You are on page 1of 23

The Editors and Board of Trustees of the Russian Review

Perestroika as Revolution from within: An Interpretation


Author(s): John Gooding
Source: Russian Review, Vol. 51, No. 1 (Jan., 1992), pp. 36-57
Published by: Wiley on behalf of The Editors and Board of Trustees of the Russian Review
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/131245 .
Accessed: 19/12/2014 08:45

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Wiley and The Editors and Board of Trustees of the Russian Review are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize,
preserve and extend access to Russian Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroikaas Revolution
from Within:
An Interpretation
JOHN GOODING

v hen Mikhail Gorbachev warned of a "crisis situation" in perestroika's early


days, he had the air of crying wolf. Now no one can doubt that the Soviet Union is
in crisis. The immediate precipitant of the crisis, whose roots go deep, has been the
perestroika program itself. Yet until 1985, Western observers generally assumed
that only if the regime faced destabilization would it "pay the political price of
radical reform" and that its current problems, though grave, were unlikely to force
real concessions out of it.1 Events, however, would disprove this analysis, and
Konstantin Chernenko's successor embarked on radical change at a time when the
dangers to the regime were no more than prospective. It was not to be
destabilization that precipitated radical change, but radical change that precipitated
destabilization. Why the Gorbachev regime risked destabilizing itself by "un-
forced" radicalism and how it pushed its policies through against fierce resistance
will be the subject of the article.
Most Western observers initially saw Gorbachev as no more than a cosmetic
reformer. When this view became untenable, they tended instead to place him into
another familiar category of Russian ruler: the "revolutionary from above," who
was pushing the country into a further phase of the revolution-stagnation-
revolution cycle from which it seemed incapable of escaping.2 This, however, was as
wide of the mark as the earlier reading, even though the reforms indeed were
instigated "from above" and revolutionary in scope. For revolutionaries-from-

1 Seweryn Bialer, The Soviet Paradox: External Expansion, Internal Decline (London: Tauris,
1986), 143. An exception to the view that Gorbachev would prove a conventional Soviet leader was,
however, provided by Archie Brown. See "Gorbachev: New Man in the Kremlin," Problems of Commu-
nism 32 (May-June 1985): 1-23.
2 For a recent discussion of "revolution from above" see T. H. Rigby, The Changing Soviet System:
Mono-organisational Socialism from Its Origins to Gorbachev's Restructuring(Brookfield, VT: Edward
Elgar, 1990), 187-88, 210.

The Russian Review, vol. 51, January 1992, pp. 36-57


Copyright ? 1992 by The Ohio State University Press

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 37

above from Peter onward had modernized in defense of an existing political struc-
ture, imposing change upon a population which was treated as a passive object and
never encouraged to see itself as a subject. Gorbachev's perestroika, by contrast,
tried to activate the masses and to create a genuinely participatory society.3 The
regeneration perestroika aimed at contained a distinct political component, and it
was in fact as a political revolution that its major success was to be achieved.
Gorbachev had good reason, however, not to advertise in advance what we can now
see to have been perestroika's political purposes, and they were not to be officially
acknowledged until after the Central Committee plenum of February 1990, at
which the CPSU agreed to surrender its monopoly on power.
Within a few weeks of that historic plenum the editor of Pravda, a close
Gorbachev aide, admitted that the idea of abolishing the party's monopoly had
been mooted by the leadership "a very long time ago" and that the only question
had been "how, in what form, and at what stage to introduce such changes." The
leadership had first, however, to create the necessary preliminary conditions,
among them a new body of deputies and a new Supreme Soviet. Only then, "in the
concluding stages of the political reform," could it carry through what was "in the
literal sense a revolution [perevorot], a completion and consummation of the remak-
ing of the political system."4 The editor of Pravda might seem an unlikely source for
truthful comment on Soviet politics, but in this case the analysis was unerring. At
the February plenum a relatively small group occupying the citadel of power in
effect completed a carefully planned and most unusual "revolution from within"
against the interests and increasingly against the wishes of a ruling class whose
position had hitherto seemed unassailable.5
Gorbachev was to be the first successful revolutionary of this type, though
there already had been unsuccessful essays in the genre. I shall discuss these earlier
failures in order to pinpoint the conditions making for Gorbachev's success, but
first I shall set out the basic features of revolution from within, indicating its phases
and suggesting something of its typology.
1. Obviously enough, a revolution from within requires a would-be revolution-
ary (or group of revolutionaries), who needs to combine strategic vision with im-
mense tactical skills, who needs to be enough of an "insider" to pass unchallenged
into the powerhouse and yet in important respects will be, or will become, an
outsider to its culture and mores. A striking case of one in whom the outsider facet

3 M. S. Gorbachev, Perestroika i novoe


myshlenie dlia nashei strany i dlia vsego mira (Moscow:
Politizdat, 1987), 52-54; idem, "Sotsialisticheskaia ideia i revoliutsionnaia perestroika," Pravda, 26
November 1989.
4 Pravda, 17 March 1990.
5 I am
taking the "ruling class" to comprehend the oligarchy proper-the few hundred members
and candidate-members of the Central Committee with the twenty-odd Politburo members at their
core-plus an encircling band of nonrulers who were nevertheless important decision-makers, were the
immediate clients of the oligarchs and enjoyed great material privileges as a result. John H. Miller
estimated the decision-making elite to amount to as many as two million. See "The Communist Party:
Trends and Problems," in Soviet Policy for the 1980s, ed. Archie Brown and Michael Kaser (London:
Macmillan, 1982), 3.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
38 John Gooding

predominated was the early-nineteenth-century reformer Mikhail Speranskii.6 A


priest's son in a noble-dominated society and a convinced liberal and constitutional-
ist in an autocratic state, Speranskii believed that radical change could be achieved
only from within, infiltrated the powerhouse, and there necessarily became a "man
with a mask" dependent upon the skill of a Machiavelli. Peter Stolypin provides a
contrary example in the early twentieth century: a bien-pensant landowner and
monarchical loyalist, who was far from a closet-liberal and yet would be driven by
circumstances to become a would-be revolutionary.7 These two figures define the
boundaries of the revolutionary-from-within as a political type. The first was an
ideologue and a Machiavel, a man in a hurry who fell, in Soviet jargon, into the
voluntarist trap of wanting to "jump stages"; the second was a man of traditional
thinking who defined himself as a "preserver"rather than a "transformer,"a conser-
vative who nevertheless came to see transformation as the essential condition of
preservation. Gorbachev would share characteristics with both, but he resembled
neither. He would trade by conviction as well as by necessity in the basic concepts of
Soviet politics, yet would steadily impart new meaning to them and, in doing so,
transform the system. At once insider and outsider, apparatchik and revolutionary,
true believer and iconoclast, he would use his ambivalence as a vitally effective
political weapon.
2. The would-be or potential revolutionary-from-within needs in turn a power-
holder, individual or collective, who has been made insecure and therefore recep-
tive to new thinking, who will be sufficiently persuaded by appeals pitched at his
apparent self-interest (laced perhaps by arguments that attempt to reactivate a
more or less extinct vein of idealism) to initiate a reform program put to him as
imperative for regime-survival and will maintain it long enough for the program to
win some degree of public following. The Soviet oligarchy of the 1980s, facing an
economic decline with profound implications for the great-power status of the
country, if not for its own security, was precisely such a power-holder.
3. The cooperative relationship between revolutionary and power-holder will,
however, eventually become antagonistic, and a moment of truth will arrive when
the power-holder glimpses through the mask of the reformer the visage of a revolu-
tionary. If the revolutionary is to win the resultant struggle his challenge to the
prevailing ideology needs to become increasingly direct and public, which not only
will weaken the power-holder (undermining both his right to rule and his ability to
dismiss the emergent challenger) but begin to sow disaffection among less-
committed members of the ruling class. It was crucial that Gorbachev had at hand a
counter-ideology that was potentially, yet not too obviously, extra-systemic, and
through this he was able to enfranchize a large constituency of supporters, some
within and some outside the party but all effectively excluded from the political

6 See John Gooding, "The Liberalism of Michael Speransky," Slavonic and East European Review
64 (July 1986): 401-24. A different view is presented by Marc Raeff in Michael Speransky: Statesman of
Imperial Russia, 1772-1838, 2d ed. (The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff, 1969).
7 Aleksander Solzhenitsyn has provided a recent portrait of Stolypin in The Red Wheel: A Narrative

in Discrete Periods of Time (London: The Bodley Head, 1989).

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 39

nation. Beginning in early 1987, Gorbachev would skillfully mobilize these people,
to whom the lackluster authoritarianism of the oligarchs had become intolerable, in
order to extract concessions from an increasingly defensive power-holder. There
was as yet, however, no overt breach with the oligarchs, and Gorbachev continued,
if with declining credibility, to maintain the fiction that the nation's interests were
inseparable from those of the party.
4. The revolution from within could not be complete until its gains were codi-
fied and given institutional form; that is, until the revolutionary could detach him-
self from the power-holder and had replaced a structure that compelled his depen-
dence by one that made him accountable instead to the newly enfranchized. Such a
decisive shift of power-base could not be achieved while the old ideology remained
formally in place. The buttresses sustaining the ideology might have been almost all
removed, yet while its central tenet-the power-holder's claim as of right to
power-remained, the revolution was incomplete. This was the position at the
beginning of 1990. The party's surrender of its monopoly at the February 1990
plenum, followed shortly by the establishment of the presidency and of the non-
party Presidential Council, then concluded the revolution. Eking out favorable
circumstances by a dazzling display of political skills, Gorbachev had carried
through his revolution with surprising ease, and in doing so must have exceeded the
expectations of those for whom he had seemed the only hope during a period of
oligarchic rule that, it was widely assumed, would continue indefinitely.8In complet-
ing a revolution from within he had not, however, completed a revolution; instead,
he had precipitated one.
PRECEDENTS FOR REVOLUTION FROM WITHIN
Almost two centuries earlier Mikhail Speranskii's experience had highlighted some
of the difficulties of the genre. His crucial deficiency was his dependence upon
Alexander I, who, either deceived or unnaturally self-denying, was to have begun a
process of change that would end in the liquidation of autocratic government.
There was little support within the narrow circle of the "political nation" for such
change or for any rights-of-man ideology; on the contrary, the upper nobility gener-
ally regarded Speranskii as a dangerous meddler. His problem was that he lacked
any real constituency: the liberal-constitutional and socially mobile Russia he envis-
aged needed for its realization that very middle class which, had his endeavor
succeeded, might eventually have come into being. Speranskii thus had to try to
persuade the power-holder that discontent with the government was widespread
and that comprehensive reform alone would stave off disaster.9 But this was no
more than make-believe, and once Alexander had had his moment of truth he
simply called Speranskii's bluff.
As the heir to a genuinely revolutionary situation, Stolypin was in a potentially

8 The
assumption that oligarchy was the definitive Russian political mode was given an historical
rationale by Edward L. Keenan, who in "Muscovite Political Folkways" interpreted the autocracy as an
oligarchy in disguise and argued that the traditional "central core of 'nominal ruler + oligarchs' " was
reestablished during the Soviet period." See Russian Review 45 (April 1986): 115-82.
9 M. M.
Speranskii, Proekty i zapiski (Moscow-Leningrad: Nauka, 1961), 163.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
40 John Gooding

stronger position than his "predecessor." His "wager on the strong" was, moreover,
quite different from Speranskii's social "wager" in that the people on whom his
hopes reposed-those peasants capable of bettering themselves and emerging as a
petty-proprietorial class fully integrated into the national community-already ex-
isted at least in embryo among the depressed peasantry of the commune. Yet it was
a wager on a class which, even when it began to emerge, would lie outside the
current political system and could be incorporated into it only by grace of the
system's brokers. The advance of the peasants-economic, cultural and civic-
could come only at the expense of the landowning nobles, who would have to yield
influence in the zemstvos as well as in national institutions and fund the advance
through increased taxation. And here Stolypin faced an insoluble problem. For the
intransigence of the Second Duma had made him impose the restrictive electoral
law of 3 June 1907, whose effect was to give a political veto to some twenty
thousand major landowners.10Thus he strengthened a class that had reacted to the
recent revolutionary events by shedding any tinge of liberal frondeurism and retreat-
ing into an embattled conservatism. The outcome was that the quasi oligarchy of
landowners was able to sabotage all of his grandiose ideas for transforming Russia
except one, his attempt to dissolve the commune. Like Speranskii, Stolypin would
fall victim not only to a monarch who had lost faith in him but also to an upper class
that had rightly come to see him as its adversary.
Gorbachev's "predecessors" differed from him, then, in that they lacked both
significant societal support and the institutional means by which such support, had
it existed, could have been brought to bear upon the power-holder and the privi-
leged. There was nevertheless one important factor linking all three: each had at
hand a political-cultural tradition that was rich in exploitable ambiguity, critical yet
seemingly within-system, potentially liberating and yet capable of being coded in
terms acceptable to the power-holder.
In Speranskii's case, this was a version of the fundamental law tradition, which
at its most conservative saw no necessary incompatibility between the rule of law
and the principle of autocracy. Speranskii most certainly did not endorse this conser-
vative reading, yet its existence was crucial for him: he would exploit Alexander I's
commitment to the rule of law, not expose the woolly thinking underlying it. And
for most of his career he acted in a spirit of what might be called "false constitu-
tionalism."11After all, no other kind of constitutionalism seemed within reach, and
even if the autocrat did grant independent institutions they were likely to prove no
more than castles on the sand. During the years 1808-12, however, Speranskii
departed from his earlier caution and won Alexander's approval for a plan of
radical reform, the central feature of which was to have been the establishment of
an elected national assembly with a right of legislative veto. The ruler would, of
course, have retained enormous powers; and Speranskii laid great emphasis on

10 Roberta
Thompson Manning, The Crisis of the Old Order in Russia: Gentry and Government
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1982), 325.
11 The term, however, was not first used in Russia until a century later, when P. N. Miliukov and
other Kadets adopted it from Max Weber (Scheinkonstitutionalismus).

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 41

these powers and did his utmost to deflect attention from the long-term implica-
tions of the plan.12The unstated intention was nevertheless to initiate a process by
which autocratic government was replaced by constitutional, and he had scored a
major success in framing proposals that seemed to reflect Alexander's thinking yet
would surreptitiously serve his own. The plan, however, risked stretching the ambi-
guities of the fundamental law tradition to breaking point. A common reformist
vocabulary and a common commitment to the rule of law could not forever mask
the difference between the autocrat and an adviser who wanted, not to give the
regime a face-lift, but to change its nature altogether; and once Alexander realized
this basic truth, Speranskiism as such was doomed.
The equivalent for Stolypin of the ambiguous fundamental law tradition lay in
the moderate and elastic liberalism of his Duma allies, the Octobrists, whose in-
stincts were oligarchic rather than democratic and who wanted a gradual, peaceful
progression from absolutism to democracy by way of a gentry-dominated polity.
Stolypin's alliance with the Octobrists was, however, no more than an expedient.
His modern admirers regard him as a true liberal,13yet his "liberalism" had little in
common with any of the current ones; he was at once more conservative than his
Octobrist allies and more radical than they were. A fervent monarchist, he saw the
monarchy as the necessary linchpin of the social order and he aimed to rescue it
from the reactionary elements that were discrediting it. He was not, however, going
to save it from reactionaries only to base it instead on the declining force of gentry
liberalism: a revitalized monarchy could be rooted in nothing other than an emanci-
pated and prosperous peasantry that was fully integrated into the community. Yet
his peasant monarchism was hardly likely to be supported either by peasants or
traditional monarchists; it was a vision without any strategy to realize it. By his
blend of conservatism and radicalism he managed to appear "a reactionary to all on
the left," in Solzhenitsyn's words, "yet practically a Kadet to the true Right";14and,
unable to develop his alliance with the admittedly unstable Octobrist grouping, he
had become isolated and politically dead well before the assassin's bullet felled him.
NEW FORCES AND NEW THINKING
The case histories of Speranskii and Stolypin highlight the advantages enjoyed by
their "successor," who had both the societal and the ideological means of pushing
his revolution to a conclusion. Unlike either Stolypin or Speranskii, who "wagered"
on a class that had yet to be created, Gorbachev wagered on enterprising and highly
educated people who already existed and were chafing at the bit. The intelligentsia
constituted an exception to the general picture of contentment that had persuaded
most Western observers that pressure for change was unlikely to come from outside
the ruling class. If state and society had indeed reached a tacit agreement that was
the guarantor of future stability, it was one from which many in the intelligentsia felt

12 Which made the


claiming of a right of legislative veto a matter of extreme delicacy. See Gooding,
"The Liberalism of Michael Speransky," 408.
13 For
Stolypin's "liberalism" see Victor Leontovitsch, Istoriia liberalizma v Rossii 1762-1914
(Paris: YMCA, 1980).
14
Solzhenitsyn, The Red Wheel, 552.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
42 John Gooding

excluded, and in two important respects their position had deteriorated in recent
years.15First, the relative freedom they had enjoyed under Khrushchev had been
curbed, and the hopes of still greater freedom which his de-Stalinization had
aroused had by the mid-1970s been dashed. Perestroika's most ardent ideologues
and supporters would in the event be found among intellectuals whose early adult-
hood had coincided with the Khrushchev thaw.16Secondly, the "social contract" of
the Brezhnev years had sacrificed economic growth to worker welfare: economic
policy had been markedly egalitarian, and the wage differential between skilled and
unskilled had narrowed. The stability of the "stagnation era" had therefore been
achieved at the expense of a key minority group whose standard of living had
declined vis-a-vis that of the working class and whose desire for greater freedom
had been frustrated no less than its desire for self-betterment. The dissatisfaction of
this group provided Gorbachev with a potential weapon against the oligarchy. The
Gorbachev revolution, as Jerry Hough remarked, would be in essence a revolt of
the middle class.17
"
Gorbachev's program differed therefore from his "predecessors' in being
reactive-in being, that is, predicated upon social and cultural changes that had
already taken place. A broad constituency of people who were sure to favor
economic-growth policies and the relaxation of political controls lay at hand. What
was in the making in fact during the later "stagnation" years was a coalition be-
tween reformers in the leadership, progressive intellectuals, and those with entre-
preneurial skills and ambitions.18 But if the potential coalition was to become an
actual and effective one, its rank-and-file had to be enfranchised and brought within
the political nation. Democratization was thus the indispensable condition of re-
form. The Soviet state had always taken great pride of course in its democratism.
And fraudulent though its claims in this respect were, the very lip service it paid to
democracy had kept alive in the party a real democratic commitment, which was
expressed and passed on in what I shall call the Alternative Tradition.19
The Alternative Tradition was a distillation of the 1920s Soviet experience in

15 See
Igor' Kliamkin, "Kakaia ulitsa vedet k khramu," Novyi mir (November 1987): 158; and
Ronald Amann, "Soviet Politics in the Gorbachev Era: The End of Hesitant Modernization," British
Journal of Political Science 20 (July 1990): 303. The "social contract" between ruled and rulers as
Stephen F. Cohen, for one, envisaged it offered the ruled vigilant national security, popular nationalism,
law-and-order safeguards, cradle-to-grave welfarism, and improving material standards. See Rethinking
the Soviet Experience: Politics and History since 1917 (New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press,
1985), 151. Cohen warned, however, that the government's failure to fulfil important aspects of its
consumer-welfare promises would create pressure for change.
16 T. Zaslavskaia, "O strategii sotsial'nogo upravleniia perestroikoi," in Inogo ne dano, ed. Iu. F.
Afanas'ev (Moscow: Progress, 1988), 28-29; N. Moiseev, "Zachem doroga, esli ona ne vedet k
khramu," ibid., 55-56.
17 Jerry Hough, Russia and the West: Gorbachev and the Politics of Reform, 2d ed. (New York and
London: Touchstone, 1990), 178.
18 It is to Moshe Lewin's great credit that he foresaw the emergence of precisely such a coalition in
his Political Undercurrentsin Soviet Economic Debates: From Bukharin to the Modern Reformers (Lon-
don: Pluto Press, 1975), 352.
19 For the importance of the party's formal democratism in keeping the commitment to real democ-
racy alive see T. H. Rigby, The Changing Soviet System, 69.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 43

the light of the country's subsequent history, and its basic belief was that the
"administrative-command system" had been a violation and perversion of the social-
ism that Lenin and his party had tried to implant in postrevolutionary Russia. This
"true socialism," buried as an official ideology at the end of the 1920s and largely
submerged ever since, purportedly had two cardinal theses,
1. that the planned socialist economy should accommodate a considerable
market element, that socialism was to be achieved by means of market relations
rather than by defiance of them, and
2. that freedom of expression should be encouraged within a one-party sys-
tem, the security of the party lying in the people's natural predisposition toward
socialism-a predisposition that would be stronger for being uncoerced.20
The Alternative Tradition thus stood for the compatibility of plan and market,
and of socialism and free expression; it was "alternative" in that its economic and
political theses were the twin prongs of a single democratic or at least democratizing
philosophy. Its leading figures (most notably Nikolai Bukharin) had long since been
expunged from the record. The Tradition had, however, been given a powerful boost
by Khrushchev with his attempt to stir popular initiative and to reintegrate the
repressed and neglected into an expanded political community, his hostility to the
apparatus as a barrier between party and people, and his belief that mass initiative
alone could regenerate the economy. Its assumptions had subsequently inspired the
unsuccessful attempt at economic reform in the 1960s; and its influence on the
reformist economic thinking of the 1970s and early 1980s was to be fundamental.
No reformer in his senses could expect to pick up the pieces where they had
been dropped six decades before; however, the Alternative Tradition was not so
much a specific blueprint as a cluster of assumptions informed by the belief, or at
least the hope, that democracy and a recognizably Leninist form of socialism were
reconcilable. With its nostalgia for the lost opportunities of the 1920s, the Tradition
was more a myth than a program, its basic elements preserved as it were in aspic
and its ambiguities yet to be exposed by the test of experience. Would the market
really prove compatible with a planned economy? Could the party give up its
monopolism without jeopardizing its ruling position? In an urban and educated
Soviet Union would democracy be socialism's ally rather than its gravedigger? In
the repressive climate of Brezhnevism, the myth nevertheless united rather than
divided people. A broad band of reformists gathered around it, united in the
conviction that the country should return to the path of "true socialism" from which
it had veered in the 1920s. Such people looked for radical within-system change
once a new period of political relaxation began, and the Tradition, with its Leninist
emphasis, provided them with both a focus and a protective mantle.
It helped that the Tradition's economic and political theses could be advanced
separately and that their interdependence (the market requiring democracy, and
democracy the market) did not need to be stressed. The political thesis came close

20 The Tradition's
assumptions were succinctly summarized by Fedor Burlatskii in "Kakoi sotsia-
lizm narodu nuzhen," Literaturnaia gazeta, 10 April 1988. They were reflected, too, in many contribu-
tions to Afanas'ev, Inogo ne dano.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
44 John Gooding

to heterodoxy, even if it did not breach the one-party system as such; and how hard
it was not to breach that system was shown by the devotedly socialist Roy
Medvedev, who put himself in the dissident category by arguing that the cause of
socialism and the Communist Party could be best served by "a loyal and legal
opposition to the existing leadership."21But if the Tradition's political position led
easily to dissidence, those who explored its economic legacy were more likely to
stay within the system. And it was to be loyally oppositional economic thinkers,
among whom A. P. Butenko, B. M. Kurashvili, and Tatiana Zaslavskaia stood out,
who were to be the progenitors of the reform movement.
The "new thinking" of the "stagnation era" sprang from the realization that the
Soviet economy was being outperformed by Western economies and that, as then
constituted, it was doomed to fall further and further behind.22This realization did
not make crypto-capitalists of the reformers, but it did lead them to conclude that
the administrative-command system had utterly frustrated the potential of Soviet
society. For them, the decline in growth rates indicated not only economic failure
but also a failure of the entire Soviet system as Stalin and his heirs had shaped it. In
devising an alternative economic model they went by implication well beyond the
economic, urging that people should be induced rather than ordered to act and
denying that Soviet society was essentially homogeneous and free of antagonistic
contradictions. On the contrary, argued Butenko, the contradiction between pro-
duction forces and the existing system of production relations was widening, and it
could be narrowed only by fundamental political reforms, without which Soviet
society faced the prospect of open conflict.23A major cause of the country's eco-
nomic plight, in Zaslavskaia's view, lay in the passivity and low morale of the
workforce, whose members were treated like cogs.24 Democratization, Kurashvili
believed, was "the moving force of economic and socio-cultural progress." All three
implied that a dynamic economy was impossible without it; and Kurashvili for one
distinguished between "quasi reform," which was "purely a reconstruction within
the apparatus," and reform proper, which changed the relationship between appara-
tus and society and would have to be carried through "despite the resistance of
conservative and inert elements in the state apparatus."25
The reformers took care not to overstep the line that divided the loyally
oppositional from the dissident. That political reform should be seen as a condition
of economic was, however, an inevitable conclusion from the failed reforms of the

21
Roy A. Medvedev, Political Essays (Nottingham: Bertrand Russell Peace Foundation, 1976),
109.
22 The
assumption of the potential greater effectiveness of the Soviet economic system was widely
shared in the West until the late 1960s. Thus Harold Macmillan confided to President Kennedy his fear
that the capitalist system would be "beaten." See John Lloyd, "Is the Soviet Union Over?" London
Review of Books, 27 September 1990.
23 A. P.
Butenko, "Protivorechiia razvitiia sotsializma kak obshchestvennogo stroia," Voprosy
filosofii, 1982, no. 10:16-29. See also B. M. Kurashvili, "Gosudarstvennoe upravlenie narodnym
khoziaistvom: perspektivy razvitiia," Sovetskoe gosudarstvo i pravo, 1982, no. 6:47.
24 "The Novosibirsk
Report," Survey 28 (Spring 1984): 89-90.
25
Kurashvili, "Obektivnye zakony gosudarstvennogo upravleniia," Sovetskoe gosudarstvo i pravo,
1983, no. 10:43, 44.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 45

1960s. The new economic model therefore contained the nucleus of a new political
model that in principle was inimical to the monopolism of the CPSU, and this
repudiation of the social monolith implied repudiation of the political monopoly as
well. And here the "new thinking" parted with the 1920s realities which had in-
spired the Alternative Tradition. Bukharin had seen society becoming progressively
more socialist as divergent interests and individualist tendencies were eliminated,
whereas the reformers of the 1980s took their stand not only on social differentia-
tion but on inevitably increasing differentiation and set out to adjust economic and
political institutions accordingly.
The extra-systemic implications of the "new thinking," however, remained
largely unexplored. Speculation about non-communist structures would have been
self-defeating, given the weakness and fragmentation of the dissident movement.
CPSU power was for the time being unassailable, and the reality the reformers
faced was not dissimilar from that which had faced Speranskii-the only force
capable of initiating change was the regime itself. The reform process had to begin
with changes within the system, and not until the process was well under way could
qualitative transformation be seriously contemplated. For the moment the reform-
ers waited for a leader who shared at least their minimum aspirations, and such a
leader they got in March 1985.
GORBACHEV BETWEEN WORLDS
In terms of our precedents Gorbachev, though clearly an oddity among the ill-
educated Kremlin gerontocrats, was by no means an "outsider." His situation was
markedly different from that of Speranskii, a humble provincial plucked from
obscurity because of his talents who had to assimilate externally to a dominant class
and political order that he secretly reviled. A peasant was at no formal disadvantage
in a workers' and peasants' state, and this particular peasant, the son and grandson
of party members, clung with almost filial piety to socialism as a basic ordering
principle.26 As he rose through the ranks of the Komsomol and Stavropol party
organizations, Gorbachev's acceptance of the fundamental values and institutions
of the Soviet state was most probably unqualified. The affinity here is not with
Speranskii but rather with the autocracy's would-be redeemer, Stolypin. Yet if
Gorbachev was no saboteur in the making, he gave early signs of a readiness to
question received truths and outdated practices.27Here was a new type of educated
apparatchik who had made his career in the post-Stalin era and had climbed into an
elderly and fossilized ruling class whose mindset was very different from his own.
His older colleagues were marked indelibly by the insecurities of the early revolu-
tionary period and the 1930s; he by contrast had risen within the secure elite of a
stable and unassailable regime. They had been frozen into doctrinal rigidity by

26 "I can't
go against my father and my grandfather," was how he defended socialism at a reunion of
his Moscow University classmates. The Guardian (London), 20 June 1990. See also Pravda, 1 December
1990.
27 The best evidence for the
questioning mind of the young Gorbachev can be found in the memoir
of his friend from student days (1950-55), Zdenek Mlynar, "II mio compagno di studi Mikhail
Gorbaciov," L'Unita (Rome), 9 April 1985.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
46 John Gooding

dangers already experienced; he would respond flexibly and imaginatively to dan-


gers that were merely prospective, and would prove open to ideas on the very
margin of orthodoxy. It was natural that once he reached the Politburo the reform-
ers should seek him out; it was no less natural that he should seek them out. For the
economic problems of the Soviet Union began, as it happened, to become alarming
around the very time when he reached the central leadership.28
During the early 1980s Gorbachev would as a result move between two worlds:
the rising star of the Politburo, the "heir apparent" was being drawn by the intracta-
ble problems of the Soviet state into the milieu of the loyal opposition. Moving
between such disparate worlds was far from easy, for if Andropov, unlike Brezhnev,
recognized the gravity of the economic problem, he allowed only strictly orthodox
palliatives to be applied to it. A close relationship nevertheless developed in this
period between Gorbachev and some of the proponents of "new thinking": genera-
tion and culture provided natural links, and the rapport may have been helped too
by the fact that Raisa Gorbachev as a pioneering sociologist belonged naturally
among them. During these years intellectuals bombarded him with ideas which
provided the basic material out of which the perestroika program would take
shape.29As Gorbachev himself would recall, his safe became "clogged" with reform
proposals. "People were clamoring that everything needed to be changed, but from
different angles: some were for scientific and technical progress, others for reform-
ing the structure of politics, and others still for new organizational forms in industry
and agriculture. In short, from all angles there were cries from the heart that affairs
could no longer be allowed to go on in the old way."30At his first meeting with
Zaslavskaia, Gorbachev not only showed sympathy for her views but surprised her
by responding to her criticisms with an "If only I could... ."31
But how much of the "new thinking" had he in fact absorbed? "We had the
same ideas-about the independence of enterprises, about the need for realistic
price policies, market relations and more progressive forms of salary," Zaslavskaia
was to comment. "We met from time to time.... I could see how he was
becoming wiser and more wide-thinking."32 If there is a suggestion here of less
than total communion, that is hardly surprising. Gorbachev's very position meant
that his dealings with the radicals had to be circumspect-not for nothing does he
refer to their proposals being kept in his "safe." The "new thinking," after all, had
implications that threatened the supreme taboo of communism-the party's mo-
nopoly. Whether Gorbachev had accepted any such implication before March

28 Anders Aslund,
following Aganbegian, dates the cessation of Soviet economic growth to 1978.
See Gorbachev's Stuggle for Economic Reform: The Soviet Reform Process, 1985-88 (London: Pinter,
1989), 15.
29 Nikolai Ryzhkov gave a statistic of 110 documents as the basis out of which the April 1985
program arose (Pravda, 8 January 1989). In conversation with American officials Gorbachev himself
dated the origins of perestroika to 1982. See W. G. Miller, ed., Towardsa More Civil Society? The USSR
under Mikhail Sergeevich Gorbachev (New York: Harper and Row, 1989), 122.
30 Pravda, 12 February 1990.
31 Zaslavskaia, The Second Socialist Revolution: An Alternative Soviet Strategy (London: Tauris,
1990), xi.
32 The Guardian, 28
February 1990.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 47

1985 we have no way of knowing. To assume that he already had a blueprint of


what became the mature reform program, which he kept concealed simply for
tactical reasons, would be unrealistic. What seems certain, however, is that from
the outset he accepted the underlying proposition of the "new thinking"-that
without political change there could be no real economic change, that an out-
moded political structure had to be brought into harmony with social realities.
"It's all gone rotten," he would report Eduard Shevardnadze telling him during
these years, and no doubt he thought the same.33 Evidence of the time as to his
state of mind came in a major speech of 10 December 1984 in which he admitted
that the contradiction between production forces and production relationships had
been a retarding factor in socioeconomic development and suggested the need for
a more democratic political system.34 It was the speech of someone who was
steeped in the "new thinking" and accepted at least its minimum program, and
predictably it incurred heavy censorship in Pravda. In talking so boldly he was
taking advantage of the relative latitude available to a number two-which was all
the greater when the number one happened to be too ill to exercise effective
control. When he became general secretary three months later, the obstacles to
speaking his own mind would, paradoxically, be more formidable.
GORBACHEV IN POWER: ACCELERATION
Between April 1985 and the end of 1986, Gorbachev's timid program of socioeco-
nomic "acceleration" offered few hints of his later radicalism. He had good reason
for acting with caution: he had few natural allies within an oligarchy that had chosen
him for his vigor and competence rather than for his reformism, and even his
control of cadres was of limited help since it did not reach to the oligarchy's inner
circle. Furthermore, any high official he did remove kept his seat on the Central
Committee, which tended as a result to become a focus of opposition to him.
Indeed, despite the enforced retirement of more than one hundred members or
candidate-members in April 1989 the Central Committee would remain a bulwark
of resistance to reform into 1990. His position in the Politburo was helped by the
early removal of Romanov, Tikhonov, and Grishin, though here too he faced a
constant struggle. In time he would find support elsewhere to compensate for his
weakness, but in 1985-86 he was not in a position to mobilize any countervailing
forces.
It may be, of course, that Gorbachev was not merely acting under constraint
during this period: he had not yet, some would argue, worked out his basic strategy,
was reacting ad hoc to the problems of the job, and did not become even a
semiradical until circumstances forced him to toward the end of 1986.35Certainly he

33 Pravda, 1 December 1990.


34 Gorbachev, "Zhivoe tvorchestvo naroda," in M. S. Gorbachev, Izbrannye rechi i stat'i, vol. 2
(Moscow: Politizdat, 1987), esp. 80-84.
35
Seweryn Bialer, for instance, has argued that it took him one and a half years "to develop even
the outlines of his program." See "The Changing Soviet Political System: The Nineteenth Party Confer-
ence and After," in Politics, Society and Nationality inside Gorbachev's Russia, ed. Seweryn Bialer
(Boulder and London: Westview, 1989), 193.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
48 John Gooding

was to learn on the job; yet the view of him as a reluctant and belated convert to
radicalism ignores the political motifs which were increasingly noticeable in his
statements from the fall of 1985 onward. "I wish, comrades," he told the October
1985 plenum, "to emphasize as forcefully as I can: without the utmost widening and
deepening of socialist democracy, that is, without the creation of conditions for the
daily, active, and effective participation of all working people, their collectives and
organizations, in resolving the problems of governmental and social life, we cannot
go forward with success."36The Twenty-seventh Party Congress the following year
would still be heavy with the weight of Soviet traditionalism, yet here too
Gorbachev managed to introduce a distinctly new note in his treatment of democ-
racy, linking it with glasnost, the rule of law, and the rights and freedoms of the
citizen, and insisting that "acceleration of social development is unthinkable and
impossible without further development of socialist democracy and of all its aspects
and manifestations."37 And in the summer of 1986 he launched the notion of pe-
restroika as a revolution that would embrace not only economic life but "social
relationships, the political system, the spiritual-ideological sphere, the style and
methods of work by the party and all our cadres." He suggested too that the
revolution was only beginning. The more perestroika advanced, he told a Siberian
audience, the more complex its task would become and the more "the huge scale
and scope of the work ahead of us" would be revealed. Many conceptions would be
shown to "lag behind the needs and tasks of the present and, all the more so, the
tasks of future development," among them those concerning democracy.38
Political motifs were, of course, subordinate to economic ones in the "accelera-
tion" program, but we should not infer that Gorbachev's later democratization was
a reluctant response to circumstances he had failed to foresee at the start of his
general-secretaryship. The most compelling reason for democratization was that it
offered the only effective method for overcoming resistance to structural reform, a
resistance that emanated not only from the middle level of the apparatus but was
entrenched at the party's highest levels.39 Structural reform was incompatible with
continued oligarchic rule and the monopolism which underpinned it, and, were the
oligarchic hegemony to remain, the reforms would be as surely emasculated as
Kosygin's had been. For that very reason a merely notional democratization was
inadequate; so too was an "inverted democracy" that established certain freedoms
at the grass roots but left the supreme political organs untouched.40 The only
effective democratization would be one targeted at an incorrigibly conservative
ruling class itself.
The general view of Western observers up to and indeed beyond 1985 was that
no party leader would contemplate such a democratization. The oligarchs would

36
Gorbachev, Izbrannye rechi i stat'i 3:8.
37 Ibid., 235.
38 Ibid. 4:37, 38.
39 Zaslavskaia, The Second Socialist Revolution, 177-80, 190.
40On "inverted democracy" see Seweryn Bialer, "Gorbachev's Program of Change: Sources, Sig-
nificance, Prospects," in Gorbachev's Russia and American Foreign Policy, ed. Seweryn Bialer and
Michael Mandelbaum (Boulder and London: Westview, 1988), 256.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroikaas Revolutionfrom Within 49

obviouslyhave everythingto lose fromit; and so wouldthe leaderhimselfif he were


fullyidentifiedwith the oligarchyor harboredautocraticaspirationsof his own. The
generalsecretary,however, was neither an autocratnor any ordinaryoligarch.He
was in the deeply ambiguousposition of arch-oligarch,locked in a frustratingand
potentially antagonisticrelationshipwith his fellow oligarchsfrom which he was
looking for an exit. Stalin had set the precedentof an autocraticresolutionof the
conflict,but Khrushchevrepresenteda more relevantalternative-neutralizingthe
oligarchswith democratic tendencies. For democratizationdid not threaten the
arch-oligarchas it did the rulingclass as a whole: on the contrary,by expandingthe
politicalnation he was more likely to augmenthis own power at the expense of his
co-rulers.
This does not mean that Gorbachevlaunchedperestroikaas a populistgamble,
thoughthe program'spopulistpotentialcan only have encouragedhim to pursueit.
But it is to say that by the early 1980s autocracywould have been a wholly inade-
quate, indeed archaicresponse to deepeningproblemsthat threatenedto jeopar-
dize the stabilityof the politicalorderand the great-powerpositionof the state. The
question that loomed large by the close of 1986was whetherGorbachevwould be
able to take the alternativeroute and break an oligarchicpower that had come to
seem the country'snaturalpoliticalmode.
GORBACHEV IN POWER: DEMOCRATIZATION
Till then he had tried to progressby meansof agreementwith the oligarchs,among
whom Egor Ligachevhad emerged as a tenaciousguardianof the system'sessen-
tials. That, however, had proved impossible, and continuationof the consensual
approachthreatened him with an impasse. At this juncture Gorbachevchanged
tacticsand enteredinto directconflictwith the oligarchy'sconservatives.His speech
to the January1987 plenum proved so contentiousthat the plenum met only after
three postponementsand after what one can only assumewere bloody behind-the-
scenes battles.41The passionswere inevitable,for Gorbachevnow raiseddemocrati-
zation from its previoussubordinatestatus and placedit unequivocallyat the heart
of his program,from which it would never thereafterbe dislodged, arguingthat
"democratismis not simply a slogan but the essence of perestroika"and showing
how seriously he took it by suggestingelectoral reform with secret ballots and a
choice of candidates.42
To abandonconsensualismwas a high-risktactic, but this does not mean that
Gorbachevadopted it reluctantly,still less that the new approachwas improvized.
The resistance to reform was foreseeable and had surely been foreseen, and the
question was not whether Gorbachevtried to overcomeit by democratizationbut
when. From now on democratizationdoubled as both strategyand tactic, since it
was indispensablenot only for nationalregenerationbut for the survivalin powerof
the regenerationprogram'sarchitects. In an earlier reformingepoch the radical
litterateurNikolai Dobroliubov had noted apropos of within-systemreform how

41
Pravda, 26 February 1987.
42
Ibid., 28 January 1987.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
50 John Gooding

hard it was to turn over a box if you happened to be inside it, but how easy the task
became once you stepped outside the box.43In unleashing democratization Gorba-
chev now stepped outside his box. The decision was fraught with incalculable
consequences, but one inevitable consequence stood out: he and his outnumbered
supporters within the ruling class faced a battle they would lose unless they could
modify the power equation by invoking societal forces on their side. They could
hardly avoid the fate of Speranskii and Stolypin unless they moved rapidly to
legitimize and encourage public opinion, and Gorbachev's speech to the January
1987 plenum was a first step toward this, loosing ideas that were to be profoundly
corrosive of oligarchic power. The oligarchs' predictable resistance thus had the
effect of activating the suppressed democratic implications of the "new thinking,"
and once these ideas had been loosed with the general secretary's imprimatur, they
could hardly be recalled. From that time the qualitative transformation so desired
by many oppositional intellectuals began to occur. It was a transformation in which
they would take a major part, and Gorbachev must have realized that the framers
of the message would demand an increasing say in its content. Yet the main theme
of the phase of perestroika that began in January 1987 and ended three years later
would not be the problem of containing the unleashed forces of democracy; rather,
it would be the defeat of a defiant, if now defensive, oligarchy.
The dominant event of the phase, coming almost in the middle, was the Nine-
teenth Party Conference, which provided the first real sign that democratization
might turn the party rank-and-file against the oligarchs. It also saw the initiation of
a still more risky tactic of revitalizing the system of soviets. Democratization within
the party might strengthen Gorbachev vis-ai-visthe party establishment, but a revi-
talized soviet system, crowned by an effective working parliament, offered a still
greater prize-through it he might deploy popular pressure against a recalcitrant
oligarchy and even create for himself an institutional position largely detached from
and immune to the party.
The need to reconcile the oligarchs to policies that would hurt their interests
forced Gorbachev to stretch "Speranskiism" to its limits. As Speranskii had taken
advantage of different understandings of the concept of "fundamental law," so
Gorbachev made the most of the different resonances in the Soviet context of
"democracy." And like Speranskii he played hard upon the insecurities of the
power-holder, justifying perestroika by arguing that the policies of the "stagnation"
years had precipitated not only an economic, but a political crisis.44He had made
no such diagnosis in 1985-86, but as his policies became more radical they de-
manded a more clamorous rhetoric. He tried to persuade the oligarchs that if the

43 N. A. Dobroliubov, Literaturnaia kritika


(Moscow: Khudozhestvennaia literatura, 1979), 306.
44 A first reference to "the danger of the growth of crisis-type phenomena" came in his speech to the
January 1987 Plenum (Pravda, 28 January 1987). Thomas Remington refers to a samizdat account of the
plenum's proceedings, according to which Gorbachev compared the Soviet crisis with the crises in other
socialist countries and argued that the Soviet Union, unlike its neighbors, could not look elsewhere for
help in solving its problems. See "A Socialist Pluralism of Opinions: Glasnost and Policy-Making under
Gorbachev," Russian Review 48 (July 1989): 273. By the summer of 1987, Gorbachev was using the
"crisis" argument more full-bloodedly. See, for instance, Gorbachev, Perestroika, 11.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 51

party backed him it would retain its vanguard role and dominate the new politics,
thus exploiting their hopes as well as their fears. Indeed, throughout this phase he
treated the party's leading position as a sine qua non of the reform process, as in a
sense it obviously was. The refurbished party riding the waves of democratic poli-
tics would have little in common other than the name with the historic CPSU, which
had been an instrument of oligarchic (and for a time, autocratic) absolutism. His
apparent refusal to recognize any possible disjunction between the interests of the
party and the nation was nevertheless by no means hypocritical. The party re-
mained the only effective weapon of change, as well as the only means of control
over the forces he was unleashing, and he would hardly want to diminish its stature
while he exercised power simply as its chief executive.
There was, however, a contradiction between his continued insistence on party
supremacy and the reform process itself, highlighted by a steady revaluation of
ideology which took the premises of the "new thinking" to their natural conclusion
by repudiating party monopolism. Communism and the "new Soviet man" disap-
peared, giving way to a more traditional man whose self-improvement and even
proprietary instincts were now harnessed to more modest goals-a "new society"
and "qualitatively new condition of socialism."45The new socialism-presented, of
course, as Leninist socialism reborn-was defined above all in terms of a democ-
racy that was participatory, rights-oriented, and of its essence pluralistic; and at the
Nineteenth Party Conference and thereafter Gorbachev explicitly contrasted such a
democracy with the older, counterfeit version.46 Pluralism, a key concept from
1988, was admittedly qualified by "socialist" and was not to lose the qualifier until
1990, but it laid an ax at the root of the ideological fiction that legitimized the
oligarchs' monopoly-the single interest and hence single will of the Soviet peo-
ple.47In a society of divergent interests and desires, the task of the state was not to
create an artificial unity by repression but rather to manage diversity, and use it
positively, by institutionalizing it.48Pluralism of opinions, in short, pointed inevita-
bly toward pluralism of politics.
Ideological revaluation prepared the way for a cardinal reform of the political
system, first outlined at the Nineteenth Party Conference. The essence of the
reform was a clear delimitation of the functions of party and state, "delimitation"
being no more than a euphemism for a transfer of powers to the latter. The reforms,
which came on stream in 1989 with the creation of the Congress of People's Depu-
ties, the revamped Supreme Soviet, and the chief executive office of Chairman

45 The disappearance of communism from Gorbachev's discourse is reflected in the indexes to the
volumes of his Izbrannye rechi i stat'i. The first volume (covering 1967 to 1983) contained twenty-eight
references to "communism" or "communist construction." By vol. 3 (October 1985 to July 1986) the
number of such references had fallen to twelve; vol. 4 (July 1986 to April 1987) had only three such
references; and in vol. 6 (December 1987 to October 1988) there were a mere two.
46 For such a contrast see Pravda, 29 June 1988.
47 On pluralism see the article by Thomas Remington cited in note 44.
48 Decision
making, Gorbachev pointed out at the Nineteenth Party Conference, might be followed
and not merely preceded by "a lack of general agreement," and such a lack was "a normal phenomenon
for the democratic process" (Pravda, 29 June 1988).

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
52 John Gooding

answerable to the new institutions, weakened the oligarchy by exposing its mem-
bers to a touch of the democracy they had always purported to defer to; and
Gorbachev made ruthless use of the March 1989 elections, which were fought in
conditions of unprecedented openness, to rout a number of hardliners.49But if the
"politicization of social awareness," as Gorbachev called it, increased pressure on
party conservatives, it also showed up the illogicality of his own continued defense
of party monopolism. The glaring contradiction between an authoritarian ruling
party whose monopolistic claims remained unretracted and a popularly elected
legislature almost instantly recognized as the nation's parliament cried out to be
resolved.
By the second half of 1989 the lines of command in the Soviet political system
had in fact become badly blurred as nascent proto-democratic politics vied with old-
style directive politics. The system had lost coherence, and Gorbachev's own dual-
ism of functions indicated as much. As general secretary-cum-chairman he uncom-
fortably straddled two competing political cultures, his authority deriving both from
the party's increasingly threadbare legitimacy and from an individual exercise of
will by the electors. The quandary of the democratizer who was not yet willing or
able to free himself from the original undemocratic source of his power deserved
some sympathy, of course, and deputies did not press him on the question of which
office claimed his greater loyalty. The issue of ultimate authority was being resolved
anyway by the processes he had set in motion, and Nikolai Ryzhkov for one noticed
how the new Supreme Soviet was encroaching on the policy-making functions of
plenum and Politburo.50Short of a retrogression, which would have violated all that
had been achieved since January 1987, integrity could be restored to the political
system only by sacrificing party monopolism and redefining the executive power in
such a way as to make it unambiguously dependent upon the legislature. These
were the changes that public opinion clearly wanted and that ideological revisions
required, and Gorbachev would push them through with skill and decisiveness in
February-March 1990, thus consummating the revolution from within.
THE REVOLUTION FROM WITHIN AND AFTER
The reform movement had been nourished by the assumption that removing the
administrative-command system would leave in place a reinvigorated party pursu-
ing socialism with the nation's support. By now, however, that assumption seemed
naive and unrealistic. Partial or "commune" democracy might have been realizable
in the 1920s, but in 1990 the democratization process either had to break the bounds
of partial democracy or go into reverse.51 The CPSU was no longer an ascendant
force riding a recent revolutionary triumph, nor did it face a peasant population
that, out of deference to the ruling power if not out of socialist conviction, might

49
Including a candidate member of the Politburo, Iurii Solov'ev, first secretary of the Leningrad
regional party committee, who though running unopposed failed to achieve the 50 percent of the poll
necessary to be elected.
50 Pravda, 21 July 1989.
51 For "commune democracy" see Richard Sakwa, "Commune Democracy and Gorbachev's Re-
forms," Political Studies 37 (June 1989): 224-43.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 53

have accepted its nostrums and its paternalistic guidance. Instead, a demoralized
party, its self-confidence sapped by unprecedented critical scrutiny, faced an elector-
ate on which decades of indoctrination had had so little impact that an opinion poll
of 1990 found that less than 20 percent of the respondents believed in socialism, and
only 14 percent in the party that claimed to embody it.52 Those who, taking the
Alternative Tradition at its face value, had assumed the question of democracy
could be fudged had merely deluded themselves.
Removing the party's discredited monopoly without doing damage to socialism
itself would not be easy. Like the sixteenth-century reformers who had set out to
save Catholicism from the Papacy, the radicals who insisted that the party had to
shed its monopoly if socialism were to recover underestimated the dependence of
the faith upon the institution that had for so long been its exclusive custodian. In the
case of the CPSU, its privileged position had been enshrined in the constitution
since the 1930s and had existed in reality since the early 1920s. For most people,
monopolism-the right to rule, to define the articles of faith, and to exact obedi-
ence to them-was the defining feature of the party, and socialism was inextricable
from it.53If this was the view of outsiders, it was all the more so for traditionalists
within the party, who could be expected to make a fierce defense of what for them
was a holy of holies.
In this final struggle with the oligarchy, which would be fought in the forum
of a still highly conservative Central Committee, Gorbachev needed support from
outside the ruling class as never before. Monopolism might have been under-
mined, but only strong and concerted pressure would make it fall. The pressure
would have to come, in the first place, from the party's rank-and-file, and a
carefully orchestrated campaign to deploy them against the elite came to a head
on the eve of the crucial February 1990 plenum, when Pravda gave front-page
coverage to a meeting between Gorbachev and miners' representatives. The min-
ers expressed strong hostility to the apparatchiks, whom they saw as blocking
perestroika's progress. "The leading role of the CPSU," one complained, "has
degenerated into the leading role of the apparatus"-and several were promptly
coopted as delegates to the plenum.54
Such support from working-class party members, the party's traditional bas-
tion, was an unqualified asset for the leadership, but the revolt of another key
group was a decidedly mixed blessing. On the Sunday before the plenum opened a
procession of some two hundred thousand people swept with its shouts and banners
into Revolution Square, where radical deputies and other representatives of the
intelligentsia attacked the party's dominant position. Obshchestvennost'-in the
prerevolutionary sense of critically thinking intellectuals-was challenging vlast' for

52 Soviet
Weekly (London), 29 November 1990.
53 As recently as 1988, Milovan Djilas maintained that "the essence of any Communist system is the
monopolistic rule of society by the Communist party." See "Djilas on Gorbachev: Milovan Djilas and
George Urban in Conversation," Encounter 71 (September/October 1988): 3. And even more recently
"Z" wrote of the leading role of the party as "the supreme taboo of communism." See "To the Stalin
Mausoleum," Daedalus 119 (Winter 1990): 328.
54
Pravda, 9 February 1990.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
54 John Gooding

the first time since the revolutionary period, and was doing so with apparent impu-
nity. Such "support" implied a challenge not merely to oligarchism but to the party
itself, and how little some in authority welcomed this could be gauged from
Pravda's sour report of the event.55The demonstration had indeed been an uncom-
fortable reminder that the forces unleashed since January 1987 might engulf the
leadership and that the position of a vanguard party within a democratizing polity
might prove untenable.
For the time being, however, pressure from the party's grass roots and from
obshchestvennost' had achieved what the leadership wanted. Coerced from without
and even outnumbered within their own forum (this being an "expanded" plenum),
the oligarchs bowed to the inevitable and surrendered their monopoly. They pro-
tested loudly, but not a voice was raised in defense of monopolism itself; and only a
single vote, ironically that of the liberal Boris Yeltsin, was cast against the draft
platform for the forthcoming congress, which included the proposition "The CPSU
does not claim a monopoly and is ready for political dialogue and cooperation with
all who stand for the renewal of socialist society."56
It was an historic surrender, and its natural sequel came a few weeks later with
the conversion of Gorbachev's chairmanship into a presidency with enhanced pow-
ers and greater independence of the party, whose holder would be elected by the
nation-though in this case the election was rushed through on grounds of urgency
by the Congress of People's Deputies alone. In his initial address as president
Gorbachev envisaged his task as being not to act on behalf of "some separate layer
and political tendency" but rather to be "the representative of the whole nation."57
Party and nation had at last been uncoupled, and the relationship between
Gorbachev's two offices had as a result been clarified: he would be chief executive
of state first and head of the party second. The party, demoted to a "separate
polticial tendency," would henceforth be no more than one of the interest groups
within the nation, if much the most influential. As for the Politburo, which for
almost forty years had symbolized the power of the oligarchy, that was almost
casually pushed to the sidelines. It would from now on meet irregularly and con-
sider only party affairs, while the main policy-making forum became instead the
nonparty Presidential Council.
The revolution of February-March 1990 came as a bitter blow to the ruling
class, which faced dispossession as a result, and diehards then began a determined
rearguard action against a leadership they felt had betrayed them. The election in
June of Ivan Polozkov as first secretary of the newly created Russian Communist
Party suggested that they might well regain control of the CPSU at the forthcoming
Twenty-eighth Party Congress. Yet the attempt at oligarchic revanche was in the
end defeated. It enjoyed strong sympathy from the delegates, but most proved in
the end to be conservative-realists rather than conservative-irreconcilables, accept-

55 Ibid., 5 February 1990.


56 Ibid., 13
February 1990.
57 Ibid., 16 March 1990.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 55

ing the diminished status of the party as an unavoidable evil.58 Gorbachev thus
triumphed against the apparent odds over his conservative opponents, the chief of
whom, Ligachev, was now ousted from both the Politburo and the Central Commit-
tee. His victory had, however, done no more than put a temporary halt to the
revanchist movement, which again gathered strength in the fall and by its advance
provoked an increasing self-assertion by the radicals. By the end of 1990 it was clear
in fact that the politics of confrontation had displaced the politics of consensus, and
as a result the prospect of a "Speranskiian" outcome-of peaceful qualitative
change through the medium of but ultimately transforming existing structures-had
become more or less negligible. In Gorbachev's case, however, it was not failure
that threatened to be his undoing but rather his very real, if partial, success.
What exactly had he achieved? In February 1990, if the editor of Pravda is to
be believed, there had been a perevorot- which may indicate no more than a coup
d'etat, but may also indicate a revolution too limited or incomplete to be seen as a
revoliutsiia.59There was certainly nothing of a coup about what happened in Febru-
ary 1990; the outcome of the plenum had, on the contrary, been prepared not only
by the political and ideological developments of the preceding five years but by
socioeconomic and cultural tendencies of much longer duration. Yet the February
changes, however zakonomerno they occurred, represented no more than a prelimi-
nary stage in the process of reconstructing power relationships and by no means
took the process to a conclusion. The main achievement of Gorbachev's revolution
from within had been the destruction of oligarchic absolutism, which had rested
upon the sacrosanct status and monopoly rights of the Communist Party. The
pseudo-democratic facade behind which oligarchic power had been exercised had
been stripped away; the desacralization of the party had been given a powerful fillip
by the removal of its privileged status; and the institutional and juridical precondi-
tions for a pluralistic society and a multiparty political system had to a considerable
extent been established.
That, however, was the limit of the achievement of a revolution that had
dismantled the formal mechanism of absolutism without eliminating the conditions
that had made absolutism possible. The party had lost its natural right to rule, and
policy-making had in part been admitted to the public domain. Yet if the party
faced dispossession it had not so far been dispossessed, and it continued to rule
through a largely unreconstructed nomenklatura, between which and the demo-
cratic opposition only the president could mediate. Gorbachev, however, cut an
increasingly ambiguous figure, and all the unresolved contradictions of the Alterna-
tive Tradition now seemed to be expressed in him. Had perestroika been a program
of economic reform and societal regeneration whose primary purpose had been to
assure the internal and external security of the party-state? Or was its democratiz-
ing element not merely instrumental but an attempt to inculcate the culture of

58 I discuss the distinction between "conservative-realists" and


"conservative-irreconcilables" in
"The XXVIII Congress of the CPSU in Perspective," Soviet Studies 43 (March 1991): 247.
59 Pravda, 17 March 1990.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
56 John Gooding

democracy? The ambiguities helped explain both the initial success of the pe-
restroika coalition, which had embraced structural and nonstructural reformers
alike, and the fact that the coalition was now manifestly falling apart. Gorbachev's
strategy had been to advance gradually toward a version of social democracy with
the support of the broad mass of the population, whose innate loyalty to socialism
and the CPSU would enable him to disregard "extremists" at either end of the
spectrum and to side-step the Tradition's contradictions. By the end of 1990, how-
ever, this strategy lay in ruins. Far from dominating Soviet politics from an expand-
ing center, he faced "extremists" to Right and Left who were encroaching fast on
the middle ground by offering clear-cut solutions to the ethnic and economic prob-
lems which had undermined any possibility of consensualism.
Revolts of the minor nationalities in the Baltic region, the Caucasus, Moldova,
and even the RSFSR now jeopardized the very existence of the multinational
state, and in doing so helped the conservatives by enabling them to exploit not
merely Russian nationalism and great-power chauvinism but deep-rooted fears of
anarchy as well. The feeling of a threat to the very fabric of everyday life was
heightened by growing economic dislocation. Perestroika had been predicated
upon the support of the intelligentsia, and by its middle-class values and emphases
it had run a foreseeable risk of alienating mass support. Few would have guessed,
however, that the reform program would precipitate a disastrous deterioration in
living conditions-empty shelves becoming for most the emblem of Gorbachev-
ism-and thereby put at risk the sympathy not only of the working class but even
of those at whose interests it had been aimed. There had in fact been a fateful
asynchronism of the political and the economic: at the very time when oligarchic
power was falling victim to democratization, an economic crisis, accompanied by
severe ethnic troubles, was creating pressures that an embryonic democratic polity
underpinned by the frailest of democratic cultures would have great difficulty in
withstanding.
Gorbachev's revolution from within had thus proved more negative than posi-
tive: it had destroyed one political-economic system but not replaced it by another.
The very "withinness" of the revolution had vitiated its effectiveness, since it had to
proceed under the auspices of that which it was in fact to undermine. What oc-
curred was a revolution against the effective party (namely, the oligarchy) and the
mental constructs which sustained it, carried through in the name of Leninist social-
ism, and its result was to erode whatever credibility the official ideology still pos-
sessed without generating any alternative ideology or even ethic that could com-
mand general assent. As with ideology, so with power-relationships. The party had
lost its right to rule but not its ruling position, and yet now found that it could no
longer rule effectively. Perestroika's unanticipated success and its transcending of
the modest parameters within which it began resulted therefore in a breakdown
rather than a transfer of authority. The revolution left in its wake a wounded party,
a more or less destroyed ideology, a president weakened and bewildered by the
collapse of the political center and hence of his strategy, a vociferous democratic
opposition given populist appeal by the personality of Boris Yeltsin, and forces of

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Perestroika as Revolution from Within 57

entrenched conservatism which showed every intention of fighting to claw back


what they had lost. The reformers had set out to restore to Russian politics the
possibilities and the squandered socialist potential of the 1920s, but they had fin-
ished by confronting the country with choices so stark and fundamental that they
recalled 1917 instead.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Fri, 19 Dec 2014 08:45:10 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like