You are on page 1of 10

Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Resources Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/resourpol

Cut-off grade: A real options analysis


Matt Thompson a,n, Drew Barr b
a
Queen's School of Business, Queen's University, Kingston, Ontario, Canada K7L 3N6
b
Kinross Corporation, 25 York Street Suite 1500, Toronto, Ontario, Canada M5J 2V5

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Article history: In this paper we examine the impact of forward price uncertainty on the optimal cut-off policy of mines.
Received 24 February 2014 We employ a new real options model for determining the optimal cut-off grade of ore under stochastic
Received in revised form prices. The economic insights and consequences of incorporating uncertainty into the cut-off decision
1 October 2014
making process are shown to be in opposition to that of traditional deterministic cut-off theory. Key
Accepted 3 October 2014
among the new insights is that when prices are stochastic, optimal cut-off grades are much lower than
Available online 12 November 2014
those determined using traditional deterministic models that are currently used in practice. This implies
JEL classification: that the traditional techniques may lead to greater resource waste than is optimal. This effect is most
Q pronounced for higher volatility metals, marginal mines, higher discount rates and longer valuation time
Keywords: horizons. In addition to the important insights, the new model produces valuations, sensitivities and
Mining policy optimal cut-off strategies that can be used to enhance project valuation, mine operation, hedging
Real options strategy determination, mine design and risk management decisions.
Cut-off grade & 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Stochastic optimization

Introduction effect; increasing the amount of waste while also increasing the rate
of metal production. The economic definition of ore requires that
Ore is defined as a concentration of a mineral or aggregate of one must balance the benefits of increased production rates, against
minerals from which a valuable constituent such as a metal can be the costs of wasting material and an increased rate of resource
economically extracted for profit. Underneath this deceptively depletion.
simple definition, lies the challenge of determining precisely what Cut-off decisions are influenced by the present value of future
“economically extracted” means. The optimization of the defini- metal prices, and (Lane, 1964) is considered to be the seminal
tion of ore has important consequences in the valuation, financing, work in understanding and optimizing the resulting trade-offs.
design, operation, and risk management decisions made by mining The important insight utilized in this work is that higher cut-off
firms while also having implications for public policy. In order to rates result in faster production. Given the time value of money,
understand the trade-offs involved in the definition of ore it is present production is more valuable than future production, all
important to understand the fundamentals of the design and else being equal. Hence traditional cut-off theory argues that some
operation of a mine. waste can be justified as profit maximizing if it shifts more
Mining engineers use the term grade, to describe the fraction of production earlier in time. Consequently, larger risk adjusted
metal that is contained in a mass of rock. The cut-off grade is the discount rates result in higher cut-off values and more waste.
minimum grade that is required in a given mass of rock to consider Since the publication of this important work, cut-off determina-
it ore. Any material not passing this minimum criteria is defined as tion by discounted cash flow maximization has become the norm
waste and is (for the most part) irreversibly discarded. Therefore in industrial and academic circles. Later works have since
the lower the choice of cut-off the less material is wasted, however extended this initial breakthrough work including (Lane, 1988;
a lower cut-off results in a lower average quantity of usable metal in Ataci, 2014; Bascetin and Nieto, 2014; Rendu, 2008; Gholamnejad,
the same amount of ore being processed. Since maximum ore 2014) however, all have continued to utilize the discounted cash-
processing capacity is generally fixed, lower cut-off values lead to flow framework.
slower metal output rates (since less metal is produced in the same The discounted cash flow (DCF) approach is predicated on the
amount of ore processed). Raising the cut-off has the opposite mathematical fact that if all cash-flows are a linear function of
price, then the expected value of the cash-flow function of the
random price variable is just the linear function evaluated at the
n
Corresponding author.
expected value of that variable. Hence, in the linear case, the price
E-mail addresses: mthompson@business.queensu.ca (M. Thompson), distribution is irrelevant, only the expected future prices (and their
drew.barr@kinross.com (D. Barr). discounted values) matter. Real options theory argues (among

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2014.10.003
0301-4207/& 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
84 M. Thompson, D. Barr / Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92

other things) that managerial flexibility such as the ability to practice. Johnson et al. (2010) also did not allow for temporary
adjust production rates with price changes (cut-off optimization), mine closure.
or to temporarily suspend/abandon production or any other non- In this paper we develop a stochastic dynamic model for cut-off
linearities, changes the mathematics in a way that invalidates the grade optimization for use in mining valuation and optimal opera-
expected value argument upon which the discounted cash-flow tion, that accurately describes the engineering realities. The model
approach is based. Jensen's inequality tells us that the expected does not require an a-priori block ordering but can incorporate any
value of a nonlinear function of a random variable is not the feasible mining schedule.1 Only those inputs that are already
same as the nonlinear function evaluated at the expected value produced by current mining industry software and are familiar to
of that variable. Hence the price distribution does matter in the mining professionals are needed. The optimization problem is
nonlinear case. formulated and solved as a system of nonlinear PDEs that can be
The first paper to incorporate real options theory in natural solved with a specially designed numerical implementation. The
resource project valuation was Brennan and Schwartz (1985). PDE simultaneously solves for the value, optimal cut-off strategy,
Other authors following this example have written extensively and the hedging statistics for every possible future price scenario.
on the use of real options in mining including: Sabour and Poulin This information can subsequently be used to simulate optimal
(2006), Samis and Poulin (2001)), Trigeorgis and Schwartz (2004), mine operation through time in order to assess and measure the
Dessureault et al. (2007), Dogbe et al. (2007), Guj and Garzon operational, market and margin risk of mining firms.
(2007), and Shafiee and Topal (2007). None of these citations The model does not rely on arbitrage assumptions and as such
however consider cut-off grade optimization. can be used for speculation purposes. However, when combined
Most of the real options mining literature to date has consid- with modern asset pricing theory and using financial parameters
ered finite choice models. Examples include options on the timing determined from the prices of market observed derivatives, the
of opening a mine, options on whether or not to expand the mine, model can be easily calibrated and produces unambiguous valua-
or options to temporarily or permanently abandon the mine. All of tions and dynamic cut-off strategies.
these types of options present yes/no type decisions throughout In addition, several new insights into the economic definition
the time horizon. In contrast to these finite choice models, cut-off of ore are explored. Among these insights is the observation that
optimization under uncertainty is an optimal control problem in in the presence of market uncertainty, cut-off grades are far lower
which the cut-off level (or levels in the case of multiple processes) than those predicted using the traditional deterministic models
can take on any continuous value. Hence numerical techniques that are commonly implemented by mining companies. This ef-
such as the least-square Monte-Carlo approach that is used so fect is most pronounced for marginal mines and is greater when
successfully in Sabour and Poulin (2006) and that rely on the discount rates are higher. Another key insight is that when valu-
finite choice assumption can become cumbersome and possibly ation time horizons are longer, cut-off values are dramatically
intractable in mathematical settings for which the set of possi- lower. Often governments consider longer time horizons than
ble decisions is very large. Hence numerical methods specifically mining firms suggesting that without the correct public policies
designed to incorporate both finite choice and optimal control are in place these two parties' interests may not be properly aligned.
required. The recent related work Evatt et al. (2013) discusses a general
The first paper to incorporate price uncertainty in cut-off grade methodology for quantifying the effect of price uncertainty within
optimization was Krautkraemer (1988). In this paper the mineral reserve estimates, in order to provide both the expected reserve size
deposit was represented by a cylinder with the highest grade at its and the associated distribution. The (Evatt et al., 2013) paper makes
axis, and decreasing grades outwards towards the cylinder's use of a PDE model similar to the one developed in this paper but
circumference. This simple geometry and grade distribution requires a cut-off strategy as an input. Hence the numerical method
allowed for the development of an analytically convenient solu- for calculating cut-off strategies presented in this paper provides a
tion. Unfortunately the method could not be applied to the more complimentary tool for use with this aforementioned work.
complex geometry and grade distributions found in actual mines. In the next section we describe the engineering model, in
Mardones (1993) took a different approach and attempted to section “Modeling price dynamics” we develop the financial
extend Lane's work into the contingent claims framework, how- model, in section “PDE Derivation” we derive the PDEs and
ever in this work the cutoff grade was not optimized simulta- describe the numerical solution method and in section “Results”
neously with the value function. we illustrate the solution with data inspired from the Grum
In the ground breaking work of Johnson et al. (2010), both deposit of the Faro mine complex located in the Yukon. In section
stochastic price and a more detailed geological model were incor- “Discussion and explanation of results” we provide an explanation
porated. The mine was divided into thousands individual blocks, the for the observed results and provide a explanation for why cut-off
order of extraction of which was assumed to be sequential and policies that account for price uncertainties are at odds with
required to be known a priori. A partial differential equation (PDE) traditional cut-off theory.
was then derived for the optimal value of the mine from which the
optimal strategy for processing the blocks could be determined.
From this initial block ordering, the model then decided whether to
process or waste each given block, at a given time, in a yes/no Mining model
binary pattern. This is an effective approach if a block ordering is
given a-priori however, it is highly dependent on this ordering. In this section we first provide a general description of the
If the block ordering is changed a different cut-off strategy may physical component of the model before developing the mathe-
result. Another difficulty with this approach is that in practice matical representation. The model aspires to match standard
the exact mineral content of any given block is highly uncertain mining engineering practice as closely as possible in order to
until the block has been exposed, and without this accurate achieve the most realistic description of the problem.
knowledge of this information, a feasible block ordering cannot Open pit mine design is a multi-step process which involves
be made. In addition, multiple blocks of ore and waste are the determination of a number of technical parameters and the
routinely processed simultaneously in order to maintain a steady
flow of ore to the processing plant. These facts make the required 1
To be clear, the algorithm presented here does not optimize block-ordering it
fixed, sequential, a-priori block ordering difficult to employ in only determines cut-off strategy from an average phase distribution.
M. Thompson, D. Barr / Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92 85

design of a number of aspects of the operation. The initial input With this technical background in hand we can begin the
into the design process is a resource model. The resource model is mathematical description of the model. We begin by defining the
a spatial representation of the ore-body as interpreted by geolo- key variables of the problem. Let I be the size of the total deposit
gists. Although there are a number of formats the resource model remaining and n be the total number of phases in the mine design.
can take, by far the most common is a three dimensional array of Then let j(I) be a function mapping ½0; I max   R-½1; 2; …; n  N
blocks, referred to as a block model. A resource geologist assigns that determines the current phase number given a value of I where
properties to each block in the array, such as its metal grade(s), Imax is the total amount of material contained in the ultimate pit.
density and geological characteristics using various geo-statistical Any volume of rock within a given phase can be classified by its
methods. fraction of recoverable metal content. This fraction is referred to as
Based on the resource model, mine planning engineers esti- the recoverable grade of the rock. Let g be the recoverable grade of
mate the mining capacities the deposit could support. Rough a given piece of rock (i.e. if g ¼0.05 then 5% of the rock, if
operating costs can then be determined from these capacities. processed, could be turned into metal). Furthermore let PDjðIÞ ðgÞ
With this information and a few other technical parameters, be the phase distribution: the total amount of rock in phase j(I)
planning engineers can develop the ultimate pit limits. The with recoverable grade g. Phase distributions given in histogram
ultimate pit is the excavation such that no combination of blocks form are direct outputs of standard mine design software (such as
could be subtracted or added to the outline that would increase SURPAC). Finally let S be the spot prices of the metal.
value (Whittle, 1990). Several commercial software packages, From these basic definitions, if S represents the price of metal
including Whittle TM, have become industry standard tools used and t the current time, then we can define cðS; I; tÞ to be the grade
to determine the ultimate pit based on all the required technical value that is to be determined by the model. For simplicity of
parameters. exposition, from this point on we will suppress the functional
Once the ultimate pit has been outlined the design engineers dependence notation of c. c is defined such that if a unit of rock
begin to schedule the extraction of the material within this contains metal grade fraction g then if g Z c the rock is considered
excavation limit. This long term, life-of-mine, scheduling is usually ore, otherwise it is considered waste. Thus c is the point that
done in a series of successively more detailed stages. The first delineates the distinction between ore and waste. The total
stage is the development of intermediate excavation limits called amount of ore OðI; cÞ in phase j(I) is therefore given by
push-backs. A series of push-backs are nested within the pre- Z 1
viously determined ultimate pit. Push-backs are designed to help OðI; cÞ ¼ PDjðIÞ ðgÞ dg tonnes ð1Þ
c
ensure a sufficient ore feed at all times to meet the plant capacities
as well as bring forward cash flows and delay costs as much as and the total amount of waste WðI; cÞ in the phase is
possible. The push-backs can then themselves be further divided. Z c
The result of the scheduling process is a sequence of excavations WðI; cÞ ¼ PDjðIÞ ðgÞ dg tonnes: ð2Þ
0
within the ultimate pit that are to be mined in order. Each of these
sequenced excavations will henceforth be referred to as a phase. The stripping ratio of waste-to-ore SRðI; cÞ is then given by
The distribution of grades within the phase can be determined WðI; cÞ
SRðI; cÞ ¼ : ð3Þ
be querying the resource model. Each phase may consist of OðI; cÞ
hundreds or possibly thousands of individual blocks that have
If Kmine and Kproc are the maximum mining and processing
been chosen to achieve a feasible mining schedule. While the
constraints respectively (measured in tonnes per year) then the
exact mineral content of each block has a very high degree of
resource depletion rate or extraction rate ExðI; cÞ measured in years
uncertainty prior to excavation, by combining many such blocks
is given by
into a phase the overall grade distribution of the phase is known
with a high degree of accuracy. ExðI; cÞ ¼ minðK proc ð1 þ SRðI; cÞÞ; K mine Þ ð4Þ
Once the long-term mine excavations and schedule have been To understand Eq. (4) suppose the stripping ratio SR was 3. Then
defined, the cut-off grade strategy is determined. While the mine three units of waste are extracted for every one unit of ore, so the
design and phases are generally fixed once in operation, the cut- maximum rate that we could extract material from the deposit
off strategy used for scheduling production of the mine is flexible before hitting the processing constraint would be 4Kproc. If this
and can be adjusted in response to market forces. During the value was greater than the mining constraint Kmine then Kmine
mine's operation, short term planning staff schedule multiple would determine the extraction rate. The rate of change of I is
simultaneous block extractions such that the overall material is therefore given by
extracted as closely as possible to the target waste to ore ratio,
known as the strip ratio, dictated by the chosen cut-off grade and dI
¼  ExðI; CÞ ð5Þ
the grade distribution of the accessible material. This ensures a dt
steady flow of ore to the processing facility and prevents oscilla- In Fig. 1 we plot Ex as a function of cut-off for a single phase of
tions between over and under utilization of the processing the Faro mine complex. We see from this graph that when cut-off
capabilities. Individual block extraction is only scheduled once grade is zero all rock is sent to the processing mill and the
the cut-off definition is given and the grade of each block is known extraction rate is at its slowest. As cut-off increases the rate of
with a higher degree of certainty. extraction increases in a nonlinear fashion, until the maximum
From the stripping ratio given by the cut-off definition, the rate mining rate restricts further increase.
of resource depletion then depends on which of the processing or In addition to the extraction rate we know the rate of produc-
the mining constraint is binding. The processing constraint is the tion of metal while operating in phase j(I). Metal production is
maximum capacity of the processing unit, while the mining simply the product of the processing rate multiplied by the
constraint is the maximum amount of rock that can be excavated average recoverable grade of ore in the phase, in other words
at a given time. Ore and waste are then extracted in the propor- the quantity Q ðI; cÞ of metal produced is
tions given by the stripping ratio until one of these two constraints R1
ExðI; cÞ c gPDjðIÞ ðgÞ dg
limit the rate of further extraction. It is in this way that the phase Q ðI; cÞ ¼ ð6Þ
1 þ SRðI; cÞ OðI; cÞ
distribution and the cut-off decision dictate the rate of metal
production, resource depletion and all associated costs. where the first of the two above fractions is the amount of ore
86 M. Thompson, D. Barr / Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92

processed and the second of the two is the average grade of the x 10
8
Annualized Total Production Cost By Cuttoff Grade
ore being processed. In Fig. 2 we plot Q as a function of cut-off for a 5

single phase of the Faro mine complex. Note the original data
consisted of two metals but we have consolidated them into a
4.5
single metal for ease of exposition. The extension to the poly-
metalic case is discussed later. From this graph we can see that the
output rate initially increases with c as higher grade ore causes

Total Production Cost ($)


4
output rates to increase. Output rates then begin to decrease once
the maximum mining rate constraint limits the delivery of ore to
the processing facility leaving some processing capacity idle. 3.5
Finally if the cost of extraction is Cmine dollars per tonne and the
cost of processing is Cproc dollars per tonne and the fixed costs are
Cfixed then the cashflow generated in an interval of time dt 3

measured in years is given by


  2.5
ExðI; cÞ
CflowðS; I; cÞ ¼ S  Q ðI; cÞ  C mine ExðI; cÞ C proc  C fixed dt:
1 þ SRðI; cÞ
ð7Þ 2
0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 0.14
Cutoff Grade

Fig. 3. Annualized production costs as a function of cut-off.


Annualized Mine Extraction Rate By Cuttoff Grade
0.3

Fig. 3 depicts production costs as a function of cut-off. This graph


0.25 shows that production costs increase initially with cut-off level until
Fraction of the Mine Extracted per Year

the maximum mining rate constraint limits the amount of ore sent
to the processing mill thereby reducing total processing costs.
0.2 In the case of a poly-metallic mine the definition of cut-off
must be modified slightly. Since ore is converted to cash at the
spot price that prevails at the time of extraction if we have M
0.15
metals in the deposit with grades g 1 ; g 2 ; …; g M respectively each
with spot price S1 ; S2 ; …; SM then the cut-off c is defined by the
0.1 inequality
∑M
i ¼ 1 Si g i
Zc
0.05 ∑M i ¼ 1 Si

and the integrals in Eqs. (1), (2) and (6) must be modified to the
0 appropriate multiple integral representation.
0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.1
Cutoff Grade

Fig. 1. Annualized rock extraction rate (fraction of deposit per year) as a function of Modeling price dynamics
cut-off.
The fundamental consideration in cut-off grade determination
is the trade-off between present and future price levels. In
addition hedging activities rely on futures contracts. Hence a
natural framework to account for these two considerations is a
x 105 Annualized Metal Production Rate By Cuttoff Grade
3.5 forward curve pricing model. Let Fðt; TÞ be the expected metal
price for delivery at time T given information available at the
3
current time t where t oT and where the expectation is taken
under some, as of yet unspecified, probability measure. At this
point we are intentionally agnostic as to the probability meas-
2.5
Tonnes of Metal Produced

ure so that the subsequent analysis applies equally to valuation


or speculation purposes. In a real options, no-arbitrage based
2 approach the risk neutral probability measure is used and Fðt; TÞ
would represent the market observable futures curve (hence no
1.5 price forecasting is required in the no-arbitrage framework).
Since we have assumed that Fðt; TÞ is the expectation under the
1 chosen measure it cannot have a drift in that same measure
(otherwise Fðt; TÞ would not be the expectation, Fðt; TÞ plus the
0.5 drift would be). Hence we employ a standard lognormal model of
the form
dFðt; TÞ
¼ σ e  ηðT  tÞ dX
0
0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 0.14 ð8Þ
Fðt; TÞ
Cutoff Grade
where σ and η are constant and where dX is the standard
Fig. 2. Annualized metal production in tonnes as a function of cut-off line
intercept given. increment of Brownian motion.
M. Thompson, D. Barr / Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92 87

In Clewlow and Strickland (Preprint) it was shown that under Black–Scholes equation for equity derivatives. If r is the discount
suitable differentiability assumptions, a spot price S consistent rate, let
with this model is Z T 
  VðΦ; I; t; cÞ ¼ maxE e  rðτ  tÞ CflowðΦðτÞ; Iðτ Þ; cðτÞÞ dτ : ð15Þ
dS ∂ lnFð0; tÞ σ2 c
þ ηð lnðFð0; tÞÞ  lnðSðtÞÞÞ þ ð1  e  2ηt Þ dt þ σ dX:
t
¼
S ∂t 4 Where E½ is the expectation under the chosen probability
ð9Þ measure, conditioned on the information available at time t.
Hence the model in Eq. (8) is the standard mean reverting This equation can be rewritten as
Z t0
lognormal model used in most real options mining literature,
adjusted to ensure that the forward prices match the initial value V ¼ maxE e  rðτ  tÞ CflowðΦ; I; cÞ dτ
c t
Fð0; TÞ exactly. The exponential decay rate parameter η in Eq. (8) Z T 
 rðτ  tÞ
corresponds to the mean reversion rate of Eq. (9). Rather than þ e CflowðΦ; I; cÞ dτ
t0
using either of these equivalent formulations, in this paper we will Z t0
use a third equivalent form, but one that gives rise to better ¼ maxE e  rðτ  tÞ CflowðΦ; I; cÞ dτ
c t
computational properties. Z 
T
Given the initial expectations curve Fð0; TÞ we know that at any
e  rðτ  t Þ CflowðΦ; I; cÞ dτ
0 0
þ e  rðt  tÞ
time t t0
Z 
 Z t  t0
e  rðτ  tÞ CflowðΦ; I; cÞ dτ þ e  rðt
0 0
1 ¼ maxE  tÞ
VðΦ ; I 0 ; t 0 Þ
Fðt; TÞ ¼ Fð0; TÞexp  σ 2 e  2ηðT  tÞ þ σ e  ηðT  sÞ dXðsÞ ð10Þ c t
2 0

If we let
where Φ and I 0 are the (unknown) values of Φ and I at time t 0 4 t.
0
Z t
By letting t 0 be a small increment greater than t (i.e. t 0 ¼ t þ dt)
Φ¼ e  ηðt  sÞ dXðsÞ ð11Þ
0 then employing Ito's lemma we expand the right hand side of the
above equation in a Taylor's series using (13) and (5) to yield
then since the spot price S(t) at time t is always simply Fðt; tÞ we
also have V ¼ maxE½CflowðΦ; I; cÞ dt þ ð1  r dtÞV þ ð1  r dtÞ
c
 
1 ðV t  ηΦV Φ þ 12 V ΦΦ  ExðI; cÞV I Þ dt þð1 r dtÞ dX
SðtÞ ¼ Fð0; tÞ exp  σ 2 e  2ηðT  tÞ þ σ e  ηðT  tÞ Φ ð12Þ
2

Therefore rather than deriving a stochastic differential equation Eliminating all terms that go to zero faster than dt and simplifying
for S it is easier to use Φ as the random variable and use Eq. (12) to shows that
convert back and forth between the two representations. Differ- 0 ¼ maxE½ðV t  ηΦV Φ þ 12 V ΦΦ  ExðI; cÞV I
entiating equation (11) with respect to t shows that this variable c

obey the stochastic differential equation  rV þ CflowðΦ; I; cÞÞÞ dt þ V Φ dX:

dΦðtÞ ¼  ηΦðtÞ dt þ dXðtÞ ð13Þ Taking expectations and dividing through by dt gives

By using Φ instead of S we achieve many advantages. Firstly, max½V t  ηΦV Φ þ 12 V ΦΦ  ExðI; cÞV I  rV þ CflowðΦ; I; cÞÞ ¼ 0
c
the stochastic equation for ϕ is simple, and time independent.
The only two terms in the above equation involve c, so the optimal
Secondly, by using this change of variables there is no need to
value for c maximizes
bootstrap a time-dependent convenience yield or instantaneous
volatility function in order to ensure that the future expectations max½  ExðI; cÞV I þ CflowðΦ; I; cÞ: ð16Þ
c
of S match those of the initial forecast Fð0; TÞ, because Eq. (12)
handles these details. Moreover, in contrast to the spot price SDE This result implies that if cn ðΦ; I; tÞ represents the value of c that
of Eq. (9), in this formulation the function Fð0; tÞ need not be maximizes Eq. (16) then
differentiable. It need not even be continuous. Any initial forecast V t  ηΦV Φ þ 12 V ΦΦ  ExðI; cn ÞV I  rV þ CflowðΦ; I; cn Þ ¼ 0: ð17Þ
can be applied without affecting the validity of the SDEs or the
We now have two conditions which will allow us to simulta-
numerical solution procedure. Lastly, the PDEs that result from
neously determine the optimal mine value VðΦ; I; tÞ and the
using this change of variables have improved stability properties
optimal strategy cn ðΦ; I; tÞ. It remains only to define boundary
and the resulting differentiation matrix becomes time indepen-
conditions.
dent, so that its computationally expensive construction need not
The terminal condition at time T is evident from Eq. (15), and is
be re-calibrated at every time-step.
given by
If we change variables from S to Φ then the cash flow model of
Eq. (7) must be modified accordingly to VðΦ; I; TÞ ¼ 0 ð18Þ
 2  2ηðT  tÞ þ σ e  ηðT  tÞ Φ
CflowðΦ; I; cÞ ¼ Fð0; tÞe  ð1=2Þσ e Q ðI; cÞ The boundary condition for I ¼0 is that once the mine has been
 exhausted the value is zero
ExðI; cÞ
 C mine ExðI; cÞ  C proc  C fixed dt: ð14Þ VðΦ; 0; tÞ ¼ 0:
1 þ SRðI; cÞ
Two more boundary conditions are required in order to complete
the formulation, this is where the option to temporarily shut-
down comes into play.
PDE derivation Let WðΦ; I; tÞ be the value of the mine given that it has been
temporarily shut down. Let Coffline be the costs of maintaining the
Now that we have representations for the dynamic processes mine in this state and let C turnon be the cost of transitioning from
which govern the variables I and Φ, we can set out to derive an off-line state to an on-line state and let C turnoff be the costs
equations for the optimal value VðΦ; I; tÞ in a way analogous to the of transitioning from an on-line state to an off-line state. By
88 M. Thompson, D. Barr / Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92

repeating the steps in the derivation of V we find that since Ex  0 derivative with respect to Φ at interior grid point i would be
when off-line W must obey the PDE calculated using the formula

W t  ηΦV Φ þ 12 W ΦΦ  rW  C offline ¼ 0 ð19Þ ∂V ki;j V kiþ 1;j  V ki 1;j


¼ ð26Þ
with ∂Φ ð2δΦÞ

WðΦ; I; TÞ ¼ 0 and ð20Þ where δΦ is the distance between grid points in the Φ axis. The
second partial derivative with respect to Φ at interior grid point i
WðΦ; 0; tÞ ¼ 0: ð21Þ would be calculated using the formula

The values of W and V are tied to each other because of the ∂2 V ki;j V kiþ 1;j 2V ki;j þ V ki 1;j
option to switch between on and off-line states by paying the ¼ ð27Þ
∂Φ
2
ðδΦÞ2
appropriate transition fee. If Φn1 ðIÞ represents the value of Φ for
which it is optimal to switch to an off-line state from an on-line Derivatives at the boundary can be determined simply by
state given I, then the value matching condition requires that applying the condition that values are linear in price when prices
are extremely high or low, to predict the values of V kiþ 1;j or V ki 1;j
VðΦ1 ðIÞ; I; tÞ ¼ WðΦ ðIÞ; I; tÞ  C turnoff :
n n
ð22Þ
outside the grid via extrapolation.
The value of Φ1 ðIÞ is determined from the “smooth pasting
n The partial derivative with respect to I in Eq. (17) is far more
condition:” complicated and cannot be calculated the same way as the
derivatives with respect to Φ. Since Eq. (17) depends only on the
∂VðΦ1 ðIÞ; I; tÞ ∂WðΦ1 ðIÞ; I; tÞ
n n
¼ ð23Þ first derivative with respect to I, it behaves as a hyperbolic
∂Φ ∂Φ equation in the I dimension. Since the coefficient in front of VI in
Similarly if Φ2 ðIÞ represents the value of Φ for which it is
n Eq. (17) is always negative the boundary information flows into
optimal to switch to an on-line state from an off-line state given I, the solution domain from smaller values of I and derivative
then the value matching condition requires that approximations must only use information at values of I less than
or equal to the current level. This concept is referred to as upwind
WðΦ2 ðIÞ; I; tÞ ¼ VðΦ2 ðIÞ; I; tÞ  C turnon :
n n
ð24Þ differencing in the computational fluid dynamics literature.
Due to the fact that there is no diffusion in the I dimension,
The value of Φ2 ðIÞ is determined from the “smooth pasting
n
second order accurate upwind differencing schemes can suffer
condition:” instabilities and wild spurious numerical oscillations can occur.
The intuition behind this is that since numerical differentiation,
∂WðΦ2 ðIÞ; I; tÞ WðΦ2 ðIÞ; I; tÞ
n n
¼ ð25Þ represents the division of two small quantities, it is quite suscep-
∂Φ ∂Φ
tible to high frequency noise. For diffusive PDEs this effect is
Eqs. (22) and (23) are lower free boundary conditions respect to reduced by the smoothing nature of diffusion. However hyperbolic
Φ while Eqs. (24) and (25) provides an upper free boundary equations do not smooth high frequency noise but rather shift
condition on W with respect to Φ. One final boundary condition is initial data along characteristic lines.
required for each of the PDEs V and W. As Φ approaches infinity so One approach to overcoming these spurious numerical oscilla-
too does the spot price of metal and the chances of the temporary tions is to use a first order upwind differencing scheme. The
shut down decision ever being exercised goes to zero, in addition drawback with this approach is that it can be less accurate and
all ore is considered economical and the operating strategy therefore spatial step sizes need to be smaller. This can increase
becomes constant. In such price regions the function V is therefore the computational complexity of the problem. The reason why
linear in S. Numerically it is impossible to solve for values of Φ at first order upwind differencing schemes work for hyperbolic
71 so a far field boundary condition must be applied in which problems is that they actually create an artificial numerical
the infinite boundary condition is applied at finite values of Φ diffusion. In essence they work because the numerical errors act
chosen to be sufficiently far that the probability of Φ ever reaching as a diffusion in the problem. This insight lead researchers to a
these extremes is negligible and as such the approximate location class of numerical schemes known as total variation diminishing
of the boundary condition has no impact on the solution in the (TVD) schemes. The basic premise of such techniques is to use a
region of interest. second order accurate scheme everywhere except in places in
which the slope is changing rapidly, when this occurs a tiny
amount of artificial diffusion is introduced to prevent instability.
Numerical solution method In this way one can achieve stability and preserve second order
accuracy see LeVeque (1992). A full discussion is beyond the scope
In what follows, an explicit finite difference solution to the PDE of this paper and interested readers are referred to LeVeque
is employed. However due to the nature of the system of PDEs of (1992). One such TVD scheme is known as the “minmod slope
interest, direct application of standard finite difference methods limiter” finite difference formula and it is given by
that are commonly used to solve Black–Scholes type equations are
unstable for the given application. Instead a flux-limiting upwind ∂V ki;j  ðV ki;j  1  V ki;j Þ
¼
scheme must be employed similar to what was used successfully ∂I δI
in Thompson et al. (2004) for power plant valuation and was
outlined in Thompson et al. (2009) for gas storage valuation. αþ k α k
þ ðV i;j  V ki;j  1 Þ  ðV  V ki;j Þ ð28Þ
We begin by discretizing each of the independent variables Φ 2δI 2δI i;j þ 1
and I into a grid. Let V ki;j and W ki;j correspond to the value of V and
W at the ith grid point value of Φ, the jth grid point value of I at where
time step k for the functions V and W respectively. Then the first !!
V ki;j  1  V ki;j  2
step would be to calculate all of the appropriate partial derivatives α þ ¼ max 0; min 1;
at each grid point at a given time step. For example the partial V ki;j  V ki;j  1
M. Thompson, D. Barr / Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92 89

and separate processing type whereby instead of receiving the spot


!! price, such metals receive the discounted futures price associated
V ki;j  V ki;j  1
α  ¼ max 0; min 1; k : with the expected time of processing. Such an assumption would
V i;j þ 1  V ki;j be easy to implement however, some of the real optionality
Finally, in the explicit finite difference case we approximate the associated with the timing of the storage option would be lost.
time derivative by To correct for this storage error a commodity storage model such
as those found in Secomandi (2010), Lai et al. (forthcoming), Lai
∂V ki;j V ki;j  V ki;j 1
¼ : ð29Þ et al. (forthcoming), Carmona and Ludkovski (2010), Chen and
∂t δt Forsyth (2007), and Thompson et al. (2009) would need to be
In solving the PDE we use a backward recursion. If K represents developed and solved simultaneously with the cut-off optimiza-
the last time step, then from the time T boundary conditions (18) tion. Such complexity is beyond the scope of the current paper.
we know V Ki;j ¼ 0 and W Ki;j ¼ 0 for all i and j. Given knowledge V ki;j So far we have only considered mines with a single metal.
and W ki;j at any k we can calculate ∂V ki;j =∂I using Eq. (28) and from Extensions to the polymetallic case is straight forward in the
this we can find cki;j by optimizing Eq. (16). We then substitute modeling sense, in that the above PDEs would contain more than
these values of c along with the derivative approximations in Eqs. one Φ variable and associated partial derivatives, there would also
(26)–(29) into Eq. (17) and solve for V ki;j 1 . By applying the be cross-derivative partials if the metals were correlated. The finite
equivalent formulas for W we can also find W ki;j 1 . To apply the difference based solution approach used in this paper could
boundary conditions (22) and (24) at the k  1 time-step, we be extended to at most three metals before the computational
compare the values of V ki;j 1 with those of W ki;j 1 for all i and j complexity becomes impractical. For cases involving more than
and if V ki;j 1 o W ki;j 1 C turnoff then we set V ki;j 1 ¼ W ki;j 1  C turnoff three products, RBF-PDE approaches such as those found in
and if W ki;j 1 o V ki;j 1  C turnon then we set W ki;j 1 ¼ V ki;j 1  C turnon . For Thompson (2013) or sparse grid techniques such as those found
a reference on using this approach to solving the free boundary in Reisinger and Wittum (2007) would have to be employed. Since
problem (smooth pasting) in this way see Tavella and Randall the vast majority of mines have three or fewer metals present in
(2000). The conditions for stability are that δt r δΦ and that
2
economically significant quantities, for most applications the finite
δΦ r 2=maxjηΦi j. difference framework will be sufficient.
The above model also assumes only one stochastic factor is
Model assumptions, limitations and extensions responsible for the fluctuations in the future price expectations.
Adding more than two additional sources of risk would require the
Before we proceed to the numerical results of the proposed use of the more sophisticated numerical techniques mentioned
model we will briefly discuss some of the assumptions and above. However, for simplicity we leave the extensions to those
limitations of the model. Additionally, extensions and impro- cases for future work. Most real options mining models in the
vements that we have left out of the current analysis in order literature have fewer than three risk factors so this assumption is
to avoid overcomplicating the model and obscuring the main not overly restrictive. More importantly understanding and
insights, are discussed. demonstrating the nature of the impact of stochasticity on cut-
In the above formulation it is assumed that the choice of cut-off off grade is more transparent and easier to visualize in the single
grade is continuous in time as opposed to being discrete. This does factor case.
not however, imply that cut-off decisions must be constantly
changed, as the subsequent results will show. What the contin-
uous time assumption does imply is that if prices change sig-
nificantly enough to warrant a different cut-off policy, that policy Results
can be implemented without delay. One could also model cut-off
decisions as occurring at finite pre-defined time intervals. In such In this section we implement the proposed model and inves-
a model if market prices change, management would be prevented tigate the impact of price stochasticity on the economic definition
from changing the cut-off policy until the next artificially defined of ore. For simplicity we assume that all phases have identical
time-step. Since typically management is free to make such phase distributions and we use the extraction rate function shown
decisions when they see fit, the continuous time assumption is in Fig. 1, the metal production function shown in Fig. 2, and the
justified. Even though in practice cut-off is only changed periodi- production cost function shown in Fig. 3. None of these assump-
cally when market prices dictate the continuous time assumption tions affect the complexity of the algorithm or the solution
provides for the flexibility of the timing of those changes to occur methodology and have only been made to facilitate the exposition.
whenever management requires. A more complicated phase design would make it difficult to
In this formulation we only consider a single processing mode. distinguish between the effects of price stochasticity from those
Often mines will have more than one processing method such as a of changing geology.
mill and leach bed for instance. To incorporate multiple processing We see in Fig. 1 that at the lowest cut-off level where at least
types into the model, each process would have its own character- some ore is present in the deposit, the extraction rate is 0.2. This
istics and would require its own cut-off level. Such cases are easily implies that it takes 5 years to extract all the material from the
incorporated into the above framework. The resulting PDEs would mine. When the cutoff rises to approximately 0.035 the extraction
be the same except that the functions Ex and Cflow would contain rate levels off at approximately .25 which corresponds to a mine
more than one cut-off variable and the optimization in Eq. (16) life of 4 years. Hence without temporary abandonment the mine
would be multi-dimensional and hence take slightly longer. life varies from 4 to 5 years depending on cut-off choice.
However, neither change would significantly impact the computa- In all experiments the initial futures curve Fð0; TÞ is assumed to
tional complexity of the model as the computational complexity of be the constant Fð0; TÞ ¼ $1520 per tonne. The values of the
finite difference solutions to PDEs is governed mainly by the various cost parameters are as follows: C turnon ¼ $1; 000; 000,
number of independent variables (Φ and I) which is unaffected C turnoff ¼ $1; 000; 000 and C offline ¼ $1; 000; 000 per year. The dis-
by the number of processing modes. count rate was assumed to be r ¼0.1 and η was taken to be zero.
Some mines also have the option of stockpiling below cut-off The range of Φ values corresponds to and initial spot price range
grade ore for future processing. This could be modeled as a of just over $300 to just under $11; 000.
90 M. Thompson, D. Barr / Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92

Fig. 4 shows the value of the mine as a function of the initial positive impact of high prices unaffected, the expected value
spot price corresponding to 4 different levels of volatility and time increase.
horizon. The first combination is σ ¼ 0; T ¼ 5 which corresponds to Fig. 5 shows the optimal cut-off grade as a function of spot
the deterministic price case, identical to that assumed by tradi- price for each of the aforementioned four cases. In each case we
tional cut-off models, with a time horizon of 5 years. The second see that as the price falls to very low levels the optimal cut-off
combination σ ¼ 0; T ¼ 10 is another deterministic example but strategy rises dramatically. With very low prices only the highest
with a longer planning horizon. Note that these two curves are grade ore is considered economic. In the zero volatility case the
identical. Due to the time value of money and the flatness of the optimal cut-off policy monotonically decreases with increasing
futures curve, the optimal strategy is extract value now (if prices prices until a constant equilibrium value is reached. However the
are profitable). So long as the time horizon length is sufficiently same cannot be said for the non-zero volatility cases. In the
long to extract all profitable ore, extending the time horizon marginal price region where the asymmetry is the greatest we
beyond this point is inconsequential. The third combination see cut-off values far lower in the stochastic examples than in the
corresponds to σ ¼0.4, T¼ 5 and the fourth combination to deterministic ones and this effect is greater for the longer time
σ ¼ 0.4, T ¼10. In each of these cases we see that the value under horizon. In addition, for prices that are within the region for which
the stochastic model is always higher than under the deterministic the mine would be operating, the optimal cut-off curve is
model. Moreover the highest valuation corresponds to the longer relatively flat in the price variable. This means that even if cut-
time horizon. The realization that valuations are higher in the off is continuously monitored, the optimal cut-off would only need
stochastic case is a basic finding in all real options models. The to be adjusted in the event of extreme price fluctuations. This
intuition behind this finding as volatility increases the likelihood indicates that continuous dynamic cut-off monitoring and control
of very high or very low prices increases. But the option to would not typically result in frequent changes to the cut-off
temporarily shut down production caps the losses associated with definition. The key result would seem to be that cut-off depends
low prices. With the negative impact of low prices capped and the on market price volatility.
In Fig. 6 we hold the spot price constant at $1520 (the marginal
x 109 Value as a Function of Spot Price (I=1)
price) and we plot valuations as a function of I for each of the four
3 cases mentioned earlier. When I ¼0 the mine has been completely
depleted and so the value in all cases is zero. The value is also zero
σ =0, T=10
2.5 for all values of I in the two deterministic cases because the price
σ=0, T=5
σ =.40, T=5 $1520 was chosen to be at the margin. For the two stochastic cases
σ=.40, T=10 value increases as I increases as the larger resource base inherently
2
contains greater option value. Also note that valuations are higher
and increase faster in the longer time horizon case.
1.5 Finally, in Fig. 7 we plot cut-off levels as a function of I for each
Value $

of the four scenarios considered. This figure shows two striking


1 features: first that cut-off levels (and hence waste) is highest in the
deterministic cases compared to the stochastic ones, and second
that cut-off is the lowest in the longer time horizon case.
0.5

0 Discussion and explanation of results

−0.5 So far these examples point to two crucial observations for cut-
500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000
off theory in general. The first observation is that a firm that used
Spot Price $
the traditional deterministic cut-off optimization and ignored
Fig. 4. Mine value as a function of initial spot price for three different volatilities. price uncertainty would, in this example, have wasted large

x 108 Value as a Function of I (Spot Price=$1520)


5
Optimal Cutoff Grade as a Function of Spot Price (I=1)
0.07
σ =0, T=10 4.5
0.065 σ =0, T=5 σ =0, T=10
σ =.40, T=5 4 σ=0, T=5
0.06 σ =.40, T=10 σ =.40, T=5
3.5 σ=.40, T=10
0.055
3
Cutoff Grade

0.05
Value $

2.5
0.045
2
0.04

1.5
0.035

0.03 1

0.025 0.5

0.02 0
1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
Spot Price $ I

Fig. 5. Cutoff as a function of initial spot price for three different volatilities. Fig. 6. Value as a function of I for different parameters.
M. Thompson, D. Barr / Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92 91

Optimal Cutoff Grade as a Function of I (Spot Price=$1520) definition of ore is intertwined with the optimal production and
0.04
operations strategy of the mine. Hence effective, practical models
0.035
and numerical techniques that can incorporate both cut-off grade
optimization and real optionality, such as the one presented here
0.03
become indispensable.

0.025
Conclusions
Cutoff Grade

0.02
The examples shown in this paper suggest two new insights
σ =0, T=10 into the economic definition of ore. The first is that in the presence
0.015
σ =0, T=5 of market uncertainty, cut-off grades are lower than those pre-
σ =.40, T=5 dicted using traditional deterministic models. This implies that the
0.01
σ =.40, T=10
traditional view may be leading to far greater resource waste than
0.005
is optimal. The second important insight is that when valuation
time horizons are longer, cut-off values are lower. Since govern-
0
ments typically consider longer time horizons than mining firms
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 with finite land lease agreements, the extrinsic value of ore will be
I higher to a government than to a mining firm if both are using a
Fig. 7. Cutoff as a function of initial spot price if I was initially 0.5 for three different stochastic framework. Governments therefore have an interest in
volatilities. encouraging the use of stochastic cut-off models in the mining
industry in order to reduce resource waste and increase valua-
tions. They should also be careful in setting mineral extraction
amounts of valuable material, a fact that has social and environ- agreements in order to ensure that their interests and those of
mental implications beyond the purely economic impacts. The their private partners align as much as possible.
second observation shows that under the stochastic model, time The insight that uncertainty has significant and profound
horizon has a large impact on cut-off. This implies that a firm impacts on cut-off grade definition, which is one of the most
using a stochastic cut-off grade model with a finite mineral lease fundamental operational decisions in mining, motivates the need
will have a higher cut-off (and hence waste more material) than a for further research into mining models that account for cut-off
party with a longer time horizon, such as a government issuing strategies in the face of price uncertainty.
mining leases, would find optimal. Another observation from Fig. 7
is that in both stochastic examples the cut-off levels increase with References
I. In other words, as the resource becomes more plentiful waste
levels are higher than when the resource is more scarce (assuming Ataci, M., 2014. Determination of optimum, cutoff grades of multiple metal deposits
the same time horizon). by using the golden section search method, J. South Afr. Inst. Min. Metall.
Bascetin, A., Nieto, A., 2014. Determination of a mining cutoff grade strategy based
These insights can be explained if one considers the fact that on an iterative factor, in: Proceedings of the SME Annual Meeting.
cut-off decisions involve a trade-off between prices today and Brennan, M., Schwartz, E., 1985. Evaluating natural resource investments. J. Bus. 58,
prices in the future. If the present value of prices are expected to 135–157.
Carmona, R., Ludkovski, M., 2010. Valuation of energy storage: an optimal switching
decline then the optimal strategy is to extract more quickly (higher approach. Quant. Financ. 10, 359–374.
cut-off) in order to receive the highest possible price for the metal. Chen, Z., Forsyth, P., 2007. A semi-Lagrangian approach for natural gas storage
In the absence of stochasticity or real optionality, and all else being valuation and optimal operation. SIAM J. Sci. Comput. 30, 339–368.
Clewlow, L., Strickland, C., Valuing energy options in a one factor model fitted to
equal, the time value of money suggests that money today is more forward prices, Preprint.
valuable then money in the future so prices would be expected to Dessureault, S., Kazakids, V.N., Mayer, Z., 2007. Flexibility valuation in operating
fall which in turn leads to the high cut-off decision. However, this mine decisions using real options pricing. Int. J. Risk Assess. Manag. 7, 656–674.
Dogbe, G., Frimpong, S., Szymanski, J., 2007. Mineral reserve risk in continuous-
changes in the face of uncertainty and real optionality. If one
time stochastic mine valuation. Int. J. Risk Assess. Manag. 7, 675–694.
considers that a mine will not blindly continue to produce metal if Evatt, G., Soltan, M., Johnson, P., 2013. Mineral reserves under price uncertainty.
it is unprofitable to do so, then when calculating the “effective” Resour. Policy 37, 340–345.
expected future price from the perspective of the mine, the Gholamnejad, J., 2014. Incorporation of rehabilitation costs into the optimum cut-
off grade determination. J. South Afr. Inst. Min. Metall.
portion of the price distribution that results in temporary or Guj, P., Garzon, R., 2007. Modern asset pricing—a valuable real option complement
permanent suspension of production should be capped accord- to discounted cash flow modelling of mining projects. In: Procedings Project
ingly, as the mine will never actually realize any of these large, low Evaluation, The Australian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne,
pp. 113–119.
price induced losses. With these low prices capped by the real Johnson, P., Evatt, G., Duck, P., Howell, S., The derivation and impact of an optimal
optionality, and the higher prices unaffected or even enhanced by cut-off grade regime upon mine valuations. In: Proceedings of the World
cut-off flexibility, the “effective” expected future price (from the Congress on Engineering, vol. 1.
Krautkraemer, J.A., 1988. The cut-off grade and the theory of extraction, The Can.
mine's perspective) increases. In addition, the more volatile the J. Econ., 146–160.
price distribution the higher this “effective” expected future price Lai, G., Wang, M.X., Kerkre, S., Scheller-Wolf, A., Secomandi, N., 2014. Valuation of
becomes. In this way volatility and uncertainty act in the opposite storage at a liquefied natural gas terminal, Oper. Res. forthcoming.
Lane, K., 1964. Choosing the optimal cut-off grade, Colorado School of Mines
manner as the discount rate, with the former raising the present Quarterly, pp. 811–829.
value of the“effective” expected future price (from the mine's Lane, K.F., 1988. The Economic Definition or Ore: Cut off Grades in Theory and
perspective) and the latter lowering it. Practice. Mining Journal Books, London.
LeVeque, R.J., 1992. Numerical Methods for Conservation Laws, 2nd edition
The extent to which uncertainty and nonlinearities counteract
Birkhauser, Zurich.
the time-value-of-money effect determines just how suboptimal Mardones, J., 1993. Option valuation of real assets: application to a copper mine
the traditional cut-off assumptions are and consequently how much with operating flexibility. Resour. Policy, 51–65.
excess waste is being produced by mines that employ traditional, Reisinger, C., Wittum, G., 2007. Efficient hierarchical approximation of high-
dimensional option pricing problems. SIAM J. Sci. Comput. 29 (1), 440–458.
deterministic cut-off strategies. When volatility and cash-flow Rendu, J.-M., 2008. An Introduction to Cut-off Grade Estimation. Society for Mining,
nonlinearities are an important aspect, the determination of the Metallurgy, and Exploration, Inc., Littleton, Colorado.
92 M. Thompson, D. Barr / Resources Policy 42 (2014) 83–92

Sabour, S.A., Poulin, R., 2006. Valuing real capital investments using the least- Thompson, M., 2013. Optimal economic dispatch and risk management of thermal
squares Monte Carlo method, Eng. Econ. 141–160. power plants in deregulated markets. Oper. Res. 61 (4), 791–809.
Samis, M., Poulin, D., 2001. Valuing multi-zone deposits with modern asset pricing Thompson, M., Davison, M., Rasmussen, H., 2004. Real options valuation and
(real options) techniques, In: Proceeding of Minsespace, Canadian Institute of optimal operation of electrical power plants in competitive markets. Oper.
Mining and Metallurgy, pp. 1–8. Res. 52, 546–562.
Secomandi, N., 2010. Optimal commodity trading with a capacitated storage asset. Thompson, M., Davison, M., Rasmussen, H., 2009. Natural gas storage valuation and
Manag. Sci. 56, 339–467. optimization: a real options application. Naval Res. Logist. 56 (3), 226–238.
Shafiee, S., Topal, E., 2007. Applied Real Option Valuation (rov) in a Conceptual Trigeorgis, L., Schwartz, R., 2004. Real Options and Investment under Uncertainty.
Mining Project. The Australian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy, Melbourne. MIT Press.
Tavella, D., Randall, C., 2000. Pricing Financial Instruments the Finite Difference Whittle, J., 1990. Open pit optimization. In: Suface Mining, 2nd edition, Society of
Method. John Wiley and Sons, Inc.. Mining Metallurgy and Exploration, Littleton Colorado, pp. 470–475.

You might also like