You are on page 1of 16

476

Corporate Governance: An International Review, 2009, 17(4): 476–491

The Determinants of Auditor Switching from


the Perspective of Corporate Governance in
China
Z. Jun Lin and Ming Liu*

ABSTRACT

Manuscript Type: Empirical


Research Question/Issue: This paper reports on the association between the internal corporate governance mechanism of
firms and their auditor switching types in the Chinese context. Two types of auditor switching – namely switching to a larger
auditor or switching to a smaller auditor – are identified and examined.
Research Findings/Insights: Controlling shareholders have the incentive to seek opaqueness gains. The empirical results
demonstrate that to realize opaqueness gains, firms with weaker corporate governance generally are more likely to switch
to a smaller auditor rather than to a larger one.
Theoretical/Academic Implications: The empirical results demonstrate that firm-specific corporate governance devices will
affect a firm’s auditor switching decision. An effective corporate governance mechanism may inhibit the controlling
shareholder from switching to a smaller auditor to exploit the minority shareholders. The emerging economies are usually
featured with concentrated ownership and insufficient legal protection of minority shareholders. Compared with prior
studies, this paper generates findings more applicable to the emerging economies.
Practitioner/Policy Implications: This study may facilitate market regulators and participants to maintain close monitoring
of the structural arrangement of corporate governance of the listed firms, the independent auditing process and the
credibility of financial reporting in an emerging market like China. The findings also suggest that in order to bolster the
confidence of the market participants, the Chinese government should promote the reform of the corporate governance
system and enforce effective regulations, in particular on firms’ auditor switches.

Keywords: Corporate Governance, Supervisory Board, Government Ownership, State-Owned Enterprise (SOE),
Auditor Switching, China

INTRODUCTION an association between a firm’s corporate governance and its


auditor selection decision. This study empirically investi-

T he purpose of this study is to investigate the association


between a firm’s internal corporate governance mecha-
nism and its auditor switching decisions in the Chinese
gates the relationship between a firm’s internal corporate
governance mechanism (proxied by ownership concentra-
tion, effectiveness of the supervisory board [SB] monitoring
context. An independent auditing function can detect and and shared board of directors [BoD] chairman and CEO)
disclose earnings management and other types of miscon- and their auditor switching decisions in the context of cor-
duct by business managers or controlling shareholders. In porate governance practice in China.
general, if a firm has established a sound corporate gover- This study was motivated by several factors. First, as cor-
nance mechanism, the firm’s management or its controlling porate governance has a positive impact on corporate finan-
shareholders will not have a free hand in making decisions cial reporting and auditing processes, a study of auditor
on auditor selection, and vice versa. Hence, there should be switching with respect to the internal corporate governance
mechanism may assist analysis of auditing quality and the
auditor’s roles in ensuring the credibility of corporate finan-
*Address for correspondence: Department of Accounting and Information Manage-
ment, Faculty of Business Administration, University of Macau, Macau, China. E-mail: cial disclosures. Second, for the controlling owners, there is
Mliu@umac.mo a tradeoff between hiring a high-quality auditor to lower the

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


doi:10.1111/j.1467-8683.2009.00759.x
THE DETERMINANTS OF AUDITOR SWITCHING FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CHINA 477

costs of raising capital and hiring a low-quality auditor to administration of CPAs and auditing firms, was established
maintain the gains from the opaqueness of corporate gover- in the early 1980s. Following the business restructuring cam-
nance (called “opaqueness gains,” such as tunneling behav- paign, shareholding (stock) companies reappeared in the
iors to transfer resources from a listed firm to its controlling Chinese economy at the turn of 1990s, resulting in a further
shareholder). The ongoing bear market in China during the sharp increase in the demand for external audits. The estab-
2001–2004 period provides a good opportunity to disen- lishment of the Shanghai and Shenzhen stock exchanges and
tangle these two incentives, thus allowing us to pinpoint the the promulgation of new accounting and auditing standards
association between a firm’s internal corporate governance also played an important role in this process. The China
mechanism and its auditor switching decisions. Third, the Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) required that the
Chinese Institute of Certified Public Accountants (CICPA) annual reports of all listed firms be audited by registered
began to rank auditors in China in the early 2000s in order to Chinese CPAs.
improve the transparency of the Chinese auditing market,
thus allowing the possibility of identifying high-quality audi-
tors in the Chinese market. An investigation of the determi-
The Role of the Auditing Function
nants of auditor switching from the perspective of corporate In contemporary market economies, business incorporation
governance should contribute to an understanding of the leads to the separation of ownership and management.
necessity and utility of independent audits in China. Professional managers, rather than owners (shareholders),
Our regression results show that firms with larger control- are directly involved in daily business operations. Due to
ling shareholders (a higher degree of ownership concentra- various self-interests and information asymmetries, busi-
tion) or firms where the positions of board of directors’ ness managers are able to pursue their own interests at the
chairman and CEO are held by the same person are more expense of those of the owners and other stakeholders
likely to switch to a smaller auditor rather than to a larger (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). One of the binding mechanisms
one. However, the supervisory board monitoring strength is over management operations and information disclosure is
not a significant factor underlying auditor switching deci- the auditing function performed by independent profession-
sions. The findings suggest that firms with a weak internal als (Watts and Zimmerman, 1986).
corporate governance mechanism generally tend to switch Nonetheless, the utility of the auditing function depends
to smaller or more pliable auditors to sustain the opaqueness upon quality of the audit which is determined by the inde-
gains. The finding that the supervisory board function pendence and expertise of the auditors (DeAngelo, 1981;
(proxied by its size to represent monitoring effectiveness) Watkins, Hillison, & Morecroft, 2004). Audit quality is con-
does not have a significant influence on auditor switching sidered to be commensurate with the size of the auditors,
decisions may imply that the supervisory board’s monitor- i.e., larger auditors should have a higher degree of indepen-
ing function is not consistently effective in practice. dence, possess more industrial expertise and resources, and
The remainder of the paper is arranged as follows. The bear higher reputation costs, so they can provide higher-
second section reviews the relevant literature. The third quality auditing services (DeAngelo, 1981; Lennox, 2005).
section develops the hypotheses to examine the association Investors perceive the accounting numbers (e.g., earnings
between the internal corporate governance mechanism and and book values) audited by large auditors to have better
auditor switching decisions. The fourth section introduces a information quality, and therefore attach greater market
regression model to test the hypotheses. The fifth section value to them (Lennox, 2005; Watkins et al., 2004).
presents and discusses the empirical results. Sensitivity tests DeFond and Subramanyam (1998) argue that there are
are presented in the sixth section. Finally, the seventh section incentives for the controlling shareholders of firms to
provides some conclusions. pursue their own interests by manipulating the accounting
numbers or transferring resources through “tunneling”
behaviors. Thus, the controlling shareholders will weigh
LITERATURE REVIEW their own self-interests when making auditor selection deci-
sions (Johnson, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, & Shleifer, 2000;
The Development of Auditing Profession in China La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 2002). On the
Shortly after the founding of the People’s Republic of China one hand, selecting a large auditor will signal to the market
in 1949, the auditing profession in China disappeared entirely that the financial statements are more reliable, thus the firms
due to the public (state) ownership of all production means. may benefit from lower capital-raising costs on the equity or
An independent auditing function was virtually nonexistent debt market. On the other hand, large auditors may be more
in the planned economy before the 1980s when the state stringent in detecting and reporting “tunneling behavior”
owned and ran enterprises directly. But the mushrooming of and hence may deprive the controlling shareholders of their
Sino-foreign joint ventures, brought about by the govern- opaqueness gains (Johnson & Lys, 1990). In particular, when
ment’s adoption of the “open-door” policy in the early 1980s, firms receive unfavorable audit reports, they might initiate
led to the emergence of independent auditing. Due to the an auditor switch, searching for a more pliable auditor with
involvement of non-state equity interests in joint-ventures, it the goal of “opinion shopping” (DeFond & Subramanyam,
became necessary to have independent professionals, or 1998; Johnson & Lys, 1990; Watkins et al., 2004). Auditor
certified public accountants (CPAs), to verify capital contri- switching may take different forms, including switching to a
butions and audit annual financial statements and income smaller auditor and switching to a larger auditor. Nonethe-
tax returns (Lin, Tang, & Xiao, 2003). Thus, the CICPA, less in the extant literature there is a general lack of research
a quasi-governmental organization in charge of national differentiating the two types of auditor switching.

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009


478 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Corporate Governance and the Auditing Function of Certified Public Accountants (AICPA) (Carpenter &
Strawser, 1971): “Almost universally, the reason expressed
Corporate governance evolved with the separation of own-
[for the change in auditors] was that the underwriters
ership and management underlying the modern corporation
informed the client that a ‘national known auditor’ was nec-
system (Ang, Cole, & Lin, 2000). There are various types of
essary to sell their offerings at the highest possible price.”
principal-agent relations, e.g., between owners and manage-
In China, on average two-thirds of the shares are held by
ment, between creditors and owners/management, and
block shareholders (Lin, Liu, & Zhang, 2007). The block
between controlling shareholders and minority sharehold-
shareholder has the power to appoint a management team,
ers. A primary objective of corporate governance is to
and through the management team has access to inside
monitor the behavior of the various interested parties and to
information. However, because the controlling shareholders
reduce the agency costs underlying the various principal-
also have the power to select the auditor,1 the minority
agent relations (Karpoff, Malatesta, & Walkling, 1996). Thus,
shareholders do not expect to rely on auditing to effectively
corporate governance can be defined as “a set of mecha-
monitor management. Hence, the internal function of audit-
nisms, both industrial and market-based, that induce the
ing to reduce owner-manager agency costs does not exist in
self-interested parties of a company to make decisions that
China and for this function there is insufficient demand for
maximize the value of the company to its owners” (Denis &
audit quality.
McConnell, 2003).
As there is no significant bond market in China, listed
An audit provides external monitoring over a firm’s finan-
firms are primarily financed by equity rather than debt. After
cial reporting by independent professionals (auditors) and
the establishment of Shanghai Stock Exchange and the
therefore serves a fundamental role in reinforcing informa-
Shenzhen Stock Exchange, Chinese listed firms achieved
tion credibility. However, the true effectiveness of external
cumulative financing of RMB 1.16 trillion (RMB 6.80 = U$1)
auditing is subject to the actuality and the development of the
between 1992 and 2004. In 2000 the total market capitaliza-
corporate governance environment (Holm & Laursen, 2007).
tion hit RMB 1.61 trillion, however the bear market thereaf-
A sound corporate governance mechanism should ensure
ter resulted in the slumping of the market value by RMB .44
that firms appoint qualified auditors and that the auditors
trillion (CSRC, 2005). During the weak market period of
exercise independent and effective monitoring over the
2001 to 2004 listed firms were not enthusiastic about offering
financial reporting process and attest to the financial state-
new equity securities to the public, therefore the external use
ments’ conformity with the Generally Accepted Accounting
of audits was also substantially diminished.
Principles (GAAP). Thus, corporate governance plays a role
In contrast, controlling shareholders are motivated to hire
in enhancing the effectiveness of the audit function.
low-quality auditors to seek potential opaqueness gains at all
Francis and Wilson (1988) examined the relationship
times, especially if they are operating in a weak corporate
between a firm’s agency costs and its demand for audit
governance environment where there are only loose monitor-
quality in the US market. They find that, concentrated own-
ing and binding contracts (Felo, Krishnamurthy, & Solieri,
ership, a proxy for close alignment of interest between a
2003). To address the research question empirically, we set
controlling shareholder and the listed firm, can substitute
out to test the association between the firms’ internal corpo-
for good audit quality and therefore is associated with
rate governance mechanism and their auditor switching deci-
choice of a low-quality auditor. However, in China, as own-
sions, i.e., whether firms with a weak internal corporate
ership is highly concentrated and legal protection of minor-
governance mechanism are more likely to switch to a lower-
ity shareholders is insufficient, ownership concentration
quality auditor.
may lead to severe entrenchment problems and therefore
If such an association does not exist, internal corporate
represent poor corporate governance.
governance mechanism may not impact the type of auditor
The association between corporate governance and exter-
switches. Alternatively, if auditors of different size offer
nal auditing is an important issue worthy of serious study. In
monitoring services with varied levels of quality, the firms’
particular, as the agency relationship, the business adminis-
internal corporate governance mechanism may impact the
trative system, and corporate governance practices in emerg-
switch type, in respect of the varied monitoring functions on
ing markets such as China differ substantially from those in
the firms’ opaqueness gains. The association may be evi-
the developed economies (Tam, 2000), we are interested in
dence of the cost-benefit based demand for audit monitor-
finding out whether empirical results are similar in the
ing: when the opaqueness gains outweigh the benefits of
Chinese market as in the United States. This study will not
lowering capital raising costs, lower-quality auditors would
only enrich the extant auditing literature, but will also further
be preferred by Chinese firms, and especially by firms with
promote the development of corporate governance and inde-
weak internal corporate governance mechanisms, as these
pendent auditing practices in the emerging economies.
firms have more opaqueness gains to protect (DeFond,
Wong, & Li, 2000; Lin et al., 2007). By switching to a smaller
DEVELOPMENT OF THE HYPOTHESES auditor, the controlling shareholder (the agent) may com-
fortably exploit the wealth of the minority shareholders
Auditing plays two major functions: internally, auditing without being watched closely by the auditor. In contrast,
can be used to monitor management behavior and reduce switching to a larger auditor leads to more rigid audit moni-
agency costs (Jensen & Meckling, 1976); and externally, toring and hence tunneling behaviors will be confined.
auditing can be used by potential creditors and investors to We used three proxies to measure a firm’s internal cor-
evaluate the cost of capital of the company, as described by porate governance mechanism: ownership concentration
the results of a survey of members of the American Institute (shareholding of the largest owner); the effectiveness of

Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009 © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


THE DETERMINANTS OF AUDITOR SWITCHING FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CHINA 479

supervisory board (size of the supervisory board); and (3) requesting the directors and senior managers to alter
shared CEO-Chair (whether the board of directors’ chair- and/or rectify their personal activities if deemed in conflict
man and CEO positions are held by the same person). with the firm’s objectives; (4) proposing specific shareholder
A high ownership concentration is a distinct feature of meetings whenever deemed necessary; (5) fulfilling any
listed firms in China. A Chinese listed firm usually has a other duties that are stipulated in the articles of incorpora-
large controlling shareholder,2 who often is the government tion of the firm; and (6) submitting a supervisory board
or the parent state-owned enterprise.3 Nonetheless, the own- report to the shareholders’ annual general meeting. The
ership structure affects corporate governance and corporate Standard Code of Corporate Governance for Listed Compa-
value in many different ways. Johnson et al. (2000) argue that nies in China issued by the CSRC and the State Economic
more narrowly held firms may face greater agency costs and Trade Commission in 2002 further requires that super-
because the controlling shareholders will have a dominant visory board members should have some professional
influence on corporate affairs and they can easily bypass knowledge or work experience in the areas of law and
monitoring by other shareholders. La Porta, Lopez-de- accounting (CSRC, 2002).
Silanes, and Shleifer (1999) and La Porta et al. (2002) show Based on the requirements of the Company Law, the
that in the emerging transitional economies, the controlling supervisory board shall independently and effectively carry
shareholders may expropriate the minority shareholders out supervision over the activities of the directors and the
through aggressive “tunneling” behaviors. They further management as well as examine the financial affairs of the
argue that “the central agency problem in large corporations firm. Such a German-style two-tiered board system with the
around the world is that of restricting expropriation of co-existence of a board of directors and a supervisory board
minority shareholders by controlling shareholders” (La has become the backbone of corporate governance in most
Porta et al., 1999). This is particularly true for Chinese listed Chinese listed firms since the mid-1990s. Using an event
firms in which the controlling shareholders usually hold a study, Dahya, Karbhari, Xiao, and Yang (2003) report that
very high percentage of the equity shares. investors consider the supervisory board to be an important
In China, the controlling shareholders have frequently device of corporate governance in China. Chen (2005) finds
intervened in the operations of the listed firms to benefit the that there is a positive association between the size of the
parent companies, e.g., using the listed firms as guarantors supervisory board and the level of corporate governance,
for loan applications for the parent and related companies suggesting that a larger supervisory board should be more
and therefore exposing the listed firms to extra financial and effective in carrying out its legitimate monitoring responsi-
operating risks. In fact, the controlling shareholders of many bilities. We use the number of supervisory board members
listed firms are keen to raise funds only on the stock market. as a proxy for the monitoring effectiveness of the supervi-
They frequently engage in benefit transfers through the mis- sory board and have the second hypothesis:
appropriation of funds and related-party transactions to
Hypothesis 2 (H2): All other things being equal, a Chinese firm
expropriate the interests of the minority shareholders,
with fewer supervisory board members will more likely switch
which, if detected, may invite external intervention by
to a smaller auditor.
minority shareholders and other stakeholders (Lin et al.,
2007). The desire to maximize self-interest through “tunnel- Within a sound corporate governance structure, the board
ing” behaviors leads the listed firms to avoid being moni- of directors must ensure that the management acts in the
tored by a high-quality auditor. The more concentrated the best interests of the shareholders. The board of directors is
ownership structure (i.e., with a larger controlling share- responsible for execution of the resolutions passed by the
holder), the weaker the internal corporate governance shareholders’ meetings and for appointing, removing, and
mechanism. Therefore, firms with larger controlling share- remunerating senior managers. Traditionally, the sharing of
holders are expected more likely to switch to pliable the position of board of directors’ chairman and CEO has
auditors to realize opaqueness gains through tunneling been common in the United States. However, in most Euro-
behaviors or other types of misconduct, as stated below: pean, British, and Canadian businesses, in an effort to
ensure better corporate governance, these two positions are
Hypothesis 1 (H1): All other things being equal, a Chinese firm
often split. Combining the two positions does have its
with a higher percentage of total shares held by its controlling
advantages, allowing the CEO multiple perspectives on the
shareholder will more likely switch to a smaller auditor.
firm as a result of his/her multiple roles and empowering
Pursuant to the Chinese Company Law, all Chinese firms him/her to act with determination. Nonetheless, this prac-
adopted a German-style dual-board governance system, tice results in less transparency of the CEO’s activities, and
thus each listed firm has both a board of directors and a as such his/her actions can go unmonitored, which paves
supervisory board. The supervisory board is composed of the way for scandals and corruptions. To the contrary, sepa-
the shareholders’ representatives (including Chinese Com- ration of the two positions allows the board of directors’
munist Party officials) and an appropriate proportion of chairman, on behalf of the stockholders, to be more impar-
employee representatives, who are nominated by the firm’s tial in overseeing the work of the CEO and the overall per-
employee union. The Company Law specifically defines the formance of management (La Porta et al., 2002; Petra, 2006).
supervisory board as a monitoring mechanism to carry out a Investors, researchers, and government officials have
series of responsibilities, including: (1) monitoring the per- gradually accepted the view that the best practices of corpo-
formance of the directors and senior managers to ensure rate governance require the separation of the roles of board
compliance with the laws, regulations, and the articles of of directors’ chairman and CEO. Such a corporate gover-
incorporation; (2) reviewing the financial affairs of the firm; nance device has received a boost since 2003. In practice,

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009


480 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

market regulators and professional bodies in many devel- ship concentration, supervisory board, shared CEO-Chair,
oped countries require that the two important positions be control variables, error terms).
separated (Jiraporn, Young, & Davidson, 2005). In 2002 the As we classify all auditor switches into two types (upward
CSRC also adopted this requirement in its Standard Code of switches or downward switches), there are only two values
Corporate Governance for Listed Companies in China. Con- possible (0 or 1) for the dependent variable. Hence, we run
sistent with the association between internal corporate gov- logit regression, which is used to predict the probability of
ernance and the auditing function, we have the third an occurrence of an event by fitting the data to a logistic
hypothesis stated as the following: curve. It makes use of several predictor variables that may be
either numerical or categorical. The logistic function is
Hypothesis 3 (H3): All other things being equal, a Chinese firm
useful because it can take as an input any value from nega-
with the board of directors’ chairman and CEO positions held
tive infinity to positive infinity, whereas the output is con-
by the same person is more likely to switch to a smaller auditor.
fined to values of either 0 or 1. The dependent variable
represents the exposure to some set of risk factors, whereas
RESEARCH METHODOLOGY f(dependent variable) = 1/(1 + exp (-dependent variable))
represents the probability of a particular outcome, given that
Model Specification set of risk factors. The following logit model is used to test
Hypotheses 1 to 3.
We intend to examine the determinants of audit switching
from the perspective of the internal corporate governance
mechanism of Chinese listed firms. Our sample includes DS = β0 + β1LSH + β2 SB + β3CEOCHR + β4 GOV + β5OPI
firms that switched auditors from 2001 to 2004. We classified + β6 LNASSET + β7 LEV + β8 MB + β9 LOSS + β10 NWISS
all firms that switched auditors only once during the 4-year + β11Yr 02 ∗ LSH + β12Yr 03 ∗ LSH + β13Yr 04 ∗ LSH
test period into two types – those switching to a larger + β14Yrr 02 ∗ SB + β15Yr 03 ∗ SB + β16Yr 04 ∗ SB
auditor (upward switching, or US firms) and those switch- + β17 Yr 02 ∗ CEOCHR + β18Yr 03 ∗ CEOCHR
ing to a smaller auditor (downward switching, or DS firms) + β19Yr 04 ∗ CEOCHR + ε (1)
according to the ranking order of auditors in China, which
was compiled by the CICPA in terms of the CPA firms’ Please see Table 1 for a description of the variables in the
annual audit revenue (see Appendix). As elaborated earlier, model.
the size of the auditing firm is regarded as an effective Three groups of variables, as discussed below, help
surrogate for the independence and monitoring strength of explain why certain factors trigger a certain type of auditor
the auditors (Copley & Douthett, 2002; DeAngelo, 1981). switching. The first group consists of corporate governance
Thus we construct a model to test whether the firm’s internal variables, namely ownership concentration (LSH), super-
corporate governance mechanism (proxied by ownership visory board (SB), and shared CEO-Chair positions
concentration, supervisory board, and shared CEO-Chair) (CEOCHR). Although the controlling shareholders may seek
is associated with the different types of auditor switch- to influence auditor selection so as to facilitate their tunnel-
ing (namely, upward switching or downward switching). ing behaviors, they are subject to the constraints of the cor-
Downward switching (DS) can be expressed as a function of porate governance structure in place. The second group
the three corporate governance variables in which we are consists of company-specific variables that have been tested
interested and the related control variables: DS = f (owner- or are considered helpful to explain auditor switching in

TABLE 1
Description of Variables

DS = 1 if the firm switches to a smaller auditor; 0 otherwise


LSH = largest owner’s shareholding as a percentage of total shares
SB = number of members of the SB
CEOCHR = 1 if the CEO also holds the position of chairman of BoD; 0 otherwise
GOV = 1 if the largest shareholder is a government agency; 0 otherwise
OPI = 1 if the firm receives an unclean auditor’s opinion for the previous year; 0 otherwise
LNASSET = log of total assets at the end of the previous year
LEV = long-term liabilities divided by total assets at the end of the previous year
MB = market to book ratio at the end of the previous year, calculated as the market value of stocks divided by
the book value
LOSS = 1 if the firm experiences a loss for the previous year; 0 otherwise
NWISS = 1 if there is a new equity issue in the two years immediately after auditor switching; 0 otherwise
Yr02 = 1 if the auditor switching occurs in Year 2002; 0 otherwise
Yr03 = 1 if the auditor switching occurs in Year 2003; 0 otherwise
Yr04 = 1 if the auditor switching occurs in Year 2004; 0 otherwise

Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009 © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


THE DETERMINANTS OF AUDITOR SWITCHING FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CHINA 481

prior studies, including government control (GOV), audi- ing Big 6 auditors tend to be highly leveraged, whereas
tor’s opinion (OPI), size (LNASSET), financial leverage Titman and Trueman (1986) predict otherwise. As there are
(LEV), market-to-book ratio (MB), profitability (LOSS), and opposing arguments and findings regarding the association
new issues (NWISS). As there were new requirements in the between a firm’s leverage and its auditor switching, we do
Standard Code of Corporate Governance during the test not predict the sign of the coefficient for financial leverage.
period, we incorporate the third group of interactions vari- We also include the market-to-book ratio to control for the
ables to capture the yearly impact of the gradual adoption of propensity of growing firms to switch to less conservative
these new requirements, namely Yr02, Yr03, and Yr04. With auditors (DeFond & Subramanyam 1998). Moreover, Sainty,
the interactions terms, we intend to test whether the impact Taylor, and Williams (2002) document that profitability may
of corporate governance mechanism on auditor switching affect the selection of auditors. In our model, we expect a net
varies with the progress of corporate governance practice. loss in the prior year (LOSS) to be positively associated with
In the regression, the dependent variable is defined by the a downward switch of auditors.
types of auditor switching, thus it is coded 1 if a firm Firms may change auditors (especially from a low-quality
switched to an auditor that was smaller than its predecessor. auditor to a high-quality auditor) to increase the marketabil-
For the independent variables, we expect b1 (for ownership ity of new securities (Carpenter & Strawser, 1971). Pae and
concentration) and b3 (for shared CEO-Chair) to have posi- Yoo (2001) document a negative relationship between audit
tive signs as firms with a high ownership concentration and quality and the cost of raising capital, i.e., a firm can reduce
a shared board of directors’ chairman and CEO are more its costs of raising capital by hiring a quality auditor. We
likely to switch to a smaller auditor. But b2 (for supervisory therefore include the variable of new issues (NWISS) in our
board) is expected to be negative as a large or strong super- regression model, which equals 1 if the listed firm issues
visory board may inhibit the firm from switching to a new equity to the public in the two years after its auditor
smaller auditor. switching and 0 otherwise. The new issue is used to proxy
Government controlled and non-government controlled for the firm’s intentions to issue new equity at the time of the
(privately owned or privately controlled) firms may have auditor switching. Although the firms in our sample gener-
differing corporate governance structures and may also have ally did not intend to issue new equity to the public during
different considerations when making auditor switching our test period, for accuracy and completeness we still
decisions. In general, government agencies have a stronger include the variable. Since 2002, new corporate governance
influence over government-controlled firms and therefore requirements have been announced and implemented,
can more easily access the firm’s financial information therefore we add the year dummy variables for 2002 to 2004
for their decision making (Chan, Lin, & Mo, 2006). There- to capture the potential impact of these new corporate gov-
fore, government-controlled firms may have less demand for ernance devices on the firms’ auditor switching decisions
high-quality independent audits and may have a greater during the test period.
propensity, compared with non-government controlled
firms, to switch to smaller auditors. Hence we add the vari-
able GOV to capture the effect of government control over
Sampling
the firm’s auditor switching decisions. This variable is coded Our sample covers A-share firms that switched auditors
as 1 if the largest owner of the firm is a government agency from the beginning of 2001 to the end of 2004.4 There are two
and 0 otherwise. It is expected to be positively associated main reasons to limit the sample firms that made auditor
with a downward switch of auditors. switches to this time period. The first one is the availability of
We also control for the effects the auditor’s opinion, firm the ranking of Chinese auditors, which has been compiled
size, financial leverage (risk), growth potential, profitability, by the CICPA since 2002. Thus it provides the possibility of
and whether there is new issue of equity after the auditor identifying or classifying the different types of auditor
switching. Prior auditor switching studies focus mainly on switches (i.e., an upward switch or a downward switch). The
the auditing markets in the Western countries. Nonetheless, second reason is that during this time period, firms had little
the basic theories and findings in prior research on auditor intention to offer equity to the public, therefore the opaque-
switching should be applicable to this study as well because ness gains from weak corporate governance significantly
the Chinese auditing profession in recent years has gradually outweighed the benefits from lowering the costs of raising
adopted international accounting and auditing standards. capital. Hence, the bear market period from 2001 to 2004 is
One very common reason cited for auditor switching is appropriate to test the association between the firms’ inter-
the qualifications of the auditor’s opinions. Prior research nal corporate governance mechanism and their auditor
has found that firms receiving unfavorable audit reports are switching decisions. Data were collected from the China
more likely to switch auditors (DeFond & Subramanyam, Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) Database,
1998). We expect that the auditor’s opinion (receiving an the TEJ database (carrying financial information and stock
unfavorable auditor opinion in the prior year = 1) to be posi- market data compiled by the Taiwan Economic Journal), and
tively related to a downward switch of auditors. Large firms authoritative national newspapers or magazines designated
may be less likely to switch to a smaller auditor, as financial by the CSRC to publish financial reports of listed firms, such
analysts and the financial press will more closely scrutinize as China Securities Daily, Shenzhen Securities Times, and
their auditor switches. Following Friedlan (1994), we use the Shanghai Securities News. The collected data on the sample
log of the total assets to control for the size effect of the firms firms were cross-checked and verified by different data
and we expect it to be negative in the regression model. sources to ensure their reliability. A description of the data is
Reed, Trombley, and Dhaliwal (2000) find that firms select- provided in Table 2.

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009


482

TABLE 2

Volume 17
Description of Data

Panel A1: Sample Selection


Firms switched auditors during 2001–2004 316
Less: Firms with missing data 47

Number 4
Financial, transportation, and utility firms 11
Firms switched auditors for more than once during 2001–2004 25
Final sample 233

Panel A2: Sample Distribution by Sector and Year

July 2009
Sector 2001 2002 2003 2004 Total

Industry 49 42 32 17 140
Commerce 10 8 6 5 29
Property 7 5 6 4 22
Conglomerate 13 10 9 10 42
Total 79 65 53 36 233

Panel B: Descriptive Statistics of Variables


Variable N Mean Median MIN MAX STD

DS 233 .42 0 0 1 .50


LSH (%) 233 48.94 48.38 .43 89.51 18.11
SB (#) 233 4.21 3 1 12 1.73
CEOCHR 233 .06 0 0 1 .25
GOV 233 .79 1 0 1 .41
OPI 233 .16 0 0 1 .37
LNASSET 233 21.04 20.94 19.03 24.60 .89
LEV 233 .08 .06 .00 .51 .09
MB 233 5.88 3.88 1.27 230.39 15.65
LOSS 233 .12 0 0 1 .33
NWISS 233 .03 0 0 1 .18
Yr02 233 .28 0 0 1 .45
Yr03 233 .23 0 0 1 .42
Yr04 233 .15 0 0 1 .36
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


Table 2.
Continued

Panel C: Correlation Coefficient Matrix of Variables

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


Variable DS LSH SB CEOCHR LNASSET LEV MB LOSS OPI GOV NWISS Yr02 Yr03 Yr04

DS 1.00***
LSH .11† 1.00***
SB .09† -.05 1.00***
CEOCHR .13** .07 .01 1.00***
LNASSET -.18*** .20*** -.07 -.15** 1.00***
LEV .04 -.16*** .05 -.16*** .25*** 1.00***
MB .13** -.04 -.02 -.03 -.10† -.01 1.00***
LOSS .07 .04 -.03 -.05 -.21*** -.08 .01 1.00***
OPI .05 -.04 .05 -.07 -.14** .06 .19*** .44*** 1.00***
GOV -.00 .21*** -.03 -.08 .09† .02 -.01 .00 -.12** 1.00***
NWISS -.07 -.08 -.06 -.05 -.04 .03 -.04 -.07 -.08 -.13** 1.00***
Yr02 .05 .02 .06 .03 .04 -.00 -.05 .03 -.04 -.01 -.01 1.00***
Yr03 -.16*** -.09† .01 .03 .10† -.02 -.08 .04 -.04 -.05 .01 -.34*** 1.00***
Yr04 .11** -.01 -.00 -.11** -.01 .05 -.04 .09† .01 .02 -.02 -.27*** -.23*** 1.00***

***, **, and † denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
The variables are defined as below:

DS = 1 if the firm switches to a smaller auditor; 0 otherwise


LSH = the largest owner’s shareholding as a percentage of total shares
SB = number of SB members
CEOCHR = 1 if the CEO also holds the position of the BoD chairman; 0 otherwise
LNASSET = log of total assets at the end of the previous year
LEV = long-term liabilities divided by total assets at the end of the previous year
MB = market-to-book ratio at the end of the previous year, calculated as the market value of stocks divided by the book value
LOSS = 1 if the firm experiences a net loss for the previous year; 0 otherwise

Volume 17
OPI = 1 if the firm receives an unclean (non-standard) auditor opinion for the previous year; 0 otherwise
GOV = 1 if the largest shareholder is a government agency; 0 otherwise
NWISS = 1 if there is a new equity issue in the two years immediately after auditor switching; 0 otherwise
Yr02 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2002; 0 otherwise
Yr03 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2003; 0 otherwise

Number 4
Yr03 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2004; 0 otherwise
THE DETERMINANTS OF AUDITOR SWITCHING FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CHINA

July 2009
483
484 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

At the end of 2004, there were 1,387 A-share firms listed upward switch), we use a logit regression. With a Chi-square
on the two stock exchanges in China, among which 316 of 40.03, p < .01, and a pseudo R-square of .21, the regression
firms (22.7 per cent) switched auditors during the four-year model is satisfactory in differentiating firms switching to
period from 2001 to 2004. This implies that generally a firm smaller auditors from firms switching to larger auditors at
is not willing to switch auditors because of the potential high an acceptable level of significance. The probability of a down-
costs associated with auditor switching, such as the costs of ward switch can be expressed as f(DS) = 1/(1 + exp(-DS)),
searching for and renegotiating with a new auditor and the i.e., the larger the value of the DS, the higher the probability
potentially unfavorable market responses to an auditor of a downward switch.
switch (Reed et al., 2000; Watkins et al., 2004). Panel A of The coefficient for ownership concentration is positively
Table 2 presents the sample size for this study. Financial, significant at the 5 per cent level (Coeff. = .02, Wald =
transportation, and utility firms are excluded because the 4.78, p < .05), which supports H1. If under the current situa-
nature of their operations is very different from that of other tion the probability of a downward switch f(DS) is exactly .50
types of firms. We also delete firms that switched auditors (equal probability of an upward switch or a downward
more than once during the four-year period. The frequent switch), then an increase of 10 per cent of the total sharehold-
switching of auditors may indicate some serious underlying ing will cause f(DS) to increase to .55. This suggests that firms
reasons that are beyond the scope of this study. Further- with a higher degree of ownership concentration (i.e., higher
more, firms that switched twice or more may have switched percentage of equity shares held by the largest shareholder)
to a larger auditor at one time and to a smaller auditor the are more likely to switch to a smaller auditor. Although the
other time, making it difficult to categorize the type of test results seem to be the same as Francis and Wilson 1988
switching. The final sample consists of 233 firms. findings, our interpretation is completely different. The rela-
tively high internal ownership in upward switches should
better align the interests between managers and sharehold-
EMPIRICAL RESULTS ers, but may not be significant enough to expropriate the
minority shareholders, and hence proxies for effective corpo-
Panel B of Table 2 presents the basic statistics on the tested rate governance (Francis & Wilson, 1988; Sabherwal & Smith,
variables. Among the 233 sample firms, 134 firms switched 2008). Effective corporate governance can substitute for a
to larger auditors and 99 firms switched to smaller auditors, quality auditor, and therefore is associated with switching to
based on the rankings prepared by the CICPA. On average, a lower-quality auditor in the United States. In contrast, in
the largest controlling owners held 48.94 per cent of the total China, due to the awfully high level of concentration, the
shares of the sample firms, indicating a high ownership divergence between cash flow rights and control rights, and
concentration in the Chinese listed firms. About 79 per cent the ineffective legal protection, entrenchment problems
of our sample firms were directly owned by the government become detrimental, hence ownership concentration proxies
or governmental agencies, reflecting that most Chinese for poor corporate governance. Poor corporate governance
listed firms were originally carved out from state-owned allows the controlling shareholders more space to hire a
enterprises and that various government agencies remain lower-quality auditor to realize their opaqueness gains,
the largest owners of the listed firms. In the sample, 16 per therefore leading to our results – a high ownership concen-
cent (37/233) of the firms received unfavorable auditor opin- tration, a proxy for poor corporate governance, is associated
ions before their auditor switches. This high percentage may with switching to a lower-quality auditor.
support the assertion that there is an association between The coefficient for the size of the supervisory board is
receiving unfavorable auditor reports and switching audi- insignificant (Coeff. = .03, Wald = .05, p > .10), therefore H2
tors. The average size of the supervisory board was about is not supported, indicating that the effectiveness of super-
4.21, with a minimum of 1 member and a maximum of 12 visory board monitoring may not be related to whether a
members. In 6 per cent of the sample firms (15/233), the firm switches to a larger or a smaller auditor. Another pos-
CEO also held the position of board of directors’ chairman. sible interpretation is that in practice the monitoring role of
Very few firms intended to issue equity during the bear the supervisory board is dubious, thus the supervisory
market, as indicated in the table that only 3 per cent (8/233) board presently does not have a significant impact on a
of the sample firms issued equity in the two-year period firm’s auditor switching decision. In fact, as supervisory
after their auditor switching. board members are mainly from inside the firm, whether the
Panel C of Table 2 presents the correlation coefficient supervisory board can effectively play a monitoring role is
matrix for the variables used in the regression model. A controversial. Some researchers contend that the supervi-
downward switch is significantly and positively correlated sory board is mainly decorative in China (Dahya et al., 2003)
with ownership concentration, shared CEO-Chair, and and our findings seem to support this viewpoint.
market-to-book ratio; and it is significantly and negatively Consistent with H3, the coefficient for the shared CEO-
related to firm size. The correlation coefficients among the Chair is positive and significant at the 5 per cent level
independent variables are moderate, with no value exceed- (Coeff. = 1.28, Wald = 3.85, p < .05). If the current status is the
ing .50 (the largest is .44). separation of the CEO and the board of directors’ chairman
Table 3 provides the empirical results from the regression and the probability of a downward switch f(DS) is exactly
which tests whether a firm with a weak internal corporate .50, then a change to the combination of the two key roles
governance mechanism is inclined to switch to a smaller will lead f(DS) to increase to .78. Thus, a firm is more likely
auditor. Since there are only two values possible for the to switch to a smaller auditor if its CEO also holds the
dependent variable (1 for a downward switch and 0 for an position of board of directors’ chairman, as expected.

Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009 © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


TABLE 3
Internal Corporate Governance Mechanism and Switching to a Smaller Auditor – Main Test
DS = β0 + β1LSH + β2 SB + β3CEOCHR + β4GOV + β5OPI + β6 LNASSET + β7 LEV + β8 MB + β9 LOSS + β10 NWISS + β11Yr 02 ∗ LSH + β12Yr 03 ∗ LSH

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


+ β13Yr 04 ∗ LSH + β14Yrr 02 ∗ SB + β15Yr 03 ∗ SB + β16Yr 04 ∗ SB + β17 Yr 02 ∗ CEOCHR + β18Yr 03 ∗ CEOCHR + β19Yr 04 ∗ CEOCHR + ε (1)

Intercept LSH SB CEOCHR GOV OPI LNASSET LEV MB LOSS


b0 b1 b2 b3 b4 b5 b6 b7 b8 b9

Prediction ? + - + + + - + + +
Coefficient 6.42 .02 .03 1.28 .03 -.11 -.43 3.56 .13 .18
Wald 2.25 4.78** .05 3.85** .01 .06 4.56** 3.95** 3.70† .12

NWISS Yr02*LSH Yr03*LSH Yr04*LSH Yr02*SB Yr03*SB Yr04*SB Yr02*CEOCHR Yr03*CEOCHR Yr04*CEOCHR
b 10 b 11 b 12 b 13 b 14 b 15 b 16 b 17 b 18 b 19

Prediction - ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ?
Coefficient -.31 .01 -.01 .01 .03 .09 .13 .26 .09 .01
Wald .12 1.18 2.21 2.24 .03 .24 .38 .53 .20 .04

Notes: (1) The Wald-Wolfowitz test examines whether the mean (median) of each variable for Top 10 clients equals to that of non Top-10 clients. ***, **, and † denote
significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
(2) N = 233, Chi-square = 40.03, and Pseudo R-square = .21.

DS = 1 if the firm switches to a smaller auditor; 0 otherwise


LSH = the largest owner’s shareholding as a percentage of total shares
SB = number of SB members
CEOCHR = 1 if the CEO also holds the position of the BoD chairman; 0 otherwise
GOV = 1 if the largest shareholder is a government agency; 0 otherwise
OPI = 1 if the firm receives an unclean (non-standard) auditor opinion for the previous year; 0 otherwise
LNASSET = log of total assets at the end of the previous year
LEV = long-term liabilities divided by total assets at the end of the previous year

Volume 17
MB = market-to-book ratio at the end of the previous year, calculated as the market value of stocks divided by the book value
LOSS = 1 if the firm experiences a net loss for the previous year; 0 otherwise
NWISS = 1 if there is a new equity issue in the two years immediately after auditor switching; 0 otherwise
Yr02 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2002; 0 otherwise
Yr03 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2003; 0 otherwise

Number 4
Yr04 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2004; 0 otherwise
THE DETERMINANTS OF AUDITOR SWITCHING FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CHINA

July 2009
485
486 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

The coefficient of government control is positive but own a significant percentage of the total shares. After delet-
insignificant, so government-controlled firms, compared to ing the observations in which the largest owners hold less
non-government-controlled firms, are more likely to switch than 10 per cent of the total shares, the empirical results
to smaller auditors, but the difference is only marginal. In remain qualitatively the same (Table 4-2).
addition, the coefficient for the auditor opinion variable We also adopt alternative proxies to measure the control
(OPI) is positively related to switching to smaller auditors, variables. We use the log of revenues to proxy for firm size,
but not at a conventional level of significance. Therefore, the total debt to asset ratio to proxy for financial leverage,
there is insufficient evidence to support the assertion that and the increase of assets for growth. After making the
Chinese firms receiving unfavorable audit opinions are changes for these control variables, the empirical results still
inclined to switch to smaller auditors for the purpose of reveal a significantly positive relation between a downward
“opinion shopping.” This is not surprising as other studies switch (DS) and ownership concentration (LSH) and
in the United States (Watkins et al., 2004) and China (Chan et between a DS and a shared CEO-Chair (CEOCHR). Again,
al., 2006) report similar findings. the coefficient for the supervisory board is insignificant.
Consistent with our prediction, firm size is negatively Therefore, H1 and H3 are robustly supported, and there is
related to switching to a smaller auditor at the .05 level insufficient evidence for H2.
of significance (Coeff. = -.43, Wald = 4.56, p < .05). This
finding confirms that larger firms are less likely to make
downward switching decisions. The reasons may be larger CONCLUSIONS
firms have more complicated operations and they care more
about their reputation. In addition, both financial leverage The purpose of this paper is to investigate the determinants
(Coeff. = 3.56, Wald = 3.95, p < .05) and the market- of Chinese firms’ auditor switching decisions from the per-
to-book ratio (Coeff. = .13, Wald = 3.70, p < .10) have positive spective of their internal corporate governance mechanism.
and significant coefficients. Therefore, firms with greater Three measures are used to proxy for the internal corporate
growth potentials and higher financial leverage ratios are governance mechanism, including the concentration of own-
inclined to switch to smaller auditors. The profitability of ership (shareholding of the controlling owner), the effective-
firms (proxied by the loss incurred in the prior year) does ness of the supervisory board’s monitoring (proxied by
not have a significant effect on auditor switching decisions, supervisory board size), and shared CEO and board of direc-
nor does a new issue (NWISS). We suggest that the rare tors’ chairman. We divided all auditor switches during the
cases of new equity issues (8 out of 233) may be the main 2001–2004 period into two types: switching to a larger
reason for the insignificant result. auditor and switching to a smaller auditor, and empirically
As indicated by Table 3, the coefficients for year dummy examined the impact of the corporate governance variables
variables are not significant. This suggests that although on the firms’ auditor switching decisions.
Chinese listed firms were required to adopt the independent Three hypotheses are used to test the association between
non-executive director and audit committee practices in the firms’ internal corporate governance mechanism and
their corporate governance after 2002, auditor switches their auditor switching decisions. H1 and H3 are supported,
during the test period were not significantly affected. Pos- but there is insufficient evidence to support H2. Hence firms
sible explanations are that most listed firms did not adopt with larger controlling owners or firms in which the posi-
the new practices until 2004 or the enforcement of the new tions of board of directors’ chairman and CEO are held by
practices was not satisfactory during the test period. the same person are more likely to switch to a smaller
In summary, the empirical results support that there is an auditor. However, it is inconclusive whether firms with
association between a firm’s internal corporate governance smaller supervisory boards opt for a smaller auditor. So
mechanism and its auditor switching decisions. Firms with generally, we conclude that firms with a relatively weak
weaker internal corporate governance (proxied by owner- internal corporate governance mechanism are more likely to
ship concentration and a shared CEO-Chair) are inclined to switch to smaller auditors in order to protect or realize the
switch to smaller auditors so that they can shirk from more opaqueness gains associated with a weak corporate gover-
stringent audit monitoring and realize opaqueness gains. nance mechanism. That the supervisory board does not have
This result implies that the opaqueness gains derived from a significant impact on firms’ auditor switching may indicate
self-interested activities such as tunneling behaviors might supervisory board members’ inability to monitor effectively,
be a crucial consideration when Chinese firms switch possibly because they are mainly from inside the firms
auditors. and/or do not have sufficient corporate governance
expertise.
This study contributes to the literature on auditing
SENSITIVITY TESTS research. First, although some prior studies have examined
whether there is an association between firms’ auditor
To examine the robustness of the empirical results, we per- switching decisions and firm-specific characteristics, most of
formed varied sensitivity tests. First, we adopt a more strict these studies do not consider the different types of auditor
definition for a downward switch (DS), which is defined as switching, driven by different motivations. In this study, two
switching from a Top 10 auditor to a non-Top 10 auditor. The major types of auditor switching are classified, namely
empirical results are similar (Table 4-1). In order to make switching to a larger auditor and switching to a smaller one.
sure that the largest shareholder controls the listed firm, we Second, compared with the Francis and Wilson, 1988, study
limit the sample to firms in which the largest shareholders of the US market, our results are more applicable to the

Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009 © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


TABLE 4-1
Internal Corporate Governance Mechanism and Switching to a Smaller Auditor – Sensitivity: Top 10 to Non-Top 10
DS = β0 + β1LSH + β2 SB + β3CEOCHR + β4GOV + β5OPI + β6 LNASSET + β7 LEV + β8 MB + β9 LOSS + β10 NWISS + β11Yr 02 ∗ LSH + β12Yr 03 ∗ LSH

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


+ β13Yr 04 ∗ LSH + β14Yrr 02 ∗ SB + β15Yr 03 ∗ SB + β16Yr 04 ∗ SB + β17 Yr 02 ∗ CEOCHR + β18Yr 03 ∗ CEOCHR + β19Yr 04 ∗ CEOCHR + ε (1)

Intercept LSH SB CEOCHR GOV OPI LNASSET LEV MB LOSS


b0 b1 b2 b3 b4 b5 b6 b7 b8 b9

Pred. ? + - + + + - + + +
Coeff. 12.80 .04 .40 1.33 -.08 -.59 -1.21 3.05 .19 -.22
Wald 3.20† 4.23** .40 4.00** .08 1.27 4.01** .51 .46 .01

NWISS Yr02*LSH Yr03*LSH Yr04*LSH Yr02*SB Yr03*SB Yr04*SB Yr02*CEOCHR Yr03*CEOCHR Yr04*CEOCHR
b 10 b 11 b 12 b 13 b 14 b 15 b 16 b 17 b 18 b 19

Pred. - ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ?
Coeff. -.18 .01 .01 .02 -.21 -.05 -.28 .35 -.34 .15
Wald .03 1.11 .58 2.19 .28 .05 .16 1.70 1.31 .60

Notes: (1) The Wald-Wolfowitz test examines whether the mean (median) of each variable for Top 10 clients equals to that of non Top-10 clients. ***, **, and † denote
significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
(2) N = 62, Chi-square = 42.02, and Pseudo R-square = .67.

DS = 1 if the firm switches to a smaller auditor; 0 otherwise


LSH = the largest owner’s shareholding as a percentage of total shares
SB = number of SB members
CEOCHR = 1 if the CEO also holds the position of the BoD chairman; 0 otherwise
GOV = 1 if the largest shareholder is a government agency; 0 otherwise
OPI = 1 if the firm receives an unclean (non-standard) auditor opinion for the previous year; 0 otherwise
LNASSET = log of total assets at the end of the previous year

Volume 17
LEV = long-term liabilities divided by total assets at the end of the previous year
MB = market-to-book ratio at the end of the previous year, calculated as the market value of stocks divided by the book value
LOSS = 1 if the firm experiences a net loss for the previous year; 0 otherwise
NWISS = 1 if there is a new equity issue in the two years immediately after auditor switching; 0 otherwise
Yr02 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2002; 0 otherwise
Yr03 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2003; 0 otherwise

Number 4
Yr04 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2004; 0 otherwise
THE DETERMINANTS OF AUDITOR SWITCHING FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CHINA

July 2009
487
488

TABLE 4-2

Volume 17
Internal Corporate Governance Mechanism and Switching to a Smaller Auditor – Sensitivity: Ten Per Cent Cutoff
DS = β0 + β1LSH + β2 SB + β3CEOCHR + β4GOV + β5OPI + β6 LNASSET + β7 LEV + β8 MB + β9 LOSS + β10 NWISS + β11Yr 02 ∗ LSH + β12Yr 03 ∗ LSH
+ β13Yr 04 ∗ LSH + β14Yrr 02 ∗ SB + β15Yr 03 ∗ SB + β16Yr 04 ∗ SB + β17 Yr 02 ∗ CEOCHR + β18Yr 03 ∗ CEOCHR + β19Yr 04 ∗ CEOCHR + ε (1)

Number 4
Intercept LSH SB CEOCHR GOV OPI LNASSET LEV MB LOSS
b0 b1 b2 b3 b4 b5 b6 b7 b8 b9

Pred. ? + - + + + - + + +
Coeff. 6.73 .02 .04 1.25 .05 -.13 -.44 3.45 .13 .16

July 2009
Wald 2.48 4.17** .05 3.93** .01 .08 4.66** 3.70† 3.57† .10

NWISS Yr02*LSH Yr03*LSH Yr04*LSH Yr02*SB Yr03*SB Yr04*SB Yr02*CEOCHR Yr03*CEOCHR Yr04*CEOCHR
b 10 b 11 b 12 b 13 b 14 b 15 b 16 b 17 b 18 b 19

Pred. - ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ?
Coeff. -.37 .00 -.01 .01 .02 .08 .12 .27 .07 .02
Wald .17 .79 1.99 2.14 .02 .22 .24 .63 .19 .15

Notes: (1) The Wald-Wolfowitz test examines whether the mean (median) of each variable for Top 10 clients equals to that of non Top-10 clients. ***, **, and † denote
significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
(2) N = 230, Chi-square = 38.88, and Pseudo R-square = .21.

DS = 1 if the firm switches to a smaller auditor; 0 otherwise


LSH = the largest owner’s shareholding as a percentage of total shares
SB = number of SB members
CEOCHR = 1 if the CEO also holds the position of the BoD chairman; 0 otherwise
GOV = 1 if the largest shareholder is a government agency; 0 otherwise
OPI = 1 if the firm receives an unclean (non-standard) auditor opinion for the previous year; 0 otherwise
LNASSET = log of total assets at the end of the previous year
LEV = long-term liabilities divided by total assets at the end of the previous year
MB = market-to-book ratio at the end of the previous year, calculated as the market value of stocks divided by the book value
LOSS = 1 if the firm experiences a net loss for the previous year; 0 otherwise
NWISS = 1 if there is a new equity issue in the two years immediately after auditor switching; 0 otherwise
Yr02 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2002; 0 otherwise
Yr03 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2003; 0 otherwise
Yr04 = 1 if the switching occurs in Year 2004; 0 otherwise
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


THE DETERMINANTS OF AUDITOR SWITCHING FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CHINA 489

emerging economies, where there is a high degree of own- the supply sides of the independent auditing function. In
ership concentration and the main agency relationship is addition, when sufficient data become available, other cor-
between the controlling and minority shareholders. Third, porate governance variables, such as the characteristics of
while prior research (Jensen & Meckling, 1976) contends the independent directors and the different committees
that auditing can serve a major role of coping with agency under board of directors may be incorporated into the
problems and reducing agency costs, this function is regression model.
not hailed by Chinese firms (usually with highly concen-
trated ownership) when financing opportunities are rare.
This study will be helpful for understanding the recent ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
development of auditing and corporate governance prac-
tices in emerging markets such as China. We are grateful to the editor William Judge, the Guest
There are also important policy implications from this Editor, two anonymous reviewers, and the participants of
study. The quality of independent audits and corporate dis- the Symposium on Corporate Governance in China and
closure is identified as an important factor for the Chinese India for their helpful comments and suggestions. We
stock market, which is in transition towards a market- acknowledge the financial support from Faculty Research
oriented economy. Our findings on the determinants of Grants of Hong Kong Baptist University and from the
auditor switching in the Chinese context will shed light on Research Committee of University of Macau.
how to improve firms’ corporate governance and audit
monitoring to enhance the credibility of corporate reporting
and to promote smooth development of the capital market. NOTES
As CSRC has granted licenses to Qualified Foreign Institu-
tional Investors (QFII) to participate directly in China’s 1. Most listed firms in China did not establish audit committees
domestic stock market, the findings suggest that interna- responsible for engaging auditors until 2004 or 2005. Before the
tional investors need to be aware of the structural arrange- establishment of audit committees, the controlling shareholders,
ment of corporate governance of the listed firms and the through the management, basically made the auditor selection
effectiveness of audit monitoring in China. decisions.
To bolster the confidence of the market participants, the 2. In China, the largest owner (mainly the parent state-owned
Chinese government should promote the reform of corpo- enterprise) held, on average, around 50 per cent of the total
rate governance of the listed firms and enhance the regula- equity of listed firms in 2000.
3. Most Chinese listed firms were restructured from former state-
tors’ surveillance over the behaviors of the controlling owned enterprises (SOEs). There are normally three types of
shareholders. In particular, regulators should closely watch equity holding for a Chinese listed firm, namely the state-owned
over firms’ auditor switches, and especially those downward shares (representing the state’s interest in the firm), the social-
switches, with an aim of preventing possible expropriation legal-entity shares (mainly the interest of the parent state-owned
of minority shareholders’ interests thereafter. As a result, the enterprise or other social agencies), and the public shares held
auditing profession and the stock market may be able to by institutional and individual investors, nevertheless, a major
develop smoothly in China. In line with the continuing part of the total equity shares is usually controlled by the
progress of the economic reforms and business restructur- state (government agencies) and/or the parent state-owned
ing, the Chinese accounting and auditing practices have enterprise.
moved towards internationalization rapidly in recent years. 4. The stock market in China is segregated. A-share firms are for
domestic investors whereas a small number of B-share firms are
Therefore the Chinese experience involving auditor switch- mainly for overseas investors. According to the existing regula-
ing can be borrowed by other emerging economies in their tions, the financial statements of B-share firms must be audited
development of the independent audit function as well. by international auditing firms (usually the Big 5/4). There are
In future research, as more Chinese firms report their few auditor switches for B-share firms because of the limited
auditing fee information, more rigorous simultaneous equa- availability of alternative auditors. In this paper, firms that issue
tion methods may be used to control both the demand and both A- and B-shares are excluded.

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009


490 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

APPENDIX
Ranking of Auditors in China
Ranking Auditor Ranking Auditor

1 PwC Zhongtian 44 Jiangsu Tianhua


2 KPMG Huazhen 45 Huayan
3 Deloitte Huayong 46 Gansu Wulian
4 EY Huaming 47 Zhejiang Wanbang
5 Lixin Changjiang 48 Beijing Zhongzhou
6 Yuehua 49 Huazheng
7 Xinyongzhonghe 50 Guangdong Hengxin
8 Beijing Jingdu 51 Nanjing Yonghua
9 Jiangsu Gongzheng 52 Shandong Wanlu
10 EY Dahua 53 Chongqing Tianjian
11 Zhongshen 54 Xi’an Sigma
12 Zhongruihua 55 Jiangsu Tianye
13 Tianzhizixin 56 Anhui Huapu
14 Shanghai Zhonghua 57 Xiamen Tianjian
15 Li’anda 58 Sichuan Huaxin
16 Zhejiang Tianjian 59 Shandong Huide
17 Tianjian 60 Beijing Zhongxingyu
18 Guangzhou Yangcheng 61 Beijing Zhongwei
19 Zhongtianhuazheng 62 Shenzhen Tianjian
20 Shenzhen Pengcheng 63 Fujian Huaxing
21 Shanghai Donghua 64 Beijing Zhongxing
22 Tianyi 65 Shanghai Wanlong
23 Hubei Daxin 66 Shandong Tianhengxin
24 Shanghai Gongxin 67 Yatai Group
25 Jiangsu Suya 68 Zhongtianyin
26 Zhongxi 69 Huajian
27 Zhongxingcai 70 Guangdong Kangyuan
28 Wuhan Zhonghuan 71 Shanghai Tongcheng
29 Zhejiang Dongfang 72 Zhonghengxin
30 Beijing Zhongluhua 73 Beijing Zhongzheng
31 Shanghai Shangkuai 74 Shanghai Shangshen
32 Tianjin Wuzhou 75 Liaoning Tianjian
33 Shandong Zhengyuan 76 Beijing Xinghua
34 Shenzhen Nanfang 77 Beijing Zhongtianheng
35 Shenzhen Dahua 78 Shandong Qianju
36 Guangdong Zhengzhong 79 Sichuan Hongri
37 Hu’nan Kaiyuan 80 Zhongqin Wanxin
38 Beijing Yongtuo 81 Hebei Hua’an
39 Yunnan Yatai 82 Beijing Zhongpingjian
40 Zhonglei 83 Sichuan Junhe
41 Jiangsu Tianheng 84 Shanghai Jiahua
42 Guangdong Tianhua 85 Guangxi Xianghao
43 Beijing Tianhua

(1) The rankings are based on average audit revenues of Year 2002–2004 as compiled by the CICPA.
(2) Auditors must be ranked among the top 100 based on revenues for each year of 2002–2004.
(3) An auditor ranked higher is larger than an auditor ranked lower. It is a downward switch if a listed firm switches from a higher
ranked auditor to a lower ranked one, and vice versa.

Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009 © 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd


THE DETERMINANTS OF AUDITOR SWITCHING FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CHINA 491

REFERENCES Johnson, W. B. & Lys, T. 1990. The market for audit services: Evi-
dence from voluntary auditor changes. Journal of Accounting
Ang, J. S., Cole, R. A., & Lin, J. W. 2000. Agency costs and owner- and Economics, 12: 281–308.
ship structure. Journal of Finance, 55: 81–106. Karpoff, J. M., Malatesta, P. H., & Walkling, R. A. 1996. Corporate
Carpenter, C. G. & Strawser, R. H. 1971. Displacement of auditors governance and shareholder initiatives: Empirical evidence.
when clients go public. Journal of Accountancy, 131(6): 55–58. Journal of Financial Economics, 42: 365–395.
Chan, K. H., Lin, K. Z., & Mo, P. L. 2006. A political-economic La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. 1999. Corporate
analysis of auditor reporting and auditor switches. Review of ownership around the world. Journal of Finance, 54: 471–517.
Accounting Studies, 11(1): 21–48. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. 2002.
Chen, J. J. 2005. China’s institutional environment and corporate Investor protection and corporate valuation. Journal of Finance,
governance. In M. Hirschey, J. Kose, & A. K. Makhija (Eds.), 57: 1147–1170.
Corporate governance: A global perspective, vol. 11: 75–93. Lennox, C. S. 2005. Audit quality and executive officers’ affiliation
Boston: JAI. with CPA firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39: 201–
Copley, P. A. & Douthett, E. B., Jr. 2002. The association between 231.
auditor choice, ownership retained, and earnings disclosure by Lin, Z. J., Tang, Q. L., & Xiao, J. 2003. An experimental study of
firms making initial public offerings. Contemporary Accounting users’ responses to qualified audit reports in China. Journal of
Research, 19(1): 49–75. International Accounting, Auditing, and Taxation, 12(1): 1–21.
CSRC. 2002. Standard code on corporate governance for publicly Lin, Z. J., Liu, M., & Zhang, X. 2007. The development of corporate
listed companies (in Chinese). Beijing, China. governance in China. The Company Lawyer, 28(7): 195–203.
CSRC. 2005. An introduction to China’s securities and futures Pae, S. & Yoo, S. W. 2001. Strategic interaction in auditing: An
markets (in Chinese). Beijing, China. analysis of auditors’ legal liability, internal control system quality,
Dahya, J., Karbhari, Y., Xiao, J. Z., & Yang, M. 2003. The usefulness and audit effort. Accounting Review, 76: 333–356.
of the supervisory board report in China. Corporate Governance: Petra, S. T. 2006. Corporate governance reforms: Fact or fiction?
An International Review, 11: 308–321. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 6: 107–116.
DeAngelo, L. E. 1981. Auditor size and audit quality. Journal of Reed, B. J., Trombley, M. A., & Dhaliwal, D. S. 2000. Demand for
Accounting and Economics, 3: 183–199. audit quality: The case of Laventhol and Horwath’s auditees.
DeFond, M. L., & Subramanyam, K. R. 1998. Auditor changes and Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance, 15(2): 183–198.
discretionary accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 25: Sabherwal, S. & Smith, S. D. 2008. Concentrated shareholders as
35–67. substitutes for outsider analysts. Corporate Governance: An
DeFond, M. L., Wong, T. J., & Li, S. 2000. The impact of improved International Review, 16: 562–577.
auditor independence on audit market concentration in China. Sainty, B. J., Taylor, G. K., & Williams, D. D. 2002. Investor dissat-
Journal of Accounting and Economics, 28: 269–305. isfaction toward auditors. Journal of Accounting. Auditing and
Denis, D. K. & McConnell, J. J. 2003. International corporate gover- Finance, 17(2): 111–136.
nance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 38(1): Tam, O. K. 2000. Models of corporate governance for Chinese com-
1–36. panies. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 8:
Felo, A. J., Krishnamurthy, S., & Solieri, S. 2003. Audit committee 52–64.
characteristics and the quality of financial reporting: An empiri- Titman, S. & Trueman, B. 1986. Information quality and the valua-
cal analysis. Working paper, Penn. State University. tion of new issues. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 8:
Francis, J. R. & Wilson, E. R. 1988. Auditor changes: A joint test of 159–172.
theories relating to agency costs and auditor differentiation. Watkins, A. L., Hillison, W., & Morecroft, S. E. 2004. Audit quality:
Accounting Review, 63: 663–682. A synthesis of theory and empirical evidence. Journal of
Friedlan, J. M. 1994. Accounting choices of issuers of initial public Accounting Literature, 23: 153–193.
offerings. Contemporary Accounting Research, 11(1): 1–31. Watts, R. L. & Zimmerman, J. L. 1986. Positive Accounting Theory.
Holm, C. & Laursen, P. B. 2007. Risk and control developments in Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
corporate governance: Changing the role of the external auditor?
Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15: 322–333. Z. Jun Lin is a professor of accounting in the School of
Jensen, M. C. & Meckling, W. H. 1976. Theory of the firm: Mana- Business Administration, Hong Kong Baptist University. His
gerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal research interests are financial accounting, international
of Financial Economics, 3: 305–360. accounting, auditing, and corporate governance.
Jiraporn, P., Young, S. K., & Davidson, W. N., III. 2005. CEO com-
pensation, shareholder rights, and corporate governance: An
empirical investigation. Journal of Economics and Finance, 29: Ming Liu is an assistant professor of accounting in the
242–258. Faculty of Business Administration, University of Macau.
Johnson, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. 2000. His research interests are auditing, capital market efficiency,
Tunneling. American Economic Review, 90(2): 22–27. and corporate governance.

© 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd Volume 17 Number 4 July 2009

You might also like