity was under constant pressure from the Castilian monarchs' Catalan history. PolitiCally, this first romantic drive seems to have been
drive toward political expansion and hegemonic rule. This loss of liberal and constitutionalist but soon it turned toward a conservative
autonomy was resisted constantly and sometimes violently (1 640 War historical particularism that stressed the volkgeist, the national spirit of
of Secession; 1705-14 War of Succession). Under the Bourbon dynasty the Catalan people (ViCens Vives 1 986: 1 71-5). This romantic definition
(1 714 onward) the Catalan region lost most of the particular institutions a nd description of the Catalan 'soul' was institutionalised by the
it still maintained and was intensely Castilianised. Economically, University of Barcelona in its teaching, by several local newspapers
however, this situation opened the interior markets to Catalan products printe d in Catalan and by the inauguration in 1 859 of a Literary
and from 1 778 up to the loss of the Spanish colonies in Latin America, C ontest of medieval inspiratio n: the Jocs Florals (Flower Games) .
the royal privilege given to the port of Barcelona (shared with other None ofthese movements could be considered 'nationalist' ofthemselves
1 80 New Directiotls in Ecotzomic Atzthropology Social Reproductiotl 181
because there was not yet a clear drive toward a political identity, toward whic h conceived of inequality a s a natural institution by God's will.
a project of self-government. (Trias 1 975: 1 70).
The emergence of political nationalism proper in Catalonia is tied They represented an enlightened bourgeoisie that clamoured for
to the Spanish political events that led to the fall in 1 868 of the
in vidual liberty as a necessary framework for political and economic
di
reigning monarch, Isabel II, and soon after to the advent of the First
transformation. The aim was a bourgeois revolution that could be
Republic. During the first half of the century the Catalan industrial
capable of attracting workers into a project ofcooperative, harmonious
bourgeoisie had wavered between its support for liberal and conservative
relations between labour and capital. But the model of workers'
governments (Balcells 1 992) . Liberals brought up reforms that were
asso ciations they had in mind was more that of the ancierl regime
needed for capitalist and industrial development such as the disentailment corporations than that of the new post-revolutio nary workers'
laws (especially in the 1830s) that broke traditional links between peasants associations (Trias 1 975: 1 68; Sewell 1 980).
and feudal or ecclesiastic lords, creating a 'free' workforce and privatising An important faction ofthe Catalan Federalists became progressively
jurisdictional, monastic and municipal properties. Conservatives on estranged from what they saw as a 'rationalist' institutional concept of
the other hand, used militarist policies to restore social order, disrupted the federal state on the part of Spanish Federalists, as opposed to their
by the numerous strikes and revolutionary outbursts. Moreover, feudal 'historical' and 'natural' definition of the Catalan state (Almirall in Trias
landlords and the Church in rural Catalonia supported mostly the arldetl 1 975:433-52). By 1 882, after the Bourbon restoration and the
regime with its absolutist, traditionalist hierarchies, but also with its 'fueros', installation of conservative and liberal alternation in government,
or local special privileges that regulated the maintenance of agreements, Alrnirall and his followers decided to forgo all participation in 'Madrid'
tenancies and leaseholds between peasant and lord for generations, and (sic) political parties and to concentrate on 'Catalan politics'. The call
included a common law regulating social relations of production for the second Catalanist Congress (1883), organised by Alrnirall's Centre
within the peasant copyholder's household. CataIa (founded in 1 882), declared its aim as 'to give birth to genuine
Thus, after the economic and subsistence crises that precipitated the Catalan politics' but this 'politics of identity' was based on the
advent of the First Republic there were at least three different proto­ homogenisation of all other possible differences that might express
nationalist currents representing different groups of Catalans, with conflict and diversity of interests within Catalonia. The Centre Catala
different strategies regarding Catalonia and the rest of Spain, yet never seeks to unite 'Catalans of all religious or political ideas, it wants to
dissociating them in political action. be formed by all those whose interest is the regeneration of our
First, there was a group of Federalist Republican Democrats in characte r and the betterment of our land, whatever their social
Catalonia. These were liberal intellectuals inspired by democratic condition' (Almirall et al. in Trias 1 975:323).
federal countries such as the USA or Switzerland and with a real interest In fact, by the 1 870s workers in Catalonia were mostly internationalists
in the 'modernisation' of Catalonia but also of Spain more generally. and revolutionary, and were not interested in participating in the
The idea of its main exponent, Almirall, was that of a Catalan state bourgeois political game, which, they argued, did not intend to
freely choosing to forge a political relationship with other equal states. radic ally transform their situation. Their aim was to get the workers
For him, however, and this was the distinctive element of Catalan organised and to make a revolution that would collectivise the means
Federalism, the state was the significant political unit, as opposed to of production. By 1 873 internationalist workers were explicitly and
the disaggregation of multiple free-standing politically equivalen� strongly opposing the m:ftn 'progressive' formula that the democratic
levels of contract such as the municipality or even the individual (PI bou rge oisie was presenting as the eventual solution to the social
i Margall 1 854, 1 973 [ 1 876]). problem: production cooperatives. The argument was that cooperatives
lured workers into becoming individualists and bourgeois, and distanced
In the labour relations domain they present a liberal attitude with full
them from their real aim - putting an end to capitalist
recognition ofworkers' associations as opposed to the paternalism and author- exploitation -
, and from their real means: a workers' union,
itarianism that dominated both Catalan bourgeoisie and Spanish conservatism . 'solidary, federative,
1 82 New Directions in Economic Social Reproduction 1 83
'
international' (Izard 1 979: 186-7) . Workers asserted clearly their aims
. ec onomy as a whole (in fact addressing the interests of large estate
and means and their estrangement from the Catalan democratic , lan downers in the south). In effect, the 'Catalan' protectionist project
federalist project of 1 883 (Trias 1 975:453-4). , was to preserve the 'Spanish' national market and the colonies that
"
Second, there was a group of monarchic, conservative, anti-liberal we re left (Cuba and the Philippines) for the Catalan industries. And,
bourgeoisie, mainly concerned with social unrest and very willing to on the other hand, as Izard has pointed out 'all Catalans were not
ask for the state's military repression in order to keep Catalonia calm. protectionists, neither was all of the rest ofSpain a free-trade supporter'
After the brief revolutionary and republican interlude during the last (1 9 79:97). Moreover, and this seems especially significant, the largest
quarter of the nineteenth century, their main interest was to ban or . workers' association in 1 874 ' Tres Clases de Vapor', very clearly stated
' that they were not interested in the protectionistlfree trade debate
restrict workers' freedom of association, to enforce law and order, to
res�rict the privilege of political rights to the bourgeoisie by opposing-, because 'there is no important difference between workers' situation
umversal male suffrage. They were also interested in keeping the in the countries with free-trade as compared with those that live

Catalan civil law that established and regulated social relations of ! where protectionism reigns. Therefore, for the working class, these
production within the family household (the casa) , by creating both ' are not such essential questions as it is pretended' (in Izard 1 979:97).
?iffere�tiation and strong ties between the members of a domestic group In fact, the moderate free trade agreements of 1 869 were not detrimental

In relatIOn to the ownership and use of the means of production. The to cotton industrialists. The Tres Clases de Vapor in 1 874 hints at a possible
Catalan civil law was the institution that preserved a certain ideological relationship between capitalists' perpetual lamentation against the
and material fabric ofrelationships organising the economy in agriculture wrongs of free trade and their drive to lengthen working hours and
and in industry (McDonogh 1 989; Terradas 1 984). Conservatives, but withhold pay increases: workers asserted that since the free trade
not only them, feared the trend of central governments (especially liberal agreements 'the industry has improved and developed a lot' (in Izard
ones) toward a unified Spanish Civil Code. And last, but not least, 1 979: 1 17). Catalan historians such as Vicens Vives (1 986) also think
they were very strongly protectionist with regard to their industries. that free trade benefited Catalan industry as a whole. The protectionist
They feared and opposed the free trade policies of the Restoration's argument, however, was the main element in the construction of a
'liberal' governments, as they had done before, in 1 869, with the 'Catalan' economic identity for the conservative bourgeoisie.
introduction of free-trade agreements by the liberal revolutionary Finally, there was a group of extremely traditionalist Catholic
governments. The Catalan industrialists, through their two main absolutists. These were mainly landlords, peasants and the Church. They
associations - the Instituto Irldustrial de Cataluiia of the large cotton were strongly anti-liberal: they fought for an authoritarian social
manufacturers and the Fometlto de la Produccion Nacional, smaller semi­ structure based on the primeval organic order ofthe 'family' mediated
artisanal cotton, wool and silk manufacturers - tried to present the by the Church and guarded by the King who would protect the
argument for 'protection' as a unified social project to protect work 'traditional' order but should not alter it (Millin 1 99 1 : 1 9) . They
through the protection of industry from foreign competition. In the fought against individual autonomy, against the idea of an egalitarian
first massive demonstration organised by the Fomento in 1 869 there basis for a contractual political and economic structure. But they did
were men of very different political affiliations (liberal, conservative, Hot fight against capitalism, an economic project geared to market
republican, even some workers' representatives) (Trias 1 975:62-3, 131). production and capital accumulati on. Landlords and the Church
In 1881 another set ofmovements against free trade policies were said wanted to retain eCCJl10mic privileges attached to their position in the
to 'unite' all Catalans - conservatives, liberals, republicans, industrialists, 'traditional' order. These privileges were threatened mainly by the
landlords and workers - in defence ofprotectionist measures (Termes disentailment policies of the liberal governments, but landlords mostly
and Colomines 1 992:69-70). It is interesting to note, however, that, managed to transform 'privileges ' into 'private property' rights.
on the one hand the conservative bourgeoisie was very insistent on Privileges, however, were never only economic . In the rural areas of
presenting its protectionist arguments as beneficial for the SparIish inland Catalonia, this traditionalist, Catholic, anti-liberal movement

hn
1 84 New Directions in Economic Anthropology Social ReproductioH 1 85
had strong support not only among landowners, fanners, sharecroppers, it c ould be easily found .But, more interesting, it was difficult to find
priests, monks and nuns, but also among landless labourers and putting­ it in large areas of southern Catalonia (Catalullya Nova) (Prat 1 989) .
out cottagers. This has been explained by the diverse pressures exerted The Church adjusted its traditional fundamentalism to fit a conservative
during the nineteenth century by disentailment, subsistence crises, the form : it presented regionalism as a natural unit as opposed to the anti­
rise of the factory organisation, increased taxation, and general insecurity natural liberal state that pretended to impose itself on domestic,
brought up not only by economic conjunctures and transfonnations, religious and communal life. The liberal centralising state, with its
but mostly by the liberal disruption (without a clear alternative) of the uniformist trend, was seen as the first step towards egalitarianism and
personal social links and reciprocal moral duties of an order that socialism, the worst menace. The idea was to reinstall or preserve the
sustained livelihood. It is important to emphasise, with Terradas Catholic values of an organic hierarchy, duty, resignation and charity
(1 984:268-9) , that the material and the cultural order of the Catalan � in civil life, not only in the rural areas where this movement had
family farm (casa, or masia) , its institution of an only heir to the originated, but also in the industrialised centres where the social
patrimony, its creation of a dense and differentiated set of relationships probkm was getting out of hand and workers were successfully
between kin and neighbours and affines can help explain the situation. organising confrontation in tenns of clear-cut, economic, international
'The work relations in the world of masies [Catalan family farms1 were class distinctions.
not perceived as relations between two classes of people clearly Torras i Bages, perhaps the main exponent of the Church's regionalist
differentiated' (1984:269) because the non-inheriting brothers and sisters programme, said among other things that 'to defend property and
usually worked as sharecroppers or servants of propertied neighbours industry, today under menace, to light the flame of discreet charity
or affines: that soothes the rough relations between owners and workers . . .this
is the straight and secure road to regionalism' (in Tennes and Colomines
Agricultural servants lived in peasant houses that had the same interests as that
of their own parents and with a way of working where obedience could not 1992: 1 26). This, in fact was a regionalised strategy in line with the
be separated from contract nor loyalty from responsibility, nor - and this might official 'Social Doctrine' of the Church that Leo XIII proposed from
be the most important - ingratitude from revolt . . . (Terradas 1 984:268) . 1 878 onwards in several Papal Encyclicals. 'Socialism, communism,
nihilism' were a 'mortal cancer' that was putting society in mortal danger.
This does not mean that conflicts could not and did not materialise,
It had to be stopped. Re-instilling the Catholic doctrine was the only
or that landless labourers or cottagers mechanically participated in the
real solution that the liberal constitutional states had sinfully rejected.
As opposed to the idea that 'all men are by nature equal':
' family farm' culture .It does mean, however, that conflicts and
confrontations were never perceived as strictly economic. For the
Catholic traditionalist elites, then, the ideology of a 'Catalan family' the Evangelic teachings have it that equality between men consists in that
presented as a natural, organic structure that could hannonise hierarchy having the same nature, they are all called to the same eminent dignity of
and differentiation and contain economic relationships within a filial Sons of God . . . . However, there exists an inequality of right and authority,
that derives from the Allthor of nature himself . . . . The Church constantly
instills in the people the precept of the Apostle: TI, ere is . . . no authority except
cast, became the essence of a regionalist identity. Regionalism was here
related with the ideological construction and the material enforcement
by God, and that which exists has been ordered by God, so that those who
of a certain social order expressed in the idealised world of the family ,
resist authority, resist God's disposition, and those who resist it bring
farm (casa, or masia) . Its political expression (once the dynastic civil
cOlldemllatioll upon them�elves. This precept also orders that subjects abide
wars were over and Catholic fundamentalism was losing ground) was I lIecessa n1y, not only by fear of punishment but by consciellce ... (Leo XIII 1 959a
the fight for a Catalan civil law as opposed to a unitarian Spanish Civil I
[ 1 878] : 1 84)
Code. In fact regionalists were not only reviving or preserving but
actively creating an institutional framework for social relations through The family, firmly held by the religious sacrament of wedlock
the Catalan Family Law (Roige 1 989). This ideal model did not expressed patriarchal authority in the image of God: 'Because, following
correspond to the full expression of material relations in the areas where Catholic doctrine, the authority of fathers and owners derives from

I
J
1 86 New Directions in ECOtlOmic Anthropology Social ReproductiOll 187
the authority of the Father and Heavenly Lord' (Leo XIII 1 959a close d unto themselves, because i n themselves it is impossible that they fulfil
[ 1 878] : 1 87) . Catalan Catholic conservatism, then, was regionalising life ' s obj ectives, therefore associations should be always in mutual
universal doctrine as a tactic and a charter of nature confronting the communication, as well as classes, seeing each other always, sharing ideas,
liberal central state. This was done through all sorts of juridical, sentiments and affections, because with this communication is how these
societies progress, not only in the particular function ofwork, but in the integral
hi�torical and cultural reconstructions while territorialising Catalan faith
functions of life. (Uni6 Catalanista 1 993: 1 1 3)
through the reconstruction and glorification oflocal shrines (Figuerola
1 99 1 , 1 994). But the Catalan regionalist project was in fact part of a Finally, the Catalan way is workers ' cooperatives: 'believe us, workers:
universal Catholic strategy for the submission of the working class. c(loperatiotl is your redemption' (1 993:84).
These different nationalist ideologies merged at the turn of the In short, nationalism appears here as a bourgeois conservative
century in a clearly nationalist (but no 'separatist') political party: programme, the heir to anti-liberal conservative and traditionalist
Unio Catalana. It was this party that wrote in 1 892 the founding regionalisms. Catalan nationalism, like other nationalisms (Anderson
document for a 'Catalan Constitution', the Bases de Matlresa. The 1 99 1 ; Eriksen 1 993), wants to create an 'imagined community' , but
document, it should be noted, gave voting rights to the family heads what is particularly revealing is that, clearly, the main objective is creating
organised in three 'classes': 'manual workers', 'professionals' and an 'imagined community' in social relations of productiort, an ideology
'landowners, industrialists and merchants'. In 1 904 the same party of harmony between capital and labour through national identity. Also
organised a meeting to debate the following issue: 'Catalanism and the revealing is that the democratic, republican, federalist group of proto­
Social Problem'. It will not come as a surprise to find the conservative, nationalists lost all its force and did not resurface until after the Primo
organic corporativist ideology expounded as a material reality and as de Rivera dictatorship (1 923-9) which, in fact, was well received by
the only solution to the social problem. The document states the need a large part of the bourgeoisie (Roig i Rosich 1 993:62). With the advent
for Catalonia to be an 'organic body with differentiated organs, unified of the Second Republic ( 1 9 3 1 ) the republican nationalist trend
in the national function by affective links and the moral cont[r]act of organised in a party, the Esguerra Republicana de Catalunya (ERC)
each with the other' (Unio Catalanista 1 993 [ 1 904] :51). (Republican Left of Catalonia), that won the first democratic elections
Catalanism has t o work with the help and cooperation o f all Catalans; and in Catalonia. The 'left' was represented by a group ofliberal republican
those that with mean spirit, because of differences of opinion over what is intellectuals, some small unions (especially the shop assistants' association)
incidental, would want to destroy the unitary outlook ... [they] are not Jnd a group of extreme nationalist groups (Estat CataIa), particularly
Cata/OII lIatiolia/ists, they are defective elements that can do more harm than virulent in its juvenile branch. It was an odd mixture that included
good to the cause of Catalunya. ( 1 993:61) sin cere republican democrats together with a proto-fascist movement
To counter the menace to Catalan integrity brought up by the social that engaged in organised violent actions against anarchist workers (Culla
problem the document warns against two mistaken ways, first, workers' 197 7: 1 62-3, 1 68, 296). It is not surprising that the main working-class
internationalism and strikes (Unio Catalanista 1 993:70, 84, 1 2(}-2) and, , organisations in Catalonia (BOC, CNT) did not see in the nationalist
second, the state's intervention (conceived as 'socialism') perceived as 'left' ofERC the defence of their interests (Culla 1 977: 1 99-200) . The
an 'artificial' as opposed to the 'natural' force of Catalan society Working class of Catalonia was resolutely 'internationalist'. Interestingly,
(1 993:96, 1 1 3) . The proposal stated in the document is that the this has been explained away by some Catalan historians by the fact
Catalan way is in the first place, paternalism. Addressing capitalists the ' that they were not 'Cat�an' but 'immigrants' (Vicens Vives 1 986: 1 28-9,
document states 'you will be responsible for them as a sacred trust. As 1 4 8-9; Giralt 1 986:vii). In any case, the nationalist left's ideas in
the proletariat gives you all it has, through you he should get all that rela tion to the social problem were essentially the same as those of the
he lacks: healthy food, decent housing, instruction and culture of the ; bourgeois conservatives (Pi i Sunyer 1 983 [1 927]:22 1 , 291 , 3 1 8, 3 1 9)
soul' ( 1 993:77, 83, 93) . Second, the Catalan way is corporativism. , and they obviously did not appeal to workers. Only with the advent
Associations of interests should not be: of a right-wing anti-democratic central government in 1 934 did the
1 88 New Directions irl EcorlOmic Anthropology Social ReproductioH 1 89
democratic republicans within the ERC, then in power in the require a profound change of the political society. The liberal transforma­
autonomous Catalan government, explicitly present themselves as the tions of the state were not useful for a liberal society, they were utopian. In
preservers of democracy within the Spanish Republic (Culla:301-2) . fact , liberal society required a non-liberal state, full of absolutist characters.
(Terradas 1 984:256-7)
Just before and after the start of the Spanish Civil War two working­
class parties were formed in Catalunya, the POUM (Partido Obrero In the same vein and more generally, speaking of the traditionalist
de Unificaci6n Marxista) and the PSUC (Partit Socialiste Unificat de reaction that permeated the whole of Spain during the nineteenth
Catalunya) , neither with a ' nationalist' programme. It was not until I century, J. Millan writes:
after the Spanish Civil War and the Social Revolution of 1 936-9, that
Some alternatives for the development of a bourgeois society do not require
the working-class organisations, mainly the communist PSUC, took a liberal configuration . . . of politics. . . . Liberalism furnished a utopian horizon
up the nationalist democratic discourse against the Franco regime. This
. . . that only in part and under specific conditions agreed with the aspirations
should be understood in the general context ofEuropean post-Second of the bourgeois groups. (199 1 : 1 8)
World War reconstruction and economic expansion, ofthe weakening
of the 'internationalist' spirit of working-class solidarity, of a 'nation­ By focusing on the development of the different strands ofnationalism
as they relate to the development of social relations ofproduction, the
alisation' ofworkers' organisations in Western contexts; but also in the
construction of meanings and the structuring of agency in Catalonia,
context of a unified fight for democracy against a repressive regime.
we have been able to get a nuanced picture of material relations in a
For the communist party in Catalonia, the PSUC, the cultural identity
local context. If we wanted to understand the whole movement of
symbols ofnationalist resistance, for example the Catalan Church's sacred
social reproduction, however, we would necessarily have to take into
places - the shrine of Montserrat - the Catalan language, the Catalan
account, for any historical period, a much wider set of related issues.
�ag, were useful as rallying points in order to get the support of the
These would include, for the above example, the participation of Catalan
mtellectual and democratic bourgeoisie in the struggle against Franco.
merchants in the slave trade and in the plantation economy in the
There was, too, a vague notion that all those that suffered from Francoist
colonies, the social relations and transformations occurring in cotton
repression must have something in common and be solidary in their
plantations in America, the worldwide market for textiles and the social
fight. And there was the increasing feeling that the right's centralism
relations of production obtaining in different producing countries
and militarism were worse than nationalist civilian conservatism for the
(England, India . . . ), social relations of production in agriculture and
:vorki.ng class. After Franco's death (1 975) nationalism again divided industry in other parts of Spain, processes of migration, etc. It would
Into dIfferent strands. Workers' organisations could now retain a certain
also include the diverse worldwide local constructions of consciousness
nationalist nuance because bourgeois nationalism had adopted a more
grounded in experience and generating agency, because all of it relates
lIberal, less organicist ideology of the nation and workers' unions and
to the local Catalan experience. There is obviously no space in this
parties had adopted a more corporativist ideological dynamic of
book to undertake such a project, but Wolfs Europe and the People without
understanding capitalist economy as 'best for all'.
History ( 1 982) is a magnificent example of what can be done in this
The example of Catalan nationalism seems to me pertinent in that
. shows how the rise of a counter-hegemonic cultural process (Catalan vein. I want clearly to warn, however, of the dangers of an uncritical
It
use of the idea of 'local culture' theories when they become central
nationalism) against the hegemonic cultural power (Castilian centralism) ,
tenets in economic models. In the last, concluding, chapter I will try
appears as the attempt of a conservative bourgeoisie to maintain a cultural o
to distinguish the s cial reproduction approach from other overly
h�gem�ny (�orporativist organicism) against a rising counter-hegemony
simplistic ersatz versions.
(lIberalIsm) m the context of the development of capitalist relations
of production . Because:
Capitalism required important political aspects ofthe absolutist state and ideas
of ascribed status. ... the capitalist transformation of Spanish society did not

You might also like