You are on page 1of 3

In 1980 the United Auto Workers (UAW) and Ford Motor Company petitioned the

International Trade Commission (ITC) to recommend relief from import


competition; during the first half of that year foreign car companies shipped 1.2
million passenger cars to the United States, an increase of 21 per cent over the
previous year. The foreign share of the US new car market increased from 17 per
cent to 25 per cent in that period.

US car manufacturers and workers faced big problems. American Motors sold out
to Renault, Chrysler made huge losses and was forced to sell most of its foreign
subsidiaries, Ford made even larger losses and General Motors had to borrow
large sums to keep afloat. By the end of 1980; 193,000 out of 750,000 members
of the UAW were unemployed. The ITC rejected the appeal, saying that the
problems of the motor industry were due to a shift in demand to small, fuel-
efficient cars caused by higher petrol prices, and that the industry had failed to
anticipate this. The reason for the US consumers’ preference for Japanese cars
was debatable. One theory, along the lines of the ITC position, was that imports
were perceived as having better fuel economy, engineering and durability. This
was supported by a survey of 10,000 US households carried out by the Motor and
Equipment Manufacturers Association. Supporters of this theory felt that imports
should not be limited. However, another theory was that price differences
created by labor cost differences were the cause. The Bureau of Labor Statistics
estimated that average Japanese car workers’ wages and benefits in the first half
of 1979 were only half those of US car workers. Those supporting this theory
largely favored taxing imports in order to raise their prices. The arguments for
protecting or aiding the US motor industry were based on two main premises. The
first was that the costs of unemployment were higher than the increased costs to
consumers of limiting imports, and the second was that the US manufacturers
could recover and become fully competitive with imports if they were given
temporary help. The first issue involved an estimation of the hardships of being
unemployed, the adverse effect of their lost purchasing power on other
industries, and the higher taxes necessary to support , the unemployed.

A New York Times poll showed that 71 per cent of Americans felt that it was
more important to protect jobs than to get cheaper foreign products. The second
issue related to the past performance of US manufacturers, the possibility of
achieving economies of scale and higher productivity with new plants. Ford, for
example, estimated that the conversion of its Dearborn engine plant would cost
$650 million but would increase productivity by 25 per cent. Those who rejected
the idea of protection, like the ITC, blamed the managers of the US companies for
their bad decisions. They claimed that these managers and firms should not be
rewarded at the expense of the consumer and taxpayer, who would not only face
higher prices and taxes, but also suffer from limited choice. Retaliation from
foreign countries was another problem that they said might ensue from any kind
of protection. The UAW was mostly concerned about maintaining jobs rather than
protecting the profits of the manufacturers. They thus pushed for foreign
manufacturers to produce in the United States and to have 75 per cent of their
parts produced in the US. This was against the interests of the manufacturers,
who were trying to produce cars globally by buying parts in many different
countries wherever they could be bought cheapest. The Ford Escort for example,
which was assembled in the United States, Britain and Germany, contained parts
from nine countries. The UAW gathered much public support and, with
opposition from consumers being largely unorganized, was successful in 1981 in
obtaining a ‘voluntary’ agreement with Japan to limit car exports to the United
States to 1.68 million units a year for three years. Japanese producers and
politicians entered the agreement fearing that lack of cooperation could result in
even stricter limits. When the agreement expired, Japan continued to limit
exports, but by that time the major manufacturers like Honda, Toyota and Nissan
already had plants in the United States and sales from these soon outnumbered
imports. The effects of the import quotas are also controversial. The US car
industry did recover, but some of this was due to the economy moving out of
recession. US consumers switched back to consuming more expensive and
profitable cars, but this was partly an effect of the import restrictions, which gave
US consumers little choice except to buy more expensive cars. The limits on
Japanese imports were in quantity not in value; therefore Japanese firms
redesigned their cars to make them more luxurious and expensive. During the
three years of the original export agreement, the average Japanese import
increased by $2,600; a Wharton Econometrics study attributed $1,000 of this to
the import limits. In the same period the prices of US-made cars increased by 40
per cent.

Questions

1 Explain how different theories presented in this case study are supported and
how they can be tested in general terms.

2 Explain why the results of the New York Times poll reported above are
meaningless.

3 Explain the conflict of interest between the US car manufacturers and the UAW.

4 Why would the Japanese car manufacturers be willing to co-operate with the
limiting of their exports to the United States?

5 Explain how the costs and benefits of the import quotas can be estimated in
monetary terms, describing any problems involved.

6 One study estimated the cost of the quotas at $160,000 per job saved. In view
of this, why do you think the quotas were implemented?

7 Explain the differences between the decision making processes of the US car
manufacturers and the US government

You might also like