You are on page 1of 16

American Economic Association

Housing Market Discrimination, Home-ownership, and Savings Behavior


Author(s): John F. Kain and John M. Quigley
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 62, No. 3 (Jun., 1972), pp. 263-277
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1803375 .
Accessed: 25/06/2014 05:14

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Housing Market Discrimination,Home-
ownership, and Savings Behavior
By JOHNF. KAIN AND JOHN M. QUIGLEY*

The question of whether discrimination cal studies leads us to conclude that blacks
in the housing market forces Negro house- may pay between 5 and 10 percent more
holds to pay more than white households than whites in most urban areas for com-
for identical bundles of residential services parable housing. Our own analyses of a
has been studied extensively. Still it re- 1967 sample of nearly 1,200 dwelling units
mains a controversial subject. Those who in St. Louis, Missouri suggests a discrim-
claim that discrimination markups exist ination markup in that city on the order of
in urban housing markets rely principally 7 percent.2
on a series of empirical studies which con- Differentials of this magnitude would
clude that blacks pay more than whites for represent a significant loss in Negro wel-
comparable housing or that housing in the fare. However, we contend that re-
ghetto is more expensive than otherwise searchers, in their concern about estimat-
identical housing located outside the ghetto. ing the magnitude of price discrimination,
(See B. Duncan and P. Hauser, R. Haugen have overlooked a far more serious conse-
and A. James Heins, Kain and Quigley Bailey who concludes, "there is no indication that
(1970b), D. McEntire, Richard Muth, C. Negroes, as such, pay more for housing than do other
Rapkin, Rapkin and W. Grigsby, Ronald people of similar density of occupation" (1966, p. 218.)
A detailed presentation of the argument against the
Ridker and John Henning, and M. Sten- existence of a ghetto markup (price discrimination) is
gel.) Those who argue that price discrim- contained in Muth. Muth's own empirical research on
ination does not exist contend that studies the South Side of Chicago, indicates that "Negroes may
pay housing prices that are from 2 to 5 percent greater"
which purport to find evidence of a dis- than whites pay, p. 239. However, he argues that these
crimination markup fail to standardize measured differences, and presumably those obtained
completely for differences in the bundles of in many other empirical studies, are due to cost dif-
ferences (higher operating costs for housing in Negro
residential services consumed by black and neig,hborhoods) and do not represent a discriminatory
white households (see Martin Bailey (1959, markup.
1966), Richard Muth, and Anthony 2 This study, based on a 1967 sample of 629 renter
observations and 438 observations on single-family de-
Pascal).' Evaluation of the diverse empiri- tached housing of the city of St. Louis, goes further than
any previous study in attempting to "standardize" the
* Harvard University and the National Bureau of bundles of residential services consumed by whites and
Economic Research. An earlier version of this paper was blacks. Contract rent or market value (for owner-
presented at the meetings of the American Economic occupied, single-family homes) was regressed upon a
Association in New York, December 28-30, 1969. We detailed set of qualitative and quantitative attributes
would like to acknowledge the assistance of Laura of the bundles of housing services. In addition to vari-
Stieg, Ana Bell, and William McNaught and the ables used in previous studies, such as the number of
helpful suggestions of H. James Brown, Daniel R. Fred- rooms and floor area, our regressions included as ex-
land, Eric A. Hanushek, Clifford R. Kern, Joseph J. planatory variables an elaborate set of quality evalua-
Persky, T. Nicolas Tideman, and Randall D. Weiss. tions for the dwelling unit, the structure, the adjacent
This paper is based on research funded by the National structures, and the immediate neighborhood, as well as
Bureau of Economic Research. The views are, however, indexes of the quality of the neighborhood public school
those of the authors and should not be interpreted as and of the level of criminal activity. Also included was a
reflecting the views of the NBER or any of its sponsors. variable measuring the racial composition of the census
I The only empirical study known to us which fails tract in 1967. These models are discussed in some detail
to find evidence of higher prices in the ghetto is by in Kain and Quigley (1970b).

263

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
264 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

quence of housing market discrimination. white households. We hypothesize that


In asking whether blacks pay more than this difference results from restrictions on
whites for the same kind of housing, they the location and types of housing available
have failed to consider adequately the way to Negro households. This "supply restric-
in which housing discrimination has af- tion" hypothesis cannot be adequately
fected the kinds of housing consumed by tested for a single metropolitan area.
Negro households. Therefore, we present a second statistical
There is a great deal of qualitative evi- analysis of the differences in actual and
dence that nonwhites have difficulty in ob- expected rates of Negro homeownership
taining housing outside the ghetto (see among eighteen large metropolitan areas.
James Hecht, Kain (1969), McEntire, and Finally, the paper examines the implica-
Karl and Alma Taeuber). Persistence, a tions of the apparent limitations on Negro
thick skin, and a willingness to spend enor- homeownership on their housing costs and
mous amounts of time house-hunting are capital accumulation.
minimum requirements for nonwhites who
wish to move into white neighborhoods. I. Homeownership and Purchase
These psychic and transaction costs may by St. Louis Households
be far more significant than out-of-pocket To investigate Negro-white differences
costs to Negroes considering a move out in homeownership, we developed models
of the ghetto. Most blacks limit their search relating the probability of homeownership
for housing to the ghetto; this limitation to the socioeconomic characteristics of a
is more than geographic. There is less sample of 1,185 households in the St. Louis
variety of housing services available inside metroplitan area (401 black and 784 white
the ghetto than outside; indeed, many households). Subsequently, we examined
bundles of housing services are unavailable the decision to purchase or to rent for a
in the ghetto at any price. This limited subsample of 466 households which had
range of housing services within the ghetto changed residence in the precedingthree
almost certainly influences the pattern of years.
Negro housing consumption. A full dis- The analysis employs the regression of a
cussion and evaluation of the many ways in binary dependent variable indicating ten-
which discrimination may modify the ure status (1 = own, 0= rent) on several
housing-consumption behavior of Negro explanatory variables reflecting family
households is beyond the scope of this size, family composition, employment
paper. However, the general principle can status, household income, and race. Many
be illustrated by the differential propensi- previous studies have emphasized the im-
ties of Negro and white households to own portance of the family life cycle to house-
and to purchase their homes. hold consumption patterns (see Martin
Two statistical analyses of the probabil- David; John Lansing and L. Kish; Lan-
ity of homeownership follow. The first is sing, Kish, and James Morgan; Sherman
a detailed analysis of the probability of Maisel; and Morgan). The life cycle hy-
ownership and purchase for a sample of pothesis includes the combined influences
St. Louis households. It indicates there is of several household characteristics, which
a substantial difference in the probability we represent by a series of family type/
of Negro and white homeownership and age interaction variables: 1) single persons
purchase even after accounting for most (living alone or in groups) under forty-five
of the important differences in the socio- years of age; 2) singles over forty-five
economic characteristics of Negro and years of age; 3) couples without children

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KAIN AND QUIGLEY: HOUSING MARKET 265

with heads under forty-five years of age; Of primary importance to this discus-
4) couples without children with heads sion is the coefficient of the race dummy
over forty-five years of age; and 5) typical variable. It indicates that, after accounting
families (individuals or married couples for differences in life cycle, income, educa-
with children). tion, and employment status, Negro
Typical families were further described households have a probability of owner-
in terms of age of head, family size, num- ship .09 less than that of whites. Thirty-
ber of school-age children, and by dummy two percent of Negro households in the
variables for: female head of less than sample owned their homes; if they were
forty-five years of age; and female head of white, 41 percent would be homeowners.
more than forty-five years of age. Income, There are some indications thlat the
years of schooling (of head), and number of barriers to Negro occupancy in white
years at present job (for head), were in- neighborhoods are gradually declining.
cluded as explanatory variables for all Thus, it could be argued that current
households. Race was indicated by a ownership patterns primarily reflect his-
dummy variable (1 = Negro, 0 = white). torical discrimination and provide a mis-
The probability of ownership equation, leading view of current conditions. To test
obtained by the method of generalized least this hypothesis, we estimated probability-
squares is summarized by equation (1) of-purchase (1 = purchase, 0= rent) equa-
(Table 1).3 All the coefficients of equation tions for those sample households which
(1) have the anticipated signs and are rea- changed their residence within the past
sonable in magnitude, and twelve are three years. Equation (2) presents the re-
highly significant statistically using con- sults for the probability-of-purchase anal-
ventional criteria. The results indicate ysis (Table 1). The explanatory variables
that old couples are more likely to be are identical to those included in equa-
homeowners than young couples, and old tion (1). The coefficients of the dummy
singles are more likely to be homeowners variables representing household type and
than their younger counterparts. None are age differ in magnitude for recent movers.
as likely to be homeowners as male-headed Aside from these contrasts, the largest
families. Female-headed families are also differences were obtained for the income
less likely to be homeowners than male- and race variables.4 The coefficient of the
headed families. Income and employment race dummy indicates that a Negro mover
are positively related to homeownership. has a probability of purchase .12 lower
Family size is negatively related to home- than an otherwise identical white. Only 8
ownership, but only after adjusting for the percent of Negro movers purchased homes;
different homeowning propensities of f am- had they been white 20 percent would
ilies with school-age children and with ad- have been home-buyers.
ditional workers. The probability of own- Previous levels of housing discrimina-
ership increases as the head of household tion may affect Negro households in at
gets older, and the introduction of a least one important way that is not re-
squared age term yields no evidence of flected in equation (2). Because of past dis-
any significant nonlinearity. crimination, Negro movers are less likely
3 The generalized least squares regression estimates
are obtained by weighting each observation by 4As with the ownership models, separate Negro and
[1/P(1 -P) ]i where P is the value of the probability white equations were estimated for the probability of
predicted by ordinary least squares. It can be shown purchase. Except for their intercepts they were identical,
that this procedure provides more efficient estimates of and a covariance test indicated no statistically different
a linear probability function. relationship.

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
266 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
ANDPURCHASE
TABLE1-MODELS OFHOMEOWNERSHIP
Equations (1), (2), and (3) for entire sample

Probability of Ownership Probability of Purchase Given Move

Equation (1) Equation (2) Equation (3)


Coef. t-Ratio Coef. t-Ratio Coef. t-Ratio

Race (1 = black, 0 = white) -0.088 -2.644 -0.124 -4.550 -0.091 -3.720


Income (thousands of dollars) 0.026 8.351 0.017 3.795 0.013 3.751
Years of education (head of house-
hold) -0.006 -1.190 0.011 2.414 0.003 0.759
Years of current job (head of
household) 0.002 1.908 0.001 0.624 0.002 1.365
Retired (1=yes, 0=no) 0.231 4.746 -0.070 -1.493 0.065 1.530
No household member employed
(1=yes, 0=no) -0.011 -0.277 -0.031 -0.868 -0.014 -0.362
More than one member employed
(1 =yes, 0=no) 0.171 6.130 -0.012 -0.438 0.002 0.102

Household Types
Single females under 45 years
(1 = yes, 0= no) -0.403 -5.596 -0.324 -3.665 -0.191 -2.075
Single females over 45 years -0.295 -5.278 -0.051 -0.569 -0.183 -2.033
Single males under 45 years -0.277 -2.577 -0.283 -2.864 -0.124 -1.170
Single males over 45 years -0.108 -1.207 -0.057 -0.539 -0.196 -1.799
Married couples under 45 years -0.213 -3.407 -0.290 -3.406 -0.095 -1.106
Married couples over 45 years -0.004 -0.070 -0.124 -1.385 -0.111 -1.159
Families
Age of head of household 0.002 2.108 0.004 2.212 0.011 2.527
(Age)2 of head of household -0.000 -2.621
Number of persons (natural
logarithm) -0.156 -3.769 -0.138 -3.342 -0 .113 -3.226
Number of school-age children -0.013 -0.986 0.032 2.626 0.018 1.518
Family headed by female under
45 years (1 = yes, 0= no) -0.007 -0. 148 -0.145 -3. 116 -0. 188 -3. 712
Family headed by female over
45 years (1 = yes, 0= no) -0. 192 -2.561 -0.241 -3.663 -0.206 -3.850
Prior Tenure
Prior owner (1= yes, 0= no) 0.267 4.323
Prior renter (1= yes, 0= no) 0.037 1.315
New household (1= yes, 0= no) -0. 146 -3.945
Intercept 0.409 5.747 0.126 1. 354 0.122 1.212
Degrees of freedom 1166 447 443
R2 0.826 0.301 0.445

than white movers to have been home- size and composition, age, and other mea-
owners in the past. This is important be- sured characteristics. Still, prior tenure
cause when homeowners change their resi- itself may have an independent influence
dence they are more likely to buy than to on subsequent tenure decisions. Therefore,
rent and, conversely, when renters move probability-of-purchase equations were es-
they are more likely to move from one timated with the addition of dummy vari-
rental property to another. ables for prior owner, prior renter, and
In large part the association between new households. A fourth category "prior
past and present, or present and future tenure unreported," is reflected in the in-
tenure arises because renters and owners tercept. Equation 3 in Table (1) illustrates
tend to differ in terms of income, family these estimates.

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KAIN AND QUIGLEY: HOUSING MARKET 267

Both the prior owner and new house- households stratified by the race and by the
hold variables have large and highly sig- years of education of the head of the house-
nificant coefficients. Previous ownership hold (see R. Ramanathan). Presumably,
raises the probability of purchase by .27. this averaging process reduces the transi-
New households are .15 less likely to buy tory component of income and thereby
than are established households of the provides an improved estimate of per-
same age, income, and family characteris- manent income. The ordinary least squares
tics. estimates of the race coefficient for all
Accounting for the effects of prior tenure three equations are consistently larger than
reduces the coefficient of the race variables. those obtained for the current income
Of course, the influence of housing market models as are the GLS estimates for the
discrimination is reflected in prior tenure. purchase model. The GLS estimate of the
In the sample of recent movers, only 2 per- race coefficient in the ownership equation
cent of Negro households had previously using the estimated permanent income is
been homeowners as compared to 17 per- more than twice as large as the race coef-
cent of white households. Yet, even after ficient obtained using annual income, and
controlling for the differences in prior ten- the GLS coefficients in the purchase
ure, Negro households are .09 less likely models using permanent income are also
to become homeowners than white house- larger than those obtained from the equa-
holds in today's "open housing" market.5 tions including annual income (see equa-
Several studies of the demand for hous- tion (1), Table 2).
ing services have concluded that housing An alternative and more dubious (both
expenditures are more strongly related to statistically and theoretically) test of the
permanent than to annual income. By ex- permanent income hypothesis used an es-
tension it might be anticipated that the timate of housing expenditures as a sur-
probabilities of homeownership and pur- rogate for permanent income.6 The most
chase would depend more on permanent obvious statistical problem arises because
than annual income. If this were true, all the estimate of housing expenditures for
or part of the measured difference in the homeowners must be imputed from hous-
probabilities of ownership and purchase ing value using a gross rent multiplier.
of white and nonwhite households in equa- The use of different variables (monthly
tions (1)-(3) might be attributable to un- rent for renters and market value for
measured white/nonwhite differences in owners) transformed by a constant divisor
permanent incomes. in a regression on owner/renter may pro-
As a test of the permanent income hy- duce a spurious correlation. The coef-
pothesis, we followed the convention sug- ficients of this housing expenditure vari-
gested by several authors and replaced able in the ownership and purchase equa-
the annual income term in equations (1)- tions vary between 20 and 45 times their
(3) by the mean incomes of the sample standard errors; this increases our sus-
picion that the relation is to a significant
I A similar difference in Negro-white probabilities of extent spurious and arises by construc-
home purchase was obtained by Daniel Fredland for tion.7
Philadelphia. Fredland's model differed in a number of
respects from equation (3) in Table 1. It included a some-
what different set of explanatory variables, was for 6 This technique was suggested by the anonymous

married households only, and was estimated by ordinary referee. We report it, in spite of strong statistical and
least squares. Even so, he obtained a coefficient of -.16 theoretical reservations.
for a minority dummy (nonwhite or Puerto Rican) and 7 The housing expenditure models reported in Table 2
a coefficient of .27 for the prior-owner dummy. use housing value . 100 as an estimate of homeowners'

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
268 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

TABLE 2-COEFFICIENTS AND t-RATIOS OF RACE VARIABLE FOR ALTERNATIVE


SPECIFICATIONS OF INCOME: OLS AND GLS

Probability of Purchase
Probability of without Prior with Prior
Ownership Tenure Tenure
Equation (1) Equation (2) Equation (3)
OLS GLS OLS GLS OLS GLS

Current Annual
Income -.150 -.088 -.154 -.124 -.114 -.091
(5.06) (2.64) (3.94) (4.55) (2.96) (3.72)

Permanent Income -. 163 -.194 -.199 -.223 -.138 - .103


(5.23) (6.33) (3.65) (4.73) (2.58) (2.69)

Housing
Expenditure -.048 -.035 - .077 -.048 -.069 -.029
(1.99) (2.33) (2.68) (2.76) (2.35) (1.63)

On theoretical grounds, moreover, there estimated. This bias is accentuated if


is reason to suspect that even an adequate housing market discrimination reduces
estimate of housing expenditures would Negro homeownership and if homeowners
not provide permanent income measures spend more for housing than renters of the
which are neutral between Negroes and same incomes for any reasons. Neverthe-
whites or between homeowners and less, the race coefficients obtained from
renters. If price discrimination exists in models using this estimate of housing ex-
the housing market, only a demand elas- penditure as an explanatory variable are
ticity of one for housing would prevent summarized in Table 2, which presents
housing expenditures from being a biased the race coefficients for all three alterna-
estimate of the permanent incomes of tive specifications. Also included in Table
black households. If housing demand is 2 are the coefficients of the racial dummy
price elastic for blacks (see Muth), price obtained by ordinary least squares.
discrimination would bias this measure In addition to the equations reported in
of permanent income downward for blacks Table 2, estimates were obtained employ-
and would reduce the race coefficient when ing several alternative specifications of the
the ownership and purchase equations are life cycle and age variables; tests for non-
linearity in the education and income
terms were also performed with negative
monthly expenditure (see Muth). This gross rent multi-
plier, as well as the 1-to-120 rule (see John Shelton),
results. For all these specifications, the
is widely used in housing market analysis to make magnitude and significance of the race co-
market value roughly commensurate with monthly rent. efficients for equations (1), (2), and (3)
In addition to the results reported, we estimated equa-
tions using gross rent multipliers of 1/185 and 1/164.
were virtually unchanged.8
These ratios were derived by regressing monthlv rent 8 As a further test of the influence of housing market
and value upon a detailed set of the individual charac- discrimination, separate Negro and white equations of
teristics of rental and owner-occupied units and thus the same form as equation (1) were estimated; a covari-
deriving estimates of the equivalent value of the average ance test indicated no statistically significant difference
rental unit (164 x rent) and the average rental fee for between them (F= 1.32). In addition separate models
the characteristics of owner-occupied units (value/ 185). for equation (1) were estimated for each of four house-
The race coefficients were indistinguishable from those hold types described above: single persons; couples;
presented. Details of the specification and implications female-headed families; and male-headed families. In
of these relationships may be found in Kain and Quigley each case, the coefficient of the race variable was highly
(1970a and 1970b). significant and varied in magnitude between -.13 and

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KAIN AND QUIGLEY: HOUSING MARKET 269

Taken together the estimates sum- Differences in the asset or wealth posi-
marized in Table 2 and the alternatives tions of Negro and white households may
mentioned strongly indicate that Negro account for part of the differences in white
households are substantially less likely to and nonwhite ownership and purchase
be homeowners or buyers than white probabilities. Unfortunately, the sample
households of similar characteristics. It used in this research shares the deficiency
does not "prove" that this is the result of of most other surveys in not including in-
discriminatory practices in urban housing formation on household assets and wealth.
markets; and there remain several com- Therefore, no direct test of the asset hy-
peting explanations for these results. These pothesis is possible using these data. How-
alternative hypotheses may be grouped ever, for several reasons, we doubt that
into three broad categories: 1) Differences much of the white-Negro differences in
in the "taste" for homeownership be- ownership and purchase are the result of
tween whites and blacks; 2) Differences in an unmeasured difference in wealth. All
the household asset and wealth positions three equations include income, years-on-
of white and black families; and 3) Racial job, and life cycle variables, which may
discrimination in the housing market as account for much of the white-black dif-
the result either of simple price discrim- ferences in assets. For most households,
ination in the owner and renter markets black and white, equity in owner-occupied
or of a more pervasive restriction on the housing is itself the largest component of
supply of owner-occupied housing avail- net worth.10 Therefore, in the probability
able to blacks. "Supply restrictions" of purchase model (equation (3)) prior ten-
could be supplemented or enforced by ure may account for much of the remaining
simple capital market discrimination or by differences in wealth. Down payment re-
an unwillingness on the part of banks and quirements are a major reason why assets
other mortgage lenders to finance home might be expected to affect the decision to
purchases by blacks outside the ghetto. purchase a home. However, FHA and VA
While it is most difficult to prove that down payment requirements, especially
the much lower probability of homeowner- for small single family homes purchased
ship of black households is not due to dif- more than ten years ago, were small or
ferences in the taste for homeownership, nonexistent.
many of the more commonly believed de- Housing market discrimination is the
terminants of the tastes of housing con- third, and to us, the most plausible hy-
sumers are included as independent vari- pothesis explaining the regression results
ables. Furthermore, stratification by race in Table 1. The exact mechanism is hard
for all of the three equations discloses no to specify. Differential price "markups" in
statistically significant differences. We the owner and rental submarkets do not
thus conclude that the "differences in
tastes" hypothesis is not an important ex-
extensive analysis of the mobility rates of the households
planation for the observed differences in in this sample indicates no important differences in the
market behavior between races.9 frequency of moves between white and Negro house-
holds after accounting for other socioeconomic factors.
-.16. When similar analyses were performed for the 10 For example, recent Survey of Economic Oppor-
probability of home purchase, the sample sizes became tunity tabulation indicates that for lower-middle income
uncomfortably small for some subgroups. ($5,000-$7,000 per annum) families, housing equity
9 Household expectations about moving frequency alone represents 40 percent of the net worth of white
may be the only important excluded taste variable. households and an even larger proportion of the net
(As will be discussed subsequently, mobility also affects worth of black households. See the Appendix for further
the economics of homeownership.) However, a fairly details.

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
270 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

explain these differences in Negro and II. Differences Among Metropolitan Areas
white purchase and homeownership prob- A complete test of the supply restriction
abilities.11 We are forced to conclude that hypothesis cannot be accomplished from
"supply restrictions" on Negro residential an analysis of a single metropolitan area.
choice and on the kinds of housing avail- A more powerful test of the effect of supply
able to black households may be largely restrictions can be obtained by analyzing
responsible for the wide discrepancy be- differences in black homeownership among
tween ownership rates for otherwise iden- cities. Metropolitan areas and their ghettos
tical black and white households. differ in terms of the characterisics of their
Further support for this position is housing stocks, and, therefore, in the ex-
provided by data on the average increase tent to which a limitation on being able to
in the market value of Negro- and white- reside outside the ghetto is an effective
owned single family units in St. Louis. For restriction on the supply of ownership-
this sample, the units owned by white type housing available to blacks. For ex-
central city residents have increased in ample, supply restrictions should be much
value at a compound annual rate of 5.2 less important in Los Angeles, where a
percent per year as contrasted to a 7.2 large portion of the ghetto housing supply
percent annual increase for the central consists of single family units, than in
city properties owned by Negro house- Chicago, where ghetto neighborhoods are
holds. If this is interpreted as a differ- predominantly multi-family. We analyzed
ence in the net appreciation of ghetto and the difference between "expected" and
nonghetto properties, the findings of equa- actual black ownership rates in several
tions (1)-(3) become even more difficult metropolitan areas. Expected black own-
to explain. Rather than a difference in the ership rates were computed by multiplying
net appreciation of black and white owned a matrix of white ownership rates (strati-
properties, however, this finding appears fied into income and family size groups) by
to be still another manifestation of limita- the income and family size distribution of
tions on Negro residential choice. White black households. Table 3 presents this
households wishing to improve their measure in 1960 for all eighteen metro-
housing can buy newer or larger houses in politan areas for which the necessary
better neighborhoods. Negro homeowners census data are published.'2 The difference
are much less able to improve their hous- between the actual black ownership rate
ing in this way; as a result we hypothesize and the expected black ownership rate for
that black homeowners spend more for each SMSA is identical in principle to the
renovation and repair than white house- difference in the probability of ownership
holds of similar characteristics. An an- attributed to race in equation (1) for St.
nual increase in suburban white-owned Louis in 1967. (For St. Louis this more
properties of 4.1 percent provides some primitive technique yields -21.0 in 1960
evidence for these inferences. as compared to an OLS estimate of - 15.0
11 Price markups were estimated for owner and renter
occupied structures using the St. Louis sample for three 12 These 18 SMSA's consisted of all those for which

alternative specifications (see Kain and Quigley the data on black and white ownership rates by income
(1970b)). Of the three specifications, two indicate a and family size classes were published. The expected
smaller percentage markup in the owner market. Even black ownership rate was obtained by applying the
if the markup were smaller for rental than for owner- ownership proportions for white households by income
occupied properties, it would require an extremely large and family size for each SMSA to the income and family
price-elasticity-of-choice to reduce the probability of size distribution of black households (see U.S. Bureau
black ownership by 10 percentage points. of the Census (1960a, Table B3)) and summing.

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KAIN AND QUIGLEY: HOUSING MARKET 271

and a GLS estimate from equation (1) of occupied housing or differences in the tim-
-8.8 in 1967.) ing of urban development. Equation (4)
As a test of the supply restriction hy- presents the regression in difference form
pothesis we then regressed these estimated (expected black ownership rate minus ac-
differences upon 1) the proportion of cen- tual black ownership rate), while equation
tral city dwelling units that are single (5) presents the same equation in ratio
family, a proxy for the proportion of the form (expected black ownership rate-
ghetto housing stock that is single family; actual black ownership rate). The t-ratios
2) the proportion of the SMSA black pop- are in parentheses under the coefficients.
ulation living in the central city, a mea-
sure of the extent of suburbanization of (4) (OB- OB) = 0.24 + 0.820w
the black population; and 3) the actual (2.36) (4.64)
- 0.36SC+ 0.12B,
TABLE 3-ACTUAL AND EXPECTED OWNERSHIP
RATES OF NEGRO HOUSEHOLDS BY (6.49) (2.03)
METROPOLITAN AREA
RI = .76
City Actual Expected
(5) (OB/OB) = 0.89 + 1.520W
Atlanta .31 .52
Boston .21 .43 (1.52) (1.47)
Chicago .18 .47
Cleveland .30 .58 - 1.74SC+ 0.90Bc
Dallas .39 .54 (5.34) (2.52)
Detroit .41 .67
Los Angeles/Long Beach .41 .51 R2 = .74
Newark .24 .50
Philadelphia .45 .66 where,
St. Louis .34 .55
Baltimore .36 .61
O* =Expected black ownership rate in
Birmingham .44 .56 the ith SMSA
Houston .46 .56
Indianapolis .45 .58
Memphis .37 .50 [Eawki*Hbki] / Hbki
New Orleans .28 .40
Pittsburgh .35 .59
San Francisco/Oakland .37 .51 OB2= Actual black ownership rate in the
ith SMSA

rate of white ownership in the SMSA.'3


The first two variables measure the extent [E tbki*Hbk/ i Hbki

of the supply restrictions among the eigh-


teen metropolitan areas, while the latter Owi= Actual white ownership rate in the
measures any differences in the level of ith SMSA
both white and Negro homeownership
that might be attributable to such factors Hwk i] Hwk i
[ Etwki
as intermetropolitan variation in the rela-
tive cost of owner-occupied and renter-
and
13 The percent of single family housing in the central wki-= Proportion of whites in the kth
city for SMSA was obtained from U.S. Bureau of the income/family size category who
Census (1960a, Table B-7). The percent of SMSA blacks
residing in the central citv was obtained from U.S. are homeowners in the ith SMSA
Bureau of the Census (1960b, Table 13). Hbki= Number of black households in

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
272 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

the kth income/family size cate- occupied units. As the statistics in Table 3
gory in the ith SMSA show, the difference between the actual
S,= Proportion of central city housing and expected homeownership rate of
that is single family (Number of black households is relatively small for
central city dwelling units that cities like Houston and Los Angeles, where
are single family *.total central the central city and its black ghetto in-
city dwelling units) clude more single-family housing, and is
Bc= Proportion of metropolitan Negro relatively large for cities like Chicago,
households residing in central city where the ghetto is predominantely multi-
(Number of Negro households in family and where blacks are effectively
central city *.number of Negro excluded from the suburbs.
households in SMSA). The extent of black suburbanization
also appears to have a significant, though
The means and standard deviations of
small, influence on the gap between actual
the variables used in equations (4) and (5)
and expected black homeownership. In all
are shown in Table 4. The average ex-
U.S. metropolitan areas, black households
are heavily concentrated in the central
TABLE 4-MEANS AND STANDARD DEVIATIONS OF
VARIABLES USED IN INTER-CITY REGRESSION
cities. The mean proportion of blacks re-
siding in the central city for the sample
Mean SD metropolitan areas is .78 and the standard
deviation is only .14. Equation (4) in-
OB-OB 0.19 0.06
0.36
dicates that a city which is one standard
OB/OB 1.61
OW 0.65 0.07 deviation above the mean in terms of this
OB 0.35 0.08 characteristic (92 percent of metropolitan
OB ?0.54 0.07
0.55 0.22
area blacks live in the central city) would
SI
BC 0.78 0.14 have a gap .034 larger than one which is
one standard deviation below the mean
(64 percent of blacks live in the central
pected homeownership rate for black city).
households is .54 and the mean actual The findings presented in equations (4)
black ownership rate is .35. The actual and (5) provide further support for the
white rate for these eighteen metropolitan view that housing market discrimination
areas in 1960 averages .65. Of the .30 dif- limits Negro homeownership.14 Specifi-
ference between actual white and black cally, these results indicate that a limited
ownership rates in these eighteen metro- supply of housing suitable for homeowner-
politan areas Negro-white differences in ship in the ghetto and restrictions on
family size and income account for .11; the Negro purchase outside the ghetto strongly
residual difference, .19, must be attributed affect the tenure-type of the housing con-
to other factors, including the differences sumed by Negro households as well as its
in supply restrictions among the areas. location.
Both equations strongly support the hy-
pothesis that the differences between ob- III. Homeownership, Housing Costs,
and Capital Accumulation
served and expected black ownership
rates are small: 1) when the ghetto hous- Limitations on homeownership have
ing supply includes a larger proportion of significant effects on Negro housing costs,
single-family units; 2) when blacks have
14At the minimum, it would take a peculiar spatial
more access to the suburban housing distribution of tastes for homeownership or of asset dif-
market, with its preponderance of owner- ferences to explain these findings.

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KAIN AND QUIGLEY: HOUSING MARKET 273

income, and welfare. As is illustrated in purchased with a twenty-year mortgage


the Appendix, an effective limitation on by a thirty-year old household head, the
homeownership can increase Negro hous- owner of this unit would have saved more
ing costs by over 30 percent, assuming no than $7,000 and would own his home free
price appreciation. and clear by his fiftieth birthday. Thus, if
Much of the savings from homeowner- his home neither appreciated or depre-
ship results from favorable treatment ac- ciated, at age fifty he would own assets
corded homeowners under the federal in- worth at least $8,000. However, the post-
come tax. These tax provisions favoring war years have hardly been characterized
homeowners are widely recognized and by price neutrality. Although difficult to
well documented (see Henry Aaron and estimate, the average appreciation of
Shelton). Our findings suggest that Negro single-family houses during the past
households at all income levels are im- twenty years most certainly exceeded the
peded by housing market discrimination 100 percent increase in the Boeck com-
from purchasing and owning single family posite cost index for small residential
homes. As a consequence, Negro house- structures (see U.S. Federal Housing Ad-
holds are prevented from taking full ad- ministration)." This conservative 100 per-
vantage of these tax benefits. Since tax cent increase in value would mean that the
savings from homeownership increase with typical FHA-financed homeowner by age
income, this aspect of discriminatory fifty would have accumulated assets worth
housing markets cuts most sharply against at least $16,000, a considerable sum that
middle and upper income black house- he could use to reduce his housing costs,
holds. to borrow against for the college education
Limitations on homeownership also rob of his children, or simply to hold for his
Negro households of an important infla- retirement. Perspective on this hypo-
tion hedge available to other low and thetical example is obtained when it is
middle income households. Calculations recognized that the mean wealth accumu-
presented in the Appendix show that under lation of white households in 1966 was
reasonable assumptions about the appre- only $20,000 (see Henry Terrell). Of
ciation of single family homes, a Negro course, the situation would have been dif-
household prevented from buying a home ferent if the postwar period had been one
since 1950 would have out-of-pocket hous- of a general decline in the price of urban
ing costs in 1970 more than twice as high real estate. But it was not.
as the costs which would have been in- Homeownership is clearly the most im-
curred if the family could have purchased portant method of wealth accumulation
a home twenty years earlier. used by low- and middle-income families
Negro households at every income level in the postwar period. Equities in single-
have less wealth than white households. family, owner-occupied structures account
Current and historical limitations on for nearly one-half of all the wealth of the
homeownership may be an important lowest income group. As family income in-
reason. The importance of this method of creases, the relative importance of home
capital accumulation among low and mid- equities decreases. Still, home equities ac-
dle income households is apparent from a counted for more than one-third of the
typical example. The average house pur- wealth of all U.S. households earning be-
chased with an FHA 203 mortgage in 1949
had a value of $8,286 and a mortgage of
15 Our sample suggests an annual rate of increase in
$7,101 (see U.S. Federal Housing Admin- value of white-owned properties of 4.7 percent during
istration). Assuming that this house was the 5-10 year period prior to 1966.

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
274 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

tween $10-15,000 in 1962 (see D. S. Pro- tion in urban housing markets has reduced
jector et al.). Negro opportunities for homeownership,
The dominant position of home equities this limitation is an important explanation
in the asset portfolios of low and middle of the smaller quantity of assets owned by
income households is not difficult to under- Negro households at each income level.
stand. Other forms of investment, such as
the stock market, require far more knowl- APPENDIX

edge, sophistication and discipline. In ad- Owning and Saving vs.


dition, low- and middle-income households Renting and Consuming
have more leverage available in the real In an analysis of the relative costs of own-
estate than in other investment markets. ing and renting a home, Shelton concludes
Much of the savings imbedded in home that owning is usually cheaper than renting,
ownership, especially among low- and as long as the household expects to live at
middle-income households, is more or less the same location for more than three and
involuntary or at least unconscious. Dis- one half years. The three and one-half year
cipline is maintained by linking the invest- cut-off is obtained by dividing a 2 percent
ment (saving) decision to monthly pay- per year annual savings into a nonrecurring
transfer cost for owner-occupied units of
ments for the provision of a necessity, with
about 7 percent of their value.
heavy penalties (foreclosure) imposed for The nonrecurring transfer cost consists of
failure to invest regularly."6 Moreover, be- realtor commissions plus an allowance for
cause of federal mortgage insurance and certain fixed costs. The annual savings from
special advantages provided to thrift in- homeownership include tax differences,
stitutions, the low- and middle-income management costs, vacancy allowances, and
home buyer is able to borrow 90 percent or savings in annual maintenance expenditures
more of the purchase price of a new home. for homeowners (who are able to maintain
This may amount to $15,000 or more of the same level of quality for about one-half
capital at moderate interest rates. By com- percent of market value less per year). For
homeowners, the total annual housing costs
parison, in the stock market he can borrow
include: maintenance, obsolescence, property
30 percent, a ratio which he must main-
taxes, interest on mortgage, opportunity cost
tain even with price declines. of money plus (discounted) transfer cost. For
If, as our findings suggest, discrimina- renters, annual rent equals landlord costs
16 As long ago as 1953, James Duesenberry argued
plus return on investment: maintenance,
persuasively that levels of savings and asset accumula- obsolescence, property taxes, vacancy allow-
tion are heavily dependent upon the form in which ance, management, interest on mortgage,
savings is maintained. Citing specifically the high pro- plus return on investment.
portion of savings invested in assets associated with the Much of the savings from homeownership
reason for saving (e.g., housing equity, pension and in-
surance reserves, and investment in unincorporated
results from favorable tax provisions, i.e.,
businesses), he suggests a close connection between the from the ability to deduct interest payments
motives for saving and the form which the saving takes. and property taxes and especially from the
Thus, although we cannot deduce that because people absence of any tax on imputed rent. There-
invested in some particular asset, they would not have fore, the magnitude of the savings in monthly
saved if that type of asset had not been available, there
appears to be a strong association. housing costs varies somewhat according to
If Duesenberry's insight is valid, then even if capital family circumstances, the size of the mort-
markets were perfect in every sense of the word, we gage and the amount amortized, and the
would expect to find substantially fewer assets for house- assumed opportunity costs of the family's
holds denied certain forms of saving (i.e., those forms
associated with the reason for saving) such as home
equity.
ownership, pension and insurance investment, and unin- Shelton develops an example which sug-
corporated business investment. gests the magnitude of the yearly savings in

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KAIN AND QUIGLEY: HOUSING MARKET 275

housing costs obtained through ownership. (as contrasted with a before tax return of 4
This example assumes that a family may percent on other assets). However, Aaron
choose to buy its dwelling for $20,000 or to implicitly assumes that the real price of
rent it for $167 per month. (This represents owner- and renter-occupied housing is the
a gross rent of $2,000 per year, based on a same. Shelton, in contrast, contends that
widely used gross rent/value ratio). To pur- there is an equilibrium price difference, ex-
chase the unit, the prospective homeowner cluding tax differences, favoring owner-
invests $4,000 as a down payment on the occupied housing by 1.4 percent of value. If
house and assumes a 6 percent mortgage. Shelton's analysis of the comparative costs
As compared to the $2,000 yearly rental of homeownership and renting is correct in
costs, Shelton estimates that purchase would this respect, the savings to homeownership
mean yearly expenses before taxes of $1,590. based on Aaron's example would amount to
Property tax and interest payments create 28 percent of monthly rent computed as
tax shields that reduce the true costs of these [$342+.014 ($25,000 in housing value)]
two items by an amount which depends on ($2,500 annual rent).
the homeowner's tax bracket. He concludes The substantial divergence in housing
that a conservative estimate of the tax sav- costs noted above is in addition to any dis-
ings created by homeownership would be criminatory pricing which may exist. More-
$200, yielding yearly after tax costs of owner- over, it must still be regarded as a lower
ship of $1,390. This represents a saving of bound estimate of the economic cost of an
$610 or a 15.2 percent return (after taxes) effective limitation on homeownership during
on the $4,000 invested in homeownership, as the postwar period, since it fails to incor-
compared to an assumed stock market return porate the effects of inflation on housing costs
of 9 percent before taxes. Since stock market and does not admit to the special position of
earnings are taxable, the comparable before homeownership in the savings behavior and
tax return on homeownership is 18 percent. capital accumulation of low- and middle-in-
The relative return on a homeownership come households.
investment declines as the mortgage is A spending unit's equity in its home can
amortized. The investment return is larger, be divided into three components: the initial
however, if down payments are smaller or if equity or down payment, the amortization
the opportunity cost of equity capital is of the mortgage (savings), and any apprecia-
lower. Thus, 18 percent is likely to be a low tion or depreciation of the property as a
estimate. result of general or particular price changes
The savings from homeownership can also (capital gains or losses). The last two items
be expressed as a percentage of the costs of form the important link between homeown-
renting. From this viewpoint a limitation ership and capital accumulation.
on homeownership would increase housing Although it is technically correct to view
costs beyond three and a half years by 30 an increase in the value of an owned home as
percent, assuming no price appreciation an increase in the household's wealth and to
($610 savings . $2,000 annual rent). As with consider the opportunity cost of the equity
the rate of return analysis, the savings are capital as part of the spending unit's monthly
larger if a smaller down payment or a lower housing costs, there are indications that
opportunity cost of capital is assumed. many households do not view the matter in
Aaron obtains even larger estimates of the precisely this way. Out-of-pocket costs ap-
tax subsidv to homeowners. He presents an pear to be more important considerations for
example, similar to the one just discussed many low- and middle-income families, and
but with a more valuable house ($25,000) it seems many view the savings in the home
and a larger equity ($10,000), which yields a as a bonus to homeownership. Thus, it is of
$342 tax saving (as contrasted to the $200 more than passing interest to compare the
saving computed by Shelton) and an after current out-of-pocket costs of a St. Louis
tax return on a $10,000 equity of 7.4 percent family who purchased an $8,000 FHA or VA

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
276 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

home on a twenty-year mortgage in 1949 homeownership over several generations may


with an otherwise identical family who be an important part of the explanation of
rented throughout the entire period. the smaller quantity of assets owned by
Assuming a conservative capital apprecia- Negro households at each income level.
tion of 100 percent over the twenty-year pe-
riod, the value of this house in 1969 would be REFERENCES
$16,000. Since the mortgage has been paid H. Aaron, "Income Taxes and Housing,"
off, the homeowner has only insurance, real Amer. Econ. Rev., Dec. 1970, 60, 789-806.
estate taxes, heating and utilities, and main- M. J. Bailey, "Note on the Economics of Resi-
tenance and repairs as out-of-pocket costs. dential Zoning and Urban Renewal," Land
These would total roughtly $64 per month Econ., Aug. 1959, 33, 288-92.
for a St. Louis home of this value in 1969.'7 , "Effects of Race and Other Demo-
By comparison, a renter would have to pay graphic Factors on the Values of Single-
somewhat more than twice this amount Family Homes," Land Econ., May 1966,
($133-160 per month) to rent a dwelling unit 40, 215-20.
of this value."8 G. S. Becker, The Economics of Discrimina-
The preceding comparisons may help to tion, Chicago 1957.
explain the recent findings of the Survey of M. H. David, Family Composition and Con-
Economic Opportunity which indicate that at sumption, Amsterdam 1962.
every level of current income, black families J. S. Duesenberry, "The Determinants of Sav-
have fewer assets than whites, but that hous- ings Behavior: A Summary," in W. W.
ing equity represents a larger proportion of Heller, F. M. Boddy, and C. L. Nelson, eds.,
the net worth of black households than of Savings in the Modern Economy, Minneap-
white households."9 In fact, limitations on olis 1953.
B. Duncan and P. Hauser, Housing a Metrop-
17 The $64 per month out-of-pocket costs is based on

estimated homeownership costs for existing (used) FHA


olis Chicago, Glencoe 1960.
insured homes in St. Louis in 1967. These totaled $58.02 D. Fredland, "Residential Mobility and
for the median home in 1967 (valued at the difference
in median value $14,597 vs. $16,000) plus increases in are less likely to be homeowners, housing equity repre-
costs between 1967 and 1969. If the homeowner still sents 67 percent of this smaller Negro net worth as com-
itemizes his tax return (less likely without interest pared to 40 percent of that of white families.
payments), he can deduct $26 per month of these ex- Although the mean housing equity of Negro home-
penses. This would produce tax savings of between $5 owners is smaller than that of white homeowners, $7,344
and $10 per month depending on his tax bracket. These vs. $11,753, the difference in Negro net worth is not to
expense data were obtained from U.S. Federal Housing any significant degree attributable to this difference.
Administration. Rather, it results from the fact that at each income level
18 The $133 ($160) per month rent is again based on a smaller proportion of Negroes than whites are home-
the same widely used rent to value ratio 1 to 120 (1 to owners and even more imTortantly from the fact that
100). There is reason to believe the above calculations the discrepancy in Negro and white ownership of other
understate the extent of asset accumulation by the assets is even larger than the discrepancy in homeowner-
average homeowner. Many homeowners increase the ship. Thus, if the Survey of Economic Opportunity data
value of their structures by improvements and addi- on assets are to be believed, Negroes in the income class
tions. These outlavs, of course, represent further savings $5,000-$7,499 have net worth in nonhousing assets
and capital accumulation. Others trade up by using equal to only 16 percent of that of white households in
their accumulated equity as a down pavment on a the same income level, and all Negroes have net worth
larger or better quality house, thus maintaining an even in nonhousing assets equal to only 9 percent of that of
higher savings rate. all whites. Of course, these results can be considered as
19 Recent tabulations from the Survey of Economic suggestive only. The weaknesses of savings and wealth
Opportunity on the asset and liability position of Negro data are notorious, and the interpretation of these dif-
and white families by income group show that home ferences, if real, would require a complete theory of
equities account for an even greater share of Negro than Negro and white savings behavior, which encompasses
white wealth. For example, these data indicate that the manner in which discrimination or lack of oppor-
white families with incomes between $5,000 and $7,499 tunity in the various markets affects the savings be-
have a net worth of $12,556 as compared with a net havior of Negro households. The authors wish to thank
worth of $3,636 for Negro families in the same income Andrew Brimmer and Henry S. Terrell for making these
class. Despite the fact that Negroes at each income level unpublished tabulations available to them.

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KAIN AND QUIGLEY: HOUSING MARKET 277

Choiceof Tenure,"unpublisheddoctoraldis- Family Finances," Federal Reserve Tech.


sertation, Harvard Univ. 1970. Paper, Washington 1968.
R. A. Haugen and A. J. Heins, "A Market C. Rapkin, "Price Discrimination Against Ne-
Separation Theory of Rent Differentials in groes in the Rental Housing Market," in
Metropolitan Areas," Quart. J. Econ., Nov. Essays in Urban Land Economics, Los
1969, 83, 660-72. Angeles 1966, pp. 333-45.
J. L. Hecht, Because It's Right: Integration in and W. Grigsby, The Demand for
Housing, Boston 1970. Housing in Racially Mixed Areas, Berkeley
J. F. Kain, "The Commuting and Residential 1960.
Decisions of Central Business District R. Ramanathan, "Measuring the Permanent
Workers," in Transportation Economics, Income of a Household: An Experiment in
Universities-Nat. Bur. Econ. Res. confer- Methodology," J. Polit. Econ., Jan. 1971,
ence series, New York 1965, pp. 245-74. 79, 177-85.
",Effect of Housing Market Segrega- M. G. Reid, Housing and Income, Chicago
tion on Urban Development," Savings and 1962.
Residential Financing, 1969 Conference R. G. Ridker and J. A. Henning, "The De-
Proceedings, Chicago 1969, pp. 88-113. terminants of Residential Property Values
and J. M. Quigley, (1970a) "Eval- with Special Reference to Air Pollution,"
uating the Quality of the Residential En- Rev. Econ. Statist., May 1967, 49, 246-57.
vironment," Environment & Planning, Jan. J. P. Shelton, "The Cost of Renting Versus
1970, 2, 23-32. Owning a Home," Land Econ., Feb. 1968,
and , (1970b) "Measuring the 42, 59-72.
Value of Housing Quality," J. Amer. Statist. M. Stengel, "Price Discrimination in the Ur-
Ass., June 1970, 65, 532-48. ban Rental Housing Market," unpublished
J. B. Lansing and L. Kish, "Family Life Cycle doctoral dissertation, Harvard Univ., May
as an Independent Variable," Amer. Soc. 1970.
Rev., 1957, 22, 512-19. K. and A. Taeuber, Negroes in Cities, Chicago
, - ',and J. N. Morgan, "Con- 1965.
sumer Finances over the Life Cycle," in L. H. S. Terrell, "Wealth Accumulationof Black
Clark, ed., Consumer Behavior: The Life and White Families: The Empirical Evi-
Cycle and Consumer Behavior, 2, New dence," paper presented before a joint ses-
York 1955, pp. 36-52. sion of the Amer. Econ. Assoc. and the
D. McEntire, Residence and Race, Berkeley Amer. Fin. Assoc., Detroit, Michigan, Dec.
1960. 28, 1970, mimeo.
S. J. Maisel, "Rates of Ownership, Mobility, Survey Research Center, Institute for Social
and Purchase," in Essays in Urban Land Research, Univ. Michigan, 1960 Survey of
Economics, Los Angeles 1966, pp. 76-108. Consumer Finances, Ann Arbor 1961.
J. N. Morgan, "Factors Related to Consumer U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Ab-
Savings When it is Defined as a Net-Worth stract of the United States: 1967, 88th ed.,
Concept," in L. R. Klein, ed., Contributions Washington 1967.
of Survey Methods to Economics, New - U.S. Census of Housing: 1960, vol.
York 1954. II, MetropolitanHousing, Washington 1963.
R. F. Muth, Cities and Housing: The Spatial , U.S. Census of Population: 1960, vol.
Pattern of Urban Residential Land Use, I., Characteristics of Population, Washing-
Chicago 1969. ton 1963.
A. H. Pascal, The Analysis of Residential U.S. Federal Housing Administration, FHA
Segregation, The RAND Corporation, P- Homes, 1967; Data for States and Selected
4234, Oct. 1969. Areas on Characteristicsof FHA Operations
D. S. Projector et al, "Survey of Changes in under Section 203, Washington 1967.

This content downloaded from 62.122.73.34 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 05:14:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like