You are on page 1of 3

Kaplinsky - GVC

The transformation of an heuristic framework into an analytical framework draws on a series of theoretical constructs, namely on changing market
dynamics, core competences and rent, chain governance, upgrading, embeddedness and the subordination of labour
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 2-2

contemporary VCs are considerably richer and more complex than this simple description. The purpose of this chapter is to explore these complexities to
show the analytical strengths of VC analysis and to show their dynamics.
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 3-3

The simple definition of a value chain provided above is an heuristic device which recognises that the life cycle of production, distribution, consumption
and recycling of a product (a physical good or a service) involves a series of discrete and linked activities. It enables us to identify and plot each of these
discrete links in the chain. What it does not do is to tell us anything about the coordination and governance of these diverse activities, the geography in
which these activities are located, their consequences for the distribution of incomes in the chain, or their impact on the environment and their
sustainability. Contemporary VC literature therefore seeks to move beyond heuristic description and to provide an analytical framework which helps us to
understand the economic, social, political and environmental dynamics of the evolving global economy.
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 3-3

six loosely-clustered families of literature


Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 6-6

Williamson’s analysis of why large firms may wish to internalise production – a reduction in transaction costs, the asset-specificity of some inputs and the
inability to trust suppliers – provides important insights into equity based GVCs (Williamson, 1985). But not long after Williamson’s contribution, it
became increasingly clear that large firms were bent on outsourcing non-core-competences (Hamel and Prahalad, 1994). To protect themselves from
the costs identified by Williamson they were required to engage in structured processes of supply chain management (Park, Nayyar and Low, 2013)
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 6-6

Porter’s ‘value system’ (which we call the ‘value chain’) as the ‘value stream’ (Womack and Jones, 1996)
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 7-7

process of supply (inbound logistics, operations, outbound logistics, marketing and sales, and after sales service), the transformation of these inputs into
outputs (production, logistics, quality and continuous improvement processes), and the support services the firm marshals to accomplish this task
(strategic planning, human resource management, technology development and procurement)
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 7-7

New International Division of Labour literature led the way in documenting the global fragmentation of production in the apparel VC (Frobel, Heinrichs
and Kreye, 1980). It
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 7-7

in 1994 Gereffi made the decisive contribution which transformed the heuristic and descriptive analysis of Porter and others into an analytical framework
(Gereffi, G.M. Korzeniewicz and R.P.Korzeniewicz, 1994). As such he can be anointed as ‘parent’ of modern GVC theory
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 8-8

his central insight was to place power and governance at the centre of these trends
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 8-8

involving complex relationships between independent firms – required coordination, and that this coordination had embedded power relations in which
lead firms controlled the dynamics of the chain
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 8-8

ambiguity of the word ‘commodities


Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 8-8

In so doing, it also sharpened the focus of the GVC framework on value creation, rents and their impact on distribution
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 8-8

intensity of global competition and the danger that insertion in GVCs might in some cases lead to a race to the bottom, upgrading was placed at the
centre of GVC analysis (Humphrey and Schmitz, 2000; Kaplinsky and Morris, 2001)
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 8-8

the networks associated with GVCs have to be taken account. This led to a family of research on Global Production Networks (GPNs) (Henderson et al,
2002: Coe et al, 2008). More recently, the analysis of embeddedness (that is, the social and political ties of local actors) has been explicitly linked to the
International Business literature on FDI, and has focused on the extent to which the embeddedness of subcontracting firms contributes to the
sustainability of subcontracted
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 8-8

production in footloose GVCs (Morris and Staritz, 2014). Although often describing itself as presenting an independent perspective, in reality good GPN
research focuses also on vertical chain relationships, and good GVC research also addresses the embeddedness of local actors and the importance of
national and regional systems of innovation (Parrillie, Nadvi and Yeung, 2013
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 9-9

In this section we consider six of these analytical underpinnings – the nature of final
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 10-10

markets; core competences, outsourcing and rents, chain governance; the complexity of upgrading; embeddedness in production; and the subordination
of labour as a determinant of location.
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 10-10

Taken together these two assumptions were helpful in explaining industrial structure in the global economy until the late 1960s. This reflected a
supplypushed world in which producers sold into price-sensitive, predictable and relatively unchanging final markets generally characterised (in the post
World War Two environment) by a shortage of supply. This final market structure in the now high income markets began to change radically from the
1970s. It reflected the end of relative scarcity and the emergence of customers seeking for branded and individualised products. It also reflected a world
of intensifying competition as trade barriers were lowered and global producers began to emerge. At the same time, new structures of production
allowed producers to tailor their final products to these increasingly differentiating markets. In their path-breaking book, The Second Industrial Divide (the
first divide being the transition to mass production in the first half of the twentieth century) Piore and Sabel characterised this as a process of flexible
specialisation (Piore and Sabel, 1984). The title of the book captures the increasingly niched basis of dynamic markets. But this fragmented market
structure was subject also to increasing volatility and time to market became an imperative for profitable production (Stalk and Hout, 1990). These
changing market requirements placed enormous pressure on firms which had been accustomed to a world of stable and predictable markets which
largely accepted their product offerings. They consequently had to find a way of adapting to this new competition, and one path to this was to refine and
specialise their roles in their value chains. They did this in part by focusing on their core competences.2.2. Core Competences, outsourcing and rents
Core competences describe a series of capabilities which satisfy three basic conditions – they are unique to the firm, they are difficult to copy and they
have a value in the market place (Hamel and Prahalad, 1994). In a world of growing knowledge-intensity in production, there is increasing space for
unique capabilities. But at the same time, in a world of intensifying10
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 10-10

Taken together these two assumptions were helpful in explaining industrial


Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 10-10

structure in the global economy until the late 1960s. This reflected a supplypushed world in which producers sold into price-sensitive, predictable and
relatively unchanging final markets generally characterised (in the post World War Two environment) by a shortage of supply.
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 10-10

In their path-breaking book, The Second Industrial Divide (the first divide being the transition to mass production in the first half of the twentieth century)
Piore and Sabel characterised this as a process of flexible specialisation (Piore and Sabel, 1984). The title of the book captures the increasingly niched
basis of dynamic markets. But this fragmented market structure was subject also to increasing volatility and time to market became an imperative for
profitable production (Stalk and Hout, 1990).
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 10-10

These changing market requirements placed enormous pressure on firms which had been accustomed to a world of stable and predictable markets
which largely accepted their product offerings
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 10-10

Core competences describe a series of capabilities which satisfy three basic conditions – they are unique to the firm, they are difficult to copy and they
have a value in the market place (Hamel and Prahalad, 1994)
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 10-10

Underlying these linked processes of core competences and outsourcing is the concept of rent
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 11-11

A rent is an attribute which is protected from competition. In Ricardo’s original conception, rents were natural endowments, gifts of nature reflected in the
differential productivity of parcels of land (Ricardo, 1817). But developments of the theory of rent see it as an outcome of agency – rents can be created
or augmented. In the Schumpeterian and Marxian framework’s it is the pursuit of rent which drives innovation (Kaplinsky, 2005). But the capacity to
generate rents through purposeful activity needs to complemented by the capacity to protect and appropriate rents, and it is here that intellectual
property rights (patents, copyright and brand names) play such an important role in a world of intensive global competition.
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 11-11

A final characteristic of rents which helps to understand the extension of GVCs is that they are inherently dynamic. A special attribute today, despite
intensive attempts to protect rents, may become a commodity tomorrow, that is a product or service which has few barriers to entry
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 11-11

Nowadays it is vocational and tertiary skills, and the capacity of firm to develop internal routines and management practices (Teece, Pisano and Shuen,
1994) which provide sustainable human resource rents.
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 11-11

But this outsourcing has to be managed to both ensure systemic chain efficiency and to institute processes whish ensure that the chain as a whole
responds to changing market conditions
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 11-11

This enabled the Japanese industry to innovate more quickly, to respond more flexibly to final market volatility and to lower production costs
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 12-12

Modular governance (for example in triangular governance) involves durable relations between lead firms and their suppliers and customers in the chain,
but with low levels of chain governance. This is because characteristically, the key suppliers in the chain possess their own unique competences and this
means that they are able to operate reasonably independently of the lead firm
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 13-13

Relational chains are chains with somewhat higher levels of governance, but where suppliers and/or intermediate suppliers possess competences of
their own
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 13-13
Standards are a central component of governance in virtually all chains
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 14-14

Corporate standards are internal to the chain.


Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 14-14

Generic standards are industry specific or relevant across a range of sectors such as ISO9000 standards on quality and ISO14000 on the environment
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 14-14

Standards set by governments (for example food safety standards) and international bodies (for example, EU farm-to-fork standards)
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 14-14

Standards emerging from civil society, such as labour standards, organic standards and fairtrade certification
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 14-14

These requirements often act to exclude small scale and informal producers, who are further disadvantaged by the costs of (generally renewable)
accreditation. On the other hand, standards are often an important conduit for capability-building, hence diminishing the learning involved in exporting
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 14-14

Even within intellectual property rights the relative strength of different barriers may vary – brand names, for example, effectively exist in perpetuity
whereas patents are time-bound.
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 15-15

functional upgrading, that is, changing position in the chain


Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 15-15

chain to another, in the way that Nokia progressed from rubber boots, through timber machinery to mobile telephony
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 15-15

Thus whilst the GVC framework focuses on the ‘stickiness’ of vertical relations in the chain the cluster literature highlights the importance of horizontal
‘stickiness’. The empirical literature suggests that, often, insertion into GVCs weakens the ‘glue’ in horizontal relations (Nadvi and Halder, 2005)
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 16-16

Nevertheless, the importance of clusters in capability-building remains, and


Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 16-16

their significance has grown as lead firms increasingly search for dynamic suppliers which allows them to move from relational to modular governance. It
not only removes the imperative for supplier development for the lead firms, but enables them to play suppliers off against each other.Hence, gainful
insertion into GVCs increasingly requires the attributes which clustering supports and it is for this reason that rigorous GVC analysis necessarily
incorporates a focus on embeddedness
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 16-16

Another reason why embeddedness is a core component of GVC dynamics is because it sharpens the focus on ownership
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 16-16

Outsourced production in many chains depends heavily on skilled labour which is mobile and which can readily cross national boundaries. In this context
skilled labour includes not only high level skills from the core northern economies but also, and perhaps more importantly
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 17-17

intermediate and artisanal skills from low and middle income economies. The triangular systems which coordinate production in many GVCs are
particularly prominent in marshalling these mobile skills.However, it is not only skilled labour which is mobile so that, in the most extreme form, the large
exportoriented Jordanian garments industry is almost wholly staffed by unskilled Asian contract workers
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 17-17

This suggests a hierarchy of upgrading which is illustrated in Figure 5 through the example of the manufacturing sector. The firm enters the GVC by
merely assembling to the designs of the lead firm (for example, the iPhone 4 in China). Its upgrading trajectory in this early stage is one of process
improvement.Subsequently, as capabilities increase, the firm moves from assembly to manufacturing, that is the transforming of materials and
incorporating a greater degree of local components. 10 As capabilities deepen the firm develops the capacity to design
Kaplinsky - GVC, pg. 19-19

You might also like