You are on page 1of 8

 > Free Law Essays > International Law

Disclaimer: This work has been submitted by a law student. This is not an example of the work
produced by our Law Essay Writing Service. You can view samples of our professional work
here.

Any opinions, findings, conclusions or recommendations expressed in this material are those of
the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of LawTeacher.net.

Share this:       

At the time of its birth in 1995, there were great expectations for the future of the WTO and its role in
the governance of the global economy. For the first time ever, the global trade regime now had a firm
legal foundation, a strong organisational basis, and an effective dispute settlement mechanism to
ensure the enforcement of multilateral trade rules and disciplines. But this optimism has proved to be
misplaced and the multilateral trade regime has been subjected to immense pressures and strains
since the late 1990s (Michalopoulos, 1999; Kessie, 1999).This paper briefly discusses the role of
WTO. What are the strengths and weaknesses of the WTO system? Do its core rules, principles and
dispute settlement procedures fairly reflect the interests of developed and developing countries?

When we look at GATT and the WTO historically, the only major trade liberalization achievement has
had been the reduction of (most) industrial tariffs in industrial countries over five decades. In
addition, the WTO scored some success eleven years ago in telecoms and financial services.
Countries acceding to the WTO have had to liberalize considerably as part of the entry price
(Srinivasan, 1999). But in agriculture and services, the record is modest, and developing countries in
general have liberalized very little on the altar of the WTO.

By contrast, the WTO is the unique supplier of the global public good of universal rules. This includes
rules about market access in the form of tariff bindings and all the other rules that entail
precommitment in policy behavior, generating greater certainty and a richer information environment.
The rules also reduce power asymmetry between strong and weak or large and small players.
Perhaps we have not done enough to emphasize the WTO’s rule-making role. The image of an
institution hell-bent on prizing open markets has been dominant, weakening the WTO’s legitimacy in
the minds of many critics. This is not an argument against liberalization—far from it but rather a
comment on the balance of the message, the WTO’s public image, and therefore the effectiveness of
the institution.

A danger, of course, is that the WTO could begin to look more like a “talk shop” than a place to


conduct substantive trade policy business.
  This
 isa matter
 ofbalance,
 and it would be important to
ensure that dialogue did not replace a negotiating agenda nor blunt commitment to effective dispute
settlement. The benefits that enhanced dialogue could bring are essentially twofold. First, it would
improve the knowledge base for informed decisions and discussions on trade policy. Information
and data are simply lacking in a wide range of areas, and improving this situation in the context of
an engagement in dialogue could make a contribution to enhanced cooperation and increased
welfare. And, second, dialogue promotes understanding and sensitizes parties to the needs, priorities,
and perspectives of their counterparts. To the extent that this occurs, it will help to shape the
contours of cooperation and increase the likelihood of mutually beneficial outcomes. This idea is not
entirely novel in GATT and the WTO.

In 2008, global trade grew by 2 percent in volume, but the WTO expects it to fall by 9 percent in 2009
—the biggest contraction in trade since World War II (WTO press release, 2009). Whereas most
members of the WTO appear to have kept the worst domestic protectionist pressures under control,
there is growing evidence of countries adopting, or threatening to adopt, trade-restricting or trade
distorting measures to protect key national businesses and jobs. For some scholars and
practitioners, the current financial crisis questions the utility of the WTO in addressing its elements.
While recognizing the primacy of the financial crisis, the articles in this special issue resist the
assertion of irrelevance. Rather, we would suggest that the financial crisis throws into sharp relief
some of the issues that the WTO needs to address if it is to remain relevant in the twenty-first
century. Specifically, are WTO rules sufficient to withstand the pressures for retaliation that will ensue
if domestic protectionist policies are enacted? This is particularly important given the increasingly
hidden or murky nature of much contemporary protectionism. It thus becomes all the more important
for the WTO to reach agreement on the Doha Round (Srinivasan, 1999).

The new welfare gains from the Doha Round may not be massive, but the need to lock them and
stop previous reforms from being reversed is crucial to the health of the trade system coming out of
the economic crisis if trade is to be an important spur to recovery. In addition, the health of the WTO
remains an important indicator of the prospects for cooperative multilateralism in the twenty-first
century more generally. When the global economic crisis eventually bottoms out, as we should
assume it will, the longer-standing issues of the governance of, and the disciplinary remit of, theWTO
will still need to be addressed. Given the importance of trade liberalization operating under a rules-
based system to the enhancement of aggregate global economic welfare, the role of theWTO will
axiomatically regain any salience it has been judged to have lost in the heat of the 2008–2009 crisis.
It is the longer-term issues that are central themes of this issue of Global Governance (WTO press
release, 2009)…

Variable Geometry and Possibilities for Special and Differential Treatment and the Push to


Operationalize

Special and differential treatment in the WTO is premised on the notion that developing country

members has different needs than developed country members, and that WTO disciplines should be
      
modified to reflect those different needs. In particular, many developing countries face difficulties in
implementing the WTO agreements, dealing with the adjustment costs of trade liberalization, and
engaging in international trade to reap the full benefits of WTO membership.4 Thus, the preamble to
the Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization recognized that “there is need
for positive efforts designed to ensure that developing countries, and especially the least developed
among them, secure a share in the growth in international trade commensurate with the needs of
their economic development.” (Meredith, 2007) Paragraph 2 of the Doha declaration reiterated this
and confirmed that “in this context, enhanced market access, balanced rules, and well targeted,
sustainably financed technical assistance and capacity-building programmes have important roles
to play” (Meredith, 2007)

Special and differential treatment takes a range of forms throughout the WTO agreements. The WTO
secretariat has identified six categories of special and differential treatment provisions in the WTO
agreements. Although these categories overlap and are somewhat arbitrary, they provide a useful
way of classifying and assessing the provisions. (Kessie, 1999) The categories are:

1. Provisions aimed at increasing the trade opportunities of developing country members, such as
the exemption from the most-favored-nation rule for developed country members providing
preferential tariff treatment to products from developing country members pursuant to Generalized
System of Preferences (GSP) schemes. (Kessie, 2002)

2. Provisions under which WTO members should safeguard the interests of developing country
members, such as the requirement that members explore the possibility of constructive remedies8
before imposing antidumping duties on developing country members. (Kessie, 2002)

3. Flexibility of commitments and actions, and use of policy instruments, such as the understanding
that developed country members “do not expect reciprocity for commitments made by them in trade
negotiations to reduce or remove tariffs and other barriers to trade” of developing country members
(socalled nonreciprocity). (Kessie, 2002)

4. Transitional time periods. For example, the prohibition on import substitution subsidies does not
apply to developing countries for five years or to Least Developed Countries (LDCs) for eight years
from the creation of the WTO.

5. Technical assistance, such as assistance from the WTO secretariat and developed country WTO
members in implementing WTO rules.

6. Provisions relating to LDC members (which also fall within one of the other categories). For
example, members agree to exercise “due restraint” in bringing dispute settlement actions against
LDC members (Kessie, 2002).



Given the long-standing recognition of the different needs and interests of developing countries in
the WTO, and the inclusion of a broad range of special and differential treatment provisions in most
 special
if not all WTO agreements, why does     
and differential  need to be operationalized in
treatment
the sense of making them more workable? The 2007Warwick Commission report identified the two
most important answers. First, most of the existing provisions are merely aspirational, vague, or
unenforceable. Second, they do not adequately reflect the differences among developing countries
(and LDCs) in the WTO, (Meredith, 2007) which includes Brazil, China, Barbados, Bangladesh, and,
most recently, Cape Verde. WTO members and others have long lamented these two key problems. A
third, perhaps more controversial, reason for operationalizing special and differential treatment is to
redress the unbalanced outcome of the Uruguay Round, whereby developing countries are typically
seen as having given more than they received. (Meredith, 2007)

For these and related reasons, the push to operationalize special and differential treatment has come
from a number of sources, including the WTO itself, as noted above. Most recently, the Warwick
Commission recommended that “efforts be redoubled to design clear, concrete [special and
differential treatment] provisions based on solid analysis of development needs and cognisant of the
reality that differing needs among developing countries call for differentiated measures,” although it
did not indicate specifically how this should be achieved. In any case, neither special and differential
treatment nor its Operationalization is a panacea for developing countries in the WTO.

Critical Mass Approaches to WTO Obligations

Some argue that the consensus rule in WTO rule making frustrates work, makes it harder to ensure
that the WTO agenda can keep up with the times, and favors an excessively status quo and lowest-
common-denominator approach to decisions in the WTO, especially but not only in relation to
questions of agenda formation. Others argue that the linkage between consensus and the Uruguay
Round-style “single undertaking” resulted in over commitment among many WTO members,
engendering resistance to any further extension of the WTO agenda (Finger, 2002). According to this
view, the single undertaking experience poisoned the atmosphere in the debate over the Singapore
issues, and led to their rejection (except trade facilitation) on grounds that were independent of any
serious consideration of their merit.

The removal of veto power through a relaxation of consensus via critical mass decision making and
acceptance of an additional degree of variable geometry under WTO rules are not strictly the same
thing (Finger, 2002). Consensus decision making could still be required while less than the full
membership accepted new obligations. Alternatively, critical mass agreements could be legitimized
by decisions among those parties accepting new obligations, with no veto rights on the part of those
who are not accepting new obligations. In the latter case, critical mass applies both to defining the
obligations in a new policy area for a subset of the membership as well as to decisions about the
outcome and its adoption.


For any consideration of this more varied approach to defining the functions of the multilateral
trading system, the point at which veto rights disappear is vital. For those with an interest in
developing the WTO agenda, the argument might well be that those taking on new obligations
should also be allowed to decide what  WTO
is in the  andwhat is out,
 provided the interests of all
WTO parties are protected (Finger, 2002). For those who eschew agenda expansion, or value their
veto for reasons other than the particular issue at hand, the argument may well be that agreements
adding obligations for some and rights for all could in principle go ahead, but that any decision even
to start negotiating, or about the adoption of results, would still have to be taken on a consensus
basis. This is the nub of the issue when it comes to designing new ways of ensuring the WTO’s
relevance while protecting the rights of all members. This is a core issue for the future functioning of
the WTO.

Dispute Settlements within WTO

The Dispute Settlement Mechanism (DSM) of the World Trade Organization (WTO), which is
officially known as the Dispute Settlement Understanding (DSU), has been in place since January 1,
1995 (Finger, 2002). Its introduction was hailed as “the victory of law over politics” in international
trade. Within the more specific context of the WTO, several studies have tackled the question of the
distributional effects of the WTO dispute settlement system, mainly focusing on the status of
developing countries after the introduction of the new system (Michalopoulos, 1999; Kessie, 1999).
However, these studies seldom go beyond fact-finding, and they are usually too narrowly focused on
specific sectors or not well organized to test general hypotheses. It is a debatable whether legal
arrangements of international relations favor stronger/richer powers or weaker/poorer powers. Some
scholars have argued that legalization will favor weaker actors in disputes, for strictly binding rules
and procedures can protect the weak from the arbitrary use of power by the strong (Whalley, 1996).

As Cameron and Campbell (1998, p. 57) contend, resolving disputes through a judicial route is
“particularly beneficial for smaller countries, as without the rules and procedures of the DSU and the
extensive obligations in the WTO agreements, they would not have the necessary bargaining power
vis-à-vis the larger powers (Srinivasan, 1999).” Some observers of the Uruguay Round (UR)
negotiations, which led to the establishment of the WTO and the introduction of the DSU, also
confirm that ‘redressing the strong’ was one of the prime goals for developing countries. “It was the
negotiating objective of developing countries to press for the adoption of measures that would
strengthen the multilateral trading system and enhance its capability to act as a bulwark against
protectionism, bilateralism, and unilateralism” (Kessie, 1999, pp. 98–99). In addition to redressing the
strong, the dispute settlement mechanism of the WTO can help weaker/poorer states by reducing the
costs of monitoring the member states’ trade practices, which had usually been too high for them
(Sevilla, 1998; Hoekman and Mavroidis, 2000). Compared to the GATT system, they claim that the
new WTO system has introduced certain innovations in the monitoring mechanism that reflect
developing countries’ interests, such as the Trade Policy Review Mechanism (TPRM). Thus, as long
as a certain level of independence in the legal mechanisms is guaranteed, the legal arrangement for


dispute resolution, compared to a purely power-based bargaining mechanism, is likely to produce
more equal outcomes among the actors, mitigating power/wealth disparities. These perspectives 
correspond to the analogy of “domestic law” where the rule of law prevails over power (Lindblom,
      
1977; Weil, 1983), and their proponents maintain that international legal mechanisms possess a
strong normative quality (Frank, 1995).

Developing countries usually have few legal resources available for complaining or defending
disputes under the legal system (Kim Van Der Borght, 1999; Michalopoulos, 1999; Reinhardt, 1999).
According to this logic, the lack of financial capacity, personnel, and information for legal activities
inevitably results in unfavorable outcomes for developing countries. Another inherent disadvantage
against developing countries is the asymmetry in enforcement capability. Although the WTO
introduced strictly binding rules and procedures in the litigation, the panel/appellate body decisions
are supposed to be implemented on a bilateral basis. Even when a powerful state does not comply
with panel decisions, the retaliation option (suspension of concessions or retaliatory sanctions) is
not viable for a weaker state in many cases due to a lack of enforcement power at the retaliation
stage (Hoekman and Mavroidis, 2000). In addition, many developing countries are exposed to the
direct and indirect threat of negative issue-linkages. In other words, their initiation of legal actions
may trigger harsh countersuits immediately, or may create negative consequences to aid programs
or security relationships, both of which are powerful instruments for stronger states.

Conclusion

The WTO judiciary has enhanced its control over WTO disputes in order to better adjudicate trade
controversies. Th e strengthening of this control is evidenced by the increasing fact-finding powers
that the WTO judiciary enjoys today and in the freedom to develop legal argumentations apart from
those exposed by parties during dispute settlement proceedings. While these are the centre pieces of
this project, there are also isolated and timid attempts that, although they do not express a deliberate
intention to expand such control over the complaining parties’ right to set the terms of reference,
have had the effect of attenuating this right by allowing the WTO judiciary to adjudicate disputes
slightly beyond the terms of reference when to do so has been necessary in order to provide a proper
resolution to the conflict (Srinivasan, 1999). WTO judiciary could assume more control over disputes
in which developing and least developed countries are complainants against developed ones in order
to rule on claims not included in the terms of reference originally established. Two conditions must
be met to ensure a lawful adjudication of such a claim by a panel: first, the developing country
complaining Member must adopt the claim later in panel proceedings; and second, the panel must
ensure the developed country respondent sufficient opportunity to respond in facts and law to such
new claim.

Share this:       


 > Free Law Essays > International Law

      
We Write Bespoke Law Essays!

Find Out More

SERVICES

Law Essay Writing Service

Law Dissertation Writing Service

Law Assignment Writing Service

All Law Services

USEFUL RESOURCES

Law Essays

Case Summaries

Act Summaries

Problem Questions

OSCOLA Referencing Tool

LLM Resources

Law Help

Study Modules

COMPANY

About

Fair Use Policy




        Order   
Complaints
Help Centre

Become a Researcher

Part of All Answers Ltd

  

Copyright © 2003 - 2020 - LawTeacher is a trading name of All Answers Ltd, a company registered in England and Wales.
Company Registration No: 4964706. VAT Registration No: 842417633. Registered Data Controller No: Z1821391. Registered
office: Venture House, Cross Street, Arnold, Nottingham, Nottinghamshire, NG5 7PJ.

Privacy Policy

Terms & Conditions

Cookies



      

You might also like