You are on page 1of 8

I

Increasing Returns to Scale process of division of labour as the main reason


why we observe technologies that exhibit increas-
Spyros Vassilakis ing returns to scale. A version of their arguments
runs as follows: Let A be the set of tasks to be
executed in order to produce good x; a partition
The focus of this essay is the set of positive A1,. . ., An is called a first-stage division of labour.
propositions that can be obtained when technol- Each sub-task Ai, i = 1,. . ., n is executed by
ogy exhibits increasing returns to scale. The basic (potentially but not necessarily) different kinds
incompatibility of perfect competition and of machinery and primary factors, to be called
increasing returns to scale is examined separately first-stage intermediate goods. The set of tasks to
in a section on existence of equilibria, in which we be executed in order to produce each first-stage
discuss how one should model economies intermediate good is also subject to division of
exhibiting such technologies, i.e. essentially how labour, to be called second-stage division of
to modify the Walrasian equilibrium concept in labour. Each subtask generated by a second-
order to guarantee existence of equilibria. Welfare stage division of labour is executed by intermedi-
and purely empirical problems are not considered. ate goods, to be called second-stage intermediate
Definitions: A technology exhibits increasing goods. Clearly, this process can go on indefinitely.
returns to scale if a proportionate increase in all We say that the process of division of labour stops
inputs allows for a more than proportionate at the nth stage if the n-stage intermediate prod-
increase in outputs; in the single-output case, ucts are all primary factors; a process is feasible if
this implies a decreasing average cost curve. it stops after a finite number of stages and if the
demand for primary factors that it generates does
not exceed supply. Suppose, now, that production
processes are indivisible, i.e. that when an inter-
Division of Labour and Increasing
mediate good is utilized in the production of some
Returns to Scale
other good, its quantity cannot fall short of a
minimum irreducible amount, to be called a
Adam Smith (1776), Babbage (1832), Marshall
fixed cost. An increase in the degree of division
(1890, 1919) and Young (1928) considered the
of labour is defined as either a finer partition of the
set of tasks to be executed in order to produce
This chapter was originally published in The New
some good, with the number of stages fixed; or an
Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, 1st edition, 1987.
Edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter increase in the number of stages. Clearly, then, an
Newman increase in the degree of division of labour implies
# The Author(s) 1987
Palgrave Macmillan (ed.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics,
DOI 10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_746-1
2 Increasing Returns to Scale

an increase in fixed costs; discarding inferior divi- by governments (Book IV, ch. II; Book I,
sions of labour, therefore, means that an increase ch. II).
in the degree of division of labour has to imply a (5) Economic activity is located in areas in which
decrease in variable cost coefficients. transportation is least costly, and therefore in
Smith (1776, p. 7) gave three reasons for such a areas with the largest potential for division of
decrease: labour and trade (Book I, pp. 18–21).
first, . . . the increase of dexterity in every particular (6) The division of labour is limited by the stabil-
workman; secondly . . ., the saving of the time ity of the market (this is not explicitly stated
which is commonly lost in passing from one species by Smith, but a number of passages indicated
of work to another; and lastly . . . the invention of a that he was aware of it: Book I, p. 21; Book
great number of machines which facilitate and
abridge labour, and enable one man to do the work IV, p. 430).
of many.
Notice that (1), (2) and (6) are general propo-
(See also Babbage 1832, ch. xix.) From now
sitions, while (3), (4) and (5) are applications.
on, the (degree of) division of labour and the
Proposition (1) has generated many important
degree of increasing returns are used as
subsidiary propositions, to be described below.
synonyms.
Smith used it to derive (3), (4) and (5) without
paying attention to the fact that he never demon-
strated how the division of labour is determined
Adam Smith (as opposed to limited) by the extent of the
market.
Adam Smith formulated the following Marx (1867, Vol. I, Part IV, section 4), Young
propositions: (1928), Coase (1937) and Stigler (1951) utilized
Proposition (1), often unwittingly, to provide the
(1) The division of labour is limited by the extent rudiments of a theory of vertical integration and
of the market (Book 1, ch. 3). production roundaboutness. Marx (1867, Vol. I)
(2) The extent of the market is positively related considered the two as different aspects of the same
to population size and density, the amount of problem, i.e. vertical (dis)integration is ‘division
natural resources and accumulated capital of labour in the society’ and production round-
available, and the ease of transportation aboutness is ‘division of labour in the workshop’.
(Book 1, ch. 3; Book 2, pp. 259–61). The following quotation is from Book I, ch. XIV,
(3) Small economies devote most of their section 4, p. 355:
resources to agriculture, while large econo- But what is it that forms the bond between the
mies specialize in industry, because the latter independent labours of the cattle-breeder, the tan-
affords a greater degree of division of labour. ner, and the shoemaker? It is the fact that their
respective products are commodities. What, on the
For exactly the same reason, increases in mar-
other hand, characterizes division of labour in man-
ket size decrease the price of industrial prod- ufactures? The fact that the detail labourer produces
ucts relative to primary products, and as a no commodities. It is only the common product of
consequence the profit rate in industry all the detail labourers that becomes a commodity.
Division of labour in society is brought about by the
declines (Book I, ch. XI, pp. 242–7; Book
purchase and sale of the products of different
III, ch. I). branches of industry, while the connexion between
(4) Trade increases market size and allows each the detail operations in a workshop is due to the sale
trader (country, region, individual) to special- of labour-power of several workmen in one capital-
ist, who applies it as combined labour-power. The
ize and reap the benefits of increased division
division of labour in the workshop implies concen-
of labour. Trade is therefore beneficial to all tration of the means of production in the hands of
parties involved, it increases real income of all one capitalist; the division of labour in society
classes, and therefore should not be restricted implies their dispersion among many independent
producers of commodities. While within the
Increasing Returns to Scale 3

workshop, the iron law of proportionality subjects firms and so sharing fixed costs with other buyers,
definite numbers of workers to definite functions, in is that the fixed cost of these functions is too high
the society outside the workshop, chance and
caprice have full play in distributing the producers relative to market size to allow for the survival of
and their means of production among the various even one specialized firm. This argument is based
branches of industry. on the implicit assumption that it is profitable for
an integrated firm to perform the increasing
Marx also saw that the degree of vertical inte-
returns to scale function, while a specialized firm
gration is higher the higher the degree of market
would make a loss because it would not be able to
imperfection:
capture all the surplus of the downstream firms,
the distinction between division of labour in society i.e. it would be able to practise only a sufficiently
and in manufacture was practically illustrated to the
Yankees. One of the new taxes devised at Washing- imperfect degree of price discrimination. As mar-
ton during the Civil War, was the duty of 6 % ‘on all ket size increases, though, the position of the
industrial products’. Question: What is an industrial specialized firm is strengthened, and eventually
product? Answer of the legislature: A thing is pro- it can extract enough surplus from the down-
duced ‘when it is made’, and it is made when it is
ready for sale . . ..The New York and Philadelphia stream firms to make positive profit; at this point
manufacturers had previously been in the habit of integrated firms abandon the increasing returns
‘making’ umbrellas with all their belongings. But function and become downstream firms (buyers)
since an umbrella is a mixtum compositum of very as far as this function is concerned. Spence and
heterogeneous parts, by degrees these parts became
the products of various separate industries, carried Porter (1977) have provided a formal, partial-
on independently in different places. They entered equilibrium model along these lines.
as separate commodities into the umbrella manu- The nature of the trade-off is different in
factory, where they were fitted together. The Yan- Vassilakis (1986b): there are global increasing
kees have given to articles thus fitted together the
name of ‘assembled articles’, a name they deserve, returns to scale, and firms can choose both the
for being an assemblage of taxes. Thus the umbrella degree of division of labour in the production of
‘assembles’ first, 6 % on the price of each of its the final good (i.e. production roundaboutness)
elements, and a further 6 % on its own total price’ and the extert to which they will make their own
(ibid., p. 355, footnote 2).
intermediate goods (vertical integration). Inte-
Coase (1937) rediscovered and generalized grated firms do not buy their intermediate goods,
these observations of Marx and constructed a and so they avoid monopolistic exploitation asso-
theory of the firm out of them: price-mediated ciated with the non-price taking behaviour of
transactions are costly, and firms exist in order to intermediate goods sellers; on the other hand,
economize on these costs by organizing transac- they have to pay the fixed cost of producing inter-
tions in a different, non-price mediated way. At mediate goods. For specialist firms the trade-off is
this level of generality, the theory is tautological. reversed. Also, a firm that adopts a high degree of
Stigler (1951) was the first to try to make it oper- division of labour has to pay higher fixed cost, but
ational: he assumes that a single-output firm exe- lower variable cost, than a firm that produces the
cutes a set of functions, some of them subject to same product with a lower degree of division of
diminishing and others to increasing average cost. labour. In equilibrium, the ratio of specialist to
The reason why the firm does not become a integrated firms (the degree of vertical disintegra-
monopoly is that the increasing cost functions tion), and the degree of division of labour within
eventually prevail over the decreasing cost ones, each firm (production roundaboutness), are such
so that the firm’s average cost curve is U-shaped. that the costs and benefits of marginal changes
(This is clearly not in the spirit of the classical cancel out. Increases in market size (the number
economists, who assumed global increasing of agents) increase vertical disintegration and pro-
returns.) The reason why with small market size, duction roundaboutness for the same reason: it
a firm performs the increasing returns functions pays to exploit economies of scale more fully
itself, instead of abandoning them to specialized now both by sharing fixed costs with other buyers
instead of bearing them unilaterally, and by
4 Increasing Returns to Scale

reducing variable cost through increases in fixed Proposition (6) has been exploited by Piore and
cost. In this sense, market size determines the Sabel (1984). Given that a reduction in demand
degree of division of labour. Very clear anticipa- uncertainty is equivalent to an increase in market
tions of these views on vertical integration are to size, reductions in uncertainty will increase the
be found in Austin Robinson (1931, pp. 19, 65, degree of division of labour. Piore and Sabel
96, 110). view the coexistence of large and small firms,
Proposition (3), another application of Propo- inventory holding, long-term contracts tying
sition (1), has not been subject to equally intensive buyers to sellers and vertical integration as
theoretical investigation. Kaldar (1978, Essay 9) uncertainty-reducing devices that allow for a
and Negishi (1986, ch. 3) provide some clarifica- higher degree of division of labour. Also, collec-
tions. Proposition (4) reappears in Ohlin (1933, tive wage bargaining and government stabiliza-
ch. 3). For the empirical puzzles that led to the tion policies are attempts to control that part of
reintroduction of increasing returns to scale in uncertainty that cannot be affected by individual
formal trade theory, see Helpman and Krugman firms. Weitzman (1982) and then Kaldor (1983)
(1985, pp. 2–4). went even further and argued that a necessary
Proposition (5) can be found in Ohlin (1933, condition for involuntary unemployment, and
pp. 200–211), who generalizes it considerably; therefore for Keynesian economics, is the pres-
increasing returns to scale in production and trans- ence of increasing returns to scale, otherwise the
portation favour concentration of economic activ- unemployed can ‘produce themselves out of
ity in as few points as possible, while the unemployment’, since non-increasing returns to
dispersion of natural resources and the fact that scale imply that small-scale production is at least
certain economics activities are resource- as efficient as large-scale. (see also the Sympo-
intensive favour decentralization. It is also impor- sium on Increasing Returns and Unemployment
tant whether raw materials for final products are Theory 1985).
cheaper to transport, with the obvious implica-
tions for localization of activities. The result of
these consicierations is a generalization of Propo- Mill and Marx
sition (5).
[5] Districts with good transport relations tend to Mill and Marx gave two closely interrelated
attract pierty of labour and capital and become propositions:
important market; consequently they tend to spe-
cialize in industries which (1) are market-localized (7) Increases in market size result in increased
and show important advantages from large-scale
production; and (2) produce goods which are diffi- concentration of economic activity, in the
cult to transport. On the other hand, districts with sense that a higher percentage of the popula-
poor transport relations become scantily populated tion earn income by selling labour (and not by
and tend to specialize in goods which are easy to producing). See Mill (1848, Book I, ch. IX,
transport and can be advantageously produced on a
small scale (Ohlin 1933, p. 208). p. 3) and Marx (1867, ch. XXXII).
(8a) Increases in market size, and the resulting
Implience in Ohlin et al. (1976, pp. 48–50) is concentration and increase in the scale of
the proposition that increases in market size production of each firm, is an unqualified
increase geographical concentration of economic benefit from the efficiency point of view,
activity; the reason seems to be that with increased but not necessarily from the equity point of
size there is more to be gained by fuller exploita- view (Mill ibid.; Marx ibid. and ch. XXV).
tion of scale economies, i.e. by higher concentra-
tion of economic activity, and this gain more than Both (7) and (8a) are derived as a consequence
compensates for loss due to increased transporta- of the fact that concentration allows for fuller
tion costs. exploitation of scale economies; Marx added
another reason, i.e. that the skills of small-scale
Increasing Returns to Scale 5

producers are ‘rendered worthless’ by division of returns to scale technology and producers facing
labour, which subdivides and simplifies the tasks downward sloping demand, so that (9) is the only
to be executed in order to produce a commodity version of the law that might be sustainable.
(Marx 1848, in McLellan 1977, p. 227). Indeed, increasing concentration and a falling
Another proposition of Marx on the same sub- profit rate have been obtained in Vassilakis
ject is: (1986a) as a result of increases in market size;
the profit rate, though, falls because both the real
(8b) Increases in market size increase the distance wage and the proportion of workers in the popu-
between the economy’s actual and potential lation rise in a full employment model, so this
performance (Marx 1867, ch. XXXII); Elster version of the law is not entirely in the Marxian
(1985, ch. 5), provides a rather exhaustive spirit. As for Proposition (8a), the formal literature
discussion of the exact meaning of this supports the view that with increasing returns to
proposition. scale only in the neighbourhood of the origin,
increases in market size reduce Pareto inefficiency
We now make (8b) more precise by thinking of and in the limit they eliminate it (Novshek and
increases in market size as generating two contra- Sonnenschein 1978; Hart 1979). On the other
dictory forces: on the one hand, efficiency hand, Hart and Guesnerie (1985) have found that
increases because the increase in market size and with global increasing returns, Pareto inefficiency
the resulting increase in concentration does not disappear in the limit, although per capita
(Proposition 7) allow for fuller exploitation of inefficiency does; Vassilakis (1986a) finds that
scale economies; on the other hand, this very even per capita welfare loss can be positive in
increase in concentration that results in fuller the limit, for a particular choice of technology;
exploitation of scale economies, hampers effi- the difference in the result is due to the fact that the
ciency by increasing the distortionary effects latter reference assumes that the alternative to
associated with non-price taking behaviour. In producing is being a worker and earning wage
other words, economies of scale are created faster income, while Hart and Guesnerie assume the
than they are exploited. Finally, we can safely opportunity cost of a producer to be zero. So, it
attribute to Marx the following proposition, a is fair to say that there is some support for Prop-
variant of his law of the falling rate of profit osition (8a), while Proposition (8b) remains
(Marx 1894, Vol. III, Part III). untested.

(9) Increases in market size reduce the profit rate.


Marshall
Proposition (9) differs from Proposition (3) of
Smith (and Ricardo), because it does not rely on
Marshall (1890, p. 318, 1919, pp. 186–9) believed
the law of diminishing returns due to land scarcity.
that all industries exhibit global increasing returns
(In Marx’s words, Ricardo ‘fled from economics
to scale, checked only by short-run fixities or land
to seek refuge in organic chemistry’ in order to
scarcities; in this case he agreed with the classical
generate a falling profit rate). It is formulated in
economists. As Stigler (1941, p. 78) remarked,
this particular way, because it has been shown that
though, ‘if the economies of large scale produc-
under constant returns to scale and a constant real
tion are so important . . ., how do small concerns
wage, the law does not hold, while with a rising
manage to exist at all?’ and ‘either the division of
real wage it holds only under very restrictive
labour is limited by the extent of the market, and,
assumptions that turn the law into an improbable
characteristically, industries are monopolized; or
special case (Roemer 1981, chs 4, 5 and 6). On the
industries are characteristically competitive, and
other hand, Negishi (1985, ch. 4) has provided
the theorem is false or of little significance’
some textual evidence to support the view that
(Stigler 1951). Marshall tried to reconcile
Marx had in mind an economy with increasing
6 Increasing Returns to Scale

economies of scale and perfect competition in thought that it cannot be elevated to a general
three different ways, namely: explanation of the coexistence of competition
and increasing returns, so he had to invent expla-
(a) (Some) economies of scale are external to nation (b); (Marshall 1919, pp. 315–16). We have
the firm. to conclude that (not only) in ‘competitive, sta-
(b) Increasing returns to scale is a dynamic phe- tionary economies, Marshall clearly fails to pro-
nomenon, and its full effects take so long to vide the conditions of stable equilibrium’ (Stigler
manifest themselves that ‘the guidance of the 1941, p. 81). Downward sloping demand and
business falls into the hands of people with non-price taking behaviour cannot be avoided,
less energy and less creative genius’ therefore; based on Marshall’s cues (Marshall
(Marshall 1890, p. 316). 1890, pp. 286–7, 453–8), Sraffa (1926), Robinson
(c) Transportation costs rise so fast in some (1933) and Chamberlin (1933) reintroduced
industries as to restrict the market area of downward sloping demand almost one hundred
each firm. years after Cournot.
Despite the fact that Marshall did not have a
Clearly, (a) assumes the problem away; in Mar- formal theory of increasing returns economies, he
shall’s own words, relentlessly applied ‘the principle of Increasing
. . . with the growth of capital, the development of Return’ to generate propositions. He is the only
machinery, and the improvement of the means of one after Smith, Marx and Mill to propose a new
communication the importance of internal econo- general proposition (not an application), namely:
mies has increased steadily and fast, while some of
the old external economies have declined in impor-
tance (Marshall 1919, p. 167). (10) ‘. . . almost every kind of horizontal exten-
sion tends to increase the internal economies
But even if we assume that most economies of of production on a large scale, but as rule, an
scale are external to the firm, competition is not increase in the variety of output lessens the
the most likely outcome; one still has to explain gain in this direction’ (Marshall 1919,
why firms do not merge to internalize external p. 216).
economies, in which case oligopoly is the most
likely outcome, or why markets for external In other words, increasing variety reduces effi-
effects do not emerge, in which case again, exter- ciency. Proposition (10) is then utilized by Mar-
nal economies become internal, and we are back shall to explain the coexistence of large and small
to square one. (Starret and Heller (1976) analyse firms, and to determine the range of products of a
external effects as absence of markets; Makowski multiproduct firm. Large firms produce those
(1980) analyses mergers as a way to internalize goods that are most in demand and/or afford the
external effects.) greatest degree of division of labour; their product
Explanation (b) is at best of limited impor- range is determined by the condition that the
tance, unless one can show that expansion by addition of one more product would increase
merger is impossible or that the market for man- cost (due to lost scale economies) by more than
agers is so imperfect that a long-lived firm is it would increase revenue (due to increased mar-
doomed to fall in the hands of the inept. Also, in ket area). Small firms produce goods whose
Stigler’s words, ‘if Marshall’s discussion of econ- demand is so low, and/or afford so small a degree
omies is correct and approximately complete, it of division of labour, that large firms do not want
would not require an extraordinarily high calibre to produce, because they can be better off devot-
of entrepreneurship to secure a monopoly, or at ing their resources to increase production of the
least a dominant position, in almost any industry’ commodities they already produce. As market
(Stigler 1941, p. 81). Finally, explanation (c) is of size increases, there is more to be gained by con-
limited applicability because it ignores increasing centration, so firm size tends to increase. On the
returns to scale in transportation. Marshall himself other hand, though, small firms will survive at all
Increasing Returns to Scale 7

market sizes, because of three factors (Marshall each firm is lower than average costs for large
1919, ch. III and IV). enough output levels, otherwise firms would pro-
duce arbitrarily large amounts; thirdly, the number
(a) The increased income generated by increased of firms should be sufficiently large to discourage
market size allows consumers to demand entry, so as to ensure that if one more agent sets up
goods closer to their ideal specifications, so a firm, he will earn less than his earnings in the
the variety of goods demanded increases. best alternative occupation. Finally, one needs a
(b) Increased market size increases household large number of agents relative to the degree of
specialization, i.e. goods previously produced increasing returns to ensure that the number of
within the household become commodities. firms is large enough to satisfy the conditions
(c) Increased size increases vertical above, and in order to convexify reaction corre-
disintegration. spondences, so that fixed-point theorems can be
applied (see Roberts and Sonnenschein 1977, and
An obvious implication of this theory is that Novshek and Sonnenschein 1978). All models in
increases in market size will have different effects, the literature on increasing returns to scale base
depending on the degree of demand homogeneity their existence results on (i), (ii) and (iii) above,
and on whether demand is concentrated on goods although they differ in specifics. Thus, we have
that afford considerable division of labour. Mar- Bertrand models, in which the agents’ strategic
shall (1919, Book I) attributes the different growth variable is price, and Cournot models, in which
patterns of industrial economies to differences in agents compete in quantities. Also, we have sym-
the size stability and perfection of their respective metric models, in which all agents are allowed the
markets. same strategic possibilities; and non-symmetric
models, in which the set of agents is, a priori
and once and for all, divided into two disjoint
Existence of Equilibrium sets: the set of consumers–factor suppliers–price
takers, and the set of producers–factor
The incompatibility of pricetaking behaviour and demanders–price makers (or quantity setters).
increasing returns to scale was first noticed by Existence in non-symmetric Cournot models
Cournot (1838, pp. 59–60), but rigorous exami- with increasing returns only in a small
nation of the issue has been taken up only very neighbourhood of the origin is proved in Novshek
recently. and Sonnenschein (1978), and with global
No general existence theorems are available increasing returns in Hart and Guesnerie (1985);
because there is no generally accepted model to existence in symmetric Cournot models with
imperfect competition. What is available, though, global increasing returns is proved in Vassilakis
points to the importance of the following three (1986a). All proofs with global increasing returns
factors: (i) downward sloping demand; (ii) a var- refer to a single-input, single-output economy. For
iable number of firms; (iii) a large number of non-symmetric Bertrand games, with a single
agents relative to the degree of increasing returns. input, see Hart (1985) and Economides (1982,
Downward sloping demand is clearly a necessary 1983); for the single-output many-inputs case
condition for existence in economies with global see Sharkey (1982, ch. 8).
increasing returns to scale, for otherwise firms
would have an incentive to produce an unlimited
amount of some output. The number of firms
See Also
should be variable for three reasons: first, because
of fixed costs, the number of firms cannot be too
▶ Competition
large for otherwise profit would be negative; sec-
▶ Division of Labour
ondly, the number of firms should be sufficiently
▶ Learning-by-Doing
large to ensure that the demand price faced by
8 Increasing Returns to Scale

Bibliography Mill, J.S. 1848. Principles of political economy. London:


J.W. Parker.
Babbage, C. 1832. On the economy of machinery and Negishi, T. 1985. Economic theories in a non-Walrasian
manufactures. London: C. Knight. tradition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Chamberlin, E. 1933. The theory of monopolistic competi- Novshek, W., and H. Sonnenschein. 1978. Cournot and
tion. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Walras equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory 19:
Coase, R. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica 4: 223–266.
386–405. Ohlin, B. 1933. Interregional and international trade.
Cournot, A. 1838. Recherches sur les principes Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
mathématiques de la théorie des richeses. Paris: Ohlin, B., et al. 1976. The international allocation of
M. Rivière. economic activity. New York: Holmes & Meier.
Economides, N. 1982. Oligopoly in differentiated products Piore, M., and C. Sabel. 1984. The second industrial
with three or more competitors. Columbia University divide. New York: Basic Books.
discussion paper no. 153. Roberts, J., and H. Sonnenschein. 1977. On the founda-
Economides, N. 1983. Symmetric equilibrium existence tions of the theory of monopolistic competition.
and optimality in differentiated products markets. Econometrica 45: 101–113.
Columbia University discussion paper no. 197. Robinson, E.A.G. 1931. The structure of competitive
Elster, J. 1985. Making sense of Marx. Cambridge: Cam- industry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
bridge University Press. Robinson, J. 1933. The economics of imperfect competi-
Hart, O. 1979. Monopolistic competition in a large econ- tion. London: Macmillan.
omy with differentiated commodities. Review of Eco- Roemer, J. 1981. Analytical foundations of Marxian eco-
nomic Studies 46: 1–30. nomic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hart, O. 1985. Monopolistic competition in the spirit of Sharkey, W.W. 1982. The theory of natural monopoly.
Chamberlin: A general model. Review of Economic Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Studies 52(4): 529–546. Smith, A. 1776. In An inquiry into the nature and the
Hart, O., and R. Guesnerie. 1985. Welfare loss due to courses of the wealth of nations, ed. E. Cannan. Lon-
imperfect competition: Asymptotic results for don: Methuen, 1961.
Cournot-Nash equilibria with and without free entry. Spence, M., and M. Porter. 1977. Vertical integration and
International Economic Review 26(3): 525–545. differentiated inputs. Harvard discussion paper no. 576.
Heller, W., and D. Starret. 1976. On the nature of external- Sraffa, P. 1926. The laws of returns under competitive
ities. In Theory and measurement of economic conditions. Economic Journal 36: 535–550.
externalities, ed. S. Lin. New York: Academic. Stigler, G. 1941. Production and distribution theories.
Helpman, E., and P. Krugman. 1985. Market structure and New York: Macmillan.
foreign trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Stigler, G. 1951. The division of labor is limited by the
Kaldor, N. 1978. Further essays on economic theory. Lon- extent of the market. Journal of Political Economy 59:
don: Duckworth. 185–193.
Kaldor, N. 1983. Keynesian economics after fifty years. In Symposium on Increasing Returns and Unemployment
Keynes and the modern world, ed. D. Worswick and Theory. 1985. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics
J. Trevithick. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 7(3): 350–409.
Makowski, L. 1980. Perfect competition, the profit crite- Vassilakis, S. 1986a. Increasing returns and strategic
rion, and the organization of economic activity. Journal behavior I: The worker-employer ratio. Johns Hopkins
of Economic Theory 22(2): 222–242. working paper no. 168.
Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of economics. London: Vassilakis, S. 1986b. Increasing returns and strategic
Macmillan. behavior II: The division of labor. Johns Hopkins work-
Marshall, A. 1919. Industry and trade. London: ing paper no. 169.
Macmillan. Weitzman, M. 1982. Increasing returns and the foundations
Marx, K. 1867–1894. Capital, 3 vols. Harmondsworth: of unemployment theory. Economic Journal 92:
Penguin Books, 1976. 787–804.
McLellan, D. 1977. Karl Marx, selected writings. Oxford: Young, A. 1928. Increasing returns and economic pro-
Oxford University Press. gress. Economic Journal 38: 527–542.

You might also like