You are on page 1of 14

World Development 106 (2018) 173–186

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

World Development
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

The impact of intergovernmental transfers on local revenue generation


in Sub-Saharan Africa: Evidence from Tanzania
Takaaki Masaki
Social, Urban, Rural and Resilience Global Practice, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, MC 10-758, Washington, DC 20433, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Do intergovernmental transfers reduce revenues collected by local government authorities (LGAs)? There
Accepted 29 January 2018 is already a well-established body of literature in public finance, which argues that intergovernmental
Available online 24 February 2018 grants ‘‘crowd out” local revenues. Most existing studies, however, explore the fiscal implications of
intergovernmental transfers in high-income countries where sound fiscal systems are taken for granted.
JEL classification: In this paper, I explore the impact of intergovernmental transfers on local revenues in sub-Saharan Africa,
H29 a region where local fiscal capacity is limited and endogenously determined by financial support from
H41
international donors and the central government. I argue that in places where the existing capacity of
H71
H79
LGAs to administer tax collection is weak and political costs of enforcing taxation are low—which are
perennial features of many rural districts in Africa—intergovernmental transfers facilitate local revenue
Keywords: generation instead of undermining it. Analyzing newly available quarterly fiscal data on local revenues
Fiscal capacity in Tanzania, I show that intergovernmental grants improve the mobilization of local revenues, and also
Intergovernmental grants that the positive effect of fiscal transfers on local revenue collection seems to be more pronounced in
Sub-Saharan Africa rural districts.
Tanzania
Ó 2018 The Author(s). Published by Elsevier Ltd. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND
Taxation
license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).

1. Introduction public finance suggesting that intergovernmental transfers crowd


out local revenues, whereby the inflow of external transfers can
The power to tax lies at the heart of state development. A moment’s sap the incentive for LGAs to collect their own dues (Buettner &
reflection on the history of today’s developed countries and the Wildasin, 2006; Bradford & Oates, 1971a, 1971b; Zhuravskaya,
current situation of today’s developing nations suggests that the 2000).
acquisition of that power cannot be taken for granted. Empirical evidence for the hypothesized negative linkage
[Besley and Persson, 2013, p. 51] between intergovernmental grants and local revenues mainly
derives from studies in countries where sound fiscal institutions
Since the early 1990s, many African countries have experi-
are already in place. In most African countries, the administrative
mented with decentralization, or the devolution of fiscal and
and institutional capacity of local governments to collect taxes
administrative duties to local government authorities (LGAs)
and provide public goods is very limited, particularly in rural areas
(Dafflon & Madies, 2013). As part of this decentralization process,
where geographical vastness, poverty, and low population density
LGAs have increasingly assumed the role of raising own revenues
all make it extremely difficult for LGAs to collect taxes (Fjeldstad
to finance their budgets and providing basic public services to their
et al., 2014). The generation of local revenues requires robust mon-
citizens. Most subnational governments in Africa, however, lack
itoring and enforcement systems and qualified staff, who are costly
institutional capacity to collect local taxes and instead rely heavily
to employ and maintain (Besley & Persson, 2013). Furthermore, fis-
on grants from the central government to keep themselves afloat
cal policy is highly centralized and politicized such that political
(Shah, 2006). Critics argue that while financial transfers from the
interference with local revenue collection is prevalent in the Afri-
central government help finance the provision of public service
can context (Fjeldstad, 2001; Kasara, 2007; Lambright, 2014;
delivery, they can also obviate the need for local revenue genera-
PMORALG, 2013).
tion, which in turn undermines the fiscal autonomy of subnational
A central argument of this paper is that when the existing fiscal
governments. There is a well-established body of literature in
capacity of local governments is weak and the political costs of
enforcing revenue collection are low—which are perennial features
E-mail address: tmasaki@worldbank.org

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.01.026
0305-750X/Ó 2018 The Author(s). Published by Elsevier Ltd.
This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).
174 T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186

of rural districts in Africa—intergovernmental transfers facilitate governments. This study shows that the relationship between trans-
local revenue generation. I posit that not only can fiscal transfers fers and local revenues defies this prediction in the context where
help rural LGAs to finance revenue collection efforts and broaden the existing fiscal capacity is low or almost non-existent, like in
the tax base, they can also facilitate the provision of public goods, many rural areas in Africa.
which in turn improves voluntary tax compliance. In urban areas, This paper is organized in the following manner. In the next sec-
on the other hand, the marginal positive effect of central govern- tion (Section 2), I review the existing literature on the fiscal impli-
ment grants on local revenue generation is lower due to the exis- cations of intergovernmental transfers. In particular, I highlight
tence of (relatively) robust fiscal institutions and higher political how the existing models in public finance fail to capture the issues
costs associated with increasing a tax burden on urban taxpayers of fiscal capacity, an essential asset that local governments need to
who already feel overly taxed compared to rural residents mobilize local revenues. Section 3 describes the data used in my
(Resnick, 2012). empirical evaluation of the causal link between transfers and local
Tanzania is an ideal country to study the link between intergov- revenue generation in Tanzania. Section 4 presents the main find-
ernmental grants and local revenues in the African context for a ings of my econometric analysis. Section 5 concludes by discussing
number of reasons. First, intergovernmental transfers make up a the policy implications of this study’s core findings.
large proportion of local government budgets in Tanzania like
many other countries in the region. In FY2012/2013, for instance, 2. Theory
91% of the local budget was financed through transfers from the
central government. This number lies on a par with corresponding 2.1. Intergovernmental transfers and local revenue generation
numbers from other African countries, such as Lesotho (90%),
Uganda (88%), and Ghana (69%), which makes Tanzania more or For the past two decades, African governments and interna-
less a representative case in the region (Fjeldstad & Heggstad, tional donors alike have encouraged decentralization as a means
2012, p. 5). Furthermore, as reported by the International Mone- to promote development.2 Many of the key responsibilities previ-
tary Fund (IMF), ‘‘Tanzania is now considered to have one of the ously vested in the central government have been discharged to local
best PFM [public financial management] systems in sub-Saharan governments, which now play the leading role in public service
Africa” (Nord et al., 2009, p. 5). Most district councils in Tanzania delivery. These decentralization efforts have been motivated partly
now have computerized budget and accounting systems, and the by the idea that LGAs are more responsive to local needs than the
Prime Minister’s Office Regional Administration and Local Govern- central government because they stay in close touch with their
ment (PMORALG) has published quarterly fiscal data on district- own constituencies, although empirical support for this line of logic
level expenditure and revenues online, which allows researchers has been mixed at best (e.g., Brollo, Nannicini, Perotti, & Tabellini,
to empirically test the linkage between intergovernmental trans- 2013; Olken, 2007; Reinikka & Svensson, 2005; Crook, 2003;
fers and local revenues. Tendler, 1997).
One of the issues that complicates the identification of causal Critics argue that intergovernmental transfers erode local fiscal
impact of intergovernmental transfers on local revenues is that autonomy because they can serve as substitutes for local tax rev-
the amount of central government grants that a given district enues (e.g., Bradford & Oates, 1971a, 1971b; Buettner & Wildasin,
receives is likely to be endogenous to the district’s fiscal capacity. 2006; Mogues & Benin, 2012; Zhuravskaya, 2000). Bradford and
To alleviate this concern, I employ the instrumental variable (IV) Oates (1971a, 1971b) offer a formal theory of how grants may
estimation, utilizing exogenous variation in precipitation as instru- affect fiscal performance at the local level. Under the assumption
ments for intergovernmental transfers. Precipitation serves as a that public and private incomes are fungible, they claim that
valid instrument for intergovernmental transfers because the allo- unconditional intergovernmental grants free up extra resources
cation of transfers is determined partly based on agricultural pro- for local governments to benefit individual citizens in the form of
ductivity, which is exogenously determined by precipitation. a lump-sum tax reduction, thus crowding out efforts to mobilize
Although rainfall is likely to directly affect local revenues by local revenues.
changing the amount of agricultural taxes being collected at the Empirical evidence for the crowding-out effects of central gov-
local level, it should have no such direct effect once those agricul- ernment grants has been far from conclusive. Analyzing fiscal data
tural revenues are excluded from my analysis. PMORALG’s new fis- of individual municipalities across the U.S. for the period between
cal data—which are highly granular and can be disaggregated by 1972 and 1997, Buettner and Wildasin (2006) find that increases in
type of revenues—allow me to actually remove agricultural taxes central government grants do indeed lead to reductions in locally
from total revenues, which can then be used as the dependent vari- raised revenues. Zhuravskaya (2000, p. 338) finds a similar pattern
able in my IV estimation. in Russia, showing that ‘‘any change in a local government’s own
My empirical analysis shows strong evidence that intergovern- revenues is almost entirely offset by an opposite change in shared
mental transfers help expand local revenues, and that this positive revenues,” indicating that intergovernmental transfers serve as
effect of transfers on local revenues is more pronounced in rural almost perfect substitutes for local revenues. In contrast, a number
areas. These findings are important on their own right and have of other studies demonstrate that intergovernmental transfers
broader implications for state building and fiscal capacity in Africa. tend to be used for public spending instead of tax reliefs—a phe-
State-building entails efforts on the part of the state to generate its nomenon known as ‘‘flypaper effects” (see Rosen, 2005; Hines &
own revenues from its citizens. Governmental accountability Thaler, 1995). For instance, Dahlberg, Mork, Rattso, and Agren
derives from a social contract between the state and taxpayers, (2008) study fiscal data in Sweden and find that transfers from
whereby the former is held accountable by the latter for its perfor- the central government do not reduce local tax revenues, but
mance.1 The same story can be told for local governments, which instead increase local spending. Furthermore, recent studies (e.g.,
have become the key provider of public services in Africa. The con- Brun & Khdari, 2016; Caldeira & Rota-Graziosi, 2014; Zhang,
ventional wisdom in public finance suggests that reliance on exter- 2013; Skidmore, 1999) find ‘‘crowding-in” effects of intergovern-
nal grants may undermine the fiscal autonomy of local mental transfers, whereby grants expand local tax revenues. In

1 2
See, for instance, Tripp (2013); Atunbas and Thornton (2012), Gadenne (2012), The World Bank, for instance, has embraced decentralization as a key element of
Fjeldstad et al. (2010), Lund (2007), Iversen, Fjeldstad, Bahiigwa, Ellis, and James its developmental strategy since the late 1990s and funded projects that promote
(2006), Moss and van de Walle (2006), and Hoffman and Gibson (2005). various aspects of the decentralization process (IEG, 2008).
T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186 175

short, the literature has not reached any consensus on the relation- local public services undermines tax compliance (e.g., Ali et al.,
ship between transfers and local revenues. 2013; Bodea & LeBas, 2016; Fjeldstad & Semboja, 2001; Kjaer, 2005).
Third, fiscal transfers pay for the direct costs of tax enforce-
ment. One of the key roles that intergovernmental grants play is
2.2. Low fiscal capacity and the politicization of local taxation in Africa to finance the administrative and operational costs of LGAs
(Fjeldstad et al., 2010; Troland, 2014). Indeed, a large share of
Most African countries in some way or another have embarked intergovernmental transfers goes to personal emolument and
on the process of fiscal decentralization after years of economic recurrent spending: that is, the payment of salaries and other ben-
stagnation and crisis in the 1980s. One of the key issues in applying efits for civil servants and other administrative costs, which also
the existing theories of public finance to Africa is that they often include the costs of hiring qualified staff and experts to administer
treat fiscal capacity as given (or exogenously determined). Fiscal revenue collection (Nyange, Tschirley, Nassoro, & Gaspar, 2014, p.
capacity is defined as the extractive capacity of a government to 10). Furthermore, in many African countries, some transfers are
raise tax revenues ‘‘given the structure of the tax system and its specifically earmarked for the capacity building of fiscal manage-
available powers of enforcement” (Besley & Persson, 2013, p. 52). ment and tax administration (Cochran et al., 2009). In short, given
As Bahl (2000) highlights, local governments in low-income coun- that most LGAs lack sound fiscal institutions, they often rely on
tries tend to suffer from the lack of fiscal capacity. Consequently, external transfers to fulfill their revenue collection responsibilities.
they are much more dependent on central governmental grants LGAs’ efforts to raise local revenues, however, are constrained
to finance their budgets than subnational governments in high- by the political costs of enforcing revenue collection. The enforce-
income countries (Bahl, 2000, p. 2). Africa has performed particu- ment of local taxation is often at odds with the political interests of
larly poorly compared to the rest of the world in terms of the level elected public officials who seek to minimize a tax burden on their
of local revenue generation.3 constituencies to garner political support (Enemu, 2000; Fjeldstad,
I argue that the impact of central government grants on local 2001). Fjeldstad and Heggstad (2012, p. 25) note that politicians
revenues is contingent on two key factors: (1) the existing level often put ‘‘political pressure on the local tax administration to
of fiscal capacity at the local level and (2) political costs associated relax on revenue collection,” especially during election years.
with revenue collection. A notoriously weak capacity of fiscal and While intergovernmental grants can improve the baseline capacity
administrative institutions is a large part of the story behind the of LGAs to mobilize local revenues through directly financing the
low level of local revenues in Africa. Collecting local taxes and fees local tax administration and public service delivery, political costs
can be very costly if monitoring and enforcement systems are not may be too high for subnational governments to scale up such rev-
well established. Due to the poor quality of fiscal institutions, the enue collection efforts. In sum, I posit that the degree to which cen-
costs of revenue collection can sometimes exceed the actual tral government grants ‘‘crowd in” local revenues is determined by
amounts of revenues collected in some localities (McCluskey & the interplay of the existing fiscal capacity at the local level as well
Franzsen, 2005, p. 50). Scott (2009, p. 7) notes that in East Africa as the political sensitivity (or cost) of tax enforcement.
local governments do not necessarily have skilled government My theoretical framework has different implications for urban
employees who have ‘‘financial literacy” to ‘‘manage public and rural areas in Africa in terms of how central government grants
finances and maintain proper accounting procedures.” The collec- may affect local revenues. In particular, I expect the marginal pos-
tion of local revenues is ‘‘often poor and many bills go unpaid itive effect of transfers on local revenue generation to be greater in
because taxpayers cannot be identified or they resist payment rural areas where the existing fiscal capacity of local governments
because their housing conditions are very poor or basic services and the political costs of tax enforcement are both low compared
and infrastructure are not provided to their areas” (Fjeldstad to urban areas. Revenue collection in rural areas is particularly
et al., 2014, p. 5). daunting because the existing institutional and administrative
When existing fiscal institutions are weak, intergovernmental capacity to enforce it is remarkably low, which leaves a large swath
transfers are conducive to facilitating revenue collection efforts. of income or various economic activities untaxed (PMORALG,
Recent studies have identified three causal channels through 2002). In many African countries, spatial inequalities in income
which financial support from the central government can facilitate and institutional capacity have resulted in stark disparities
revenue collection at the local level: fiscal stimulus, public services, between urban and rural LGAs in terms of the amount of revenues
and tax enforcement. First, intergovernmental grants can expand collected at the local level (Fjeldstad et al., 2014). Intergovernmen-
the tax base by stimulating local economies through transfer tal grants alleviate these issues associated with revenue collection
spending (fiscal stimulus) (Caldeira & Rota-Graziosi, 2014; in rural areas because such grants financially enable rural LGAs to
Ilzetzki, Mendoza, & Veǵh, 2013). As Caldeira and Rota-Graziosi not only overcome cost hurdles for tax enforcement, but also to
(2014, p. 367) note, transfers may generate ‘‘a virtuous circle” provide basic public services to meet the demands of citizens,
where ‘‘central grants increase local public spending, which [in which is a sine qua non for promoting voluntary tax compliance.
turn] improves private income and/or voluntary tax compliance, The link between intergovernmental transfers and local rev-
and consequently local own revenue.”4 Second, citizens are more enue generation is more nuanced in urban areas. Since urban LGAs
likely to pay taxes in exchange for better public services, which on average raise higher local revenues than rural counterparts,
are largely financed by transfers (public services) (Bodea & LeBas, which leaves lower margins of revenue growth in the former, the
2016; Caldeira & Rota-Graziosi, 2014). LGAs, particularly in low- extent to which external grants can help further expand the urban
income countries, are often financially incapable of providing basic revenue base is likely limited. In addition, since urban LGAs tend to
public services without support from the central government. In fact, rely less on external grants to finance their budgets (due to their
a number of studies suggest that dissatisfaction with the quality of higher existing fiscal capacity), such grants have less impact on
public service delivery and, hence, on local revenue expansion in
3
Fjeldstad et al. (2014, p. 7) report that ‘‘[w]ith the exception of South Africa, the urban areas. There are diminishing returns to inputs invested in
total local revenues in African countries in 1999 did not exceed 1% of the GDP service provision (Caldeira & Rota-Graziosi, 2014).5
compared to 5.5% of GDP on average for developing countries in other regions.”
4
Although Caldeira and Rota-Graziosi’s analysis is exclusively focused on uncon-
5
ditional fiscal transfers—or grants that are not earmarked for specific purposes set by Resnick (2014, p. S11) notes that ‘‘[t]he city’s high tax base. . .mitigates the
the central government—one may extend this line of logic to other types of central potential impact that any type of reduced inter-governmental transfers has on service
grants. delivery.”
176 T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186

Table 1
Local government revenue sources (in billions of Tanzania shillings) for FY2010/
2011–FY2012/2013a

Fiscal Year 2010/ 2011/ 2012/


2011 2012 2013
Total Revenues 2,251 2,439 2,988
Intergovernmental Transfers 2,084 2,243 2,733
Own Revenues 158 196 241
Intergovernmental Transfers as 92.59% 91.97% 91.47%
% of Total Revenues
Own Revenues as % of Total Revenues 7.03% 8.02% 8.06%

Source: Author’s calculations from PMORALG’s financial data ( http://lginf.pmoralg.


go.tz/lginformation/).
a
Fiscal year in Tanzania starts on July 1 and ends on June 30.

Furthermore, the political costs of tax enforcement in urban


areas are far greater than in rural areas because urban groups
‘‘can present a more credible threat of political unrest” to political Fig. 1. The level of own revenue collection: urban vs. rural. Source: Author’s
leaders (Stasavage, 2005, p. 344). Existing studies show strong evi- construction based on PMORALG’s financial data (http://lginf.pmoralg.go.tz/lgin-
formation/)
dence that policy makers in low-income countries exhibit a ten-
dency to favor urban interests over rural counterparts.6 Lipton
(1971) and Bates (1981) both explain this urban bias as a function these sub-national government entities the main providers of local
of the urban elites holding greater bargaining power to solicit policy public services.
concessions from the government. Urban residents are also better One of the goals of the LGRP has been to ‘‘give LGAs wide discre-
informed about the role and performance of their government tionary powers and a strong financial base” because their own
authorities ‘‘due to greater average wealth, higher education, better capacities to raise revenues are limited (Cochran et al., 2009, p.
access to the media as well as a stronger urban focus in media cov- 19). Accordingly, the program has expanded the amount of central
erage” (Majumdar et al., 2004, p. 139). They leverage this informa- government grants allocated to local district councils. Sarzin and
tion to pressure the government to adopt fiscal policy that better Raich (2012, p. 13) report that ‘‘[i]ntergovernmental transfers
reflects urban interests. Rural residents often do not enjoy this infor- increased from 79 percent of total LGA revenues in 2001/02 to
mational advantage to press the government to heed their voices, 93 percent in 2006/07 while own-source revenue decreased from
thus yielding lesser political influence. 21 percent of total LGA revenues in 2001/02 to 7 percent in
This imbalance between urban and rural residents in political 2006/07.”7 Table 1 shows local government budgets for the period
salience and influence feeds into the calculus of fiscal policy in between FY2010/2011 and FY2012/2013 in Tanzania. Locally raised
Africa. Expanding urban sources of local revenues is often not a revenues account for less than 10% of the local budget (Fjeldstad &
politically viable option because doing so would instigate signifi- Heggstad, 2012). These transfers are allocated according to a
cant resistance from the urban elites. Take property tax, for formula-based mechanism, which takes into account various socio-
instance. As Bahl and Bird (2008, p. 16) note, ‘‘the political costs economic factors such as the size of population, area, poverty, as well
of reliance on residential property taxes are so high that no govern- as access to health facilities (Boex & Martinez-Vazquez, 2006).
ment with access to politically ‘cheaper’ sources of finance will One of the key factors in the low level of local revenue genera-
willingly do so.” For this very reason, property taxes are very much tion in Tanzania lies in the absence of sound fiscal institutions at
underutilized in many African urban cities, while the academics the local level. There has been a perennial shortage of tax evalua-
argue that scaling up efforts to collect such untapped property tors/collectors in the local tax administration. LGAs in Tanzania
taxes would significantly improve the fiscal health of urban district also lack the capacity to monitor and penalize tax evasion or
councils. In other cases, political leaders cut or abolish taxes to non-compliance (Venugopal & Yilmaz, 2010, p. 222). While the
explicitly cater to the needs of urban residents. In Uganda, Presi- beneficiaries of public service are supposed to pay user charges,
dent Museveni removed the graduated tax, a type of income tax the level of compliance with the payment of such dues tends to
imposed on all adults, as part of his political campaign to appeal be low due to the poor quality of services provided and inefficiency
to urban voters whose support was critical to his political survival, in the local tax administration (Fjeldstad & Heggstad, 2012, pp. 21–
although this policy significantly undermined the revenue- 22). In fact, as Therkildsen (1993, p. 86) points out, local govern-
generating capacity of urban districts (Lambright, 2014, p. S48). ments in Tanzania (and other countries in Anglophone East Africa)
have historically suffered from a lack of legitimacy, whereby their
2.3. The case of Tanzania constituencies view them as ‘‘corrupt, inefficient, a waste of time—
and ‘foreign”’.
The process of fiscal decentralization has gained momentum in In Tanzania, like elsewhere in the region, the collection of local
Tanzania since the government launched the Local Government revenues has been particularly challenging in rural areas. Fig. 1
Reform Program (LGRP) in the late 1990s. Before the program took
off, the central government controlled all aspects of financial and 7
The sharp decline in the share of own revenues is mainly driven by two different
human resources while leaving little role for local councils to play
factors. First, the amount of intergovernmental transfers increased not only as a
in planning and implementing fiscal policy. Partly driven by the portion of total local revenues but also in absolute amounts, which pushed the share
increasing demand for more accountable and democratic systems of own revenues in total local revenues down. Second, as part of the nationwide tax
at the local level, the LGRP has delegated many fiscal responsibili- reform, the government abolished the ‘‘head tax” as well as ‘‘nuisance taxes” while
ties previously vested in the central government to LGAs and made also limiting the produce cess ‘‘to a maximum of 5% (compared to rates as high as 20%
in the past)” (Nyange et al., 2014). These measures not only simplified the local tax
system but also narrowed the set of taxes that each LGA could tap into, pushing it to
6
See Majumdar, Mani, and Mukand (2004) for a review of the literature on the instead broaden the tax base for authorized local taxes and collect revenues in a more
urban bias. efficient and effective way.
T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186 177

Fig. 2. The sources of own revenues (FY2010/11-FY2012/13) Source: Author’s construction based on PMORALG’s financial data (http://lginf.pmoralg.go.tz/lginformation/) The
Author(s)

Fig. 3. Local revenues and intergovernmental transfers at the district level. Source: Author’s own construction based on PMORALG’s financial data (http://lginf.pmoralg.go.tz/
lginformation/).

shows district-level, local revenues per capita from FY2010/2011 between FY2010/11 and FY2012/13. Just like many other councils
to FY2012/2013. Urban district councils collect far greater rev- in Tanzania, Bukoba District initially had a very narrow tax base
enues (both in absolute and per capita terms) than rural district and its local tax administration lacked efficiency and technical
councils because the former enjoy a broader tax base and higher expertise to effectively enforce revenue collection. It was during
administrative and institutional capacity than the latter (UNICEF, FY2011/12 that Bukoba began to implement a number of different
2012; World Bank, 2006).8 A large share of local revenues generated policy initiatives to boost own revenues, such as setting up a new
in urban district councils derives from taxes on business and corpo- revenue management team to oversee the implementation of rev-
rate activities (e.g., service levy), while the agricultural produce cess enue collection plans, carrying out community sensitization efforts
constitutes a major source of revenues for rural LGAs (see Fig. 2). for taxpayers who were uninformed about their tax obligation, and
Nyange et al. (2014, p. iv) note that ‘‘[m]uch potential cess revenue installing notice boards regarding tax items/rates across all rev-
goes uncollected” due to ‘‘limited human and institutional capacity enue collection points (e.g., market places, village/ward offices)
at local level and widespread tax evasion, some of it likely featuring (PMORALG, 2015, pp. 66–69). None of these policy initiatives
the collaboration of some local officials”. would have been possible had it not been for enough financial
Despite these institutional deficits, some LGAs have shown real resources available to implement them (PMORALG, 2015). Bukoba
success in expanding their revenue-generating capacity during the District, though facing significant financial constraints, managed to
period under study (FY2010/11–FY2012/13), and finance seems to dedicate a portion of its annual budget to strengthen its internal
be one of the key drivers for their success. Among the best per- tax collection system, and transfers from the central government
formers in local revenue enhancement was Bukoba District whose were indispensable for the core functioning of the LGA to under-
reported amount of own revenues had more than quadrupled take such reforms.9

8 9
Aiko (2013) also shows that there is a high disparity between urban and rural In fact, approximately, 95% of Bukoba’s district budget was financed through
areas in Tanzania in terms of the awareness of tax obligations where rural residents transfers during the period under study (FY2010/11–FY2012/13) when those tax
are less informed and thus less aware of their tax obligations than urban residents. reforms were underway.
178 T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186

3. Econometric models

To empirically test the relationship between intergovernmental


transfers and local tax revenues, I use district-level, quarterly data
on local revenues in Tanzania between FY2010/2011 and
FY2012/2013. All my fiscal data derives from PMORALG’s online
financial database, which is constructed based on financial reports
from each LGA. The collected data are published at each quarter for
all LGAs that report to PMORALG. One of the key advantages of
PMORALG’s financial data is its high level of granularity, which
allows me to disaggregate revenues (e.g., intergovernmental trans-
fers) by source such that I can test how different types of transfers
may influence local revenues differently.10 The first set of models
estimates the impact of intergovernmental transfers on local rev-
enues in the following equation, which is a simple Ordinary Least
Squares (OLS) model akin to the baseline model used in Caldeira
and Rota-Graziosi (2014):
Fig. 4. Precipitation at the district level. Source: Author’s own construction based on
OWN REVENUEi;t ¼ b1 TRANSFERi;t þ cXi;t þ /i þ dt þ i;t ð1Þ the ‘UDel’ (University of Delaware) data set, a gridded monthly precipitation data
set (Matsuura & Willmott, 2015).
where i and t index district i and quarter t, respectively; OWN REV-
ENUE refers to the volume of local revenues per capita (log-
transformed); TRANSFER denotes the size of intergovernmental (AREA) and the length of roads (in km, log-transformed) as addi-
transfers per capita (log-transformed)11; Xi;t includes all observable tional controls. Lastly, I also control for the share of presidential
controls; and /i and dt are district-fixed and quarter-fixed effects.12 votes for the incumbent (SUPPORT) to capture electoral dynamics,
A battery of control variables are included to alleviate omitted which are known to affect the quality of public service
variable bias. Intergovernmental transfers are allocated based on (Rosenzweig, 2015) (and, for that reason, the level of local taxes)
socio-economic factors, which, in turn, affect the level of local rev- as well as the flow of transfers (Allers & Ishemoi, 2011).
enues (Boex & Martinez-Vazquez, 2006). The subnational level of My OLS estimates of the effect of transfers on local revenues are
development is one such potential confounder. To control for the likely to be biased because the flow of intergovernmental transfers
varying levels of development at the subnational level, I use the is expected to be endogenous to local revenues. Simply lagging the
district-level, annual average rate of extreme poverty (or an esti- level of transfers does not alleviate concerns with endogeneity or
mated proportion of people living on less than $1.25 a day).13 In reverse causality because there are a number of potential unob-
addition, geographical factors may play a role in determining the servable variables that may be persistent over time, which would
extent to which LGAs can tap into their own revenue sources. I confound the relationship between the dependent variable and
expect that as the size of geographical areas that LGAs govern the lagged endogeneous variable (Bellemare, Masaki, & Pepinsky,
increases and the total length of roads in each district (given its size) 2017). To alleviate concerns with endogeneity, I use the level of
decreases, the cost of administering revenue collection rises. Thus, I precipitation (in mm, log-transformed) (which is referred to as
include the size of land (in km2, log-transformed) for each district PRECIP in the models) as instruments for intergovernmental
transfers.
10
Sanoh (2015) shows that rainfall is an exogenous shock that
While PMORALG’s financial database offers the best possible source of informa-
tion on district-level finance, it is by no means free from errors and omissions (The
impact both local revenues and the flow of intergovernmental
National Audit Office of Tanzania, 2014). Financial misstatements by LGAs are transfers because they affect agricultural yields, which are a func-
frequent and potentially introduce significant noise in the data (The National Audit tion of climate factors. The Government of Tanzania (GoT) indeed
Office of Tanzania, 2014). The level and depth of errors may be particularly severe in explicitly links the amount of transfer allocation to precipitation
the quarterly data, which LGAs have started reporting only in recent years. While it is
(Tanzania Ministry of Finance, 2011). I argue that rainfall should
not possible to confirm the extent to which these errors can influence my results, it is
important to make sure that my empirical findings are not an artifact of reporting serve as a valid instrument for OWN REVENUE when all agricultural
errors. Given that these reporting errors are likely more rampant in the quarterly taxes are removed from our IV analysis. Since rainfall affect local rev-
data, I test if using the annual–rather than quarterly–fiscal data in my analysis yields enues mainly through their direct impact on the amount of agricul-
similar results. I confirm that the main conclusions of my analysis remain unchanged tural taxes collected at the local level (Sanoh, 2015), removing the
regardless of whether annual or quarterly fiscal data are used.
11 agricultural cess from OWN REVENUE ensures that they fulfill the
My econometric analysis excludes Mbozi District whose financial reports in the
PMORALG database most likely suffer from significant errors. The reported amount of exclusion restriction.14 Fig. 3 shows spatial variation in the quar-
transfers being disbursed to the district has extreme (and unreasonable) fluctuations, terly average amount of local revenues and intergovernmental trans-
and including this district in my analysis adds significant noise to my estimation. fers per capita across districts for the period of FY2010/11–
However, my main econometric findings remain unchanged regardless of whether FY2012/13, and Fig. 4 presents the monthly average level of precip-
Mbozi District is included or not.
12
In the calculation of OWN REVENUE, I exclude Local Government Capital
itation in each district for the same time period.
Development Grants (LCDGs). Including the LCDGs in my analysis introduces issues Additionally, I use distance (in km) from Dar es Salaam, a de
of reverse causality because this particular type of grant is allocated based explicitly facto capital of the country, as another instrument for central
on LGAs’ fiscal performance, which includes local revenue mobilization as one of the governmental grants (DISTANCE). Gisselquist, Leiderer, and
key criteria to qualify for the grant (PMORALG, 2008, p. 7). The LGCDG accounts for
roughly a 5% of the total transfers made during FY2010/11–FY2012/13. My empirical
findings do not significantly change even if the LGCDG is included in the calculation of
14
OWN REVENUE. It is plausible that climate shocks (e.g., droughts) may directly affect farmers’
13
The data on poverty is taken from WorldPop (Tatem, Gething, Bhatt, Weiss, & propensity or ability to pay taxes by changing their income levels (Burke, Gong, &
Pezzulo, 2013). WorldPop’s population mapping program integrates various sources Jones, 2015; Fjeldstad & Semboja, 2001). In my econometric analysis, I consider this
of welfare and consumption data (e.g., USAID’s Demographic and Health Survey and possibility and run a robustness check to evaluate if my findings are sensitive to the
the WB’s Living Standards Measurement Survey) to produce its own estimates of incidence of such climate shocks (and their potential impact on rural income and local
poverty (e.g., the proportion of people living under $1.25 or $2.00) at a highly granular revenues). My main conclusions do not change when drought-afflicted districts are
level (with a high resolution of 1 square kilometer). excluded from my analysis.
T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186 179

Nino-Zarazúa (2016) show that distance from the national capital Hansen tests becomes inflated (sometimes approaching 1.00)
is an exogenous variable that influences how much grant each dis- when there are too many instruments that overfit the endogenous
trict receives from the central government. The closer local com- variables. Since the number of time periods in my panel (T = 12) is
munities are to the capital, the more they are expected to enjoy relatively large, my models would be subject to the problem of
bargaining power to attract money from the center. There is no instrument proliferation if all lags are exploited as instruments.
theoretical reason to believe, however, that distance itself affects Following Roodman’s (2009) suggestion, I restrict the maximum
the extent to which local governments can mobilize local revenues. lag of GMM-style instruments to 2 to avoid the inclusion of too
The institutional and administrative capacity of local governments many instruments. I treat OWN REVENUEt1 ; TRANSFERt , and
in collecting taxes should not be directly linked to how far they are TRANSFERt1 as endogenous and generate the GMM-type instru-
from Dar es Salaam. Based on this line of logic, distance should ments for these three variables.
meet the exclusion restriction. Table A-1 gives the descriptive
statistics of all the variables described above.
4. Estimation results
The second set of models explores the dynamic relationship
between transfers and local revenues by introducing the lagged
4.1. On the effects of transfers on local revenue generation in the OLS
levels of own revenues and transfers in the right-hand side of the
and IV estimation
equation. A dynamic model may be more appropriate for this anal-
ysis because the level of tax revenue collection is likely to be highly
Table 2 presents main results. I find that intergovernmental
persistent over time. It is reasonable to assume that the current
transfers increase local revenues, and that this effect seems to be
level of local revenues depends on the amounts of local revenues
slightly more pronounced in rural district councils. Models 1–3
and intergovernmental grants received in the past, and the follow-
employ the pooled OLS regression while Models 4 and 5 include
ing equation captures this dynamic:
district-fixed effects. In Models 6–9, I use rainfall to instrument
OWN REVENUEi;t ¼ a1 OWN REVENUEi;t1 þ b1 TRANSFERi;t TRANSFER, and Models 8 and 9 adopt the IV estimation that also
accounts for district-fixed effects. The results from the first-stage
þ b2 TRANSFERi;t1 þ /i þ dt þ cXi;t þ i;t ð2Þ regressions are presented in Table 3. The F test of the excluded
instruments (PRECIP and DISTANCE) shows that they jointly have
One of the key differences between Eqs. (1) and (2) is that the latter
significant impact on the flow of intergovernmental transfers both
now captures both the contemporaneous and lagged effects of
in the subsamples of rural and urban LGAs.15 Precipitation and dis-
transfers on local revenues. Estimating this dynamic model allows
tance are particularly strong predictors of transfer flows in the sub-
me to conduct an indirect test of different causal mechanisms. As
sample of rural LGAs (see Table 3). The Hansen J test rejects the null
highlighted earlier, there are three plausible channels of effects: fis-
hypothesis of the joint exogeneity of instruments for Models 6–8 (p-
cal stimulus, public services, and tax enforcement. Some of these
value <0.05); thus, there is a certain degree of uncertainty over
effects are observed immediately after transfers are disbursed while
whether instruments in those models are jointly valid and the esti-
others may be delayed. For instance, after transfers are disbursed,
mated results should be interpreted with some caution. Across all
there is likely some temporal lag before they stimulate economic
these models, the estimated effects of TRANSFER are positive and
activities (fiscal stimulus), which are then expected to increase
significant in the subsample of rural LGAs in Table 2. It is also impor-
the value of the tax base. In contrast, local tax administrators need
tant to note that these effects are slightly but consistently greater in
transfers to pay for the fixed costs of tax enforcement and service
magnitude in rural LGAs compared to urban LGAs.
delivery, which should then have immediate positive effects on
the amount of revenues they can tap at the same time period.
Eq. 2 produces biased estimates if there is residual autocorrela- 4.2. On the contemporaneous and lagged effects of transfers on local
tion (Keele & Kelly, 2006) and/or if there are endogenous variables revenue generation by source
on the right-hand side of the equation. To account for these poten-
tial sources of bias, I employ the Blundell-Bond (Blundell & Bond, Table 4 summarizes results from the SGMM models, which now
1998) system GMM estimators (SGMM). The SGMM estimation estimate the contemporaneous and lagged effects of transfers on
exploits both the lagged differences of the endogenous variables local revenue in a dynamic setting. The Hansen J test fails to reject
and the lagged levels of the equation as instruments to circumvent the null of the joint exogeneity of all instruments across Models 1–
the issue of endogeneity. For robustness, I report results from the 8 (p-value >0.05), which brings some confidence that my instru-
one-step and two-step GMM estimation. The two-step GMM esti- ments are jointly valid (p-value >0.05). The difference-in-Hansen
mators are said to be asymptotically efficient and robust to test also indicates that the GMM-type internal instruments are also
heteroskedasticity and cross-correlation although they are also valid (p-value >0.05).16
criticized for introducing downward bias in standard errors. To Two patterns emerge in Table 4. First, the estimated (positive)
correct for this potential bias, robust standard errors for two-step effects of transfers on local revenues are larger in magnitude in
estimation are corrected for finite sample using Windmeijer’s rural districts compared to urban districts. The contemporaneous
(2005) correction. Since the ‘‘SGMM improves the accuracy of esti- and lagged effects of transfers (b^1 and b ^2 , as defined in Eq. 2) are
mates by exploiting additional moment conditions that are infor- positive and statistically significant in the subsample of rural dis-
mative in the presence of persistent data” (Gisselquist et al., tricts while only the contemporaneous effects are significant at
2016, pp. 315–316), I combine GMM instruments with a set of the conventional level in the subsample of urban districts. The esti-
external instruments as discussed above (precipitation and dis- mated effect sizes also appear to be larger when all sources of own
tance from Dar es Salaam). revenues are used as the dependent variable (in Models 1–2 and
To show the validity of instruments, I report the p-value from
the Hansen J test and the difference-in-Hansen test. The null 15
Note that DISTANCE is not included as an instrument in Models 8 and 9 because
hypothesis of the former test is the joint exogeneity of all instru- these two models account for district-fixed effects and drop all variables that do not
vary over time.
ments, while that of the latter is the joint exogeneity of additional 16
It should be noted that in the subsample of urban districts, the N of Instruments
instruments (e.g., GMM-type instruments for levels) used in the exceeds the number of districts and is likely to inflate the p-value for the Hansen J test
SGMM estimation (Murtin & Wacziarg, 2014; Roodman, 2009). and the difference-in-Hansen test (Roodman, 2007). Thus, the test results should be
As Roodman (2009) points out, the p-value associated with the treated with caution.
180 T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186

Table 2
The effect of intergovernmental transfers on own revenue generation.

Model (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Pooled Pooled Pooled FE FE FE FE IV + FE IV + FE
DV All All All All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes
Subsample All Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban
TRANSFER 0.329⁄⁄⁄ 0.370*** 0.327*** 0.317*** 0.262** 1.225*** 0.402* 1.397⁄⁄⁄ 0.475⁄⁄⁄
(0.052) (0.062) (0.099) (0.064) (0.102) (0.285) (0.244) (0.374) (0.174)
POVERTY 2.869⁄⁄⁄ 2.945⁄⁄⁄ 3.093⁄⁄⁄ 1.699⁄ 3.048⁄⁄⁄
(0.607) (0.786) (0.924) (0.901) (0.879)
ROAD 0.053 0.057 0.221 0.126 0.196
(0.104) (0.111) (0.165) (0.145) (0.187)
AREA 0.051 0.123 0.333⁄⁄⁄ 0.154 0.296⁄⁄
(0.065) (0.090) (0.102) (0.100) (0.129)
SUPPORT 0.490 0.375 1.562 0.734⁄ 2.472⁄⁄
(0.433) (0.437) (0.992) (0.445) (1.054)
District Fixed Effects No No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes
Time Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No
N of observations 1572 1248 324 1248 324 1196 312 1196 312

Notes: Standard errors are clustered by district and reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Sources: Author’s estimation based on PMORALG’s financial data ( http://lginf.pmoralg.go.tz/lginformation/), the ‘UDel’ precipitation dataset Matsuura and Willmott (2015),
Tatem et al. (2013), the Center for International Earth Science Information Network’s (CIESIN) Global Roads Open Access Data Set (Version 1), the National Electoral
Commission of Tanzania, and Global Administrative Unit Layers (GAUL).

Table 3
First-Stage Regression Results for Models 6–9 in Table 2.

Model (6) (7) (8) (9)


IV IV IVþFE IV + FE
Subsample Rural Urban Rural Urban
PRECIPt1 0.019 0.000 0.058⁄⁄ 0.001
(0.019) (0.037) (0.023) (0.053)
PRECIPt2 0.016 0.084 0.056⁄⁄⁄ 0.086
(0.019) (0.054) (0.020) (0.057)
PRECIPt3 0.006 0.056 0.032⁄ 0.057
(0.019) (0.060) (0.019) (0.054)
PRECIPt4 0.079⁄⁄⁄ 0.170⁄⁄⁄ 0.116⁄⁄⁄ 0.164⁄⁄⁄
(0.023) (0.050) (0.026) (0.054)
DISTANCE 0.001⁄⁄⁄ 0.000
(0.000) (0.000)
POVERTY 1.254⁄⁄ 1.688⁄
(0.509) (0.848)
ROAD 0.036 0.073
(0.064) (0.168)
AREA 0.075 0.231⁄⁄
(0.051) (0.089)
SUPPORT 0.171 0.905
(0.279) (0.789)
F test of excluded instruments (p-value) 0.000 0.028 0.001 0.020
Kleibergen-Paap LM test (p-value) 0.001 0.051 0.003 0.048
Hansen J test (p-value) 0.007 0.016 0.012 0.158

Notes: See Table 2.


Sources: See Table 2.

5–8) instead of only a subset of taxes excluding agricultural taxes The differences between the estimated effects of TRANSFERt and
(Models 3–4 and 7–8).17 More substantively, a 1% increase in fiscal TRANSFERt1 (b ^1  b
^2 ) are largely positive and these differentials
^1 þ b
transfers is expected to induce a 0.55–0.59% increase (b ^2 ) in are significant in the subsample of rural districts when all own rev-
the total amount of local revenues in rural districts (based on Models enues are considered (Models 1 and 5). As discussed earlier, the
1 and 5) and a 0.45–0.47% increase in urban districts (based on Mod- contemporaneous effects of transfers mostly capture their direct
els 2 and 6). and immediate impact on local revenue generation by financing
Another key finding is that the contemporaneous impact of fis- the fixed costs of tax enforcement and service delivery. In contrast,
cal transfers on local revenues are larger than their lagged effects. the lagged effects of transfers capture the indirect effects of trans-
fers on local revenues through stimulating local economies, which,
after some temporal lag, affect the value of the local tax base (fiscal
17
In Models 3–4 and 7–8 where precipitation is used as an external instrument, I stimulus) (Troland, 2014). My findings seem to provide some sup-
make sure to remove the produce cess (or agricultural taxes) from the dependent port that a larger proportion of increases in local revenues may be
variable to ensure the validity of the weather instruments. The estimated effects of explained by the direct effects of transfers on tax enforcement and
transfers in rural districts, as reported in Table 4, are smaller in magnitude when the
public services, instead of fiscal stimulus.
agricultural taxes are removed. This is consistent with the fact that agricultural taxes
are a major source of revenues in rural areas and removing this type of revenues can To further explore the causal channels through which transfers
reduce the extent of variation in the dependent variable. may influence local revenues, I also break down the effects of
T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186 181

Table 4
Results from GMM estimation.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Models SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM
One-Step One-Step One-Step One-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step
DV All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl.Ag. Taxes All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes
Subsample Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban
TRANSFER 0.432⁄⁄⁄ 0.348⁄⁄⁄ 0.186⁄⁄ 0.038 0.462⁄⁄⁄ 0.333⁄⁄ 0.190⁄⁄ 0.018
(0.073) (0.113) (0.073) (0.044) (0.073) (0.149) (0.080) (0.119)
TRANSFERt1 0.120⁄⁄⁄ 0.119 0.179⁄⁄⁄ 0.028 0.127⁄⁄⁄ 0.117 0.171⁄⁄⁄ 0.026
(0.043) (0.104) (0.047) (0.054) (0.047) (0.124) (0.049) (0.187)
POVERTY 7.017⁄⁄ 3.524 2.651 0.406 7.470⁄⁄ 2.525 2.567 7.927
(3.139) (2.199) (2.835) (1.004) (3.586) (7.653) (3.126) (22.887)
ROAD 0.125 0.620 0.348 0.122 0.087 0.606 0.405 0.003
(0.444) (0.454) (0.411) (0.324) (0.502) (0.855) (0.442) (0.569)
AREA 0.474 0.364 0.054 0.132 0.354 0.460 0.073 0.690
(0.303) (0.338) (0.274) (0.254) (0.332) (0.761) (0.308) (2.115)
SUPPORT 0.851 0.303 1.993 1.725 1.435 0.000 2.133 1.426
(2.043) (2.219) (1.473) (1.050) (2.290) (0.000) (1.683) (5.925)
DISTANCE 0.000 0.001 0.001⁄⁄ 0.001⁄⁄⁄ 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.001
(0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.005)
OWN REVENUEt1 0.044 0.078 0.123⁄ 0.287⁄⁄ 0.051 0.075 0.133⁄ 0.299
(0.040) (0.060) (0.071) (0.107) (0.040) (0.120) (0.070) (0.295)
^1 þ b
b ^2 0.552 0.467 0.364 0.066 0.590 0.450 0.361 0.044
[0.000] [0.004] [0.000] [0.414] [0.000] [0.047] [0.000] [0.873]
^1  b
b ^2 0.312 0.228 0.007 0.010 0.335 0.217 0.018 0.009
[0.000] [0.167] [0.933] [0.867] [0.000] [0.215] [0.836] [0.955]
AR1 (p-value) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.009 0.000 0.048
AR2 (p-value) 0.639 0.940 0.004 0.285 0.712 0.945 0.060 0.372
Hansen J test (p-value) 0.055 1.000 0.109 1.000 0.055 1.000 0.109 1.000
Diff. in Hansen test (p-value) 0.998 1.000 0.342 1.000 0.998 1.000 0.342 1.000
N of Instruments 71 71 85 84 71 71 85 84
N of Observations 1144 297 1060 273 1144 297 1060 273

Notes: Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. For two-step results, robust standard errors are corrected for finite sample using Windmeijer’s (Windmeijer, 2005)
correction. GMM-style instruments are used in combination with the external instruments. In Models 1–2 and 5–6, DISTANCE is used as an external instrument in addition to
internal GMM instruments while in Models 3–4 and 7–8, the full set of external instruments (DISTANCE; PRECIPt1 , PRECIPt2 , PRECIPt3 , PRECIPt4 ) and internal GMM
instruments are used. I also report the p-values from the t-tests on the combined effects of TRANSFERt and TRANSFERt1 (b ^1 þ b
^2 ) and the estimated differences between
^1  b
those two coefficients (b ^2 ) in brackets. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Sources: See Table 2.

transfers by their types. If it is true that the ‘‘crowding-in” effects of consistent with the hypothesis that transfers directly pay for the
transfers are largely through their direct impact on tax enforce- fixed costs of tax enforcement and thus augment the capacity of
ment, transfers that are specifically earmarked for tax enforcement LGAs to raise their own revenues. The contemporaneous and
should have independent effects on local revenues. Unfortunately, lagged effects of SERVICE-RELATED TRANSFERS are both positive
PMORALG’s fiscal data are not granular enough to distinguish and statistically significant but they seem to exert larger effects
between transfers that are spent on tax enforcement and transfers in rural districts compared to urban districts. These findings give
that are purposed for public service provision. However, I can still credence to the notion that the marginal positive effects of trans-
estimate how much transfer is spent on general local administra- fers on public service provision (and, thus, tax compliance) are
tive purposes, instead of public service delivery, and use it as a expected to be higher in rural districts where LGAs tend to rely
proxy measure of the amount of transfers that could potentially more excessively on transfers to deliver basic public goods and ser-
be used for tax enforcement. More specifically, I distinguish two vices to their citizens.18
types of transfers: transfers being used for administrative purposes I subject my findings to a number of different robustness tests.
(e.g., paying salaries and covering administrative costs) (which I The first test addresses issues surrounding the quality of PMOR-
refer to as ADMINISTRATIVE TRANSFERS) and conditional transfers ALG’s financial data. This database relies on financial statements
being earmarked for service delivery (SERVICE-RELATED TRANS- from each LGA, which may not report accurately at times (The
FERS). The former include the General Purpose Grants (GPGs)— National Audit Office of Tanzania, 2014). While there is no effective
which are unconditional grants that local governments can use way to confirm the accuracy of the data itself, I attempt to reduce
flexibly to pay for administrative costs—and development grants the noise in the data that derives from measurement or reporting
being earmarked specifically for local administration. Although errors by using the annual data on local revenues and intergovern-
not all of this administrative transfer is spent on tax enforcement, mental transfers. Aggregating the quarterly data to the annual level
it at least serves as a proxy for the amount of transfers that could certainly is not a panacea for data quality issues but it at least
have been used to cover the fixed costs of tax enforcement. All the ensures that my findings are not an artifact of measurement errors
other remaining transfers can then be considered conditional
transfers for public service provision. 18
For robustness, I also test whether controlling for public service spending
Table 5 reports the estimated effects of general administrative influences my results. If improvement in the quality of public service associated with
transfers and conditional service-related transfers on local rev- transfers is not the solo explanation for the observed crowding-in effects of fiscal
enues. As predicted, the contemporaneous effects of ADMINISTRA- transfers, the estimated effects of transfers should remain positive and significant
even after controlling for local government spending on service delivery. Including
TIVE TRANSFER are positive and largely statistically significant the amount of public service spending per capita (PUBLIC SERVICE SPENDINGt and
both in rural and urban districts while their lagged effects are close PUBLIC SERVICE SPENDINGt1 ) as additional controls does not significantly influence
to zero across all models reported in Table 5. These findings are my results (See Table A-6).
182 T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186

Table 5
Results from GMM estimation by different types of transfers.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Models SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM
One-Step One-Step One-Step One-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step
DV All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes
Subsample Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban
ADMINISTRATIVE TRANSFER 0.159⁄⁄⁄ 0.236⁄⁄⁄ 0.079⁄⁄ 0.067 0.148⁄⁄⁄ 0.204⁄⁄ 0.060⁄ 0.117
(0.039) (0.071) (0.036) (0.040) (0.046) (0.079) (0.035) (0.089)
ADMINISTRATIVE TRANSFERt1 0.028 0.007 0.066⁄ 0.002 0.037 0.010 0.054 0.050
(0.030) (0.040) (0.035) (0.022) (0.033) (0.044) (0.036) (0.056)
^1 þ b
b ^2 0.187 0.243 0.145 0.065 0.185 0.214 0.113 0.167
[0.001] [0.012] [0.020] [0.152] [0.004] [0.028] [0.068] [0.199]
b ^2
^1  b 0.131 0.229 0.012 0.069 0.112 0.194 0.006 0.067
[0.002] [0.004] [0.731] [0.153] [0.027] [0.038] [0.867] [0.401]
AR1 (p-value) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.010 0.000 0.059
AR2 (p-value) 0.692 0.932 0.001 0.200 0.727 0.665 0.034 0.167
Hansen J test (p-value) 0.048 1.000 0.272 1.000 0.048 1.000 0.272 1.000
Diff. in Hansen test (p-value) 0.999 1.000 0.612 1.000 0.999 1.000 0.612 1.000
SERVICE-RELATED TRANSFER 0.450⁄⁄⁄ 0.321⁄⁄ 0.195⁄⁄⁄ 0.029 0.462⁄⁄⁄ 0.332⁄⁄ 0.192⁄⁄ 0.010
(0.075) (0.120) (0.073) (0.042) (0.076) (0.150) (0.080) (0.123)
SERVICE-RELATED TRANSFERt1 0.125⁄⁄⁄ 0.121 0.184⁄⁄⁄ 0.027 0.126⁄⁄⁄ 0.127 0.176⁄⁄⁄ 0.034
(0.043) (0.102) (0.047) (0.056) (0.045) (0.114) (0.049) (0.175)
^1 þ b
b ^2 0.575 0.442 0.379 0.056 0.588 0.459 0.368 0.044
[0.000] [0.005] [0.000] [0.490] [0.000] [0.027] [0.000] [0.873]
^1  b
b ^2 0.326 0.200 0.011 0.002 0.336 0.205 0.017 0.024
[0.000] [0.248] [0.892] [0.970] [0.000] [0.267] [0.853] [0.855]
AR1 (p-value) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.004 0.000 0.059
AR2 (p-value) 0.568 0.894 0.004 0.287 0.645 0.968 0.062 0.385
Hansen J test (p-value) 0.038 1.000 0.125 1.000 0.038 1.000 0.125 1.000
Diff. in Hansen test (p-value) 0.995 1.000 0.364 1.000 0.995 1.000 0.364 1.000

Notes: Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. For two-step results, robust standard errors are corrected for finite sample using Windmeijer’s (Windmeijer, 2005)
correction. GMM-style instruments are used in combination with the external instruments. In Models 1–2 and 5–6, DISTANCE is used as an external instrument in addition to
internal GMM instruments while in Models 3–4 and 7–8, the full set of external instruments (DISTANCE; PRECIPt1 ; PRECIPt2 ; PRECIPt3 ; PRECIPt4 ) and internal GMM
instruments are used. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Sources: See Table 2.

associated with the quarterly data, which can be alleviated by such rainfall shocks may have significantly undermined farmers’
aggregation. My main conclusions remain intact if the annual income.20 My findings again remain robust to the exclusion of
aggregate fiscal data are used instead of the quarterly fiscal data drought-afflicted districts (see Table A-4).
(see Table A-2). Lastly, I examine if my findings are sensitive to the N of Instru-
Another potential threat to the validity of my empirical analysis ments used in the GMM estimation. As highlighted above, if the N
has to do with the seasonability of the quarterly data. Some taxes of Instruments is too many, the diagnostic tests like the Hansen J
(e.g., civil service levy) are collected on the quarterly basis while test or the difference-in-Hansen test fail (Roodman, 2009).21 The
some other taxes (e.g., business license fees, land rent, property parameter estimates also suffer from bias as ‘‘[s]imply by being
tax) are collected only annually. This cyclical nature of local rev- numerous, instruments can overfit instrumented variables, failing
enue collection may also be correlated with the timing of central to expunge their endogenous components and biasing coefficient
grant transfers or the weather conditions whereby temporal estimates towards those from non-instrumenting estimators”
dynamics can potentially be a confounder. I replicate Models 1–8 (Roodman, 2009, p. 139). To evaluate the sensitivity of my findings,
in Table 4 but with seasonable dummies (e.g., introducing a I replicate Models 1–8 in Table 4 using (1) a single lag of the endoge-
dummy for each of the four seasons), linear time trends, and quar- nous variables (OWN REVENUEt1 ; TRANSFERt , and TRANSFERt1 )
terly dummies. I find that introducing different controls to account and (2) a full set of lags. The results from these re-defined GMM
for temporal dynamics does not affect my main conclusions (See models are akin to what I report in Table 4 (see Table A-5).
Table A-3).
My IV estimation rests on the assumption that rainfall affects 5. Conclusion
local revenues only through their impact on central grants. How-
ever, it is possible that if there are strong income shocks driven For the past two decades, international donors have praised
by significant climate events (e.g., droughts), these shocks may also efforts towards fiscal decentralization as one of the key policy
affect farmers’ ability or propensity to pay taxes (Aikaeli, 2010). If prescriptions to address issues related to poor public service
this proposition holds true, rainfall does not meet the exclusion
restriction.19 To ensure that my findings are not sensitive to these 20
I follow Burke et al. (2015) in defining a drought as a rainfall realization below a
significant climate events in my data, I replicate my IV estimation
certain quantile of a historical rainfall distribution in a given district. I use the 5%, 15%,
reported in Model 8 in Table 2 but exclude those rural districts that 25%, and 35% quantiles as thresholds to determine the events of droughts. The
experienced droughts in the current or previous fiscal year, where historical rainfall distribution was derived from district-level rainfall data for the
period between 1900 and 2014 (for which rainfall data are available).
21
While there is no consensus on what constitutes the optimal number of
19
In 2008/09 and 2010/11, droughts hit farmers and patoralists in Northern instruments, ‘‘a rule of thumb is to keep the N of Instruments below the number of
Tanzania (and elsewhere in East Africa) (Goldman, Daly, & Lovell, 2016). cross-section units in a panel” (Heckelman & Wilson, 2014, p. 446).
T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186 183

provision and poverty in Africa. Some real progress has been governments, it should be emphasized that these transfers may
made in this area with many key responsibilities of the central also provide LGAs with strong incentives to generate more local
government (e.g., providing public service, collecting taxes) revenues, through improving their capability to deliver public ser-
devolved to lower tiers of the political system. However, most vices and also strengthening their institutional capacity to collect
LGAs are still financially weak and rely excessively on support taxes/fees.
from the central government to finance their budgets. Various Attributing the low level of local revenue collection efforts in
scholars claim that such intergovernmental transfers may obviate Africa to over-reliance on the central government misplaces the
the need for local revenue generation and thus undermine the fis- fundamental cause of the problem in a symptom of the problem
cal autonomy of LGAs (e.g., Mogues & Benin, 2012; Buettner & itself. Scholars and policy makers alike often paint a bleak picture
Wildasin, 2006; Zhuravskaya, 2000). Although there has been that the central government’s efforts to help LGAs financially come
some empirical support for the potential ‘‘crowding-out” effects at the cost of reducing incentives for local revenue mobilization. In
of fiscal transfers, however, most of the existing studies are many African countries, however, LGAs have never developed the
focused on developed countries where sound fiscal capacity fiscal capacity to effectively raise their own revenues. Endowing
already exists at the local level. In fact, few scholarly efforts have LGAs with financial capacities to respond to the needs of their con-
been made to empirically test the fiscal implications of intergov- stituencies is essential in improving government accountability as
ernmental transfers in the context of low-income countries—and well as establishing citizens’ trust in local governments. In this
Africa, in particular. respect, central grants can play an essential role in improving the
I argue that intergovernmental transfers play an integral role in fiscal capacity of LGAs.
facilitating the mobilization of local revenues in Africa where local
governments lack the internal capacity to raise their own revenues.
Acknowledgement
LGAs are financially weak and cannot hire qualified staff or pur-
chase equipment necessary for the collection of taxes and fees.
I am grateful to Nicolas van de Walle, Thomas Pepinsky, Peter
They also rely on financial transfers from the central government
Enns, and Christopher Way for their advice and constant encour-
to provide public services, which, in turn, generates further local
agements. I would also like to thank Ryan Briggs and Miguel
revenues through promoting voluntary tax compliance. Using
Niño-Zarazúa for helpful comments and suggestions. I am also
quarterly fiscal data on local government revenues and expendi-
indebted to participants at meetings where versions of this article
ture in Tanzania, my empirical findings demonstrate that intergov-
were presented, including a UNU-WIDER Symposium on ‘‘The Eco-
ernmental transfers actually increase local revenues, which runs
nomics and Politics of Taxation and Social Protection” and the
directly counter to the hypothesized ‘‘crowding-out” effects of
Institute for African Development’s Seminar Series on ‘‘Governance
financial transfers, and that this positive effect is more pronounced
in Africa” at Cornell University, and AidData’s workshop on
in rural districts.
‘‘Pioneering Development Research Using Geospatial Data.” Finally,
The issues of fiscal capacity are largely ignored in the existing
I gratefully acknowledge financial support from UNU-WIDER. The
literature on intergovernmental transfers and local revenues.
findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this publi-
Scholars often take for granted the capacity of local governments
cation are those of the author and should not be attributed in
to extract revenues if they want to do so. In Africa, intergovern-
any manner to UNU-WIDER or The World Bank, its Board of Exec-
mental transfers account for a significant proportion of the local
utive Directors, or the governments they represent. All remaining
budget, in which case the functionality of the local tax administra-
errors are my own.
tion also depends crucially on financial support from the center.
Without financial support from the central government, LGAs can-
not maintain and/or improve their fiscal systems and are thus Appendix A. Descriptive statistics and data sources
unable to expand the tax base. While some claim that intergovern-
mental transfers undermine the fiscal autonomy of local

Table A-1
Descriptive statistics.

Variable Names Description N Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Sources


OWN REVENUE Log of own revenues per capita (in TSh) 1572 6.551 1.075 1.489 9.325 A
Zeros or negative values are replaced by
minimum positive values
TRANSFER Log of transfers per capita (in TSh) 1572 9.406 0.892 3.526 11.577 A
Zeros or negative values are replaced by minimum positive values
ADMINISTRATIVE TRANSFERS Log of admin. transfers per capita (in Tsh) 1572 6.794 1.360 0.146 10.361 A
Zeros or negative values are replaced by minimum positive values
SERVICE-RELATED TRANSFERS Log of service-related transfers per capita (in TSh) 1572 9.316 0.864 3.661 11.716 A
Zeros or negative values are replaced by minimum positive values
POVERTY The average rate of extreme poverty (living on less than $1.25 a day) 1572 0.810 0.092 0.457 0.935 B
DISTANCE Distance from Dar es Salaam (in km) 1572 544.173 276.089 0.000 1084.776 C
AREA Log of the size of area (in km2) 1572 8.181 1.397 4.149 10.824 C
ROAD Log of road length (in km) 1572 6.205 0.890 2.941 8.271 D
SUPPORT Share of presidential votes for the incumbent 1572 0.661 0.126 0.311 0.916 E
PRECIP Log of (1 + precipitation) (in mm) 1560 3.932 1.239 0.000 5.949 F

A: PMORALG ( http://lginf.pmoralg.go.tz/lginformation/).
B: Tatem et al. (2013).
C: Computed based on Global Administrative Unit Layers (GAUL).
D: The Center for International Earth Science Information Network (CIESIN) (http://CIESIN.ciesin.columbia.edu/data/set/groads-global-roads-open-access-v1).
E: The National Electoral Commission of Tanzania.
F: The ‘UDel’ precipitation dataset Matsuura and Willmott (2015).
184 T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186

Appendix B. Robustness tests

Table A-2
The Effect of Intergovernmental transfers on local revenue generation using annual fiscal data.

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Models Pooled Pooled IV IV
Subsample Rural Urban Rural Urban
TRANSFER 0.694⁄⁄⁄ 0.500⁄⁄ 1.221⁄⁄⁄ 0.289
(0.154) (0.214) (0.347) (0.666)
POVERTY 2.393⁄⁄⁄ 3.398⁄⁄⁄ 2.308⁄⁄ 3.304⁄⁄
(0.712) (0.887) (0.943) (1.301)
ROAD 0.032 0.218 0.088 0.285
(0.111) (0.153) (0.153) (0.242)
AREA 0.137 0.341⁄⁄⁄ 0.134 0.298
(0.096) (0.112) (0.110) (0.207)
SUPPORT 0.625 1.432 1.044⁄⁄ 1.666
(0.479) (0.929) (0.449) (1.133)
N of observations 312 81 309 81

Notes: The dependent variable here is the annual total amount of local revenues generated by each district and TRANSFER denotes the annual sum of intergovernmental
transfers that each LGA received. For the IV estimation, I used the lagged annual average levels of precipitation as instruments. All the other variables are averaged by year.
Standard errors are clustered by districts and reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Sources: See Table 2.

Table A-3
Results from SGMM estimation controlling for temporal dynamics.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Models SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM
One-Step One-Step One-Step One-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step
DV All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes
Subsample Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban
Seasonal dummies
TRANSFER 0.437⁄⁄⁄ 0.351⁄⁄⁄ 0.184⁄⁄ 0.037 0.463⁄⁄⁄ 0.313⁄⁄ 0.181⁄⁄ 0.040
(0.072) (0.113) (0.044) (0.066) (0.066) (0.144) (0.080) (0.147)
TRANSFERt1 0.117⁄⁄⁄ 0.113 0.176⁄⁄⁄ 0.040 0.118⁄⁄⁄ 0.095 0.169⁄⁄⁄ 0.071
(0.044) (0.106) (0.055) (0.039) (0.039) (0.140) (0.047) (0.279)
Linear time trend
TRANSFER 0.381⁄⁄⁄ 0.330⁄⁄⁄ 0.098 0.021 0.380⁄⁄⁄ 0.311⁄⁄ 0.093 0.041
(0.076) (0.117) (0.069) (0.044) (0.084) (0.137) (0.075) (0.086)
TRANSFERt1 0.079⁄ 0.109 0.100⁄⁄ 0.014 0.088⁄⁄ 0.105 0.088⁄ 0.020
(0.044) (0.104) (0.045) (0.054) (0.041) (0.126) (0.046) (0.129)
Time fixed dummies
TRANSFER 0.395⁄⁄⁄ 0.316⁄⁄ 0.090 0.008 0.398⁄⁄⁄ 0.300 0.088 0.009
(0.075) (0.117) (0.068) (0.047) (0.070) (0.289) (0.081) (0.594)
TRANSFERt1 0.072 0.086 0.087⁄ 0.011 0.081⁄⁄ 0.115 0.081⁄ 0.101
(0.045) (0.104) (0.045) (0.054) (0.034) (0.125) (0.045) (0.344)

Notes: Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. For two-step results, robust standard errors are corrected for finite sample using Windmeijer’s (Windmeijer, 2005)
correction. GMM-style instruments are used in combination with the external instruments. In Models 1–2 and 5–6, DISTANCE is used as an external instrument in addition to
internal GMM instruments while in Models 3–4 and 7–8, the full set of external instruments (DISTANCE; PRECIPt1 , PRECIPt2 , PRECIPt3 ; PRECIPt4 ) and internal GMM
instruments are used. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Sources: See Table 2.

Table A-4
Replication of IV + FE estimation without districts affected by droughts.

Subsample P5% quantile P15% quantile P25% quantile P35% quantile


Models IV + FE IV + FE IV + FE IV + FE
TRANSFER 1.347⁄⁄⁄ 1.451⁄⁄⁄ 2.001⁄⁄ 1.264⁄⁄
(0.381) (0.436) (0.851) (0.524)

Notes: In these regressions, I replicate Models 8 (IV + FE) in Table 2 but exclude those LGAs that experienced climate shocks or droughts in the current or previous fiscal year. A
drought is defined as a district-year rainfall level below the 5%, 15%, 25%, and 35% quantiles of each district’s historical rainfall distribution between 1900 and 2014,
respectively. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Sources: See Table 2.
T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186 185

Table A-5
Results from SGMM estimation, varying instrument set.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Models SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM
One-Step One-Step One-Step One-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step
DV All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes
Subsample Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban
Lag 1 Only
TRANSFER 0.448⁄⁄⁄ 0.370⁄⁄⁄ 0.188⁄⁄ 0.047 0.504⁄⁄⁄ 0.379⁄⁄⁄ 0.204⁄⁄ 0.005
(0.077) (0.115) (0.072) (0.042) (0.102) (0.132) (0.081) (0.127)
TRANSFERt1 0.130⁄⁄⁄ 0.151 0.180⁄⁄⁄ 0.039 0.154⁄⁄⁄ 0.159 0.183⁄⁄⁄ 0.002
(0.046) (0.128) (0.052) (0.052) (0.052) (0.149) (0.051) (0.176)
AR1 (p-value) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.002 0.000 0.059
AR2 (p-value) 0.821 0.988 0.006 0.252 0.869 0.803 0.121 0.441
Hansen J test (p-value) 0.018 0.997 0.072 1.000 0.018 0.997 0.072 1.000
Diff. in Hansen test (p-value) 0.973 1.000 0.488 1.000 0.973 1.000 0.488 1.000
N of Instruments 53 53 67 66 53 53 67 66
Full instrument set
TRANSFER 0.402⁄⁄⁄ 0.360⁄⁄⁄ 0.186⁄⁄ 0.044 0.397⁄⁄⁄ 0.397⁄ 0.194⁄⁄ 0.107
(0.075) (0.106) (0.078) (0.045) (0.079) (0.200) (0.076) (0.133)
TRANSFERt1 0.091⁄ 0.123 0.183⁄⁄⁄ 0.035 0.089⁄ 0.150 0.177⁄⁄⁄ 0.127
(0.047) (0.101) (0.050) (0.055) (0.048) (0.119) (0.050) (0.179)
AR1 (p-value) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.011 0.000 0.061
AR2 (p-value) 0.647 0.579 0.006 0.260 0.679 0.877 0.054 0.283
Hansen J test (p-value) 0.981 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.981 1.000 1.000 1.000
Diff. in Hansen test (p-value) 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
N of Instruments 143 143 157 156 143 143 157 156

Notes: Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. For two-step results, robust standard errors are corrected for finite sample using Windmeijer’s (Windmeijer, 2005)
correction. GMM-style instruments are used in combination with the external instruments. In Models 1–2 and 5–6, DISTANCE is used as an external instrument in addition to
internal GMM instruments while in Models 3–4 and 7–8, the full set of external instruments (DISTANCE; PRECIPt1 ; PRECIPt2 , PRECIPt3 ; PRECIPt4 ) and internal GMM
instruments are used. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Sources: See Table 2.

Table A-6
Results from SGMM estimation, controlling for public service spending (the flypaper effects).

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Models SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM SGMM
One-Step One-Step One-Step One-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step Two-Step
DV All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes All All Excl. Ag. Taxes Excl. Ag. Taxes
Subsample Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban
Accounting for the Flypaper Effects
TRANSFER 0.318⁄⁄⁄ 0.350⁄⁄ 0.188⁄⁄⁄ 0.031 0.328⁄⁄⁄ 0.449⁄⁄ 0.191⁄⁄⁄ 0.030
(0.076) (0.127) (0.070) (0.037) (0.075) (0.189) (0.072) (0.183)
TRANSFERt1 0.110⁄⁄ 0.170 0.159⁄⁄⁄ 0.012 0.112⁄⁄ 0.307 0.164⁄⁄⁄ 0.114
(0.053) (0.125) (0.052) (0.064) (0.053) (0.227) (0.052) (0.272)
PUBLIC SERVICE SPENDING 0.120⁄⁄ 0.039 0.001 0.038 0.118⁄⁄ 0.116 0.009 0.026
(0.049) (0.061) (0.039) (0.030) (0.051) (0.127) (0.041) (0.079)
PUBLIC SERVICE SPENDINGt1 0.004 0.037 0.024 0.026 0.006 0.036 0.024 0.042
(0.033) (0.046) (0.034) (0.023) (0.034) (0.077) (0.034) (0.192)

Notes: Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. For two-step results, robust standard errors are corrected for finite sample using Windmeijer’s (Windmeijer, 2005)
correction. GMM-style instruments are used in combination with the external instruments. In Models 1–2 and 5–6, DISTANCE is used as an external instrument in addition to
internal GMM instruments while in Models 3–4 and 7–8, the full set of external instruments (DISTANCE; PRECIPt1 ; PRECIPt2 , PRECIPt3 ; PRECIPt4 ) and internal GMM
instruments are used. PUBLIC SERVICE SPENDING includes all public spending except on local administrative costs. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Bellemare, M. F., Masaki, T., & Pepinsky, T. B. (2017). Lagged explanatory variables
References and the estimation of causal effects. Journal of Politics, 79(3), 949–963.
Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2013). Taxation and development. In A. J. Auerbach, R.
Aikaeli, J. (2010). Determinants of rural income in Tanzania: An empirical approach. Chetty, M. Feldstein, & E. Saez (Eds.). Handbook of Public Economics (Vol. 5).
Research on Poverty Alleviation (REPOA) Research Report 10/4. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Aiko, R. (2013, 7). Do I have to pay tax? Citizens’ awareness of their tax obligations in Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in
Tanzania. Afrobarometer Briefing Paper 69. dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.
Ali, M., O.-H. Fjeldstad, & I.H. Sjursen (2013). To pay or not to pay? Citizens’ attitudes Bodea, C., & LeBas, A. (2016). The origins of voluntary compliance: Attitudes toward
towards taxation in Kenya, Tanzania, Uganda and South Africa. Afrobarometer taxation in urban Nigeria. British Journal of Political Science, 46(1), 215–238.
Working Paper 143. Boex, J., & Martinez-Vazquez, J. (2006). Local government finance reform in developing
Allers, M. A., & Ishemoi, L. J. (2011). Do formulas reduce political influence on countries: The case of Tanzania. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire: Palgrave
intergovernmental grants? Evidence from Tanzania. Journal of Development Macmillan.
Studies, 47(12), 1781–1797. Bradford, D. F., & Oates, W. E. (1971a). The analysis of revenue sharing in a new
Atunbas, Y., & Thornton, J. (2012). Fiscal decentralization and governance. Public approach to collective fiscal decisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85(3),
Finance Review, 4(1), 66–85. 416–439.
Bahl, R. (2000). Intergovernmental transfers in developing and transition countries: Bradford, D. F., & Oates, W. E. (1971b). Towards a predictive theory of
Principles and practice. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. intergovernmental grants. American Economic Review, 61(2), 440–448.
Bahl, R., & Bird, R. (2008). Subnational taxes in developing countries: The way Brollo, F., Nannicini, T., Perotti, R., & Tabellini, G. (2013). The political resource curse.
forward. Public Budgeting & Finance, 28(4), 1–25. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1759–1796.
Bates, R. H. (1981). Markets and states in tropical Africa: The political basis of Brun, J.-F. & M.E. Khdari (2016). The incentive effects of conditional and
agricultural policies. Berkeley: University of California Press. unconditional transfers on local own revenue generation: Empirical evidence
186 T. Masaki / World Development 106 (2018) 173–186

from moroccan municipalities. CERDI. Retrieved from < http://cerdi.org/ Murtin, F., & Wacziarg, R. (2014). The democratic transition. Journal of Economic
production/show/id/1790/typeproductionid/1>. Growth, 19, 141–181.
Buettner, T., & Wildasin, D. E. (2006). The dynamics of municipal fiscal adjustment. Nord, R., Sobolev, Y., Dunn, D., Hajdenberg, A., Hobdari, N., Maziad, S., & Roudet, S.
Journal of Public Economics, 90, 1115–1132. (2009). Tanzania: The story of an African transition. International Monetary Fund.
Burke, M., Gong, E., & Jones, K. (2015). Income shocks and HIV in Africa. The < https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/books/2009/tanzania/tanzania.pdf>.
Economic Journal, 125(585), 1157–1189. Nyange, D., Tschirley, D., Nassoro, H., & Gaspar, A. (2014). Agricultural produce cess in
Caldeira, E., & Rota-Graziosi, G. (2014). The crowding-in effect of simple Tanzania: Policy options for fiscal reforms. Food Security and Cooperatives:
unconditional central grants on local own-source revenue: The case of Benin. PMORALG and Ministry of Agriculture.
Journal of African Economies, 23(3), 361–387. Olken, B. A. (2007). Monitoring corruption: Evidence from a field experiment in
Cochran, T.H., D.L. Bond, B. Sheppard, & B. Samuels (2009). Financing Local Indonesia. Journal of Political Economy, 115(2), 200–249.
Infrastructures: Part One Report—The Tanzania Environmental Scan. Report PMORALG (2002). Formative process research on the local government reform
prepared for the United Nations Capital Development Fund. programme in Tanzania. < http://www.repoa.or.tz/documentsstorage/Research>.
Crook, R. C. (2003). Decentralisation and poverty reduction in Africa: The politics of PMORALG (2008, November). Local government development grant system: Manual
local–central relations. Public Administration and Development, 23, 77–88. for the assessment of councils against minimum conditions and performance
Dafflon, B., & Madies, T. (2013). The political economy of decentralization in Sub- measurement criteria. The Prime Minister’s Office Regional Administration and
Saharan Africa: A new implementation model in burkina faso, ghana, kenya, and Local Government (PMORALG), Dodoma, Tanzania.
senegal. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. PMORALG (2013). A study on LGAs’ Own source revenue collection.http://www.
Dahlberg, M., Mork, E., Rattso, J., & Agren, H. (2008). Using a discontinous grant rule pmoralg.go.tz.
to identify the effect of grants on local taxes and spending. Journal of Public PMORALG (2015). Tanzania osaka alumni: Best practices hand book 2. The Prime
Economics, 92, 2320–2335. Minister’s Office Regional Administration and Local Government (PMORALG),
Enemu, F. C. (2000). Problems and prospects of local governance. In G. Hyden, D. Dodoma, Tanzania.
Olowu, & H. Ogendo (Eds.), African Perspectives of Governance (pp. 181–204). Reinikka, R., & Svensson, J. (2005). Fighting corruption to improve schooling:
Trenton/Asmara: Africa World Press. Evidence from a newspaper campaign in Uganda. Journal of the European
Fjeldstad, O.-H. (2001). Taxation, coercion and donors: Local government tax Economic Association, 3(2/3), 259–267.
enforcement in Tanzania. Journal of Modern African Studies, 39(2), 289–306. Resnick, D. (2012). Opposition parties and the urban poor in African democracies.
Fjeldstad, O.-H., G. Chambas, & J.-F. Brun (2014). Local government taxation in sub- Comparative Political Studies, 45(11), 1351–1378.
Saharan Africa. CMI Working Paper 2014:2, Norway. Resnick, D. (2014). Urban governance and service delivery in African cities: The role
Fjeldstad, O.-H. and K. Heggstad (2012). Local government revenue mobilization in of politics and policies. Development Policy Review, 32(S1), S3–S17.
Anglophone Africa. CMI Working Paper, Norway. Roodman, D. (2007). A short note on the theme of too many instruments. Center for
Fjeldstad, O.-H., L. Katera, J. Msami, & E. Ngalewa (2010). Local government finances Global Development Working Paper 125, Washington, D.C.
and financial management in Tanzania: Empirical evidence of trends 2000– Roodman, D. (2009). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system
2007. REPOA Special Paper No. 10-2010, Dar es Salaam. GMM in stata. The Stata Journal, 9(1), 86–136.
Fjeldstad, O.-H., & Semboja, J. (2001). Why people pay taxes: The case of the Rosen, H. S. (2005). Public finance (7 ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill Irwin.
development levy in Tanzania. World Development, 29(12), 2059–2074. Rosenzweig, S. C. (2015). Does electoral competition affect public goods provision in
Gadenne, L. (2012). Tax me, but spend wisely: The political economy of taxes, evidence dominant-party regimes? Evidence from Tanzania. Electoral Studies, 39, 72–84.
from Brazilian local governments. Working Paper, Paris School of Economics. Sanoh, A. (2015). Rainfall shocks, local revenues, and intergovernmental transfer in
Gisselquist, R. M., Leiderer, S., & Nino-Zarazúa, M. (2016). Ethnic heterogeneity and Mali. World Development, 66, 359–370.
public goods provision in Zambia: Evidence of a subnational diversity dividend. Sarzin, Z. & Raich, U. (2012). Financing the urban expansion in Tanzania. Urban
World Development, 78, 308–323. Development Series Knowledge Papers 14, Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Goldman, M. J., Daly, M., & Lovell, E. J. (2016). Exploring multiple ontologies of Scott, Z. (2009). Decentralization, local development and social cohesion: An analytical
drought in agro-pastoral regions of Northern Tanzania: A topological approach. review. Governance and Social Development Resource Center (GSDRC) Research
Area, 48(1), 27–33. Paper, Birmingham.
Heckelman, J. C., & Wilson, B. (2014). Interest groups and the rise and decline of Shah, A. (2006). A practitioner’s guide to intergovernmental fiscal transfers. World
growth. Southern Economic Journal, 81(2), 435–456. Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4039, Washington, D.C.
Hines, J., & Thaler, R. (1995). The flypaper effect. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9, Skidmore, M. (1999). Tax and expenditure limitations and the fiscal relationships
217–226. between state and local governments. Public Choice, 99, 77–102.
Hoffman, B. D., & Gibson, C. C. (2005). Fiscal governance and public services: Evidence Stasavage, D. (2005). Democracy and education spending in Africa. American Journal
from Tanzania and Zambia. San Diego: University of California. of Political Science, 49(2), 343–358.
IEG (2008). Decentralization in client countries: An evaluation of World Bank Support Tanzania Ministry of Finance (2011). Guidelines for the Preparation of Plan and Budget
1990–2007. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. for 2011/12 within the Five Year Development Plan Framework. Dar es Salaam:
Ilzetzki, E., Mendoza, E. G., & Veǵh, C. A. (2013). How big (small?) are fiscal Tanzania Ministry of Finance.
multipliers? Journal of Monetary Economics, 60(2), 239–254. Tatem, A. J., Gething, P. W., Bhatt, S., Weiss, D., & Pezzulo, C. (2013). Pilot high
Iversen, V., Fjeldstad, O.-H., Bahiigwa, G., Ellis, F., & James, R. (2006). Private tax resolution poverty maps. Oxford: University of Southampton.
collection: Remnant of the past or a way forward? Evidence from rural Uganda. Tendler, J. (1997). Good Government in the Tropics. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
Public Administration and Development, 26, 317–328. University Press.
Kasara, K. (2007). Tax me if you can: Ethnic geography, democracy, and the taxation The National Audit Office of Tanzania (2014). Annual general report of the controller
of agriculture in Africa. American Political Science Review, 101(1), 159–172. and auditor general: On the financial statements of local government authorities for
Keele, L., & Kelly, N. J. (2006). Dynamic models for dynamic theories: The ins and the financial year ended 30th June, 2013. The United Republic of Tanzania
outs of lagged dependent variables. Political Analysis, 14, 186–205. National Audit Office.
Kjaer, A. M. (2005). Accountability and the graduated tax in Uganda. Prepared for the Therkildsen, O. (1993). Legitimacy, local governments and natural resource
2nd Meeting on Fiscal Decentralization. Copenhagen: Kommunernes management in sub-Saharan Africa. Occasional Paper 9, International
Landsforening. Development Studies, Roskilde University, Denmark.
Lambright, G. M. S. (2014). Opposition politics and urban service delivery in Tripp, A. M. (2013). Donor assistance and political reform in Tanzania. In D. Resnick
Kampala, Uganda. Development Policy Review, 32(S1), S39–S60. & N. van de Walle (Eds.), Democratic Trajectories in Africa: Unravelling the Impact
Lipton, M. (1971). Why poor people stay poor: Urban bias in world development. of Foreign Aid. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Troland, E. (2014). Can fiscal transfers increase local revenue collection? evidence from
Lund, J. F. (2007). Is small beautiful? Village level taxation of natural resources in the philippines, Job Market Paper. San Diego: University of California.
Tanzania. Public Administration and Development, 27(4), 307–318. UNICEF (2012). Cities and children: The challenge of urbanisation in Tanzania. Dar es
Majumdar, S., Mani, A., & Mukand, S. W. (2004). Politics, information and the urban Salaam, Tanzania: United Nations Children’s Fund.
bias. Journal of Development Economics, 75(1), 137–165. Venugopal, V., & Yilmaz, S. (2010). Decentralization in Tanzania: An assessment of
Matsuura, K. and C.J. Willmott (2015). Terrestrial air temperature and precipitation: local government discretion and accountability. Public Administration and
1900–2014 gridded time series (version 4.01).http://climate.geog.udel. Development, 30, 215–231.
edu/climate/htmlpages/download.html#T2014. Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient
McCluskey, W. J., & Franzsen, R. (2005). An evaluation of the property tax in two-step gmm estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25–51.
Tanzania: An untapped fiscal resource or administrative headache? Property World Bank (2006). Local government taxation reform in Tanzania: A Poverty and
Management, 23(1), 43–69. Social Impact Analysis (PSIA). Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Mogues, T., & Benin, S. (2012). Do external grants to district governments Zhang, G. (2013). The impacts of intergovernmental transfers on local governments’
discourage own revenue generation? A look at local public finance dynamics fiscal behavior in China: A cross-country analysis. Australian Journal of Public
in Ghana. World Development, 40(5), 1054–1067. Administration, 72(3), 264–277.
Moss, T., Pettersson, G., & van de Walle, N. (2006). An aid-institution paradox? A Zhuravskaya, E. V. (2000). Incentives to provide local public goods: Fiscal
review essay on aid dependency and state building in sub-Saharan Africa. Center federalism, russian style. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 337–368.
for Global Development Working Paper 74, Washington, D.C.

You might also like