You are on page 1of 11

This article was downloaded by: [158.42.28.

33] On: 12 January 2015, At: 04:05


Publisher: Institute for Operations Research and the Management Sciences (INFORMS)
INFORMS is located in Maryland, USA

Marketing Science
Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://pubsonline.informs.org

Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of


Interaction Effects
Prasad A. Naik, Kalyan Raman, Russell S. Winer,

To cite this article:


Prasad A. Naik, Kalyan Raman, Russell S. Winer, (2005) Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction
Effects. Marketing Science 24(1):25-34. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1040.0083

Full terms and conditions of use: http://pubsonline.informs.org/page/terms-and-conditions

This article may be used only for the purposes of research, teaching, and/or private study. Commercial use
or systematic downloading (by robots or other automatic processes) is prohibited without explicit Publisher
approval, unless otherwise noted. For more information, contact permissions@informs.org.

The Publisher does not warrant or guarantee the article’s accuracy, completeness, merchantability, fitness
for a particular purpose, or non-infringement. Descriptions of, or references to, products or publications, or
inclusion of an advertisement in this article, neither constitutes nor implies a guarantee, endorsement, or
support of claims made of that product, publication, or service.

© 2005 INFORMS

Please scroll down for article—it is on subsequent pages

INFORMS is the largest professional society in the world for professionals in the fields of operations research, management
science, and analytics.
For more information on INFORMS, its publications, membership, or meetings visit http://www.informs.org
informs ®
Vol. 24, No. 1, Winter 2005, pp. 25–34
issn 0732-2399  eissn 1526-548X  05  2401  0025 doi 10.1287/mksc.1040.0083
© 2005 INFORMS

Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the


Presence of Interaction Effects
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

Prasad A. Naik
University of California Davis, 1 Shields Avenue, Davis, California 95616, panaik@ucdavis.edu

Kalyan Raman
Loughborough Business School, Loughborough University, Ashby Road, Loughborough,
Leicestershire, United Kingdom LE11 3TU, k.raman@lboro.ac.uk

Russell S. Winer
Stern School of Business, New York University, 44 West 4th Street, New York, New York 10012, rwiner@stern.nyu.edu

C ompanies spend millions of dollars on advertising to boost a brand’s image and simultaneously spend
millions of dollars on promotion that many believe calls attention to price and erodes brand equity. We
believe this paradoxical situation exists because both advertising and promotion are necessary to compete effec-
tively in dynamic markets. Consequently, brand managers need to account for interactions between marketing
activities and interactions among competing brands. By recognizing interaction effects between activities, man-
agers can consider interactivity trade-offs in planning the marketing-mix strategies. On the other hand, by
recognizing interactions with competitors, managers can incorporate strategic foresight in their planning, which
requires them to look forward and reason backward in making optimal decisions. Looking forward means that
each brand manager anticipates how other competing brands are likely to make future decisions, and then by
reasoning backward deduces one’s own optimal decisions in response to the best decisions to be made by all
other brands. The joint consideration of interaction effects and strategic foresight in planning marketing-mix
strategies is a challenging and unsolved marketing problem, which motivates this paper.
This paper investigates the problem of planning marketing mix in dynamic competitive markets. We extend
the Lanchester model by incorporating interaction effects, constructing the marketing-mix algorithm that yields
marketing-mix plans with strategic foresight, and developing the continuous-discrete estimation method to
calibrate dynamic models of oligopoly using market data. Both the marketing-mix algorithm and the estimation
method are general, so they can be applied to any other alternative model specifications for dynamic oligopoly
markets. Thus, this dual methodology augments the decision-making toolkit of managers, empowering them to
tackle realistic marketing problems in dynamic oligopoly markets.
We illustrate the application of this dual methodology by studying the dynamic Lanchester competition across
five brands in the detergents market, where each brand uses advertising and promotion to influence its own
market share and the shares of competing brands. Empirically, we find that advertising and promotion not only
affect the brand shares (own and competitors’) but also exert interaction effects, i.e., each activity amplifies or
attenuates the effectiveness of the other activity. Normatively, we find that large brands underadvertise and
overspend on promotion, while small brands underadvertise and underpromote. Finally, comparative statics
reveal managerial insights into how a specific brand should respond optimally to the changes in a competing
brand’s situation; more generally, we find evidence that competitive responsiveness is asymmetric.
Key words: continuous-discrete estimation; dynamic competition; interaction effects; marketing-mix planning;
strategic foresight; two-point boundary value problem
History: This paper was received June 19, 2001, and was with the authors 14 months for 4 revisions; processed
by William Boulding.

1. Introduction Mantrala 2002 for literature review). In the extant lit-


American corporations collectively spend over $500 erature, dynamic planning models such as Naik et al.
billion on marketing activities; even individual com- (1998) and Silva-Risso et al. (1999) provide decision-
support tools to determine advertising schedules and
panies such as Procter and Gamble spend several bil-
promotional calendars, respectively. These decision-
lion dollars on advertising and promotion. Conse- support models, however, ignore the game-theoretic
quently, the optimal allocation of marketing resources principle of strategic foresight, a notion that requires
to multiple activities—referred to as “planning the the brand manager to look forward, i.e., anticipate how
marketing mix”—is of paramount importance (see other competing brands are likely to make future
25
Naik, Raman, and Winer: Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects
26 Marketing Science 24(1), pp. 25–34, © 2005 INFORMS

decisions, and then reason backward, i.e., deduce one’s To help answer such questions, we develop two
own optimal decisions in response to the best deci- methods: (i) a marketing-mix algorithm to plan opti-
sions to be made by all other brands. On the other mal marketing-mix strategies and (ii) an estimation
hand, dynamic game-theoretic models that advo- method to determine the effectiveness of marketing
cate strategic foresight ignore the role of interactions activities and their interaction effects for each brand
among multiple marketing activities. Such interac- in dynamic competitive markets.
tions are central to the marketing-mix concept, which The proposed marketing-mix algorithm solves the
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

“   emphasizes that marketing efforts create sales syn- multiple-player differential game resulting from the
ergistically rather than independently” (see Gatignon dynamic models of oligopoly markets. Specifically,
and Hanssens 1987, p. 247; Lilien et al. 1992, p. 5; also it yields optimal marketing-mix strategies that are
see Gatignon 1993 for a literature review). (a) in equilibrium across multiple brands and over
The joint consideration of both strategic foresight time, (b) accounts for intertemporal trade-offs across
and interaction effects in dynamic response models multiple periods (i.e., now versus later), and (c) bal-
represents an important gap in the marketing litera- ances interactivity trade-off among multiple market-
ture. For example, Fruchter and Kalish (1998, p. 22) ing activities (e.g., advertising versus promotion).
acknowledge Because this algorithm solves a general nonlinear
two-point boundary value problem, its applicability
“   the limitations of current studies [not] to take into extends to several differential game models in mar-
account the interactions among the different instru- keting, not only the Lanchester model that we present
ments. A challenge which we see for a future direction for the sake of exposition (see Remark 2 for details). In
is to develop a model which incorporates interactions addition, it furnishes both the open-loop and closed-
between promotional instruments.”
loop marketing-mix strategies (see the unabridged
The challenging problems arise for the following manuscript, which is available from the authors upon
two reasons. First, as we show later, in the presence of request).
interaction effects, the optimal plans for all activities The proposed estimation method calibrates a simul-
are interdependent, thereby requiring managers to taneous system of coupled differential equations that
account for the interactivity trade-offs in budget allo- arise in the differential game competition in an
cations. In other words, the optimal level to spend on oligopoly. We note that standard time-series tech-
advertising depends on the optimal level to spend on niques are applicable for discrete-time difference
equations (e.g., ARIMA-type models; see Blattberg
promotion (and vice versa). Second, managers need
and Neslin 1990, Ch. 9) but not for continuous-
to know the joint effectiveness of marketing activi-
time models based on differential equations. Hence,
ties of all other brands to be able to determine their
we develop an estimation approach for estimating
own optimal marketing-mix plans. This demands a
continuous-time models using discrete-time observed
new methodology for estimating dynamic models
data (e.g., weekly). Specifically, this approach pro-
of oligopoly markets using market data. Thus, both
vides maximum-likelihood estimates and standard
the substantive problems—the determination of opti-
errors that incorporate (a) the temporal dependence
mal marketing-mix strategies and the estimation of
in brand shares, (b) their nonstationary dynamics, and
dynamic models for oligopoly markets—are unsolved
(c) the marketing-mix interactions and competitive
research topics because the necessary methodology interdependencies.
does not yet exist in marketing, economics, or man- To illustrate the application of these dual method-
agement science (see Erickson 1991, Kamien and ologies, we extend the Lanchester model in §2. Sec-
Schwartz 1991, Dockner et al. 2000). tion 3 analyzes the N -player differential game and
Given this gap in the literature, one cannot answer constructs the marketing-mix algorithm. Section 4
basic questions of managerial interest: Do advertis- develops the continuous-discrete estimation approach
ing and promotion amplify or attenuate their impact to estimate dynamic oligopoly models. We present an
on market outcomes (e.g., brand share) when used illustrative example in §5 and conclude in §6.
together? How should managers allocate resources to
advertising and promotion in the presence of inter-
action effects? What is the level of optimal budget 2. Extended Lanchester Model
and its allocation to promotional activities in the We extend the classical Lanchester model by intro-
presence of strategic foresight? Is own (or competi- ducing the following phenomena: multiple brands in
tor’s) brand underadvertising or overpromoting, or competition, multiple marketing activities that each
both? If brand A’s interaction effect increases, should brand employs to influence its own and competing
brand B optimally respond by increasing advertising brands’ shares, and interactions between marketing
or increasing promotion? activities.
Naik, Raman, and Winer: Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects
Marketing Science 24(1), pp. 25–34, © 2005 INFORMS 27

Table 1 Related Literature

Multiple activities with Multiple activities


Single activity no interactions with interactions

Monopoly Sethi (1977) Naik and Raman (2003) Naik and Raman (2003)
Little (1979)
Duopoly Erickson (1991) Chintagunta and Vilcassim (1994) This study
Oligopoly Dockner et al. (2000) Fruchter and Kalish (1998) This study
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

2.1. Multiple Brands interaction effect. Equation (4) states that the market-
In the classical Lanchester model, two brands com- ing force depends not only on the weight of adver-
pete for market shares using advertising. Let mi t tising and promotion but also on their interaction;
and ui t denote market share and advertising effort, both the weights and effectiveness are brand-specific.
respectively, for brand i, i = 1 and 2. Then, the Furthermore, each activity can amplify or attenuate
Lanchester model is the effectiveness of other activities. Assuming posi-
tive effect of advertising, when brand i increases ui ,
ṁ1 = 1 u1 1 − m1  − 2 u2 m1
(1)
it not only increases its brand share mi (directly via
where ṁi = dmi /dt is the rate of change in mi , and i Equation (3)) but also influences the effectiveness of
denotes advertising effectiveness. In Equation (1), the the other activity vi because of the nonzero i (indi-
change in market share of the first brand is due to two rectly via Equation (4)). The two activities strengthen
sources. First, the first brand captures some market the marketing force by creating synergy when  > 0;
share from the other brand m2 = 1 − m1  via its own they weaken the marketing force when  < 0. Finally,
advertising (i.e., by increasing 1 or u1 . Second, it we focus on two marketing activities because no new
loses market share when the other brand increases conceptual issues arise in extending (4) to multiple
advertising or improves effectiveness (i.e., as u2 or 2 activities.
increases). Remark 1. Table 1 shows how the extended
Next, we extend this model to an oligopoly mar- Lanchester model augments the marketing literature
ket with N brands. For each brand i, i = 1
  
N , on important dimensions. Specifically, Sethi (1977)
let fi be the force of one’s own marketing activities; and Little (1979) review the literature on dynamic
for example, f1 = 1 u1 and f2 = 2 u2 in (1). Then, gen- monopoly models with single activity; Erickson (1991)
eralizing (1) to N brands, the market share of brand 1 and Dockner et al. (2000) summarize dynamic com-
evolves as follows: petitive models with a single activity. By introducing
dm1 multiple activities, Chintagunta and Vilcassim (1994)
= f1 1 − m1  − f2 m1 − f3 m1 · · · and Fruchter and Kalish (1998) extend these differen-
dt
tial game models but ignore interactions among these
− fi m1 · · · − fN m1  (2)
activities. By introducing interaction effects, which
We further simplify (2) to obtain ṁ1 = f1 − F m1 , where are central to the marketing-mix concept (see, e.g.,

F = Ni=1 fi denotes the marketing force of all the Gatignon and Hanssens 1987; Gatignon 1993; Lilien
brands (including the first brand). Thus, we formulate et al. 1992, p. 5), Naik and Raman (2003) establish
the N -brand Lanchester model as the simultaneous empirically the existence of synergy and offer theoret-
system of coupled differential equations: ical insights into budgeting and allocation decisions.
       However, they investigate monopoly markets, which
ṁ1 f1 F ··· 0 m1
ignore a competitor’s response to one’s own bud-
             
  =  −         (3) geting and allocation decisions. Hence, the extended
ṁN fN 0 ··· F mN Lanchester model via (3) and (4) fills this gap in the
literature by incorporating both the interaction effects
2.2. Multiple Marketing Activities with and dynamic competition. Next, we analyze the dif-
Interaction Effects ferential game for this extended model and construct
Marketing activities such as advertising and promo- an algorithm that yields equilibrium marketing-mix
tion generate the marketing force of a brand. Denot- plans.
ing advertising and promotional efforts by ui
vi , we
specify the marketing force of brand i, i = 1
  
N ,
3. Marketing-Mix Algorithm
fi = i ui + i vi + i ui vi
(4)
3.1. Differential Game Formulation
where  i
i  represent the advertising and pro- Each brand i develops its advertising plan ui t and
motion effectiveness, respectively, and i is the promotion plan vi t by maximizing its performance
Naik, Raman, and Winer: Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects
28 Marketing Science 24(1), pp. 25–34, © 2005 INFORMS

index (Erickson 1991, p. 18): which will not yield the optimal promotion plan v∗ t
upon equating to zero. Hence, we define the switch-
J ui
vi  ing function,
 T 
= e−t pi t−vi t mi t − cui t dt


(5) Di = −mi + i 1 − mi i + i ui 
(9)
t=0



discounting margin share advertising cost

which yields the optimal bang-bang policy,2
net value 
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.



discounted net value v
i Di > 0
vi =
i = 1
  
N
(10)
0 Di < 0
which quantifies the performance of a strategy pair
ui t
vi t. In (5),  denotes the discount rate, pi is where v
i denotes the maximum deal amount for
the price of brand i,1 vi is the size of the deal, mi is the brand i at time t. The promotion plan is either “on”
market share, ui is the advertising effort, and cu is (i.e., offer price discount) or “off,” so we express it
the cost of expending u. The associated Hamiltonian is by vi t = v
i IDi > 0, where I· denotes an indicator
variable 1 or 0 depending on whether the switch Di
H i ui
vi  = pi − vi mi − cui  + i fi − F mi 
is positive or not. This switch depends on the co-state
i = 1
  
N
(6) variable i t, which involves the strategies of all com-
peting brands. Consequently, each brand forms an
where i t is the co-state variable for brand i. Below expectation of whether other brands would promote
we assume the cost function cu = bu + u2 /2 (e.g., or not. By taking expectations, we find that brand i’s
Fruchter and Kalish 1998), although the proposed policy is given by
marketing-mix algorithm permits other functional
vi∗ = v
i E!IDi > 0"
forms (see Remark 2 later).
= v
i Pr−mi + i 1 − mi i + i ui  > 0
3.2. Equilibrium Strategies  
i i + i ui 
= v
i Pr mi <
3.2.1. Optimal Advertising. By differentiating (6) 1 + i i + i ui 
with respect to ui , and solving H i /ui = 0, we obtain v
i i i + i ui 
=
(11)
1 + i i + i ui 
u∗i = i  i + i vi 1 − mi  − b
i = 1
  
N  (7)
where the last equality follows by noting that the
Equation (7) specifies the optimal advertising strategy support of brand share mi is the unit interval (0, 1),
for each brand i, which depends on one’s own mar- which like the standard uniform variable U yields
ket share mi , ad effectiveness  i , the cost param- PrU < c = c. The fixed point of (7) and (11) yields the
eter b, and other brands’ strategies via the co-state equilibrium pair (u∗
v∗ ) as a function of the co-state
variable i t, whose dynamics we derive in Equa- variables t.
tion (12). It further reveals that, in the absence of inter-
3.2.3. Co-State Dynamics. We derive the co-state
action effects (i.e., when i = 0), advertising plans do
dynamics by evaluating ˙ i = i − H i /mi and obtain
not directly depend on the promotion plans. In con-
trast, in the presence of interaction effects (i.e., when       
˙ 1 +F ··· 0 1 p1 − v1
i = 0), optimal advertising u∗i t depends directly              
   =       −  

on the promotion plan vi t. Hence, the interaction  


effect qualitatively changes the planning of the marketing- ˙ N 0 ··· +F N pN − vN
mix by requiring managers to account for interactivity (12)
trade-offs.
where ˙ i = di /dt, and i = 1
  
N . The co-state
3.2.2. Optimal Promotion. By differentiating (6)
dynamics incorporate the fundamental principle of
with respect to vi , we obtain

H i /vi = −mi + i 1 − mi i + i ui 

2
(8) We derive the limiting condition when the bang-bang policy could
degenerate to a singular value (i.e., constant discount). The con-
dition requires that every brand satisfies the equality: 1 − m1  ·
1
In practice, managers should use the net price p i t = pi t − ci t p1 − v1 1 + 1 u1 /m1 = · · · = 1 − mi pi − vi i + i ui /mi = · · · =
to account for the unit cost of goods sold, ci . In developing the 1 − mN pN − vN N + N uN /mN . If this equality holds in some
marketing-mix algorithm, however, we assume it zero to minimize market, every brand would offer a fixed discount, thus lowering its
notation without loss of generality. When using the algorithm, regular price effectively, and the resulting marketing-mix problem
managers can include the unit cost and perform the sensitivity reduces to one of finding the optimal advertising plans, which is a
analysis (as we do in the empirical example). special case of the above problem.
Naik, Raman, and Winer: Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects
Marketing Science 24(1), pp. 25–34, © 2005 INFORMS 29

strategic foresight, which requires managers to look differential games in marketing because all of them
forward (i.e., forecast outcomes and anticipate com- are expressible in the form of Equation (13). After
petitive moves) and reason backward (i.e., deduce expressing a game as Equation (13), the above algo-
the best strategy via backward induction). Specifi- rithm yields the optimal strategies—only the shape
cally, to look forward, we apply the state dynamics of the link function g· and the set of input argu-
in (3) and (4); to anticipate competitive moves, we ments y
( change to accommodate different specifi-
evaluate the best strategies using (7) and (11); to rea- cations and phenomena. Specifically, it accommodates
son backward, we solve the co-state dynamics in (12)
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

different state dynamics instead of (3); different mar-


from the terminal period to the initial time. Thus, we keting forces instead of (4); different marketing objec-
can systematically create equilibrium marketing-mix tives instead of (5); and different phenomena such
plans with strategic foresight by stacking the two sys- as channel members, reference prices, or cost func-
tems of differential equations (3) and (12) and solving tions. Furthermore, it is not restricted to open-loop
them simultaneously together with (4), (7), and (11). marketing-mix plans; it also furnishes closed-loop
To solve the resulting two-point boundary value prob- marketing-mix strategies (see §5.3 in the unabridged
lem (TPBVP), we next construct a marketing-mix manuscript). Next, we develop an approach to quan-
algorithm. tify the effectiveness and interaction effects for each
brand in the oligopoly and to infer their statistical sig-
3.3. Marketing-Mix Algorithm
We note that extant algorithms in marketing (e.g., nificance based on market data.
Deal 1979, Thompson and Teng 1984, Erickson 1991)
are not applicable to solve the above TPBVP because 4. Continuous-Discrete Estimation
they ignore the coupling between and within the state
Method
and the co-state equations. For example, the coupling
We note that the brand-share dynamics in (3) are in
of differentialequations arises because of the market
continuous time; that is, the time parameter t in the
force F = fi + fj in both (3) and (12). Hence, we con-
model is continuously differentiable on any interval
struct the following algorithm that not only accounts
t
t̄. In contrast, brand-share data arrive at discrete
for interequation coupling but also permits a general
points in time (e.g., weeks). In other words, the time
nonlinear TPBVP specified by
parameter t in the data series is not continuously
ẏ = gy' (
(13) differentiable; rather it takes discrete values in the
integer set .1
2
3
  
T /. To resolve this mismatch,
where y and ẏ are vectors with 2N elements (i.e., N
we develop an approach to estimate continuous-time
state and N co-state variables), and ( denotes the
models using discrete-time data.
parameter space. Specifically, the algorithm consists
Let mk denote the N × 1 vector of brand shares
of the four steps:
at time tk , where k is an integer in the index set
Step 1. Boundary conditions. Choose M grid points
.1
2
  
T /. Using (3), we integrate over the inter-
on a timeline, k = 1
2
  
M, and specify two points
val (tk−1
tk ] to obtain the exact equation relating the
for the boundary conditions: the initial k = 0, and the
brand shares at two discrete time points:
terminal k = M + 1.
Step 2. Finite difference equations. Create difference  tk  tk  dm   tk
equations Ek ≡ yk − yk−1 − hgwk ' -, where h = mk − mk−1 = dm = dt = ṁ dt

tk−1 tk−1 dt tk−1


tk − tk−1 , and wk = yk + yk−1 /2. Then stack all the
equations E1
E2
  
EM+1 one below the other, and which, upon simplification, yields the matrix transi-
denote this stack by the vector-valued function Gx, tion equation
where x = vecy1
y2
  
yM . mk = 0k mk−1 + 1k
(14)
Step 3. Nonlinear root-finding. Solve the equations
Gx = 0 via Newton-Rahpson method. where 0k = expAk  is a N × N transition matrix,
Step 4. Optimal marketing-mix plans. Using state and exp· is the matrix exponentiation function, Ak is a
co-state trajectories obtained from step 3, determine diagonal N × N matrix with −Fk  as the elements
the marketing-mix plans via (7) through (10), and on the principal diagonal, and the N × 1 drift vector
evaluate their performance via (5). 1k = expAk  − IN A−1
k fk , where IN is an N -dimensional
For further details, see Table 3 in the unabridged identity matrix, and fk = f1k
  
fNk  is the vector of
manuscript (available from the authors). marketing forces for the N brands.
Remark 2. This algorithm is not restricted to the Let yik denote the observed share for brand i at
extended Lanchester model; it encompasses other time tk . Because brand shares sum to 100%, once we
alternative model specifications for dynamic oligo- know N − 1 brand shares, the realized share for the
poly markets. Its generality stems from the mathe- remaining brand, yNk , provides no new information,

matical structure of a TPBVP, which subsumes several because it must equal 100 − Ni=1−1 yik . Consequently,
Naik, Raman, and Winer: Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects
30 Marketing Science 24(1), pp. 25–34, © 2005 INFORMS

we need information on any N − 1 brands, which vanish or diminish because brand-share dynamics
we link to (14) via the observation equation are nonstationary, a fact evident from the transition
     matrix 0k in (14), which is time-varying because it
y1k 100 · · · 0 m1k depends on k. Finally, the shares of all N brands
           in an oligopoly are highly interdependent on each
  =     
   
(15)
other’s marketing activities. Specifically, we observe
yN −1
k 0 · · · 100 mN −1
k
from (14) that both 0k and 1k depend nonlinearly
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

on the marketing forces F and fi . Therefore, in the


where Yk = y1k
  
yN −1
k  are the observed brand
proposed method, we explicitly account for temporal
shares (in percentages).
dependence, nonstationary dynamics, promotional
We express (14) and (15), together, in the state-space
mix interactions, and competitive interdependencies
form (Shumway and Stoffer 2000):
in estimating dynamic oligopoly models. We next
Yk = z mk + 5k
illustrate its application to the dynamic oligopoly of
(16) detergents brands.
mk = 0k mk−1 + 1k + 6k

where z is a diagonal matrix with its principal ele- 5. Empirical Application


ments equal to 100, and the error-terms follow the
5.1. Data
normal distributions, 5k ∼ N 0
H  and 6k ∼ N 0
Q,
We use single-source data for the five detergents
where H is the diagonal matrix 8 2 IN −1 and Q is the
brands Tide, Wisk, Era, Solo, and Bold, whose aver-
diagonal matrix, diag812
  
8N2 −1 . We then compute
age percentage shares are 43, 19, 16, 13, and 9, respec-
the likelihood function for observing the trajectory of
tively. The data consist of the purchase histories,
market shares of all the brands in an oligopoly by
prices paid, cents-off deal, and TV viewing by house-
L(' Y  = hY1
Y2
  
YT  holds over 84 weeks (see Winer 1993 for details).
Because the Lanchester model is specified at the
= hY1  × hY2  Y1  × hY3  Y1
Y2  brand level, researchers usually use market- or store-
× · · · × hYT  Y1
Y2
  
YT −1  level data for calibration (e.g., Little 1979, Chintagunta
and Vilcassim 1994). While aggregate market data

T
furnish information on competing brands for many
= hYk  k−1 
(17)
k=1
nongrocery products, the household-level data pro-
vide opportunities not available in aggregate data.
where hY1
  
YT denotes the joint density func- For example, we can identify the advertisements seen
tion, hYk  k−1  represents the conditional density by each household, the deal it received, and the
function, whose moments are obtained from the brands it bought subsequently. Using this detailed
Kalman filter recursions, and the information set information, we can operationalize better measures of
k = .Y1
Y2
  
Yk / contains the market history up to advertising and promotion. For example, to measure
time tk . By maximizing (17), we obtain the maximum- advertising, we use opportunity-to-see (OTS), which
likelihood estimates is defined as the number of exposures viewed by a
household within a purchase cycle (Lilien et al. 1992,
- = Arg Max LnL(' Y  (18) pp. 272–274). For further details, see the unabridged
-∈(
version.
For statistical inference, we obtain the standard errors
by taking the square-root of the diagonal elements of 5.2. Empirical Results
the covariance matrix:
5.2.1. Model Selection, Cross-Validation, and
 2 −1
Hausman Test. We apply the proposed continuous-
 = −  LnL(' Y 
Var-  (19)
(( discrete estimation method to estimate several alter-
-=-
native model specifications: dynamic model with
Remark 3. The estimation of continuous-time interactions, dynamic model without interactions,
models (e.g., Equation (3)) via the ordinary least- price effects with interactions, price effects with-
squares (OLS) regression results in biased estimates out interactions, diminishing returns (square-root),
for the following three reasons. First, the OLS regres- increasing returns (quadratic). Based on information
sion requires independence between brand shares at criteria (not presented here for brevity), we retain
two points in time, Yk and Yk . Clearly, such temporal the extended Lanchester model in (3) and (4)—
independence cannot exist because the differential it is not only parsimonious but also fits the data
equation (3) explicitly induces dependence over well for all five brands. In addition, to assess pre-
time. Second, this temporal dependence does not dictive validity, we conduct cross-validation using
Naik, Raman, and Winer: Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects
Marketing Science 24(1), pp. 25–34, © 2005 INFORMS 31

Table 2 Continuous-Discrete Kalman Filter Estimates

Parameters Tide Wisk Era Solo Bold

Ad effectiveness, i 035 033 013 010 035


007 011 004 003 026
Promotion effectiveness, i 038 014 018 018 022
009 004 005 004 012
Ad-promotion interaction, i −033 −013 002 −008 −035
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

−008 −022 006 −006 −062


Transition noise, expbi  bi −470 −521 −541 −630 —
−019 −024 −028 −038
Observation noise,
296
107
Maximized log-likelihood, LL∗ −85255

72 observations for calibration and 12 observations for promotion are used together, their impact on brand
out-of-sample validation, and we find high R2 for out- shares is attenuated.
of-sample forecasts across all five brands. Finally, we One interpretation of negative interaction, as in
apply the Hausman test, find m = 1023 and critical Mela et al. (1997) and Jedidi et al. (1999), is that “pro-
2
;20
095 = 3141, and thus cannot reject the null hypoth- motions are bad”—but not because they directly hurt
esis of exogeneity of advertising and promotion. We brand shares. Indeed, the direct effect of promotion
present the parameter estimates and standard errors is positive, making it an effective marketing activity.
(in parentheses) in Table 2. Rather, promotion negatively moderates the impact
5.2.2. Advertising and Promotion Effectiveness. of advertising, thereby reducing the effectiveness of
Table 2 indicates that ad and promotion effectiveness advertising in building brands. Another interpretation
vary considerably in this detergents market. Specif- of this negative interaction is that advertising lowers
ically, ad effectiveness of all brands, except Bold, consumer sensitivity to promotion activities.
is significant (p-values < 005). Tide’s advertising is 5.2.4. Optimal Advertising and Promotion. We
the most effective, whereas Solo’s advertising is the apply the proposed marketing-mix algorithm to find
least effective. Similarly, promotion effectiveness of all optimal advertising and promotion and present the
brands, except Bold, is significant (p-values < 005). results in Table 3. We observe that all brands under-
Tide’s promotion is the most effective, while Wisk’s advertise (i.e., actual advertising is below the optimal
promotion is the least effective. level). In contrast, some brands overpromote whereas
5.2.3. Interaction Effects. Table 2 also shows that others underpromote. These findings are not sensitive
all brands, except Era, exhibit negative interactions to marginal changes in unit cost (not reported here
between advertising and promotion. For assessing for space constraints). Specifically, Tide and Wisk,
joint significance, we test the null H0 < 1 = 2 = 3 = who underadvertise, tend to promote excessively. It
4 = 5 = 0 by using the likelihood ratio (LR) test. The appears that large brands allocate fewer resources to
LR statistic is 20.6, which exceeds the critical value advertising relative to promotion, a finding consis-
;52 = 111 (p-value = 000096). Hence, we reject the null tent with the notion of escalation of promotion due
hypothesis of no interaction effects. In addition, multi- to managers’ lack of strategic foresight (Leeflang and
ple information criteria (not reported here for brevity) Wittink 2001, p. 120). On the other hand, some small
reinforce the finding that interaction effects exist in brands (e.g., Era) both underadvertise and underpro-
this detergents market. Thus, when advertising and mote, perhaps due to lack of resources.

Table 3 Actual Versus Optimal Advertising and Promotion

Advertising Promotion
(weekly opportunity-to-see in minutes) (average deal in cents)

Brands Actual Optimal Actual Optimal

Tide 180 256 Underadvertise 62 0 Overpromote


Wisk 62 249 Underadvertise 44 0 Overpromote
Era 99 206 Underadvertise 37 47 Underpromote
Solo 88 206 Underadvertise 39 47 Underpromote
Bold 33 186 Underadvertise 23 2 Overpromote
Naik, Raman, and Winer: Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects
32 Marketing Science 24(1), pp. 25–34, © 2005 INFORMS

5.2.5. Optimal Competitive Responsiveness. of “switching functions” (see Equation (9) and the
Managers can gain further insights via comparative unabridged manuscript for details).
statics analyses. For example, if Tide’s interaction
effect increases, would Wisk respond with increased
advertising or should it increase promotion? Would 6. Discussion
Solo’s response differ from Tide’s? Managers can We acknowledge limitations of the model and identify
answer these strategic questions by first applying the avenues for future research.
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

proposed marketing-mix algorithm to characterize


the optimal advertising and promotion strategies for 6.1. Alternative Specifications
own and competitors brands, and then changing the Wittink et al. (1988, p. 4) make the point forcefully
parameter of interest (say, Tide’s interaction effect), that, although managers have strong interest in mar-
while keeping other parameters constant, to find the ket share, category sales may fluctuate over time.
new optimal strategies. Market share models, such as the Lanchester model,
Table 4 displays the comparative statics results ignore the fluctuations in category sales. To capture
with respect to interaction effects i for each brand this feature, let Mt denote category volume at time t
i = 1
  
5. Specifically, it reveals that the optimal so that Equation (3) becomes Ṡi = Mtfi t − F tSi t,
competitive response is not symmetric. For example, where Si t is the sales of brand i i = 1
  
N . Then,
based on the second column in Table 4, when Tide’s the first-order conditions for the resulting sales game
negative interaction increases, it decreases advertis- are structurally equivalent to Equations (7) and (9).
ing and increases promotion; all other brands’ fol- Consequently, we can apply the proposed marketing-
low Tide’s actions. By contrast, based on the third mix algorithm to obtain the optimal strategies in the
column in Table 4, when Wisk’s negative interaction presence of fluctuating category sales (see Remark 2).
increases, it increases advertising and decreases promo- Thus, managers can investigate how over- or under-
tion (unlike Tide’s actions in column 2); other brands’ spending changes across various patterns of category
follow suit, but not Tide whose best response is to sales (e.g., seasonality).
decrease advertising and increase promotion. While Another limitation of the Lanchester model is that
this finding of asymmetry is new, the main point of it misses lead and lag effects for advertising and
this illustration is the ability afforded by the proposed promotion. Recently, van Heerde et al. (2000) stud-
marketing-mix algorithm for managers to gain such ied the role of lead and lag effects of promotion and
insights into their product markets. Thus, in practice, detected pre- and postpromotion dips in store-level
managers can also learn competitive responsiveness data. To incorporate this feature in the Lanchester
with respect to other parameters (e.g., what if ad or model, let uit+> ∗ and vt+> i
∗ denote the lead variables
i i
promotion effectiveness changes?). and ut−> and vt−> be the lagged variables for adver-
Remark 4. We close by noting a useful property tising and promotion, respectively. Then, by extend-
of this marketing-mix algorithm. Consider a typical ing (4), we obtain the marketing force fi = i ui +
 ∗ 
brand manager who decides whether to promote or i vi + i ui vi + K> ∗ =1 @i
> ∗ ui
t+> ∗ + K>=1 Ai
> ui
t−> , for
not in each week of the annual horizon. This brand each brand i = 1
  
N , where K ∗ and K denote the
manager then encounters 2 × 2 × 2 × · · · 52 times = 252 number of lead and lagged variables in the model.
possibilities, which represents thousands of trillions of Note that these new regressors in the extended spec-
promotion plans. Brand managers cannot enumerate ification naturally (i.e., without any modifications)
trillions of plans to select the best one, even with enter into the transition matrix 0k and the drift
the availability of modern computers. Consequently, vector 1k via Fk and fk in Equation (14). Conse-
the determination of the “best” promotion schedule quently, managers can apply the proposed estima-
is practically impossible. Hence, it is remarkable that tion method (see §4) to estimate the lead effects
the proposed marketing-mix algorithm finds the opti- @ i
1
@  i
2
  
@  i
K ∗  as well as the lagged effects
mal plan in a few minutes via the powerful concept A i
1
A i
2
  
A i
K . To determine the optimal values
of K ∗ and K, classical information criteria (e.g., AIC,
BIC) can be applied for parametric model specifica-
Table 4 Change in Relative Allocation Between Advertising and
Promotion Due to Marginal Change in Own Interaction Effect
tions. When model specification is semiparametric or
nonparametric (for example, local polynomial regres-
Brands Tide  ↑ Wisk  ↑ Era  ↑ Solo  ↑ Bold  ↑ sion; see van Heerde et al. 2004), then the corrected
Tide’s response Decrease Decrease Increase Decrease Decrease criterion AICC (Naik and Tsai 2001) or RIC (Naik and
Wisk’s response Decrease Increase Decrease Increase Increase Tsai 2003) needs to be applied. Thus, managers can
Era’s response Decrease Increase Increase Increase Increase investigate the number and nature of lead and lagged
Solo’s response Decrease Increase Decrease Decrease Increase effects of both advertising and promotion in dynamic
Bold’s response Decrease Increase Decrease Increase Increase
competitive markets.
Naik, Raman, and Winer: Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects
Marketing Science 24(1), pp. 25–34, © 2005 INFORMS 33

Finally, our model specification misses the sup- in their planning by looking forward and reasoning
port variables such as features and displays, backward in making optimal decisions. By looking
which are shown to interact with price discounts forward, each brand manager forecasts his own future
(see van Heerde et al. 2004). While we focused plans and anticipates the decisions to be made by
on advertising-promotion interactions in order to other competing brands; by reasoning backward, they
develop general methods for estimating dynamic deduce their own optimal decisions in response to the
game-theoretic models and computing optimal strate- best strategies of all other brands. To incorporate the
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

gies, we note that no new methodological issues arise interaction effects and strategic foresight in dynamic
in applying the dual methodology to study other oligopoly models, this paper contributes to the mar-
interaction effects. Indeed, different model specifica- keting literature by creating two methods: marketing-
tions would influence empirical results and yield new mix algorithm and continuous-discrete estimation
marketing insights. Hence, to enrich our understand- method. These dual methodologies enable the com-
ing of marketing, future researchers should investi- putation of optimal marketing-mix plans and the esti-
gate the impact of interaction effects of support activ- mation of dynamic game-theoretic models.
ities on optimal budgeting and allocation. We apply the dual methodologies to (a) deter-
mine the optimal budget and allocation decisions, and
6.2. Dynamic Endogeneity (b) estimate the effectiveness of advertising and pro-
We conducted the Hausman (1978) test and rejected motion and their interaction effect for each of the five
endogeneity of advertising and promotion. Further- brands in a detergents market. We caution the readers
more, we applied the notions in Engle et al. (1983) that our empirical conclusions about over- and under-
and reached the same conclusions (see the unabridged spending can change under different, more realistic
version). Both the approaches reinforce each other model specifications. Hence, managers should first fit
to enhance confidence and convergent validity. How- several alternative specifications using the proposed
ever, parameter estimates could still be biased due to estimation method (see §6.1) and then determine
the possibility of serial correlation causing dynamic the specification to retain using appropriate infor-
endogeneity in advertising and promotion. Thus, mation criteria (Naik and Tsai 2001, 2004). Finally,
future researchers need to develop statistical tests when managers apply the marketing-mix algorithm
for detecting dynamic endogeneity, characterize the
to their specific markets, they may discover opti-
profit impact of such biased estimates, and recom-
mal marketing-mix plans that could appear different
mend approaches for de-biasing (see Naik and Tsai
from the “business-as-usual” norm. In such situations,
2000 for such efforts in dynamic errors-in-variable
managers should use the resulting insights to conduct
problem).
a small-scale experiment in real markets to generate
6.3. Role of Retailers further market-based evidence and to gain support
We formulated and examined an extended Lanchester from other constituencies, both internal (e.g., sales
game that describes dynamic competition among force) and external (e.g., channel members), for suc-
multiple manufacturers who incorporate strategic cessful implementation of marketing-mix strategies.
foresight in making intertemporal decisions for mul-
tiple marketing activities in the presence of interac- Acknowledgments
tions. Our analysis ignores the role of retailers. On The authors benefited from insightful comments and valu-
able suggestions of the reviewers, area editor, co-editors of
the other hand, Moorthy (2005) and Besanko et al.
the special issue, the marketing faculty at the Haas School
(2005) investigate retailers’ pass-through behavior but
of UC Berkeley, Krannert School of Purdue University, the
ignore the effects of intertemporal dynamics, multiple Graduate School of Management at UC Davis, and the sem-
marketing activities, and interaction effects. Future inar participants at the MSI conference in Boston and the
researchers could combine these strands of research Marketing Science conference in UCLA. They also benefited
by analyzing dynamic competition among manu- from the valuable feedback from the participants of the 2nd
facturers over time, among retailers, and among Annual Control Seminar at UC Davis. Special thanks to pro-
manufacturer-retailer dyads. This problem is not only fessors Sanjay Joshi (Aerospace Engineering), Ahmet Pala-
challenging but also an important unsolved problem zoglu (Head of Chemical Engineering), Alan J. Laub (Dean
in marketing science. Emeritus of Engineering School), and Zhaojun Bai (Com-
puter Science and Mathematics). Research of the first author
was supported in part by the UCD Faculty Research Grant.
7. Concluding Remarks
In dynamic competitive markets, managers should References
recognize the presence of interactions within mar- Besanko, David, Jean-Pierre Dubé, Sachin Gupta. 2005. Own-
keting activities and between competing brands. To brand and cross-brand retail pass-through. Marketing Sci. 24(1)
this end, they should incorporate strategic foresight 123–137.
Naik, Raman, and Winer: Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of Interaction Effects
34 Marketing Science 24(1), pp. 25–34, © 2005 INFORMS

Blattberg, Robert C., Scott A. Neslin. 1990. Sales Promotion: Concepts, Moorthy, Sridhar K. 2005. A general theory of pass-through in
Methods, and Strategies. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. channels with category management and retail competition.
Chintagunta, Pradeep K., Naufel J. Vilcassim. 1994. Marketing Marketing Sci. 24(1) 110–122.
investment decisions in a dynamic duopoly: A model and Naik, Prasad A., Chih-Ling Tsai. 2000. Controlling measurement
empirical analysis. Internat. J. Res. Marketing 11(2) 287–306. errors in models of advertising competition. J. Marketing Res.
Deal, Kenneth R. 1979. Optimizing advertising expenditures in a 37(1) 113–124.
dynamic duopoly. Oper. Res. 27(3) 682–692. Naik, Prasad A., Chih-Ling Tsai. 2001. Single-index model selec-
Dockner, E. J., S. Jorgensen, N. Van Long, G. Sorger. 2000. Differ- tions. Biometrika 88(3) 821–832.
Downloaded from informs.org by [158.42.28.33] on 12 January 2015, at 04:05 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

ential Games in Economics and Management Science. Cambridge Naik, Prasad A., Chih-Ling Tsai. 2004. Residual information crite-
University Press, Cambridge, UK. rion for single-index model selections. J. Nonparametric Statist.
Engle, R. F., D. F. Hendry, J.-F. Richard. 1983. Exogeneity. Economet- 16(1–2) 187–195.
rica 51(2) 277–304. Naik, Prasad A., Kalyan Raman. 2003. Understanding the impact of
Erickson, Gary M. 1991. Dynamic Models of Advertising Competition: synergy in multimedia communications. J. Marketing Res. 40(3)
Open- and Closed-Loop Extensions. Kluwer Academic Publishers, 375–388.
Boston, MA. Naik, Prasad A., Murali K. Mantrala, Alan Sawyer. 1998. Planning
Fruchter, Gila E., Shlomo Kalish. 1998. Dynamic promotional bud- pulsing media schedules in the presence of dynamic advertis-
geting and media allocation. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 111(1) 15–27. ing quality. Marketing Sci. 17(2) 214–235.
Gatignon, Hubert. 1993. Marketing-mix models. Josh Eliashberg, Sethi, Suresh P. 1977. Dynamic optimal control models in advertis-
Gary L. Lilien, eds. Handbook of OR and MS, Vol. 5. Elsevier ing: A survey. SIAM Rev. 19(4) 685–725.
Science Publishers, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 697–732. Shumway, Robert H., David S. Stoffer. 2000. Time Series Analysis and
Gatignon, Hubert, Dominique M. Hanssens. 1987. Modeling mar- Its Applications. Springer-Verlag, Inc., New York.
keting interactions with application to salesforce effectiveness. Silva-Risso, Jorge M., Randolph E. Bucklin, Donald G. Morrison.
J. Marketing Res. 24(2) 247–257. 1999. A decision support system for planning manufacturers’
Jedidi, Kamel, Carl Mela, Sunil Gupta. 1999. Managing advertising sales promotion calendars. Marketing Sci. 18(2) 274–300.
and promotion for long-run profitability. Marketing Sci. 18(1) Thompson, Gerald L., Jinn-Tsair Teng. 1984. Optimal pricing
1–22. and advertising policies for new product oligopoly models.
Kamien, Morton, Nancy Schwartz. 1991. Dynamic Optimization. Marketing Sci. 3(1) 148–168.
Elsevier Science Publishing Company, New York. van Heerde, Harald J., P. S. H. Leeflang, Dick R. Wittink. 2000.
Leeflang, P. H. S., Dick R. Wittink. 2001. Explaining competitive The estimation of pre- and post-promotion dips with store-
reaction effects. Internat. J. Res. Marketing 18(1–2) 119–137. level scanner data. J. Marketing Res. 37(3) 383–395.
Lilien, Gary L., Philip Kotler, K. Sridhar Moorthy. 1992. Marketing van Heerde, Harald J., P. S. H. Leeflang, Dick R. Wittink. 2004.
Models. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Decomposing the sales promotion bump with store data.
Little, John D. C. 1979. Aggregate advertising models: The state of Marketing Sci. 23(3) 317–334.
the art. Oper. Res. 27(4) 629–667. Winer, Russell S. 1993. Using single-source scanner data as a natural
Mantrala, Murali K. 2002. Allocating marketing resources. Barton experiment for evaluating advertising effects. J. Marketing Sci.
A. Weitz, Robin Wensley, eds. Handbook of Marketing. 2(2) 15–31.
Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA, 409–435. Witttink, Dick R., Michael J. Addona, William J. Hawkes, John C.
Mela, Carl F., Sunil Gupta, Donald R. Lehmann. 1997. The long- Porter. 1988. SCAN∗ PRO® : The estimation, validation, and use
term impact of promotion and advertising on consumer brand of promotional effects based on scanner data. Working paper,
choice. J. Marketing Res. 34(1) 248–261. Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.

You might also like