You are on page 1of 15

 R.E.

Marks 1998 Oligopoly 1


 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 2

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing


In this section we consider how firms compete Perfect Monopolistic Pure
when there are few sellers — an oligopolistic Competition Competition Monopoly
market (from the Greek).
Small numbers of firms may result in strategic
interaction, in which what Firm 1 does in choosing
price or quantity affects Firm 2’s profits, and vice
versa. Mixed Market Structure

How to incorporate the reactions of your rivals into


your profit-maximising?
Look forwards and reason backwards.
Price
Oligopoly Cartel
Put yourself in their shoes, as they try to Leadership
anticipate your actions.
Use game theory: assuming rationality.
After a brief look at mixed market structures, we Cartel: a group of sellers acting together and
consider: facing a downwards-sloping demand
curve, to fix price and quantity in
1. price leadership, such as the OPEC cartel, concert. (H&H Ch. 8.5)
and limit entry pricing,
Oligopoly: A “few” sellers. (H&H Ch. 10)
2. simultaneous quantity setting: Cournot
competition, Price Leadership: can occur in a market with
3. quantity leadership, with possible first- one large seller (or cartel) and many
mover advantage, small ones (“the competitor fringe” of
price takers); the large firm can affect
4. simultaneous price setting: Bertrand the price by varying its output.
competition,
5. collusion and repeated interactions,
6. predatory pricing, “natural monopolies”,
skimming pricing, and tie-in pricing.
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 3  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 4

Strategic Pricing — Oligopolistic Behaviour Benchmarking Equilibria I


Two firms produce homogeneous output. Industry
No grand model. Many different behaviour
demand P = 10 − Q, where Q = y 1 + y 2 . Identical
patterns. A guide to possible patterns, and an
costs: AC = MC = $1/unit.
indication of which factors important.
The two benchmarks are comeptitive price-taking
Duopoly — two firms, identical product. and monopoly.
We consider three oligopoly models below.
Four variables of interest:
1. They behave as competitive price takers, each
• each firm’s price: p 1 , p 2
setting price equal to marginal cost.
• each firm’s output: y 1 , y 2
Price PPC = $1/unit, total quantity Q = 9, and
each produces y 1 = y 2 = 4.5 units.
Sequential games:
Since PPC = AC, their profits are zero:
1. A price leader sets its prices before the other
π 1 = π 2 = 0.
firm, the price follower.
2. A quantity leader sets its quantities before 2. They collude and act as a monopolistic cartel.
the quantity follower does. (Stackelberg) Each produces half of the monopolist’s output
and receive half the monopolist’s profit.
Simultaneous games:
Total output QM is such that MR (QM ) = MC
3. Simultaneously choose prices (Bertrand), or
= $1/unit.
4. Simultaneously choose quantities. (Cournot)
The MR curve is given by MR = 10 − 2Q, so
5. Collusion on prices or quantities to maximise QM = 4.5 units, PM = $5.5/unit, and π M =
the sum of their profits — a cooperative (5.5 – 1)×4.5 = $20.25.
game? (e.g. a cartel, such as OPEC) (See the
Each produces y 1 = y 2 = 2.25 units, and
Prisoner’s Dilemma.)
earns π 1 = π 2 = $10.125 profit.
Can use Game Theory to analyse all kinds: the
discipline for analysing strategic interactions.
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 5  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 6

Graphically: 1. Forchheimer’s Dominant-Firm


Price Leadership
10 See Reading __________.
Demand: One large firm and many small firms selling a
8 P = 10 − Q homogeneous good.

6 • one large firm (or perhaps a cartel), the price


$/unit • Monopoly Cartel leader—
has some market power, but this is
4 constrained by the—

2 • many small firms, the “competitive fringe”—


Price-taking who are price takers (they have no market

MC = AC = 1 power) and face a horizontal demand curve.
0
0 2 4 6 8 10 The large firm faces the residual demand curve
Quantity Q = y 1 + y 2
≡ the market demand curve
minus the supply curve of the
competitive fringe.
The other three models will fall along the demand
curve between the Price-Taking combination of 9
units @ $1/unit and the Monopoly Cartel What will the strategy of the price leader be?
combination of 41⁄2 units @ $5.50/unit.
(See the Package Reading ____.)
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 7  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 8

Limit Entry Pricing


P
Because of set-up costs & other irreversible
investments, entry may not be costless, i.e., D industry SCF = Σ MCi
barriers to entry.
The price leader may forgo profits today for the
sake of higher profits later by setting the price
low enough to prevent entry by others (the
“competitive fringe” CF).
If the industry is a falling-average-cost (⇔ IRTS) DPL SPL = MCPL
industry, then the firm can set an
limit entry price PLE
so that: the competitive fringe (& other new
entrants) will find it unprofitable to P PL
continue operating (or to enter). SCF + SPL
PC
Examples ? = S industry

MRPL

Q PL
CF Q PL
PL Q PL Q C Q
Price Leadership

DPL is the residual demand curve:


DPL ≡ D industry − S competitive fringe
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 9  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 10

Comparison of Price Leadership (PL) & Question:


Competitive (C) Pricing without Limit Entry
What is the Marginal Revenue when the Demand
Pricing:
Curve is kinked?
(i.e. long-run pricing)
P
P PL > P C , competitive price D industry
∴ Q PL
CF > QCCF , comp. fringe price (CF)
& Q PL < Q C , industry output
∴ Q PL
PL < QC
PL , price leadership output
but π PL
PL > πC
PL , price leader profit
DPL

which explains it all! (See diagram above.)


P PL is the price under price leadership
PC is the competitive, price-taking price
Q PL is the total quantity sold under price
leadership
MRPL
C
Q is the total quantity sold under price-taking
PL , π PL are the sales and profit of the Price
Q PL PL
Q
Leader under price leadership
CF , π CF are the total sales and profits of the
Q PL PL
Marginal Revenue with a Kinked Demand Curve
Competitive Fringe under price leadership
PL , π PL are the sales and profit of the Price
QC C
Leader under competitive price taking
CF , π CF are the total sales and profits of the
QC C
Competitive Fringe under competitive price
taking
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 11  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 12

2. Simultaneous Quantity Setting — Similarly, derive Firm 2’s reaction function:


y *2 = f 2 ( y e1 )
The Cournot model — set quantity, let market set
price. (H&H Ch. 10.2) — So the Firm 1’s profits are a function of its
output and the other firm’s reaction
• Symmetrical payoffs. function: π 1 = π 1 (y 1 , y 2 (y e1 )).
• One-period model: each firm forecasts the — In general each firm’s assumption of the
other’s output choice and then chooses its own other’s output will be wrong:
profit-maximising output level. y *2 ≠ y e2 , and
• Seek an equilibrium in forecasts, a Nash y *1 ≠ y e1 .
equilibrium1, a situation where each firm finds — Only when forecasts of the other’s output
its beliefs about the other to be confirmed, with are correct will the forecasts be mutually
no incentive to alter its behaviour. consistent:
• A Nash–Cournot equilibrium. y 1 * = f 1 ( y 2 *) , and y 2 * = f 2 ( y 1 *).
• Firm 1 expects that Firm 2 will produce y e2
y 1 * = y e1 and y 2 * = y e2
units of output. • In a Nash–Cournot equilibrium, each firm is
— If Firm 1 chooses y 1 units, then the total maximising its profits, given its beliefs about
out put will be the other’s output choice, and furthermore
those beliefs are confirmed in equilibrium.
Y = y 1 + y e2 ,
• Neither firm will find it profitable to change its
— and the price will be: output once it discovers the choice actually
p (Y) = p ( y 1 + y e2 ). made by the other firm. No incentive to
— Firm 1’s problem is to choose y 1 to max π 1 : change: a Nash equilibrium.
π 1 = p ( y 1 + y e2 ) y 1 − c ( y 1 )
— For any belief about Firm 2’s output, y e2 ,
exists an optimal output for Firm 1: _________
y *1 = f 1 ( y e2 ) 1. John Nash jointly won the 1994 Nobel economics prize
— This is the reaction function: here one firm’s for his 1951 formulation of this.
optimal choice as a function of its beliefs of
the other’s action.
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 13  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 14

• An example is given in the figure (Varian 25.2): 3. Quantity Leadership


the pair of outputs at which the two reaction
curves cross: Cournot equilibrium where each The Stackelberg model — describes a dominant
firm is producing a profit-maximising level of firm or natural leader (once IBM, now Microsoft, or
output, given the output choice of the other. OPEC, etc.). Cournot or quantity competition.
(H&H Ch. 10.2)
2.1 Benchmarking Equilibria II
Model:
They behave as Cournot oligopolists, each choosing Leader Firm 1 produces quantity y 1
an amount of output to maximise its profit, on the Follower Firm 2 responds with quantity y 2
assumption that the other is doing likewise: they
• Equilibrium price P is a function of total output
are not colluding, but competing. They choose
Y = y 1 + y 2:
simultaneously.
P ( y 1 + y 2)
Cournot equilibrium occurs where their reaction
curves intersect and the expectations of each of • What should the Leader do?
what the other firm is doing are fulfilled. Depends on how the Leader thinks the
(Questions of stability are postponed until Follower will react.
Industrial Organisation /Economics in Term 1 Look forward and reason back.
next year.)
• The Follower: choose y 2 to max profit π 2
Firm 1 determines Firm 2’s reaction function: “If I = P ( y 1 + y 2) y 2 − C 2( y 2)
were Firm 2, I’d choose my output y *2 to maximise
my Firm 2 profit conditional on the expectation (from the Follower’s viewpoint, the Leader’s
that Firm 1 produced output of y e1 .” output is predetermined — a constant y 1 ).
• So Follower sets his MR ( y 1, y *2 ) = MC ( y *2 ) to
max π 2 = (10 − y 2 − y e1 ) × y 2 − y 2
y2 get y *2 :
Thus y 2 = 1⁄2 (9 − y e1 ), which is Firm 2’s reaction ∂P
MR ( y 1 ,y *2 ) ≡ P( y 1 + y *2 ) + ____ y *2 = MC( y *2 )
function. ∂y 2
Since the two firms are apparently identical, → y *2 = f 2 ( y 1 )
Cournot equilibrium occurs where the two reaction i.e. the profit-maximising output of the
curves intersect, at y *1 = y e1 = y *2 = y e2 = 3 units. Follower y *2 is a function of what the Leader’s
So QCo = 6 units, price PCo is then $4/unit, and the choice y 1 was already.
profit of each firm is $9.
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 15  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 16

• This function is known as the Follower’s — Since for any level of output y 2 , π 2
reaction function, since it tells us how the increases as y 1 falls, the isoprofit lines to
Follower will react to the Leader’s choice of the left are on higher profit levels. The
output. limit is when y 1 = 0 and so Firm 2 is a
monopolist.
• e.g. Assume simple linear demand and zero
costs. — For every y 1 , Firm 2 wants to attain the
The (inverse) demand function is highest profit: occurs at y 2 which is on the
P ( y 1 + y 2 ) = 10 − ( y 1 + y 2 ) highest profit line: tangency.
— Firm 2’s profit function: — Firm 2’s marginal revenue, from:
π 2 ( y 1 ,y 2 ) = [10 − ( y 1 + y 2 )] y 2 TR 2 = (10 − ( y 1 + y 2 )) y 2
= 10 y 2 − y 1 y 2 − y 22 ∴ MR 2 = 10 − y 1 − 2y 2
— Plot isoprofit lines: combinations of y 1 and = MC 2 = 0 (in this case)
y 2 that yield a constant level of Firm 2’s a straight line: Firm 2’s reaction function,
profit π 2 10 − y 1
y *2 = ________ = f 2 ( y 1 )
y2 2
Firm 2’s output • The Leader’s problem:
the Leader will recognise the influence its
decision (y 1 ) has on the Follower, through Firm
2’s reaction function, y 2 = f 2 ( y 1 )
• So Firm 1 maximises profit π 1 by choosing y 1 :
max P ( y 1 + y 2 ) y 1 − C 1 ( y 1 )
y1
s.t. y 2 = f 2 ( y 1 )
or
y1 max P [y 1 + f 2 ( y 1 )]y 1 − C 1 ( y 1 )
y1
Firm 1’s output
— For the linear demand function above:
(Varian 25.1) _10 − y1
_______
f 2( y 1) = y 2 =
2
(the Follower’s reaction function)
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 17  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 18

— With zero costs (assumed), Leader’s profit 3.1 Benchmarking Equilibria III
π 1:
π 1 ( y 1 ,y 2 ) = 10y 1 − y 21 −y 1 y 2 Stackelberg Quantity Leadership: What if one
B 10−y 1 E firm, Firm 1, gets to choose its output level y 1
= 10y 1 − y 21 − y 1 A _______ A first? It realises that Firm 2 will know what Firm
D 2 G 1’s output level is when Firm 2 chooses its level:
10 1 this is given by Firm 2’s reaction function from
= ___ y 1 − y 21 (choose y 1 to max. π 1 )
__
2 2 above, but with the actual, not the expected, level
10
___ of Firm 1’s output, y 1 .
Now MR 1 = − y 1 = MC 1 = 0
2 So Firm 1’s problem is to choose y *1 to maximise its
Hence the Nash equilibrium: profit:
102
____
⇒ y 1 * = 5, π 1 * = = 12.5 max π 1 = (10− y 2 − y 1 ) × y 1 − y 1 ,
8 y1
102
____
⇒ y 2 * = 2.5, π 2 * = = 6.25 where Firm 2’s output y 2 is given by Firm 2’s
16
reaction function: y 2 = 1⁄2 (9 − y 1 ).
Note: First-Mover Advantage in this case.
Substituting this into Firm 1’s maximisation
y2 problem, we get: y *1 = 4.5 units, and so y *2 = 2.25
Firm 2’s output units, so that QSt = 6.75 units and PSt =
$3.25/unit.
The profits are π 1 = $10.125 (the same as in the
cartel case above) and π 2 = $5.063 (half the cartel
(Varian 25.2) profit).

y1
Firm 1’s output
— Firm 1 is on its reaction curve f 2 ( y 1 ).
Firm 2: choose y 1 on f 2 ( y 1 ) on the highest
isoprofit line, tangency at point A.
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 19  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 20

4. Simultaneous Price Setting 4.1 Benchmarking Equilibria IV


Instead of firms choosing quantity and letting the
Bertrand Simultaneous Price Setting. The only
market demand determine price, think of firms
equilibrium (where there is no incentive to
setting their prices and letting the market
undercut the other firm) is where each is selling at
determine the quantity sold — Bertrand
P 1 = P 2 = MC 1 = MC 2 = $1/unit. This is identical
competition. (H&H Ch. 10.2)
to the price-taking case above.
• When setting its price, each firm has to forecast
If MC 1 is greater than MC 2 , then Firm 2 will
the price set by the other firm in the industry.
capture the whole market at a price just below
• Just as in the Cournot case of simultaneous MC 1 , and will make a positive profit; y 1 = 0.
quantity setting, we want to find a pair of
prices such that each price is a profit- Graphically:
maximising choice given the choice made by
the other firm.
10
• With identical products (not differentiated), the
Bertrand equilibrium is identical with the Demand:
competitive equilibrium and 1, where 8 P = 10 − Q
P = MC ( y*).
• As though the two firms are “bidding” for 6
$/unit • Monopoly Cartel
consumers’ business: any price above marginal
cost will be undercut by the other. 4 • Cournot
•Stackelberg

2
Bertrand & Price-taking

MC = AC = 1
0
0 2 4 6 8 10
Quantity Q = y 1 + y 2
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 21  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 22

5. Collusion — Cartel Behaviour We plot a payoff matrix, which show the


outcomes (each firm’s profits) for all four
(H&H Ch. 10.4)
combinations of pricing High and Low:

• Colluding over price may enable two or more The Prisoner’s Dilemma
firms to push price above the competitive level,
by holding industry output below the
competitive level.
The other player
• They must then agree how to share the
monopolist’s profits.
High Low
• This has elements of the Prisoner’s Dilemma _ _________________________
(See Reading __, Marks: “Competition and L L L
Common Property”.) High L $100, $100 L –$10, $140 L
L L L
• In a simple example: if both firms price High, _
L _________________________
L L
You
each earns $100, while if both price Low, each L L L
earns only $70. Low L $140, –$10 L $70, $70 L
L_ _________________________
L L
• But if one prices High while then other prices
Low, the first earns –$10, while the second
earns $140. TABLE 1. The payoff matrix (You, Other)
A non-cooperative, positive-sum game,
with a dominant strategy.
• Collusion would see the firms agreeing to screw
the customers and each charging High, the
joint-profit-maximising combination of {$100,
$100}.
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 23  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 24

• But the temptation is to screw the other firm 6. Predatory Pricing:


too, by pricing Low when the other firm prices
High. is cutting prices below the break-even point of
Nash Equ. of {Low, Low} → {$70, $70}. competing firms, to cause them to leave the
Efficient outcome is {High, High} and {$100, industry. (H&H Example 10.2)
$100}. (ignoring whom?)
But it may be cheaper to buy out rivals than to
• Moreover, the risk is that you’re left pricing
force them out by predatory pricing.
High when the other firm prices Low.
• The dominant strategy is to price Low. Firm 1 (with market power) prices at P:
AC 1 < P < AC 2 , means that Firm 2 (with higher
• So both do, resulting in an inefficient Nash
costs) cannot make a positive profit.
equilibrium of {Low, Low}, of {$70, $70}.
• Collusion {High, High} can only occur (laws Unless the production process exhibits decreasing
prohibiting collusive behaviour apart) when costs (Increasing Returns to Scale, IRTS) over a
each firm overcomes the temptation to cheat long range of output (perhaps because of high fixed
the other firm and the fear of being cheated. costs), in which case a firm with larger market
We need a credible commitment. share will have lower average cost than do smaller
firms, and the large firm may be able to continue
• If two or more producers collude to push prices
making profits while forcing out the smaller firms.
up while squeezing output, then they are acting
as a cartel. → a race for market share, e.g. ?

Other games? (See Fortune article in Package.)


(See Dixit and Nalebuff’s book Thinking
Strategically.)

e.g. Chicken! — competition
A “Natural Monopoly” (with falling average
e.g. Battle of the Sexes — coordination
cost)
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 25  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 26

>> Include H&H Fig 8.6 <<


7. Dilemma of “Natural Monopolies”:

(H&H Ch. 8.3)

A. Profit maximizing → Pm , Qm the monopoly


output where MR = MC.

B. The competitive solution (Pc , Qc ) where


P = MC & S = D: the firm will fail because
P < AC, and yet this is the ideally efficient
outcome.

C. The breakeven solution (Pr , Qr) where


P = AC, but at a dead-weight loss (DWL) of
consumers’ and producers’ surplus.

This diagram shows why “natural monopolies” are


often

(a) closely regulated (e.g. ?) or

(b) government-owned.
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 27  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 28

To summarise the equilibria considered in these


Lectures:
Skimming Pricing _________________________________________________________
y1 π1 y2 π2 P Q
_________________________________________________________
Price-taking 4.5 0 4.5 0 1 9
• Set relatively high prices at the outset then Cartel 2.25 10.125 2.25 10.125 5.5 4.5
lower them progressively as the market Cournot 3 9 3 9 4 6
expands later. Stackelberg 4.5 10.125 2.25 5.063 3.25 6.75
_________________________________________________________
Bertrand 4.5 0 4.5 0 1 9

(One way of segmenting the market into Graphically:


segments of increasing price elasticity of
demand.)
10
Example? Demand:
8 P = 10 − Q

6
$/unit • Monopoly Cartel
Tie-In Sales
4 • Cournot
•Stackelberg
• Require retailers to buy a “bundle” or “block” of
less preferred as well as more preferred. 2
Bertrand & Price-taking

MC = AC = 1
(A way of capturing more of the retailer’s 0
consumer’s surplus or net willingness to pay.) 0 2 4 6 8 10
Quantity Q = y 1 + y 2
or Leasing may prevent resale among price-
discriminated customers.
 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 29  R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 30

10

8
y1 = y2
6
y2
•Price-taking & Bertrand
4
•Cournot
• •Stackelberg
2 Cartel

0
0 2 4 6 8 10
Quantity y 1

12
π1 = π2
10 Monopoly Cartel •
• Cournot
8
π2
6
• Stackelberg
4

0 •
Price-taking & Bertrand
0 2 4 6 8 10 12
Profit π 1

You might also like