You are on page 1of 5

The Journal of Nutrition

Supplement: The Impact of Climate Change, the Economic Crisis,


and the Increase in Food Prices on Malnutrition

Preventing Food Crises Using a Food


Policy Approach1,2
C. Peter Timmer3*

Thomas D. Cabot Professor of Development Studies, emeritus, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jn/article-abstract/140/1/224S/4743317 by guest on 26 February 2020


Abstract
A food crisis occurs when rates of hunger and malnutrition rise sharply at local, national, or global levels. This definition
distinguishes a food crisis from chronic hunger, although food crises are far more likely among populations already
suffering from prolonged hunger and malnutrition. A food crisis is usually set off by a shock to either supply or demand for
food and often involves a sudden spike in food prices. It is important to remember that in a market economy, food prices
measure the scarcity of food, not its value in any nutritional sense. Except in rare circumstances, the straightforward way
to prevent a food crisis is to have rapidly rising labor productivity through economic growth and keep food prices stable
while maintaining access by the poor. The formula is easier to state than to implement, especially on a global scale, but it is
good to have both the objective, reducing short-run spikes in hunger, and the deep mechanisms, pro-poor economic
growth and stable food prices, clearly in mind. A coherent food policy seeks to use these mechanisms, and others, to
achieve a sustained reduction in chronic hunger over the long run while preventing spikes in hunger in the short
run. J. Nutr. 140: 224S–228S, 2010.

The evolution of the food policy perspective simplistic in methodology and too anecdotal in presentation).
It has been more than 25 years since Food Policy Analysis (1) Instead, we targeted the message at practitioners, an ill-defined
was published and more than 30 years since the initial outline for group of analysts in need of an understanding of how a
the book was circulated among the authors. It is fair to say that complicated and interconnected food system actually worked.
the volume has been very influential in thinking about food Training these practitioners has turned out to be the main
policy issues since its publication and it remains in use as a mission of the book.
textbook for a number of university courses (2). The early drafts of Food Policy Analysis (henceforth FPA)
Its academic success is a bit surprising, because the audience were stimulated by the attention to high food prices following
was not primarily university faculty (for whom it seemed too the world food crisis in 1973–74 and the fears of a repeat in
1979–80. But by the 4th full draft, in 1982, it became apparent
that surpluses were returning to world food markets. A volume
predicated on a world running out of food would have been out-
1
Published in a supplement to The Journal of Nutrition. Presented at the of-date before the ink was dry and a full-scale revamping of the
workshop “The Impact of Climate Change, the Economic Crisis, and the analytical messages was needed. The new theme, which has
Increase in Food Prices on Malnutrition,” held in Castel Gandolfo, Italy, January
stood the test of a quarter-century of market fluctuations, was
25, 2009. The workshop was organized by Martin W. Bloem, United Nations
World Food Programme, Rome, Italy; Klaus Kraemer, Sight and Life, Basel, the need for flexibility to cope with market instability.
Switzerland; and Richard D. Semba, Johns Hopkins University School of Such flexibility is not a natural feature of domestic policy
Medicine, and with the support of an educational grant from Sight and Life, making, in the food sector or elsewhere, and providing the
Basel, Switzerland. Supplement contents are solely the responsibility of the analytical tools for understanding how to create flexible responses
authors and do not necessarily represent the official views of the organization
that they are affiliated with. Publication costs for this supplement were defrayed
both to high and low price environments turned out to be a real
in part by the payment of page charges. This publication must therefore be challenge. But the relevance of the approach remains to this day,
hereby marked "advertisement" in accordance with 18 USC section 1734 solely accounting for the continued usefulness of an analytical guidebook
to indicate this fact. Supplement Coordinator disclosures: Martin Bloem, Klaus that is a quarter-century old. The approach presented here builds
Kraemer, and Richard Semba have no relationships to disclose. Supplement
on FPA (1,2), Getting Prices Right (3), and ongoing analysis of the
Guest Editor disclosures: A. Catharine Ross and Richard Semba have no
relationships to disclose. The opinions expressed in this publication are those of 2008 world food crisis, e.g. “Causes of High Food Prices” (4).
the authors and are not attributable to the sponsors or the publisher, Editor, or
Editorial Board of The Journal of Nutrition. The changing global environment
2
Author disclosure: C. P. Timmer, no conflicts of interest.
3
Present address: 415 Oak Point Place, Santa Rosa, CA 95409.
The international context for domestic food policy decision
* To whom correspondence should be addressed. E-mail: ptimmer63@gmail. making has changed substantially since FPA was drafted in the
com. early 1980s. Five basic trends stand out:

224S 0022-3166/08 $8.00 ã 2010 American Society for Nutrition.


First published online November 18, 2009; doi:10.3945/jn.109.110379.
1. Despite ups and downs, the last quarter-century has seen and the economics of global supply chains. The new link
surprisingly rapid economic growth, especially in Asia, was through the demand side. Higher prices for energy
with hundreds of millions of people pulled out of poverty. translated directly into greater demand for food com-
The strong connection between inclusive economic modities to convert into liquid fuels. If oil prices remain
growth, especially in rural areas, and rapid reduction of low, ,$60–80 a barrel, this link will turn out to have
poverty was simply not apparent in the empirical record been temporary, but industry analysts do not think this is
in the early 1980s. The East Asian Miracle (5) did not likely from the perspective of a decade or longer.
appear for another decade. This rapid growth validated
the central theme of FPA, which was the unsustainability What causes a food crisis? Supply, demand, and panic
of poverty reduction efforts without higher economic The world food crisis of 2008 actually had its origins in the
productivity of unskilled, especially rural, labor. surpluses of the 1980s. As food prices plummeted and markets
2. A communications revolution at both the household and remained depressed for years, investors, donors, and domestic
international levels has radically reduced transactions policymakers all walked away from agriculture, because it was a
costs and increased access to knowledge. Again, the “declining industry” with low financial returns. Why invest in
centrality in FPA of markets and price formation to

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jn/article-abstract/140/1/224S/4743317 by guest on 26 February 2020


food production when market signals screamed that industry
understanding food policy design and implementation was not only more profitable but the wave of the (technological)
received a boost as marketing margins narrowed under future? We are now paying a very high price for that neglect
improved and more informed competition. Consumers (which did not go totally unnoticed at the time).
and farmers both benefited from more competitive local Prices of basic foods increased sharply after mid-2007 and
food markets. peaked in the first half of 2008 before declining. The causes and
3. Global financial markets became interested in “emerging impact of higher prices are the subject of much analytical
economies.” The early 1980s were an era of fixed and policy debate, with little agreement except on the tragic
exchange rates, tight controls on the flow of foreign consequences for poor consumers. In response, the world
capital, and virtually no financial intermediation beyond community mobilized vast new resources to feed the poor,
state banks. At first, the influx of foreign capital was including a doubling of the budget for the World Food Program
welcomed as a sign of confidence, but except for foreign from $3 billion/y to over $6 billion for 2008. But little progress
direct investment in “real” assets such as factories and has been made in addressing the basic causes of high food prices,
real estate, the global financial interest in emerging partly because these causes remain poorly understood and
economies was a 2-edged sword. A rapid influx could controversial.
cause currency appreciation and a loss of competitiveness; Fortunately, a combination of decent weather in most
its rapid exit if the economy started to decline caused a growing regions in the first half of 2008, vigorous response
crisis in local financial markets. Global financial integra- from farmers to higher prices, and announcement in May of
tion came with very poorly understood risks. intentions to release substantial quantities of imported rice
4. The rapid emergence in the 1990s of China and India as stocks by Japan stopped the price panics seen early in 2008
global growth engines meant a gradual shift in the drivers (although the “intentions” have still not been realized). Market
of demand for commodities and natural resources. Ad- psychology for rice, wheat, corn, and vegetable oils has clearly
vanced economies had become more knowledge-driven and turned negative and prices in January 2009 are well below their
less dependent on energy, metals, and other basic com- peaks. But price levels remain well above long-run trends and
modities, including food commodities, to fuel their eco- considerable micro- and macro-adjustments are in the works.
nomic growth. The price depression for nearly all
commodities in the 1980s reinforced the view that the
future depended on value added from skills and knowledge, What international regime will be in play?
not from exploitation of natural resources. But industrial- The components of these adjustments will be conditioned, as
ization, especially as practiced by China and India, is a very never before, by the international context in which a new macro
intensive user of natural resources. By the turn of the food policy is formulated. It is both exciting, and troubling, that
millennium, it was increasingly clear that the growth path this international context, the “global food price regime,” is in a
of developing countries was the primary driver of com- greater state of flux, with more uncertainty, than at any time
modity prices, starting with energy prices, but quickly since FPA was being drafted. Which regime will drive policy
extending to food prices. formation in the coming quarter-century? Will it be the
5. High energy prices have turned out to be a “game historical path of structural transformation with falling food
changer” for agriculture and the food economy. Once oil prices, leading to a “world without agriculture” (6)? Or will it be
prices were high enough to justify using sugar, maize, or a new and uncertain path of rising real costs for food with a
vegetable oils to produce gasoline or diesel substitutes, reversal of structural transformation (7)? Management of food
agricultural commodity prices became directly linked to policy, and the outlook for sustained poverty reduction, will be
oil prices. The concern to reduce emissions of greenhouse radically different depending on which of these global price
gases provided ample motivation to US and European regimes plays out.
legislatures to mandate the use of domestic food crops to
produce liquid fuels. The combination of legislative Preventing food crises: knowing what to do
mandates, which provided essential risk coverage to Food crises have important short-run and long-run conse-
investors in bio-fuel facilities, and high oil prices, which quences for the welfare of the poor. Poverty traps and irrevers-
provided market-based incentives, led to a new set of ible effects from childhood malnutrition (learning, stature,
linkages between agriculture and the energy sector. There mortality) stem from even temporary loss of access to food.
had long been a link on the supply side, as energy prices Markets are usually not the best mechanism for preventing these
affected fertilizer costs, fuel costs for tractors and trucks, problems in the first place or alleviating them once they happen.
Preventing food crises 225S
Markets are crucial in the medium- to long-run as the institu- through the nature of incentives being set up by policy initiatives
tional vehicles for raising productivity of poor workers, but is almost a sure way to guarantee an unsuccessful outcome.
sudden spikes in food prices that cut off these workers from Equally, policy design needs to be clear on whether the
access to food supplies reflect serious market failures. Price initiative is meant to be a temporary palliative for the problem at
stability is not a routine market outcome. hand or a long-run cure. There is nothing wrong with palliatives,
It should be recognized, of course, that high food prices also especially if they build support for longer-run approaches that
offer opportunities, for surplus producers, both at the farm level solve the problem. But it is important not to confuse palliatives
and at the national level. High food prices provide incentives for with cures. Thus, bridges between short-run approaches and
technical change, which paradoxically has been the long-run long-run impact become the essence of successful food policy
mechanism for generating low food prices and better nutrition design and implementation.
for the poor. But again, the temporal disconnect between These bridges will be built from “real” policy instruments,
the poor losing access to food in the short run and a positive not “theoretical” ones. The distinction lies in understanding
long-run technological response requires public understanding how realistic the assumptions are that underlie the expected
and intervention. By necessity, the poor live in the short run but behavioral responses to policy initiatives. A policy that assumes
must place their hope for an escape from poverty in long-run poor people have unimpeded access to financial markets to

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jn/article-abstract/140/1/224S/4743317 by guest on 26 February 2020


forces. hedge risks will fail. But equally, a policy that assumes poor
Building the intuition needed to understand these issues people will not change their consumption behavior in the face of
involves a combination of theory, history, quantitative analysis, price subsidies will also be challenged by unexpected results.
and experience. Different analysts will bring different combina- In the end, food policy initiatives must stress the importance
tions to bear and differences in individual temperament, of economic growth that includes the poor and rising labor
training, and hands-on opportunities probably mean that a productivity for unskilled workers. Without these long-run
variety of combinations can work. But no single component economic dynamics working reasonably smoothly, food policy
alone will make for effective policy analysis and advising. becomes an exercise in permanent, and expensive, palliatives.

Implementation, monitoring, and evaluation (and


Analytical understanding involvement in the full policy cycle)
A “vision” of an interconnected food system is the starting point How do food policy analysts know when an initiative has
for a deeper analytical understanding of how it works and, worked and when it has failed? The answer comes through long-
especially, how it would respond to external shocks, technical term engagement by policy analysts and scholar-practitioners in
change, and policy initiatives. Building a vision is an intuitive
the design process in implementation, monitoring, and evalua-
and pedagogical process. Some analysts see the interconnections tion of policies. The engagement of at least a few analysts in the
most clearly in the context of general equilibrium theory, now a full policy cycle ensures that someone understands constraints
standard tool in all macro economists’ kit. Others find the on the ground and provides feedback to the design process itself.
equilibrium of ecological systems a guidepost. Whatever the It is possible to be “captured” in this full-cycle involvement, to
underlying framework, understanding how markets process be so determined the design is right that the evaluation gets
billions of pieces of information on a daily basis to generate price “cooked.” But early and critical feedback from the field is
signals to all participants is absolutely crucial to building this essential to good policy design.
food policy vision. Markets cannot solve all of society’s Experimental design in policy evaluation is important, but
problems and sometimes make them worse. But no other form randomization is difficult, if not impossible, with the breadth of
of institutional organization has evolved that is capable of the
policies under consideration. Randomized trials are the true gold
necessary information processing required for individuals and standard for evaluating many social sector interventions at the
firms to make efficient allocation and investment decisions and, project level, but they are not the primary methodology for
thus, to raise long-run productivity. Without reasonably efficient policy evaluation.
markets, we are all doomed to poverty.
The dilemma, of course, is that markets often fail at tasks that
Knowing what not to do: the political economy of
society regards as important, such as poverty reduction or food
unintended consequences
price stability. Fortunately, relatively simple analytical tools and
Good intentions do not inevitably lead to good outcomes. The
models are available that cast light on these market failures and
concern for appropriate mechanism design is one reflection of
point the way toward appropriate government interventions to
this potential disconnect, but that concern is primarily a
solve them. Not all market failures are susceptible to successful
technical one. A broader concern is at issue here: the potential
government interventions—effective risk-sharing mechanisms
(indeed, likely) disconnect between political rhetoric and effec-
would be high on the list—but historical experience demon-
tive public action. The problem is that political rhetoric can
strates that public action against poverty and food price
generate expectations that cannot be met, with subsequent loss
instability can be effective in both the short run and the long run.
of credibility (and hope). Because credibility is often crucial to
successful implementation of government policies, especially in
Mechanism design short-run price stabilization activities, this loss is potentially
The key to effective public action is to get the “mechanism serious.
design” right. That is, policy initiatives must worry about the In the original FPA, we tried to dodge this issue by noting in
incentive structures set up so that they are compatible both with the preface that it was “beyond the scope of this book to
respect to government budgetary and bureaucratic capacity and structure meaningfully the political issues of food policy.”
with respect to self-interested behavior on the part of market Understandable as that stance may have been at the time, when
participants who are exposed to the results of policy changes. the economics of food policy were also poorly developed, the
This may seem an arcane and theoretical point (and worthy of intervening quarter-century has amply demonstrated the pri-
the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2007), but failure to think macy of politics in the design and implementation of food policy.
226S Supplement
Unfortunately, there is no equivalent to FPA in the political agriculture. But there is no clear set of lessons on which
science literature, perhaps because “all politics is local” (to institutional base provides the best incentives for high quality
quote a famous American congressional leader Tip O’Neil). analysis that is effectively plugged into the policy process. Perhaps
Without clear guidelines, then, on how to implement effective serendipity and leadership are the key variables in such success.
food policies, the best that can be done is to review what those
policies need to accomplish. A way must be found to link short- Where were the donors during the neglect
run political imperatives with long-run economic realities. of agriculture?
Democratic societies have the best historical track record at The world food crisis of 2007–2008 caught by surprise the
building and maintaining this link, but the deep institutions major donors who support economic development. As prices
needed for democracies to fulfill this task take time to build. spiraled out of control, their uniform response was more food
A way must be found to make markets work to deliver long- aid and a commitment to fund agricultural research at higher
run growth. No alternative exists to organizing economies levels than in the past. Their own role in undervaluing this
around market-based transactions if societies are to reach their research for more than 2 decades, thus making the world
goals of greater material welfare and broad political freedom. vulnerable to the crisis, was little recognized internally but
Markets produce both. But markets also fail in important social

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jn/article-abstract/140/1/224S/4743317 by guest on 26 February 2020


widely criticized externally, especially in the international press
tasks. Responsible governments must find a way to prevent those (8). The World Bank was lucky in having its flagship publication
failures through careful regulation and to fix them when World Development Report 2008 go to press in October, 2007,
innocent workers and consumers cannot participate in the with the title Agriculture for Development (9). But even this
promises of market outcomes. volume did not foresee the “blowout” in commodity prices that
Thus, finding a way to make governments work to deliver caused so much economic distress for food importing countries,
effective and efficient safety nets as both a moral and political for the poor in affected regions, and for agencies that provided
imperative—to allow markets to deliver these promises—is the food aid to millions of destitute individuals globally. There is still
essence of policymaking. Governments, like the poor, live in the little recognition in the donor community that much of the spike
short run. Their vision and strategic design for inclusive, long- in food prices was not caused by basic supply-demand imbal-
run growth must survive the day-to-day challenges of managing ances but by speculative pressures from global financial markets.
power. The political economy of food policy lies in meeting these Preventing such speculative excesses in the markets for staple
challenges. foods would seem to be a high priority.

The future agenda: human capital and The political economy of food policy
institutional capacity Finally, there are a set of questions that revolve around the
Stepping back from the details of how to do food policy analysis, political economy of food policy. When politics is in command,
several other questions arise: who will do the analysis and where which seems to be the normal state of affairs for most developing
will they be trained; what is the appropriate institutional base countries, how do efficiency issues stay on the agenda?
for food policy analysts; and why do this difficult analysis if When markets are in command, which seems to be the main
politics is in command? policy advice from the donor community to poor countries, how
do distributional and welfare issues stay on the agenda?
Where (and how) will food policy analysts be trained? More broadly, how do we educate policymakers as well as
The role of scholar-practitioners analysts? In democratic societies, it would seem to require
The human capital investment needed to train skilled food educating citizens so that they could be informed voters, but the
policy analysts is substantial and the educational institutions time horizon implied by this approach is very long indeed.
capable of providing the training are hard to find. A successful Other articles in this supplement include (10–25).
food policy analyst needs an unusual blend of technical skills,
mostly economic, and a broad vision of how food systems Acknowledgment
interact and evolve over time. University Ph.D. programs have The sole author had responsibility for all parts of the manuscript.
basically stopped doing this kind of training. Economics
programs, e.g., increasingly focus on microeconomic decision
making that needs to be understood through careful experimen-
tal design of the data needed for analysis. Some extraordinarily Literature Cited
smart students have come out of these programs with field 1. Timmer CP, Falson WP, Pearson SR. Food policy analysis. Baltimore:
experience in rural settings and their journal articles are Johns Hopkins University Press for the World Bank; 1983.
technical gems. But it is rare for these students to be trained in 2. Food policy analysis, pages 1–301 [cited 2009 1 Oct]. Available from:
http://www.stanford.edu/group/FRI/indonesia/documents/foodpolicy/
the macroeconomics of growth and development, much less
fronttoc.fm.html.
economic history. Such students have little intuition about how
3. Timmer CP. Getting prices right: the scope and limits of agricultural
complex food systems function and change. Undergraduates price policy. Ithaca: Cornell University Press; 1986.
seeking graduate programs to train them as food policy analysts 4. Timmer CP. Causes of high food prices. Asian development outlook
have nowhere to go. update. Manila: Asian Development Bank; 2008. Available from: http://
The failure of academic programs to provide coherent training www.adb.org/documents/books/ADO/2008/Update/Part02-Food-Prices.
in food policy analysis is partly due to the lack of clear career tracks pdf
for such analysts. Just where are the jobs? What institutional base 5. World Bank. The East Asian miracle: economic growth and public
policy. London and New York: Oxford University Press; 1993.
provides the best opportunities for food policy analysts to do good
6. Timmer CP. A world without agriculture: the structural transformation
work and be effective advocates for sound policies and programs? in historical perspective. The Henry Wendt lecture. Washington, DC:
The historical record is quite fuzzy, as successful food policy units American Enterprise Institute; 2009.
have functioned in planning agencies, food logistics agencies, trade 7. Timmer CP, Akkus S. The structural transformation as a pathway out of
and commerce ministries, ministries of health, even ministries of poverty: analytics, empirics and politics. Working paper 150. Wash-

Preventing food crises 227S


ington, DC: Center for Global Development; 2008. Available from: 18. Ruel MT, Garrett JL, Hawkes C, Cohen MJ. The food, fuel, and
http://www.cgdev.org/content/publications/detail/16421. financial crises affect the urban and rural poor disproportionately:
8. Food and the poor: the new face of hunger. Economist. 2008 April 17. a review of the evidence. J Nutr. 2010;140:170–6.
9. World BankWorld development report 2008: agriculture for develop- 19. Christian P. Impact of the economic crisis and increase in food prices on
ment. London and New York: Oxford University Press; 2007. child mortality: exploring nutritional pathways. J Nutr. 2010;140:
10. Badham J. World food crisis: a wake-up call to save a generation of 177–81.
children. participants statement: Castel Gondolfo, Italy, 25 January, 20. Thorne-Lyman AL, Valpiani N, Sun K, Semba RD, Klotz CL, Kraemer
2009. J Nutr. 2010;140:130–1. K, Akhter N, de Pee S, Moench-Pfanner R, et al. Household dietary
11. Bloem MW, Semba RD, Kraemer K. Castel Gandolfo Workshop: An diversity and food expenditures are closely linked in rural Bangladesh,
introduction to the impact of climate change, the economic crisis, and the increasing the risk of malnutrition due to the financial crisis. J Nutr.
increase in the food prices on malnutrition. J Nutr. 2010;140:132–5. 2010;140:182–8.
12. Nabarro D. Editorial comment: helping the vulnerable. J Nutr. 2010; 21. Campbell AA, de Pee S, Sun K, Kraemer K, Thorne-Lyman A, Moench-
140:136–7. Pfanner R, Sari M, Akhter N, Bloem MW, Semba RD. Household rice
13. de Pee S, Brinkman H-J, Webb P, Godfrey S, Darnton-Hill I, Alderman expenditure and maternal and child nutritional status in Bangladesh.
H, Semba RD, Piwoz E, Bloem MW. How to ensure nutrition security in J Nutr. 2010;140:189–94.
the global economic crisis to protect and enhance development of young 22. Sari M, de Pee S, Bloem MW, Sun K, Thorne-Lyman A, Moench-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/jn/article-abstract/140/1/224S/4743317 by guest on 26 February 2020


children and our common future. J Nutr. 2010;140:138–42. Pfanner R, Akhter N, Kraemer K, Semba RD. Higher household
14. Webb P. Medium- to long-run implications of high food prices for global expenditure on animal-source and nongrain foods lowers the risk of
nutrition. J Nutr. 2010;140:143–7. stunting among children 0–59 months old in Indonesia: implications of
15. Alderman H. Safety nets can help address the risks to nutrition from rising food prices. J Nutr. 2010;140:195–200.
increasing climate variability. J Nutr. 2010;140:148–52. 23. West KP, Mehra S. Vitamin A intake and status in populations facing
16. Brinkman H-J, de Pee S, Sanogo I, Subran L, Bloem MW. High food economic stress. J Nutr. 2010;140:201–7.
prices and the global financial crisis have reduced access to nutritious 24. Semba RD, de Pee S, Sun K, Bloem MW, Raju VK. The role of expanded
food and worsened nutritional status and health. J Nutr. 2010;140: coverage of the national vitamin a program in preventing morbidity
153–61. and mortality among preschool children in India. J Nutr.
17. Darnton-Hill I, Cogill B. Maternal and young child nutrition adversely 2010;140:208–12.
affected by external shocks such as increasing global food prices. J Nutr. 25. Sztam KA, Fawzi WW, Duggan C. Macronutrient supplementation and
2010;140:162–9. food prices in HIV treatment. J Nutr. 2010;140:213–23.

228S Supplement

You might also like