You are on page 1of 6

SPOTLIGHT 3

How do effective and equitable legal


institutions emerge?

Closing the gap between law on paper and law in that they are able to compel compliance with their
practice requires well-functioning legal institutions. decisions.
Effective and equitable legal institutions operate as
safeguards against abuses of power and as channels
for the protection of rights and peaceful resolution
Under what conditions do
of conflict. Well-functioning legal institutions are effective and equitable legal
important to elicit voluntary compliance by signaling institutions emerge?
legitimacy. By reducing transaction costs and increas-
ing the predictability of behavior and certainty of All high-income member countries of the Organisa-
process, they underpin credible commitment, which tion for Economic Co-operation and Development
is needed to modernize socioeconomic relations. (OECD) score well on de jure and de facto indicators
of rule of law, including judicial independence,
accountability, and effectiveness. This relationship
What are effective and illustrates the need for such institutions to support
equitable legal institutions? sophisticated and diversified economic models. But
as this Report has emphasized, simply transplanting
Core state legal institutions include those that declare institutional forms to developing countries does not
law (legislatures, government agencies), enforce law work; such forms need to emerge in a homegrown
(prosecutors, regulators, police, prisons), and apply fashion from internal governance dynamics that
law to individual instances (courts). These institu- reflect socioeconomic demands and other incentives.
tions must operate in an integrated fashion with the As shown in figure S3.1, a positive correlation between
cadre of private lawyers, academics, and civil society rule of law and income is observed today, but this does
engaged in legal activity—the so-called legal com- not explain causality or how countries move up the
plex (Karpik and Halliday 2011). They also require an scale. The empirical and theoretical literature point to
appropriate enabling environment, including legal five sets of factors that are most likely to contribute
mandates, functional institutional systems and rules, to the development of equitable legal institutions that
and financial, human, and material resources. Mean- can act as an effective check on power: socioeconomic
while, they need to be physically and financially factors, historical factors, institutional factors, strate-
accessible to the population, while resonating with gic factors, and ideational factors.
peoples’ needs and perceptions of fairness in order to Socioeconomic factors. Across history and all soci-
generate trust. To act as an effective check on power, eties, informal mechanisms for social order, dispute
courts especially need to be independent of political resolution, and checks on power have arisen in ways
pressure, while remaining accountable and effective in that meet local contexts. As Hadfield and Weingast
(2013) document, predictable systems relying entirely
WDR 2017 team. on communal enforcement arose to bring order to the

102 | World Development Report 2017


Figure S3.1 Although high-income OECD countries generally have well-functioning
legal institutions, the relationship between institutional quality and income varies
in developing countries
Various rule of law indexes versus GDP per capita (log scale)

a. Government constraints b. Absence of corruption c. Open governments

1.0 1.0 1.0


Log of GDP per capita

Log of GDP per capita

Log of GDP per capita


0.8 0.8 0.8

0.6 0.6 0.6

0.4 0.4 0.4

0.2 0.2 0.2

250 5,000 100,000 250 5,000 100,000 250 5,000 100,000


Rule of Law Index Rule of Law Index Rule of Law Index

d. Fundamental rights e. Order and security f. Effective regulations

1.0 1.0 1.0


Log of GDP per capita

Log of GDP per capita

Log of GDP per capita


0.8 0.8 0.8

0.6 0.6 0.6

0.4 0.4 0.4

0.2 0.2 0.2

250 5,000 100,000 250 5,000 100,000 250 5,000 100,000


Rule of Law Index Rule of Law Index Rule of Law Index

g. Civil justice h. Criminal justice

1.0 1.0
Log of GDP per capita

Log of GDP per capita

0.8 0.8

0.6 0.6

0.4 0.4

0.2 0.2

250 5,000 100,000 250 5,000 100,000


Rule of Law Index Rule of Law Index

High-income OECD countries Other countries

Sources: WDR 2017 team, based on data from World Justice Project, Rule of Law Index, 2014, and World Bank, World Development Indicators (database), 2016.
Note: GDP = gross domestic product; OECD = Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

How do effective and equitable legal institutions emerge? | 103


seemingly lawless period of the California gold rush rules, systems, and human capacity to protect judges
in the mid-19th century, as well as to solve the con- from political pressure, incentivize efficiency, and
tract enforcement dilemmas of traveling merchants promote access and transparency. These are import-
in medieval Europe (see also Greif 2006). The diver- ant and necessary interventions, but often they are
sification of societies and the increasing complexity insufficient.
of socioeconomic transactions created demands for a As figure S3.2 shows, even the most stringent
more formalized, arms-length mechanism for a state constitutional guarantees of independence and
legal system (Dixit 2004). Even so, a wide range of best-practice forms of judicial appointment often
alternative formal and informal mechanisms continue do not correlate with de facto measures of indepen-
to exist, often proving capable of serving at least some dent judicial behavior (Feld and Voigt 2003; Ríos-
functions of an effective legal system. Neighborhood Figueroa and Staton 2012). Moreover, the same formal
mediation practices in urban Papua New Guinea, for rules can produce different incentives, depending
example, manage disputes and maintain order in dif- on broader contextual factors (Helmke and Staton
ficult urban communities in ways that formal police 2011). At the same time, empirical studies show that
and courts have not (Craig, Porter, and Hukula 2016). seemingly minor technical rule changes can have
Tribal and customary courts in Afghanistan, Liberia, major effects on a court’s role and assertiveness. For
and South Sudan have brought closure to vengeance example, obscure rules on who has the right to bring
killings, land disputes, and a range of social concerns, a case (“standing rules”) were instrumental in the rise
whereas the formal mechanisms used in some cases to prominence of the courts in Costa Rica and India.
have exacerbated tensions (Isser 2011). Without dis- In short, rules and capacity matter, but their relation-
counting the important role they can play, such mech- ship to judicial effectiveness in practice is mediated
anisms are often effective precisely because they by strategic and ideational factors (Helmke and Ríos-
reflect the social norms and power relations in which Figueroa 2011).
they are embedded. Ultimately, state legal institutions Strategic factors. The first set of strategic factors
are generally needed to promote equity and to serve as relates to the calculus elites undertake to determine
an effective check on power. for what reasons they would endow courts with auton-
Historical factors. One explanation for why some omy and effectiveness, keeping in mind that both
judiciaries emerge as credible and effective while oth- could be used against elite interests. The literature
ers do not is rooted in the historical circumstances— points to five key reasons. First, elites may strengthen
in particular, colonial legacies—in which the modern judiciaries to signal a credible commitment to commercial
justice system developed. Where colonial legal sys- investment by raising the cost of political interference
tems and their national aftermaths sought to incorpo- with economic activity, as in several fast-growing
rate, accommodate, and adapt to the contending nor- transition economies. The establishment of robust
mative orders of society, national law and courts have judicial institutions may also be in response to
emerged as relatively effective and legitimate institu- requirements for engagement in international orga-
tions, as in India. By contrast, where colonial systems nizations and transnational trade regimes (Moustafa
created fragmented spaces of Western law and indi- and Ginsburg 2008). Second, elites may endow courts
rect rule through which native authorities were often with capacity in order to use them to enforce central
invented, as in Nigeria and Kenya, national law and policy, control agents, and maintain elite cohesion. This
courts faced an uphill battle in establishing credible was a key goal underlying Mexico’s introduction of
commitments to legality. Although these dynamics the mechanism of amparo, which allows citizens to
tend to persist in some ways (through path depen- challenge arbitrary action by individual bureaucrats
dency), they are constantly renegotiated in response (Magaloni 2008). Third, elites may bind their hands
to underlying patterns of social and economic change by establishing powerful courts during periods of
(Daniels, Trebilcock, and Carson 2011).1 political uncertainty as political insurance to protect
Institutional factors. Courts are governed by an their policies from being undermined in the event of
array of rules—constitutional and otherwise—that a government transition (Ginsburg 2003; Staton and
shape the independence, accountability, and effec- Moore 2011). Fourth, judicial review of legislation can
tiveness of the judiciary. These rules include judicial serve an important information-gathering role for policy
appointment and disciplinary procedures, the scope makers when they are unsure of how laws and poli-
of judicial review, case management systems and pro- cies will play out in practice (Staton and Moore 2011).
cedures, legal standing, and access. Judicial reform Fifth, elites may empower courts in order to channel
efforts often focus on strengthening the formal controversial questions away from executive institutions.

104 | World Development Report 2017


Figure S3.2 The correlation is weak between de jure and de facto measures of
judicial independence

a. Independence: How often does the high b. Influence: How often does the government
court make decisions that merely reflect comply with important decisions of the high
government wishes regardless of the court’s court with which it disagrees?
sincere view of the legal record?

Always Never

Usually Seldom

About half About half


the time the time

Seldom Usually

Never Always

0 10 20 30 40 50 0 10 20 30 40 50 60
Number of countries Number of countries
Countries with judicial independence Countries where high court decisions are final
Countries with no such constitutional provision

Sources: WDR 2017 team, based on data from V-Dem, 2016, and Comparative Constitutions Project, 2016.

For example, by empowering the Egyptian Supreme The experience of the Supreme Court of India
Constitutional Court to rule on policies related to illustrates this process. At independence, the Court
economic liberalization, the executive was able to was endowed with expansive constitutional powers
pass important reforms without significant political of judicial review and rights protection. During the
fallout (Moustafa 2007). period of emergency rule, the executive sought to
When used strategically by elites in these five curb these powers and pack the Court with govern-
ways, courts may be empowered with autonomy for ment supporters. As India transitioned to multiparty
some types of cases but not others—and that power politics and a coalition government, the Court began
may be taken away when it no longer serves elite to reassert its independence by expanding popular
interests. But even limited autonomy may create access to the Court through public interest litigation.
spaces for judicial actors to assert themselves and to This step served to consolidate the strength of the
strategically expand their role. Judges’ calculus must Court through popular support and to establish prec-
take into account their institutional powers, but also edent for a more activist role (Mate 2013).
the likelihood of compliance with their rulings. There Ideational factors. Despite their favorable institu-
is strong evidence that judiciaries are more likely to tional rules and strategic opportunities to consolidate
exercise power in cases of political uncertainty or power, some judiciaries remain constrained. The
fragmentation because this reduces the ability of final factor is the so-called legal culture—that is, the
others to put political pressure on the courts. This “contested and ever-shifting repertoires of ideas and
factor accounts for the emergence of autonomous behaviors relating to law, legal justice and legal sys-
judicial behavior in Brazil, Indonesia, and Mexico, tems” (Couso, Huneeus, and Sieder 2010, 6). Simply
among other countries (Helmke and Ríos-Figueroa stated, ideas, norms, beliefs, and values matter. For
2011; Dressel and Mietzner 2012). Public expectations example, judges in Chile have been constrained by a
and demands on courts are also an important factor tradition of legal formalism. By contrast, in Colombia
in this calculus, as is the broader role played by the judges’ perceptions of their own role have shifted
private bar, legal academia, and other legal actors as indigenous groups have increasingly employed
(Halliday 2013; Shapiro 2013). Judicial autonomy and rights-based strategies (Domingo 2010). A social net-
effectiveness are thus an outcome of strategic inter- work analysis of Mexican judges depicts how profes-
actions among the judiciary, other branches of gov- sional networks can diffuse fundamental ideas about
ernment, and the public (McNollgast 2006). the role of judges (Ingram 2016).

How do effective and equitable legal institutions emerge? | 105


Implications for judicial Guinea’s Urban Settlements.” World Bank Research
Report, Justice for the Poor, Washington, DC.
reform efforts Daniels, Ronald J., Michael J. Trebilcock, and Lindsey D.
Carson. 2011. “The Legacy of Empire: The Common
Analyzing how these factors play out in a given con-
Law Inheritance and Commitments to Legality on
text can help identify what kind of reformist activi-
Former British Colonies.” American Journal of Compar-
ties are most likely to have traction. Investments in ative Law 59: 111–78.
improving the efficiency and effectiveness of com- Dixit, Avinash. 2004. Lawlessness and Economics. Prince-
mercial courts, for example, may take root where elite ton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
incentives and business demands align in favor of Domingo, Pilar. 2010. “Novel Appropriations of the Law
effective, impartial courts. Investments to strengthen in the Pursuit of Political and Social Change in Latin
citizen access and empowerment and improve judges’ America.” In Cultures of Legality: Judicialization and Polit-
perceptions of their own roles are more likely to prove ical Activism in Latin America, edited by Javier A. Couso,
Alexandra Huneeus, and Rachel Sieder. New York:
fruitful where strategic opportunities exist to expand
Cambridge University Press.
the judicial role to limit abuse of power and protect
Dressel, Björn, and Marcus Mietzner. 2012. “A Tale of
rights. Conversely, the absence of such conditions Two Courts: The Judicialization of Electoral Politics
may undermine efforts to build the capacity of legal in Asia.” Governance: An International Journal of Policy,
institutions. Administration, and Institutions 25 (3): 391–414.
Where conditions do not favor empowerment Ellickson, Robert. 1991. Order without Law. Cambridge,
of formal legal institutions, reformists can look to MA: Harvard University Press.
a broader set of formal and informal institutions Feld, Lars, and Stefan Voigt. 2003. “Economic Growth
that may be relevant in terms of meeting the key and Judicial Independence: Cross-Country Evidence
Using a New Set of Indicators.” Working Paper
functions of commitment, coordination, and coop-
906, Center for Economic Studies and Ifo Institute
eration for particular issues. Commitment devices
(CESifo), Munich.
for commercial transactions include reputational Ginsburg, Tom. 2003. Judicial Review in New Democracies:
considerations that might be served by industry Constitutional Courts in Asian Cases. New York: Cam-
mechanisms of alternative dispute resolution.2 A bridge University Press.
range of customary, communal, or nonstate institu- Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern
tions may serve as effective cooperation mechanisms Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge, U.K.:
to resolve social and economic disputes peacefully. In Cambridge University Press.
such cases, efforts to improve the desired functions Hadfield, Gillian, and Barry Weingast. 2013. “Law with-
out the State: Legal Attributes and the Coordination
will be better served by understanding the strengths
of Decentralized Collective Punishment.” Journal of
of existing institutions and seeking to enhance and
Law and Courts 1 (1): 3–34.
complement their functional capacity by expanding Halliday, Terence. 2013. “Why the Legal Complex Is
accountability. Integral to Theories of Consequential Courts.” In
Consequential Courts: Judicial Roles in Global Perspective,
edited by Diana Kapiszewski, Gordon Silverstein,
Notes and Robert Kagan. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge Uni-
1. For a more nuanced discussion of how legal cultures versity Press.
were forged by a dynamic interplay between imperial Helmke, Gretchen, and Julio Ríos-Figueroa. 2011. Courts
policies and native agency, see Yannakakis (2015). in Latin America. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge Univer-
2. For examples of social mechanisms of commitment, sity Press.
see Ellickson (1991); Dixit (2004); and Greif (2006). Helmke, Gretchen, and Jeffrey Staton. 2011. “The Puz-
zling Judicial Politics of Latin America: A Theory of
Litigation, Judicial Decisions and Interbranch Con-
References flict.” In Courts in Latin America, edited by Gretchen
Helmke and Julio Ríos-Figueroa. Cambridge, U.K.:
Comparative Constitutions Project. Various years. http:// Cambridge University Press.
comparativeconstitutionsproject.org/#. Ingram, Matthew. 2016. Crafting Courts in New Democra-
Couso, Javier A., Alexandra Huneeus, and Rachel Sieder. cies: The Politics of Subnational Judicial Reform in Brazil
2010. Cultures of Legality: Judicialization and Political and Mexico. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University
Activism in Latin America. New York: Cambridge Uni- Press.
versity Press. Isser, Deborah H. 2011. Customary Justice and the Rule of Law
Craig, D., D. Porter, and F. Hukula. 2016. “Come and See the in War-Torn Societies. Washington, DC: United States
System in Place: Mediation Capabilities in Papua New Institute of Peace Press.

106 | World Development Report 2017


Karpik, Lucien, and Terrence C. Halliday. 2011. “The Legal Ríos-Figueroa, Julio, and Jeffrey Staton. 2012. “An Eval-
Complex.” Annual Review of Law and Social Science 7: uation of Cross-National Measures of Judicial Inde-
217–36. pendence.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2008. “Enforcing the Autocratic 30 (1): 104–37.
Political Order and the Role of Courts: The Case of Shapiro, Martin. 2013. “The Might Problem Continues.”
Mexico.” In Rule by Law: The Politics of Courts in Author- In Consequential Courts: Judicial Roles in Global Perspec-
itarian Regimes, edited by Tamir Moustafa and Tom tive, edited by Diana Kapiszewski, Gordon Silverstein,
Ginsburg. New York: Cambridge University Press. and Robert Kagan. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge Uni-
Mate, Manoj. 2013. “Public Interest Litigation and the versity Press.
Transformation of the Supreme Court of India.” In Staton, Jeffrey, and Will H. Moore. 2011. “Judicial Power
Consequential Courts: Judicial Roles in Global Perspective, in Domestic and International Politics.” International
edited by Diana Kapiszewski, Gordon Silverstein, Organizations 65 (3): 553–87.
and Robert Kagan. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge Uni- V-Dem (Varieties of Democracy). Various years. Database
versity Press. hosted by Gothenburg Institute (Europe) and Kellogg
McNollgast. 2006. “Conditions for Judicial Indepen- Institute (United States), https://www.v-dem.net/en/.
dence.” Journal of Contemporary Legal Issues 15 (1): 105–27. World Bank. Various years. World Development Indi-
Moustafa, Tamir. 2007. The Struggle for Constitutional cators (database). Washington, DC, http://data.world
Power: Law, Politics, and Economic Development in Egypt. bank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators.
New York: Cambridge University Press. World Justice Project. Various years. Rule of Law Index.
Moustafa, Tamir, and Tom Ginsburg. 2008. “Intro­ Washington, DC, http://worldjusticeproject.org/.
duction: The Functions of Courts in Authoritarian Yannakakis, Yanna. 2015. “Beyond Jurisdictions: Native
Politics.” In Rule by Law: The Politics of Courts in Author- Agency in the Making of Colonial Legal Cultures.
itarian Regimes, edited by Tamir Moustafa and Tom A Review Essay.” Comparative Studies in Society and
Ginsburg. New York: Cambridge University Press. History 57 (4): 1070–82.

How do effective and equitable legal institutions emerge? | 107

You might also like