You are on page 1of 11

Brownfield Entry in Emerging Markets

Author(s): Klaus E. Meyer and Saul Estrin


Source: Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 32, No. 3 (3rd Qtr., 2001), pp. 575-584
Published by: Palgrave Macmillan Journals
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3069498 .
Accessed: 04/10/2013 08:03

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Palgrave Macmillan Journals is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of
International Business Studies.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Brownfield Entry in Emerging Markets

Klaus E. Meyer*
COPENHAGENBUSINESSSCHOOL

Saul Estrin**
LONDON
BUSINESS
SCHOOL

This paper focuses on the brown- analyzed on the basis of a frame-


field entry mode, as a special case work utilizing both resource-based
of acquisition, in which the re- and transaction-cost theories. The
sources transferred by the investor resource requirements have to be
dominate over those provided by matched with resources available to
the acquired firm. We see this mode the investor through an acquired
as having particular relevance for firm, and the decision has to ac-
entry strategies in emerging mar- count for the costs of acquiring and
kets. The choice of entry mode is integrating the resources.

INTRODUCTION emerging markets, this restructuring is


so extensive that the new operation re-
The choice of appropriate mode of en-
sembles a greenfield investment. We
try into new markets is a key strategic
term such investment "brownfield", and
decision for international business. A
present it as a hybrid mode of entry.
greenfield project gives the investor the
Our aim in this paper is to delineate
opportunity to create an entirely new or-
the concept of brownfield entry and,
ganization specified to its own require-
ments, but usually implies a gradual drawing on an analytical framework that
we derived from the literature (e.g. Hen-
market entry. An acquisition facilitates
nart and Park, 1993; Barkema and Ver-
quick entry and immediate access to lo-
cal resources, but the acquired company meulen, 1998; Buckley and Casson,
1998), identify the circumstances for its
may require deep restructuring to over-
come a lack of fit between the two orga- emergence. The framework draws upon
both the resource-based view of the firm
nizations. In some situations, notably in

*Klaus E. Meyer is Research Professor at the Center for East European Studies, Copenhagen
Business School, Denmark.His research focuses on foreign investment in emergingmarkets.
**Saul Estrin is Professor of Economics and Deputy Dean, London Business School, UK. His
research focuses on privatization, corporategovernance, direct foreign investment and tran-
sition economies.
The authors wish their colleagues, especially GabrielBenito, Keith Brouthers,Matts Forsgren,
SumantraGhoshal, Torben Pedersen, Freek Vermeulen, seminar participants in Copenhagen
Business School, London Business School and University of Reading as well as participantsof
the AIB conference in Vienna and this journal's referees for their helpful comments on earlier
drafts of this paper.

JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONALBUSINESSSTUDIES, 32, 3 (THIRD QUARTER2001): 575-584 575

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MARKETS
ENTRYIN EMERGING
BROWNFIELD

and transaction cost analysis.1 Brown- chase of stock in an already existing


field projects are attractive if local re- company in an amount sufficient to con-
sources are necessary but not sufficient fer control' Kogut and Singh (1988, p.
for the envisaged operation, and if high 412). The new affiliate joins the invest-
transaction costs inhibit the traditional ing company as a going concern that nor-
modes of entry. mally possesses production facilities,
The analysis builds on our empirical sales force, and market share. The main
work on entry strategies of Western com- distinction is therefore in the origin of
panies in Central and Eastern Europe the resources employed in the new op-
(CEE) (Estrin et al., 1997; Meyer, 1998). eration. Whereas a greenfield uses the
Brownfield emerges as an important en- resources of the investor and combines
try mode in this case study research. The them with assets acquired on local mar-
emerging markets of CEE pose particular kets, an acquisition uses primarily assets
challenges to investors because the legal of a local firm and combines them with
and institutional environment is poorly the investor's resources, notably mana-
developed, markets - especially for cap- gerial capabilities.
ital and skilled labor - are thin and there Most research on mode choice ana-
are numerous market failures (EBRD, lyzes a dichotomous decision between
1999). At the same time, few local firms acquisition and greenfield. However, we
match international standards in tech- found in our casework on CEE that many
nology and management. Since such im- investments, which are formally an ac-
perfect institutional frameworks and quisition, in fact resemble greenfield
weak resource bases exist throughout projects. In such 'brownfield' cases, the
emerging economies, our hybrid entry foreign investor initially acquires a local
mode may be of significance in other firm but almost completely replaces
developing regions. In the next section, plant and equipment, labor and product
we introduce the alternative entry line (Estrin et al., 1997). The new opera-
modes. Our analytical framework is pre- tion is built quickly and primarily with
sented in the third section while the resources provided by the investor. After
fourth section discusses how brownfield only a short transformation period, often
can substitute for either of the traditional less than two years, the acquired local
modes. Implications and directions for firm has undergone deep restructuring,
further research are outlined in section and both its tangible assets and its intan-
five. gibles such as brand names and organi-
zational culture have been reduced to a
ALTERNATIVEMODES OF INVESTMENT
supplementary role.
The literature distinguishes two pri- For instance, Sch6ller Lebensmittel, a
mary modes of foreign direct investment medium-size German frozen-food manu-
(FDI); greenfield (start-up) and acquisi- facturer, acquired a majority share of the
tion. A greenfield project entails build- Hungarian ice-cream factory Budatej.
ing a subsidiary from bottom up to en- Soon after their entry, Scholler recon-
able foreign sale and/or production. Real structed the factory replacing all but one
estate is purchased locally and employ- production line. The factory infrastruc-
ees are hired and trained using the inves- ture was rebuilt, new warehouses were
tor's management, technology, know- established and new freezers provided to
how and capital. Acquisitions are 'pur- the retail outlets. Sch6ller initially even

576 JOURNALOF INTERNATIONAL


BUSINESS STUDIES

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KLAUSE. MEYER,
SAULESTRIN

discontinued the local brand, which was the former dominates over the latter in
perceived to have a low-quality image, the initial post-acquisition integration,
replacing it with their international and that the acquired firm is fundamen-
brands. The motive for the choice of en- tally transformed from the outset. This
try mode was to obtain faster access to includes all investments undertaken on
the market and to benefit from the exist- the basis of integration strategies estab-
ing market share of the local firm. The lished before closing the deal and mod-
new affiliate employed Scholler's pro- ified on the basis of the first comprehen-
duction technology, international brand sive assessment of the acquired firm after
names and management know-how (Es- the acquisition.
trin et al., 1997). Brownfield investors often pursue
Brownfield entry, like the one illus- strategic objectives that assign the ac-
trated, represents a special form of an quired firm a clearly defined role within
acquisition.2 We suggest the following the MNE network, which may require
definition: the affiliate to pursue entirely new func-
a brownfield is a foreign acquisition tions, product lines, or markets. Four of
the five acquisition cases in Estrin et al.
undertaken as part of the establish-
ment of a local operation. From the (1997) share these characteristics, mak-
outset, its resources and capabilities ing them more similar to the five green-
field operations in the same study than
are primarilyprovided by the investor,
to conventional acquisitions.
replacing most resources and capabil-
ities of the acquired firm. DETERMINANTSOF ENTRY MODE
This definition focuses on the newly CHOICE
created subsidiary, and the process of Firms grow through various ways of
combining the resources required for its combining internal and external re-
operation. Most acquisitions involve sources (Penrose, 1959). An optimal en-
some restructuringof the acquired firm, try mode matches the resources required
unbundling or even disposal of assets, for the strategic objectives of the entry
and introduction of new management.In with those available within the multina-
the longer run, most affiliates will more- tional enterprise, in local firms, and in
over develop their own new resources unbundled form on local markets,taking
and capabilities. What makes a brown- into account the pertinent transaction
field acquisition special is that the deep and integrationcosts (TC/ IC).This logic
restructuringis planned from the outset, illustrated in figure 1 sets the structure
and is implemented with the initial in- for our discussion of entry mode choice.
tegration or restructuring strategy. Thus
it is based on decisions taken when the Strategic Resource Requirements
investor first moves in, occurs within a Foreign investors frequently pursue
short time (we consider 2 years as useful strategic objectives concerning the con-
benchmark),and draws only to a limited trol of resources in oligopolistic markets.
extent on the existing resources of the Their strategic intent often predeter-
acquired firm. mines the entry mode, for instance for
In other words, brownfield projects market-seeking and resource-seeking
combine resources from the investor and FDI. Market-orientedFDI may seek a lo-
the acquired business in such way that cal partner to provide market intelli-

VOL. 32, No. 3, THIRD QUARTER, 2001 577

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
BROWNFIELDENTRY IN EMERGINGMARKETS

FIGURE 1
A MODEL OF ENTRY MODE CHOICE

Resources held by
local firms
- Assets, e.g. technology C) ^---Acquisition
>-^:"(ionl
- Marketpower/ barriersto entry
;r:??-i
/
A
Resources /
A-
A
A-/
requiredfor Resources held by / Y
the strategic the investor AK<1~ ~Brownfield
objectives e.g. - Transferableknowledge
- Managerialservices A
- Financialcapital

Resources available ree_' G rie


on markets -- : reenie
e.g. - real estate
- labourskills
- access to utilities TC: Transaction costs of IC: Costs of adapting and
the relevant markets integrating resources

gence or access to distribution networks, strategic intent sets the stage for entry
brand names and market share, espe- mode choice.
cially if pursuing first-mover advantages
(Lieberman and Montgomery, 1998). En- Sources of Resources
trants could borrow brand names (Terp-
Greenfield, and to a lesser extent
stra and Yu, 1990), build their own
brownfield entry, is easier for investors
global brands, or purchase existing
brands from local firms, but all these op- controlling resources that can be trans-
ferred internally and can constitute core
tions are risky or slow. Therefore, the
best way to attain control over marketing competences of the new business unit.
Three kinds of resources of the investing
assets may be through the acquisition of
firm are of particular relevance:
a local firm (Chen and Zeng, 1996) even
if these are the only interesting assets
that the firm controls. * Firm-specific assets that "partake of
Resource-seeking investment may aim the character of a public good
to utilize the local human capital to within the firm, such as knowledge
strengthen the global R&D of the inves- fundamental to the production of a
tor. In this situation, the direct take-over profitable saleable commodity" mo-
of a research laboratory may be more tivate horizontal expansion Caves
efficient than hiring researchers individ- (1971, p. 4). Such resources can be
ually to be able to capture team-embed- employed in a new foreign opera-
ded tacit knowledge. Similarly, firms tion without incurring the initial
pursuing a diversification strategy sunk costs of their development.
abroad may use acquisitions to obtain They include knowledge-based' ca-
the industry-specific assets they lack pabilities, such as technological
(e.g. Hennart and Park, 1993). Thus, the know-how, and access to the inves-

578 JOURNALOF INTERNATIONAL


BUSINESS STUDIES

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KLAUSE. MEYER,
SAULESTRIN

tor's global network of production Finally, local markets provide assets


and distribution channels. required in greenfield ventures, such as
* Excess managerial resources that real estate, business licenses, local blue-
can be redeployed in greenfield op- collar workers, and supplies of interme-
erations stimulate the growth of diate goods. In emerging markets, their
firms (Penrose, 1959). Such organic availability cannot be taken for granted.
growth is preferredby firms that de- Certainresources, notably skills and ma-
velop their capabilities internally terial inputs, may be underdeveloped,
and can integrate a new project into which induces investors to consider ac-
their organizational learning pro- quisitions instead of a greenfield invest-
cess (Kogut and Zander, 1993; ment.
Barkema and Vermeulen, 1998). On
other hand, firms with ambitious en- Transaction Costs
trepreneurs may pursue rapid ex- Bringingtogetherresources previously
pansion relative to their own size held by differentbusinesses incurs trans-
and resources, and favor acquisi- action costs either in the market for cor-
tions. porate control, or on local markets for
* Financial resources also facilitate complementary assets. Markets for cor-
greenfield operations in distant and porate control are highly imperfect in
risky markets. External investors emerging markets, which raises transac-
may be reluctant to finance these as tion costs of foreign acquisitions. Cost
they face difficulties in accessing are incurred for instance for searching
and verifying information, which suitable targets, analyzing their eco-
the firm may posses, on the merits of nomic viability, and negotiating with
the project. Acquisitions, in con- management, owners and government
trast, can more easily be assessed by authorities. Brownfield investors can re-
outsiders, based on the track record duce these costs by considering a wider
of the acquired organization (Chat- array of potential targets (as require-
terjee, 1990). ments are less specific). Yet, they may
incur more conflicts during negotiations
Second, resources of local firms can with local stakeholders, other than own-
attractacquisition entry. They could pro- ers, as restructuringaffects their interests
vide for instance technological assets or (e.g. Antal-Mokos, 1998). In emerging
market share in the target markets. In markets, the transaction costs in equity
industrialized economies, potential tar- markets can thus be a major constraint
gets may be commonly available, and the on foreign acquisitions.
key issue is their valuation by the inves- Similarly, the marketsfor complemen-
tor viz. current owners. In emerging mar- tary resources are fairly efficient in de-
kets, however, there may be few suitable veloped economies, but not necessarily
firms with the sought assets (e.g. Caves, in emerging markets.Estrin et al., (1997)
1995, p. 72; Estrin et al., 1997). At the observe that inefficiencies in these mar-
same time, industries are less likely to be kets led to substantial extra costs and
concentrated and saturated,such that re- delays, or deterred greenfield invest-
taliatorymoves by incumbent firms (Yip, ments. For instance, inefficient bureau-
1982; Buckley and Casson, 1998) are cracy in the local land registries inhibits
only a minor concern. real estate markets in CEE.The resultant

VOL. 32, No. 3, THIRDQUARTER,2001 579

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
BROWNFIELDENTRY IN EMERGINGMARKETS

transaction costs inhibit greenfield zational fit (Kogut and Singh, 1988)
projects. Yet they can be overcome facilitates the creation of a common,
through brownfield entry, which - in Es- or at least compatible, organiza-
trin et al.'s cases - was motivated in par- tional culture in the merged firm
ticular by the control over real estate and (Nahavandi and Malekzadeh, 1988).
access to local networks. Firms whose core competences are
build on a unique corporate culture
Integration and Adaptation thus face greater challenges in inte-
The investment is not complete with grating acquired firms, and would
the collection and acquisition of re- consider greenfield entry.
sources; they have to be amalgated to * International acquisitions are fur-
create an efficient new business unit thermore inhibited by the interac-
within the investors' network. Mode tion between two national cultures
choice therefore has to reflect the costs (e.g. Barkema et al., 1996). Cultural
and time lags required for integration distance between two firms in-
and adaptation. Firms' ability to manage creases communication problems,
the post-entry integration process thus and less of the transferred capabili-
feeds back into their choice of entry ties can be adopted by the acquired
strategy: organization. Firms without experi-
ence in the host country, or originat-
* Capabilities for integration are built ing in high psychic distance coun-
through experience with acquisi- tries, thus face more obstacles to in-
tions. This involves the manage- tegration and are more likely to
ment of the process (e.g. Buono and choose greenfield entry.
Bowditch, 1989; Haspeslagh and
Jemison, 1991) and the development Greenfield investors avoid the costs of
and implementation of a new strat- integration, but are more sensitive to re-
egy that utilizes synergies in the location costs associated with the inter-
new organization, which is more di- national transfer of resources. They are
versified in terms of economic activ- not crossing organizational boundaries,
ities, national cultures and network but international ones, which also can
relationships. result in considerable costs, e.g. for train-
* Integration is furthermore facilitated ing and remunerating expatriates. In ad-
by the prior 'fit' between two orga- dition, organizational and technological
nizations in both strategic and orga- assets have to be adapted to local cul-
nizational-cultural terms (e.g. Bir- tures and standards; and marketing as-
kinshaw et al., 2000). Strategic fit sets such as brand names may have to be
reduces the need to restructure the recreated.
acquired firm to fulfill its strategic
role within the investor's network. BROWNFIELDAS AN OPTION FOR
ENTRY MODE
However, if a local manufacturer is
acquired to access local markets for Figure 1 summarizes the arguments.
the acquirer's global product line - a The mode choice depends first on the
common occurrence in transition resources required for the envisaged
economies - then substantial opera- project, and on the resources available in
tional changes are required. Organi- local firms, in the investing firm, and on

580 BUSINESS STUDIES


JOURNALOF INTERNATIONAL

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KLAUSE. MEYER,SAULESTRIN

FIGURE2
A MODELOF ENTRYMODECHOICE

Conventional
Preferencefor an Does the (to be) yes Acquisitions
extemal expansion
acquiredfirm
strategy (acquisition) possess sufficient
resources? no
Brownfield
Mode
Choice
Brownfield
Does the project yes
Preferencefor an
internalexpansion dependon critical
resourcesnotfreely
strategy(greenfield) available? no
Greenfield

local markets. However, each resource based on the model presented in Figure
has to be evaluated in the light of the 1. By extending the model to a two-stage
costs of the transaction, incurred on mar- decision tree (Figure 2), it can be shown
kets for equity or on markets for unbun- how brownfield projects can be chosen
dled resources. Subsequently, resources in two situations.
have to be transformed to meet the re- First, an external expansion strategy
quirements of the project. may be inhibited by weak assets of local
Brownfield projects can draw upon firms or by high transaction costs in mar-
more sources of resources enabling kets for corporate control. If such con-
projects that neither the foreign investor cerns are overcome by the weight of
nor the local firm could implement other arguments, substantial new facili-
themselves. They can overcome obsta- ties may have to be added to an acquired
cles arising from the limited availability firm. This need may be recognized dur-
of certain assets or from high transaction ing the due diligence stage when prepar-
costs in specific markets by considering ing the acquisition. It may also result
a wider choice of potential target firms. from an 'emerging strategy' if the ex-post
However, brownfields typically incur assessment of the acquired firm reveals a
high integration costs because the inves- need for major restructuring. The latter
tor engages in deep restructuring and in case contains an element of bounded ra-
major resource transfer. This requires in tionality, in that managers should be ex-
particular managerial resources for the pected to do proper due diligence before
complex post-acquisition process. acquisitions. However, Estrin et al.
From a strategic perspective, brown- (1997) suggest that in many cases in CEE,
field projects can substitute for either acquisition decisions had to be made
conventional form. They offer an alter- with incomplete information, leading to
native if the pure strategies of conven- ex post surprises and failed acquisitions,
tional acquisition or greenfield are not due to the unexpectedly serious prob-
feasible, or too costly. Firms may form lems faced in restructuring former so-
their preferences on a bimodal choice cialist enterprises.

VOL. 32, No. 3, THIRDQUARTER,2001 581

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
BROWNFIELD
ENTRYIN EMERGING
MARKETS

Second, a brownfield can complement firm can expect radical restructuring,as


an internal expansion strategy if green- many of its assets are not interesting to
field projects are inhibited because as- the investor. The new operation takes
sets in possession of local firms are a characteristics of the investor, like a de
limiting factor to entry. Firms may pos- novo greenfield investment, while offer-
sess valuable transferable resources or ing little continuity for the local firm.
favor a close integration of the local op- Future research should address in par-
erationbut still depend on a critical local ticular two issues. We observed the phe-
asset. This can induce an acquisition if nomenon in transition economies, where
the asset is inseparable from the local corporate strategies are adapted to the
firm, or if the firm is unwilling to sell the specific institutional context (Peng,
asset unbundled from its operations. Es- 2000; Meyer, 2001). Similarities of insti-
trin et al. (1997) show a variety of such tutions across emerging markets suggest
critical resources: a local partner who that it should be of wider relevance, yet
alone could provide legal permission, lo- not necessarily for developed econo-
cal distribution channels, and patents mies. We have been able to identify in-
and brand names. cidences in for example Egypt, India and
The cases suggest that a 'critical asset' Vietnam. Yet, the relation between insti-
motive driving the acquisition entry is tutional variation across countries and
typical for brownfield projects, and at the emergence of brownfield as entry
least as important as brownfield as 'sec- strategyremains to be explored by future
ond best' acquisition. Having recognized research.
brownfield as an option, it may in fact Empirical research should incorporate
become the prime mode of international brownfield into analyses of both deter-
expansion for firms that combine highly minants of entry mode choice, and the
competitive resources or high organiza- impact of entry modes on subsidiary per-
tional integration with some crucial lo- formance. In particular, we encourage
cal assets.3 analysis of the empirical relevance of the
alternativeproposed decisions processes
OUTLOOK
leading to brownfield:how importantare
Entrymode choice is not only between critical assets for acquisition decisions,
acquisition and greenfield; we have and to what extend does brownfield in-
identified a hybrid option: brownfield. It vestment emerge out of insufficient pre-
is chosen especially by firms with core acquisition due diligence?
competences based on a combination of
firm-specific international resources NOTES
with specific local assets. As companies 1. Many empirical studies have also
are increasingly competing with global been taken into account. These focus on
strategies that require both high integra- firm-specific characteristics that foster
tion and local resources, brownfield can the ability to manage either mode, or to
be expected to be of increasing impor- enhance the benefits investors can obtain
tance worldwide. from them (e.g. Caves and Mehra, 1986;
For local stakeholders, the distinction Hennart and Park, 1993; Andersson and
between brownfield and conventional Svensson, 1994; Chen and Zeng, 1996;
acquisition should help form their ex- Barkema and Vermeulen, 1998). While
pectations. In a brownfield, the acquired most studies consider a two-way choice

582 JOURNALOF INTERNATIONAL


BUSINESS STUDIES

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KLAUSE. MEYER,SAUL ESTRIN

between acquisitions and greenfield, tural Barriers, and Learning, Strategic


Kogut and Singh (1988) consider a three- Management Journal 17, p. 151-66.
way choice that includes joint-ventures. & Freek Vermeulen. 1998. Inter-
2. Acquisitions can vary from legal national Expansion through Start-up or
transactions without changes in opera- through Acquisition: a Learning Per-
tions to cases where a single critical asset spective, Academy of Management
controlled by a local firm induces the Journal 41, 7-26.
take-over. Examples of the former are Birkinshaw, Julian, Henrik Bresman &
take-overs of suppliers to increase con- Lars Hakanson. 2000. Managing the
trol in a corporate network (Forsgren,
Post-Acquisition Integration Process,
1989). At the other end of the spectrum Journal of Management Studies 37,
of acquisitions stands the East German no. 3.
acquisition by Danisco A/S, a Danish
Buckley, Peter J. & Mark Casson. 1998.
food-conglomerate (Meyer and M0ller,
Analysing Foreign Market Entry
1998). Danisco sought a quota under the
Strategies: Extending the Internalisa-
EU sugar market regulation; regulatory
tion Approach, Journal of Interna-
constraints on refining capacity imply
tional Business Studies 29, p. 539-62.
that firms can expand only by acquiring
Buono, Anthony F. & James L. Bow-
quotas from other producers. When East
ditch. 1989. The Human Side of Merg-
Germany joined the system, each of its
ers and Acquisitions, London: Jossey
small refineries received a quota. Al-
Bass.
though the facilities were technologi-
obsolete, Caves, Richard E. 1971. International
cally sharp competition
emerged over acquisition of these firms. Corporations: The Industrial Econom-
3. We encountered one such firm: in ics of Foreign Investment, Economica
the US, the "fastest growing health care 38, p. 1-27.
maintenance organization ... made no .1995. Multinational Enterprises
large acquisitions, though it does buy and Economic Analysis, 2nd ed., New
tiny firms to save it from having to apply York: Cambridge University Press.
for operating licences in states (of the & Sanjeev Mehra. 1986. Entry of
USA) it wants to enter" (Economist, Foreign Multinationals into U.S. Man-
1997). ufacturing Industries, in: M. Porter,
ed.: Competition in Global Industries,
REFERENCES Boston: HBS Press.
Andersson, Thomas & Roger Svensson. Chatterjee, Sayan. 1990. Excess Re-
1994. Entry Modes for Direct Invest- sources, Utilization Costs, and Mode
ment Determined by the Composition of Entry, Academy of Management
of Firm-Specific Skills, Scandinavian Journal 33, p. 780-800.
Journal of Economics 96, p. 551-560. Chen, Shih-Fen & Ming Zeng. 1996. Rep-
Antal-Mokos, Zoltan. 1998. Privatisa- utation Barriers, Marketing Capabili-
tion, Politics, and Economic Perfor- ties, and Japanese Investors' Choice of
mance in Hungary, Cambridge, Cam- Entry Strategy into the US, Working
bridge University Press. Paper no. 97-27, Anderson Graduate
Barkema, Harry, John Bell & Johannes School of Management, University of
Pennings. 1996. Foreign Entry, Cul- California, Riverside.

VOL. 32, No. 3, THIRDQUARTER,2001 583

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ENTRYIN EMERGING
BROWNFIELD MARKETS

Economist. 1997. Managed Health Care: advantages: Retrospective and Link


Aetna Implodes, The Economist, Octo- with the Resource-based View, Strate-
ber 4, 1997, p. 77. gic Management Journal 19, p. 1111-
Estrin, Saul, Kirsty Hughes & Sarah 25.
Todd. 1997. Foreign Direct Investment Meyer, Klaus E. 1998. Direct Investment
in Central and Eastern Europe, in Economies in Transition, Aldershot:
London: Cassel. Elgar.
European Bank for Reconstruction and . 2001. International Business Re-
Development. 1999. Transition Re- search on Transition Economies, in: T.
port, London: EBRD. Brewer and A. Rugman, eds.: Oxford
Forsgren, Matts. 1989. Foreign Handbook of International Business,
Acquisitions: Internalization or Net- in press.
work Interdependency, Advances in In- & Inger Bjerg M0ller. 1998. Man-
ternational Marketing 3, p. 141-59. aging Deep Restructuring: Danish Ex-
Haspeslagh, Philippe C. & David B. Jemi- periences in Eastern Germany, Euro-
son. 1991. Managing Acquisitions: Cre- pean Management Review 16, p. 411-
ating Value through Corporate Renewal, 21.
New York: Free Press. Nahavandi, Afsaneh & Ali R. Malekza-
Hennart, Jean-Frangois & Young-Ryeoul deh. 1988. Acculturation in Mergers
Park. 1993. Greenfield vs. Acquisition: and Acquisitions, Academy of Man-
The Strategy of Japanese Investors in agement Review 13, 79-90.
the United States, Management Sci- Peng, Mike W. 2000. Business Strategies
ence 39, p. 1054-1070. in Transition Economies, Sage.
Kogut, Bruce & Harbir Singh. 1988. The Penrose, Edith. 1959. The Theory of the
Effect of National Culture on the Growth of the Firm, 3rd edition with
Choice of Entry Mode, Journal of Inter- new preface, London: Oxford Univer-
national Business Studies 19, no. 3, p. sity Press, 1995.
411-32. Terpstra, Vern & Joseph C. Yu. 1990.
& Udo Zander. 1993. Knowledge Piggybacking: A Quick Road to Inter-
of the Firm and the Evolutionary The- nationalization, International Market-
ory of the Multinational Corporation, ing Review 7 (4), p. 52-63.
Journal of International Business Yip, George. 1982. Diversification Entry:
Studies 24, p. 625-46. Internal Development versus Acquisi-
Liebermann, Marvin B. & David B. tion, Strategic Management Journal 3,
Montgomery. 1998. First-mover (Dis)- p. 331-45.

584 BUSINESS STUDIES


JOURNALOF INTERNATIONAL

This content downloaded from 152.13.18.10 on Fri, 4 Oct 2013 08:03:15 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like