You are on page 1of 3

Chapter 10

Ch.10 Time Series Data - Basic


Time Series Data
1. The Nature of Time Series Data
2. Examples of Times Series Regression
yt = 0 + 1xt1 + . . .+ kxtk + ut 3. Finite Sample Properties of OLSE
4. Functional Form, Dummy Variables
1. Basic Analysis & Index Numbers*
5. Trends & Seasonality

Econometrics 1 Econometrics 2

10.1 Nature of Time Series Data 10.2 Examples of Time Series Models
A static model relates contemporaneous
Time series data has a temporal ordering,
variables:
unlike cross-section data (see table10.1).
 Past can affect the future, but not vice versa. yt = 0 + 1zt + ut (10.1)
 So, we will need to alter some of our assumptions A finite distributed lag (FDL) model allows
to take into account that we no longer have an one or more variables to affect y with a lag:
usual random sample of individuals. yt = 0+0zt+1zt-1+2zt-2+ut (10.5)
Instead, we have one realization of a  More generally, a finite distributed lag model of
stochastic process. (i.e. random) order q will include q lags of z.

Econometrics 3 Econometrics 4

Finite Distributed Lag Models 10.3 Finite Sample Properties of OLSE


yt = 0+0zt+1zt-1+…+qzt-q+ut (10.6) Assumptions for Unbiasedness
We can call 0 the impact propensity – it 1. Linear in parameters:
reflects the immediate change in y. yt = 0 + 1xt1 + . . .+ kxtk + ut (10.8)
 For a temporary, 1-period change, y returns to 2. No perfect collinearity:
its original level in period q+1. (see fig.10.1)
No x is constant or a perfect linear
We can call 0 + 1 +…+ q the long-run combination of the others.
propensity (LRP) – it reflects the long-run 3. Zero conditional mean:
change in y after a permanent change.
E(ut|X) = 0, t = 1, 2, …, n (10.9)
Econometrics 5 Econometrics 6

Time Series Data: Basic 1


Chapter 10

Zero Conditional Mean Assumption Cont. Zero Conditional Mean


Note that this implies the error term in any An alternative assumption, more parallel
given period is uncorrelated with the to the cross-sectional case, is E(ut|xt) = 0.
explanatory variables in all time periods.  This assumption would imply the x’s are
 The x’s are strictly exogenous. contemporaneously exogenous.
 Note we have skipped the random sample  In this case, ut and xt are contemporaneously
assumption, that each ui is independent. Our independent.
strict exogeneity assumption takes care of it in  Contemporaneous exogeneity will only be
the case. sufficient in large samples.

Econometrics 7 Econometrics 8

Unbiasedness of OLS Variances of OLS Estimators


Based on these 3 assumptions, when using Assumptions for Efficiency
time-series data, the OLS estimators are 4. Homosckedasticity:
unbiased. Var(ut|X) = Var(ut) = 2
 Thus, just as the case with cross-section data,  The error variance is independent of all the
under the appropriate conditions OLS is x’s, and it is constant over time.
unbiased. 5. No serial correlation:
Omitted variable bias can be analyzed in Corr(ut,us|X) = 0 for t  s (10.12)’
the same manner as in the cross-section case.  When (10.12)’ is false, the error terms suffer
from serial correlation, or autocorrelation.

Econometrics 9 Econometrics 10

Gauss-Markov Assumptions Inference under the CLM Assumptions


Under these 5 assumptions, OLS variances Assumptions for Hypothesis testing
& the estimators of 2 in time series case
6. Normality:
are the same as in the cross section case.
 The errors are independently and identically
 See theorem 10.2 & 10.3 distributed as Normal.
Under the time series Gauss-Markov With this assumption, inference in time
assumptions, the OLS estimators are BLUE. series case is also the same as in cross
 Even in cross sectional data, non-random section.
sampling case needs these assumptions.
 See theorem 10.5

Econometrics 11 Econometrics 12

Time Series Data: Basic 2


Chapter 10

10.5 Trends & Seasonality Controlling the Trends


Trending Time Series Linear trend:
Economic time series often have a trend. yt = 0 + 1t + et, t = 1, 2, … (10.24)
If y & x series are trending together, we
Exponential trend:
can’t assume that the relation is causal.
 Often, both will be trending because of other ln(yt) = 0 + 1t + et, t = 1, 2, … (10.26)
unobserved factors. Quadratic trend:
Even if those factors are unobserved, we yt = 0 + 1t + 2t2 + et, t = 1, 2, … (10.29)
can control for them by directly controlling
for the trend.
Econometrics 13 Econometrics 14

Using Trending Variables Detrending Interpretation


Though nothing about trending variables
Adding a linear trend term to a regression
necessarily violates the CLM assumptions,
is the same thing as using “detrended”
trending factors that affect y might also be
series in a regression.
correlated with x.
 Detrending a series involves regressing each
 If we ignore this possibility, we may find variable in the model on t.
spurious relationship between y and x.
 The residuals form the detrended series.
Adding a time trend eliminates this problem:
Basically, the trend has been partialled out
yt = 0 + 1xt1 + 2xt2+ 3t + ut (10.31)
by adding the term.
Econometrics 15 Econometrics 16

Computing R2 & Detrending Seasonality


Often time-series data exhibits some
Time-series regressions tend to have very
periodicity, referred to seasonality.
high R2, as the trend is well explained.
 Example: Quarterly data on retail sales will
An advantage to actually detrending the tend to jump up in the 4th quarter.
data (vs. adding a trend) involves the
Seasonality can be dealt with by adding a
calculation of goodness of fit.
set of seasonal dummies.
The R2 from a regression on detrended data  As with trends, the series can be seasonally
better reflects how well the xt’s explain yt. adjusted before running the regression.

Econometrics 17 Econometrics 18

Time Series Data: Basic 3

You might also like