You are on page 1of 28

Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal

Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)


Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com). DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263

Social Entrepreneurship and the Development


Paradox of Prosocial Motivation: A Cautionary Tale
Jeffery S. McMullen* and Brian J. Bergman, Jr.
Department of Management & Entrepreneurship, Kelley School of
Business, Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana

Research summary: We provide an ethnographic account of how social entrepreneurs


in the Safe Water for Africa program made sense of hybrid goods, as well as how and
why those understandings affected both the social enterprise’s marketing mix and stake-
holders’ expectations of the enterprise’s rights and responsibilities. We find that output
maximizing-behavior enabled by prosocial motivation elicits a psychological feeling of
entitlement to a socio-emotional return on investment in the form of beneficiary gratitude.
When external stakeholders consider them justified, these feelings become moral norms
that can induce or prevent the institutionalization of a suboptimal path of development,
depending on the motivations of competitors. We show that social entrepreneurs’ emo-
tional attachment can have consequences for development, challenging the functionalist
conception of social enterprise as a temporary patch to institutional voids.
Managerial summary: We present a detailed account of the Safe Water for Africa pro-
gram that examines: (a) how the program’s stakeholders made sense of water as a
“hybrid good;” and (b) how these understandings shaped the social entrepreneurs’
attitudes, the social enterprise’s marketing mix, and stakeholder’s expectations of the
enterprise’s rights and responsibilities. We find that the same motivation that prompted
social entrepreneurs to act on behalf of those without safe water elicited a sense of
entitlement to a “return on investment” in the form of beneficiary gratitude. If recipro-
cated, these feelings may become normalized and, depending on competitors’ motives,
hinder long-term development efforts by precluding their entry. Copyright © 2017 Stra-
tegic Management Society.

Around the same time that Strategic Entrepreneur- Negroponte accused Intel of dumping their Class-
ship Journal was being formed, Nicholas Negro- mate PCs, ultimately dissolving the partnership in
ponte was in the throes of creating One Laptop Per January 2008 (Kirkpatrick, 2008a). Controversy
Child (OLPC), a social enterprise (SE) seeking to continued on May 23, 2008, as OLPC entered into
create and distribute $100 laptops to poor children an agreement with Microsoft to run Windows
in least developed countries (LDCs).1 Backed by instead of XO’s open-source operating system
the United Nations Development Program, OLPC (Kirkpatrick, 2008b). This time key personnel
looked promising enough to attract potential part- resigned in protest, and Negroponte refused to
nerships with Intel in 2007 and Microsoft in 2008. share the stage with Microsoft executives at various
However, tension between OLPC and Intel grew as public relations events. Journalists asked at the
time, “Did Negroponte really expect [Intel and
Keywords: social entrepreneurship; prosocial motivation; Microsoft] to stand idly by while he introduced a
social enterprise; paradox; development; entitlement product that would marginalize them” (Mitchell,
*Correspondence to: Jeffery S. McMullen, Kelley School of
Business, Indiana University, 1309 E. 10 Street, M3121,
2007)? In fact, these journalists appeared to see
Bloomington, IN 47405. E-mail: mcmullej@indiana.edu what Negroponte could or would not: OLPC was
1
At the time, the typical laptop ran about $1,500. already having the transformative effect on the

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society


244 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

computer industry for which it was ostensibly created. “The greatest success for a social entrepre-
“There’s no question,” noted one journalist, “OLPC neur would be to tackle a problem with
has had a catalytic effect on the industry so far. With positive externalities in such a way that the
its partnership with Microsoft, it could finally start externality is internalized for the benefit of
having the effect Negroponte has always wanted it to society and the work of the social entrepre-
have on kids” (Kirkpatrick, 2008b). Another pointed neur is no longer necessary. Note that this
out, “One good thing has come of this: The initiative same outcome of redundancy would repre-
has focused the attention of Intel and Microsoft on sent a failure for commercial entrepreneurs
low-cost laptops as never before” (Mitchell, 2007). seeking to maximize value capture through
According to social entrepreneurship theorists, sustainable advantage for their venture.
“social entrepreneurs are concerned with correcting While true commercial entrepreneurs who
perceived market and government failures—their focus care for value capture try to become indis-
is on achieving sustainable solutions instead of achiev- pensable, true social entrepreneurs who
ing sustainable advantage” (Santos, 2012, p. 345); care for value creation try to make them-
social entrepreneurs are interested “not primarily on selves dispensable. Naturally, social entre-
achieving a competitive economic advantage, but on preneurs often get emotionally attached to
spreading the social innovation as widely as possible their organization and may focus on sus-
taining the organization more than solving
in order to maximize social change and solve the pro-
the problem for society. Yet, true social
blems that [the social enterprise] aims to address
entrepreneurs should invite competition
(Chell, 2007; Drayton, 2002)” (Perrini, Vurro, & Cost-
instead of resisting it, since replication of
anzo, 2010, p. 525). Social enterprises like OLPC are
the innovative solutions will increase the
the only organizational form that seeks to maximize value created to society.”
value creation while satisficing on value capture
(Agafonow, 2014), and social entrepreneurs like
Negroponte engage in it because of prosocial motives Therefore, SE is often conceived of as an
(Miller, Grimes, McMullen, & Vogus, 2012). institutional patch that arguably succeeds by rend-
Without prosocial motives, development pro- ering itself no longer necessary, implying that it
blems, such as the underprovision of so-called pub- is temporary (e.g., Mair & Martí, 2009; McMul-
lic goods, are likely to persist because of a lack of len, 2011; Santos, 2012). But if this is true, then
financial incentives caused by institutional voids how do we reconcile it with Negroponte’s reac-
(Mair & Martí, 2006). That is, few (if any) would tion to Intel’s and Microsoft’s foray into the
offer a $100 laptop to poor children in LDCs LDC market for inexpensive laptops? If the focus
because market failure would imply that firms of social entrepreneurship is truly on value crea-
lacked the financial incentives to do so; government tion, not value capture, and SE is indeed an insti-
failure would imply that government agencies tutional patch, then would it not be reasonable to
lacked the tax revenue base to pay for them; and expect Negroponte to jump for joy and declare
charities would lack the sustained source of revenue his mission accomplished upon any announce-
needed to offer the solution in perpetuity. Hence, ment that multinational corporations (MNCs) like
there is a need for SEs like OLPC and social entre- Intel or Microsoft have taken up his cross
preneurs like Negroponte who draw upon their pro- to bear?
social motives to supplement what would otherwise Reactions like Negroponte’s to the threat of
be insufficient incentive to act. market entry by competitors appear not only
These prosocial motives encourage entrepre- inconsistent with social value creation and the
neurial action, effectively creating social value by prosocial motives from which it ostensibly flows,
creating more value than the SE can capture. In but potentially indicative of the paradoxical effect
addition, some of the value they create is financial; that prosocial motives play in encouraging social
thus, SEs can contribute to institutional develop- value creation and facilitating institutional devel-
ment by aiding the formation of a market as well opment via SE. W. K. Smith and Lewis (2011, p.
(McMullen, 2011). Such reasoning leads Santos 382) define a paradox as “contradictory yet inter-
(2012, p. 346) to suggest: related elements that exist simultaneously and

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 245

persist over time.” They add, “This definition can become moral norms that may paradoxically
highlights two components of paradox: (1) underly- preclude market entry by new competitors offering
ing tensions—that is, elements that seem logical similar or even superior solutions. Contrary to the
individually but inconsistent and even absurd functionalistic conception of social enterprise as a
when juxtaposed—and (2) responses that embrace temporary patch for institutional voids caused by
tensions simultaneously (Lewis, 2000)” (Smith & market and government failure in LDCs, our find-
Lewis, 2011, p. 382). Social entrepreneurship, and ings suggest that the feelings of entitlement evoked
SE in particular, is often presented by the litera- by prosocial motivation can contribute to the long-
ture as the paragon of paradox, mixing two mutu- term institutionalization of social enterprise, indu-
ally exclusive views. Agafonow (2015, p. 1046) cing or preventing a suboptimal path of develop-
notes: ment depending on the motives of new
organizational rivals.
“A social enterprise must either maximize
profits to have a chance to make invest-
ments that have an impact, by attracting Social Enterprise as Temporary
the capital needed to scale up, or must Institutional Patch
avoid profit maximization to prevent the
mission drift that occurs when it forgoes Institutional Voids, LDCs, and MNCs
less profitable opportunities that would Inquiries into how organizations might intention-
benefit disadvantaged people. In other ally address institutional voids have been of sig-
words, a social enterprise either aims at nificant interest to social entrepreneurship (Mair &
value capture to achieve impact invest- Martí, 2009; Mair, Martí, & Ventresca, 2012) and
ments or prevents mission drift by avoiding development entrepreneurship scholars (Dorado &
capture.” Ventresca, 2013; McMullen, 2011). Building on
Khanna and Palepu (1997), Webb and colleagues
Paradox theory is ideally suited for examining pre- (2011, p. 548) define formal institutional voids as
cisely the kind of organizational tensions that Agafo- “poorly developed or wholly undeveloped formal
now (2015) highlights and that are commonly institutions and infrastructures that can signifi-
associated with hybrid identities and multiple institu- cantly reduce transaction efficiency.” The presence
tional logics (Battilana & Lee, 2014; Kraatz & Block, of an institutional void does not mean an absence
2008). W. K. Smith and Lewis (2011) note that this of institutions in a given context; rather, institu-
is because paradox theory shifts the focus away from tional voids exist “in the presence of plural, often
inquiries into which motivators are effective under contending, institutional arrangements” (Mair
certain conditions (e.g. Ryan & Deci, 2000; Crocker, et al., 2012, p. 822), many of which can be char-
2008) to questions of “how individuals engage in acterized as informal or cultural. Thus, formal
these competing drives simultaneously” (p. 397). institutional voids often prevent market develop-
In this study, we provide an ethnographic ment, frustrate their functioning, or prevent certain
account of how the attitudes of a social enterprise’s individuals from participating altogether (Mair &
stakeholders evolved in response to feedback on Martí, 2009).
their prosocially motivated entrepreneurial actions. Although institutional voids can occur any-
The study investigates how the Safe Water for where, they are perhaps most problematic in LDCs,
Africa (SWA) program sacrificed value capture where they hinder the formation and growth of
because of prosocial motivation, enabling entrepre- inclusive markets for private goods and services
neurial action and output-maximizing behavior. We (McMullen, 2011) and stifle the provision of public
describe the social enterprise and its stakeholders goods (Dean & McMullen, 2007). Public goods are
and provide a detailed account of the dynamics non-excludible—open to all individuals regardless
leading to the emergence of a feeling of entitlement of whether an individual has paid for such use
to a socio-emotional return on investment in the (Cowen, 1988)—and non-rivalrous—one person’s
form of beneficiary gratitude or customer loyalty. use does not diminish the amount or quality of the
Our account depicts how feelings of entitlement good available to others (Randall, 1993). Common

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
246 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

examples include knowledge, national security, and social entrepreneurship literatures (e.g., Hoogendoorn,
common languages. Through the collection and uti- 2016), water, like most of the goods and services pro-
lization of tax revenue, governments are often vided by social enterprises (Agafonow, 2015), is not
expected to provide public goods and to “build and technically a public good. Not only is water clearly
maintain the necessary institutions for the existence excludible and rivalrous, but also it possesses char-
and the functioning of markets” (Mair & Martí, acteristics similar to private goods, such as clothes,
2009, p. 422). When governments are unwilling or food, cars, books, etc., that are typically traded in
unable to fulfill these expectations, “a compensatory markets to ensure they are allocated to their highest
social structure is needed to spur market formation value uses.
and operation” (Mair et al., 2012, p. 821). Business Unlike these private, marketable goods, how-
groups (Khanna & Palepu, 2000) often serve as this ever, water has some unique characteristics that
“compensatory social structure.” can lead to inefficient or inequitable allocations.
Institutional voids have grown in interest to For example, in 2010, the United Nations declared
MNCs aiming to sustain their growth through the access to safe drinking water and sanitation to be a
emerging markets situated within LDCs. These “human right.” As a human right, water cannot be
voids, however, often present a number of ten- treated the same way as other private goods
sions for MNCs, such as growing demand for because the transfer of water to those who value it
critical resources (like water) to which many citi- most highly may be morally unacceptable if this
zens may lack access. This can trigger an transfer means that some people who need it to sur-
increasing demand for MNC accountability by vive no longer have access. After basic water needs
the public as well as a need for MNCs to ensure have been satisfied, however, additional water use
their social license to operate in that country. If is no longer a basic human right. When water use
MNCs are able to overcome these and other ten- exceeds around 50-100 liters (13-26 gallons) per
sions, however, they become well positioned to persons per day, it becomes a private good and so
supply the growing demand for their products— is most efficiently allocated, like other private
demand made possible by economic growth. Fur- goods, through markets.
ther, with the accompanying increase in disposa- All life depends on water and because of its
ble income often comes an increase in tax dual nature as a human right and a private good,
revenue such that the government is better as well as competing demands for its use, debate
equipped to provide utilities through formal insti- continues about how finite and increasingly scarce
tutions (North, 1990). Thus, for some goods, eco- water resources should be allocated and by whom.
nomic growth diminishes the institutional void Therefore, it is not difficult to understand why
from both market failure and government failure multinational beverage companies around the
concurrently. As a result, many MNCs have world have invested heavily in (a) sustainability
sought to shift their attention from promoting initiatives that seek to reduce consumption of this
corporate social responsibility (CSR) to facilitat- critical resource (Karnani, 2014; Kent & Ignatius,
ing development initiatives. Perhaps nowhere is 2011; Raman, 2007) and (b) CSR initiatives that
this more pronounced than with the most critical seek to ensure a continuing social license to oper-
natural resource of all—water—in the global ate (Dahlsrud, 2008; Ite, 2004; N. C. Smith,
region promising the most economic growth over 2003). This is especially true in developing coun-
the next 50 years—sub-Saharan Africa—for some tries where a lack of infrastructure often denies
of the most influential MNCs on the planet—The large segments of the population access to munici-
Coca-Cola Company and Diageo, PLC (aka pal water supplies or individuals lack the ability to
Guinness). pay for water (Lambooy, 2011). In such contexts,
MNCs like Coca-Cola have experienced intense
scrutiny and have sought to counter them directly
through water-related CSR initiatives and indirectly
Water is Not a Public Good
through the charitable activities of corporate-
Despite rampant confusion within the economics funded philanthropic foundations (Karnani, 2014;
(Boudreaux, 2016; Krugman, 2016; Worstall, 2016), Lambooy, 2011). Despite significant investments,
management (e.g., Fan & Zietsma, in press), and however, even Coca-Cola executives, such as

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 247

Philippe Ayivor, have gradually become aware of exhibit characteristics of private goods after a cer-
the possibility that “there might not be enough tain threshold is met, but until that point, are typi-
money in the entire world to enable universal cally considered human rights. Examples include
access to safe water” and, therefore, identification water, food, shelter, and possibly basic health
of an operationally sustainable business solution is care. Blending both market-based and social
needed for true, lasting change. welfare-based institutional logics (Battilana &
Lee, 2014), SE appears to be equipped to address
both the private and public properties of hybrid
Hybrid Organizations for Hybrid Goods goods while offering a natural match of social
MNCs like Coca-Cola have begun to take an problem and business solution (Grimes, McMul-
increasingly collaborative approach to tackling len, Vogus, & Miller, 2013). Such thinking
development problems like access to safe water via inspired both the founding of WaterHealth Inter-
social entrepreneurship. According to Santos national (WHI) in 1995, an SE created to provide
(2012, pp. 345-346), “social entrepreneurship is safe water through micro-utilities known as
not specifically about creating market mechanisms WaterHealth centers, as well as Coca-Cola’s belief
or securing government subsidies or creating a that these centers might be the vehicle needed to
social enterprise, it is about crafting effective and sustainably provide the poor access to safe water.
sustainable solutions using whatever combination In 2011, the two formed the SWA strategic part-
of institutional means is deemed effective.” Santos nership. This program brought together MNCs,
(p. 344) adds, charitable foundations, international aid agencies,
municipal governments, local leaders and politi-
“Economic agents who, due to their motiva- cians, and social enterprise to provide the poor
tion to create value without concern for the access to safe water in Ghana, Nigeria, and Libe-
amount they capture, will enter areas of ria via WaterHealth centers.
activity where the more severe market and The SWA-sponsored centers of West Africa
government failures occur […] these are are emblematic of a growing challenge facing
usually areas with neglected positive MNCs, international aid agencies, and govern-
externalities affecting disadvantaged ments regarding hybrid goods, particularly in
populations.” LDCs. Are hybrid goods primarily human rights
to be provided by the public sector once it has
As Montgomery, Dacin, and Dacin (2012, the tax revenue needed to do so? Or are they pri-
p. 385) point out, however, the economic agency marily private goods to be provided by the pri-
of which Santos speaks is not necessarily isolated vate sector once the market has the ability to pay
to a particular individual like Nicholas Negroponte; the offering price that businesses must charge to
it may also manifest as a collective effort that not remain viable? Because of formal institutional
only involves a “multitude of external actors that voids from a combination of government failure
often collaborate to form and support entrepreneur- and market failure, social entrepreneurship theor-
ial ventures” but also “happens across levels and ists have argued that the provision of so-called
between actors, drawing on markets, movements public goods through SEs tends to be a second-
and alliances as templates for success.” Thus, we best strategy that serves as an institutional patch
use the term social entrepreneur throughout this until the government has the revenue to meet its
article to refer to any of the internal stakeholders responsibility (McMullen, 2011; Santos, 2012).
whose efforts were intended to advance the partner- In LDCs experiencing rapid economic growth,
ship’s objective of creating value for the the potential for institutional change suggests that
disadvantaged. the institutional patch offered by SE may be tem-
With its emphasis on innovative approaches to porary. Thus, Agafonow (2014, pp. 710-711)
creating social as well as financial value suggests that “social entrepreneurs will be dis-
(McMullen & Warnick, 2016), social entrepre- placed in the long term to domains where the
neurship would seem ideally suited for the provi- market does not perform well and the potential
sion of hybrid goods—defined as goods that for value capture is limited.”

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
248 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

Institutionalist Views of SE existing institutions (henceforth the interpretivist


view); or (c) social entrepreneurship research of a
If SEs are merely a temporary patch for a long-
managerial bent emphasizes the motivations, objec-
term solution involving the more traditional organi-
tives, and experiences of the stakeholders involved
zational forms associated with formal institutions,
in social enterprise (henceforth the behavioralist
then theory might suggest that government has the
view). Subject to varying degrees of institutional
right to displace SEs, forcing them to move or
influence, these three views of social entrepreneur-
shutdown in the future, and that government may
ship share a common focus on social enterprise,
even be obligated to regulate these organizations in but they employ a different level of abstraction,
the interim. Would social entrepreneurs necessarily conception of the social entrepreneur, and under-
endorse this view? If SEs assume responsibility for standing of the importance of a priori expectations
serving the water needs of their customers and do in the formation of entrepreneurial attitudes and
so successfully, then do SE managers and employ- action.
ees subscribe to the notion that their rights are sub- The functionalist view often suggests that all
servient to a public sector that left these segments aspects of a society serve a function and are neces-
of the population without service for years? Con- sary for the survival of that society (Burrell and
versely, if SEs are merely a patch until economic Morgan, 2017). This view portrays social entrepre-
growth raises disposable incomes enough to create neurs as systemic agents involved in institutional
demand, then might market theory imply that new change and development. These agents need not
businesses have the right to profit from these indi- create an organization to enact this change and
viduals as soon as they have the purchasing power may include policy makers or bureaucrats
to become customers? Would social entrepreneurs (e.g., Dorado & Ventresca, 2013). However, social
agree with this premise? Arguably, these new cus- entrepreneurship, as epitomized by SE, is typically
tomers may owe their lives to the social entrepre- considered to be an institution whose purpose is
neurs and SEs that served them when others would unique and distinctive from the profit-seeking firms
not; as a result, might SEs expect something more of the market, the agencies of government, or the
than gratitude or loyalty from them, such as a statu- charities of the citizen sector (e.g., Grimes et al.,
tory monopoly in the same spirit that the public 2013; Santos, 2012). Action, according to this
grants a temporary monopoly to patent holders for view, requires the promise of external rewards as
contributing new knowledge to the public good? well as intrinsic or prosocial motivations, such as
Clearly, these questions introduce the potential for compassion or empathy (Miller et al., 2012), and,
conflict between theory and practice, depending thus, places heavy emphasis on favorable a priori
upon the motives, expectations, and understandings expectations, lest entrepreneurial attitude—i.e.,
that stakeholders bring with them to the hybrid how favorable or unfavorable an individual’s
goods problem. appraisal of entrepreneurial behavior is (Kautonen,
Initiation of entrepreneurial action may not Tornikoski, & Kibler, 2011)—and the entrepre-
require social entrepreneurs to answer these ques- neurial action it encourages suffer.
tions, but the decision to invite or resist competi- Scholars of the interpretivist view study the sta-
tors does. Upon entry of competitors, the social bility of behavior from the individual’s viewpoint.
entrepreneur’s understanding of SE’s institutional Taking a slightly less abstract view of social entre-
role in providing hybrid goods is likely to reveal preneurship and SE than their functionalist counter-
itself in both stakeholders’ attitudes and in the parts, advocates of this approach tend to conceive
actions the SE takes. Whether these attitudes and of social entrepreneurs as individuals working
actions comply with theorists’ expectations likely alone or together to create social enterprise. This
depends on which view of social entrepreneurship social enterprise, in turn, is portrayed as a hybrid
is employed: (a) social entrepreneurship theory of organization, which mixes different logics associ-
an economic bent emphasizes the institutional role ated with distinct institutions (e.g., Battilana &
that social enterprise likely plays in development Lee, 2014). This view seeks to understand how
(henceforth the functionalist view); (b) organiza- actors reconcile the tensions or paradoxes arising
tional theory explores the possibilities and pro- from competing or contradictory institutional logics
blems encountered by hybrid organizations given (e.g., Battilana & Dorado, 2010), defined as the

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 249

“rules of the game” that prescribe and proscribe Emotional Attachment, Increased Awareness, or
individual and organizational behavior within spe- Dissonant Loyalty?
cific institutional settings (Thornton, Ocasio, & Despite the functionalist assumption that social
Lounsbury, 2012). Examining organizational entrepreneurial attitudes toward SE are relatively
dilemmas like mission drift, members of this constant, social entrepreneurs can become emotion-
school wrestle with the fact that the expectations ally attached to the organizations they create
and motives responsible for enabling entrepreneur- (Santos, 2012). Perrini et al. (2010, p. 529) point
ial action can change, revealing incentives that out that
actors were either unaware of when they initiated
action or which did not exist when action was
initiated but now do because of institutional change “…anyone interested in initiating an SE
(Ebrahim, Battilana, & Mair, 2014). Thus, process should be aware of the relation
attitudes—entrepreneurial or otherwise—can between his/her personal attitudes and
change as a result of changes in the institutional abilities and the evolution of the process.
environment itself or as a result of learning about In this sense, the ability to articulate a
oneself, one’s institutional environment, or oneself clear vision of the project is the necessary
in relation to one’s institutional environment. antecedent of all subsequent steps, from
Lastly, the behavioralist view is the least resource collection to consensus. Personal
abstract of the three approaches, depicting social commitment is a double-edged sword. It
entrepreneurs not solely as agents of some social can hinder the long-term sustainability of
system or organization, but as autonomous indivi- the organization, in that over time it brings
duals (e.g., Austin, Stevenson, & Wei-Skillern, about a progressive reification of the
2006; Hockerts, 2015). It is concerned with institu- organization itself.”
tions only to the degree that they indirectly pro-
scribe or prescribe entrepreneurial action through Indeed, a number of functionalist studies turn to
some more proximate construct—e.g., laws, norms, emotional attachment as an explanation of behavior
or beliefs. This view does not deny the influence of that is considered inconsistent with the prosocial
institutions, but instead of examining different developmental purpose that this functionalistic
entrepreneurial responses across different institu- view ascribes to SE. Yet, Fan and Zietsma (in
tional contexts (e.g., Hoogendoorn, 2016; McMul- press, p. 8) observe that, “A blind spot affecting
len, Bagby, & Palich, 2008), it tends to examine both the institutional theory of collective govern-
perceptions of institutions in terms of the payoff ance and the institutional logics perspective is the
structures their proxies present decision makers emotional attachment that actors feel towards the
within a particular institutional context logic they are embedded within.” The emotional
(e.g., Collins, McMullen, & Reutzel, 2016; Zachar- attachment to which Fan and Zietsma refer is con-
akis, McMullen, & Shepherd, 2007). Institutional stancy, not change, as one clings to the institutional
change is, therefore, a result of entrepreneurial logic that encouraged action in the first place.
action, but is not always conceived of as a con- Therefore, even though functionalists tend to con-
scious objective of the entrepreneur. Individuals ceive of SE as an institutional archetype, the grow-
may possess an entrepreneurial attitude in response ing emotional attachment described by Santos,
to the current situation, viewing that situation as Perrini and colleagues and others shifts the concep-
permanent while not realizing that through their tion of SE from archetypical organizational form to
actions, they may alter the payoff structures associ- an actual organization; in so doing, it unwittingly
ated with it and in so doing, alter the institutions in substitutes an interpretivist view of SE to account
which those payoff structures are embedded for the unexpected discrepancy between social
(North, 1990, 2005; Schumpeter, 1934, 1942). entrepreneurs’ theoretically presumed prosocial
Thus, participants and the scholars who study them motivation for engaging in SE and behavioral
can know that laws, norms, or beliefs influence atti- observations of what appears to be a presumed
tudes and action without necessarily acknowled- entitlement to protection from competitors.
ging the institutional underpinnings of these There are, however, alternative theoretical
concepts. mechanisms that can rationally explain reactions

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
250 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

like Negroponte’s attitude toward competitors laptops until OLPC was forced to exit the market,
while enabling reconciliation of the conflicting the- at which time Microsoft and Intel would be at lib-
oretical expectations associated with emotional erty to once again increase their prices. Whether
attachment described earlier. Hirschman (1958, either firm would actually do this would only be
1970), for example, identifies two kinds of institu- hypothetically relevant because the social entrepre-
tional conditions capable of triggering actors’ moti- neur’s assumption that profit-seeking firms operate
vation to engage in developmental initiatives like according to such a logic would be sufficient for
SEs: increased public awareness and dissonant loy- him to generate dissonant loyalty to SE as an alter-
alty (Dorado & Ventresca, 2013). Increased public native organizational form and to worry about these
awareness makes it “socially costly for [people] to firms’ entry into the market. In such a scenario,
disregard the problem,” whereas dissonant loyalty emotional attachment might ensure: (a) an unwa-
“influences engagement by creating unexpectedly a vering commitment to SE as an archetypical organ-
sense of membership into a particular collective izational form and (b) a growing commitment to
increasing their willingness to advance the interests SE as an actual organization. Both would encour-
of this collective.” Together, increased public age a reluctance to exit, like that exhibited by
awareness and dissonant loyalty could be expected Negroponte.
to alter the prosocial cost–benefit calculus of Whether entrepreneurial attitudes toward SE dis-
involvement in SE, enticing others to join or courage entrepreneurial exit because of emotional
improving the payoff structure for those already attachment to the actual organization or because of
involved. Dorado and Ventresca (2013, p. 74) add, emotional attachment to the institutional logic that
“Though actors with social aspirations may be encouraged entrepreneurial action via SE, the out-
more likely than those with economic aspirations come according to functionalism remains the same:
to engage in endeavors serving a public instead of SE will render itself unnecessary by temporarily
a private goal, the presence of Hirschman-informed filling and, thus, contributing to the elimination of,
institutional conditions stirs up actors’ motivation institutional voids that will eventually be satisfied
redefining the likelihood of their engagement, by traditional institutional solutions such as firms
regardless of initial aspirations.” Such Hirschman- or government agencies. However, determining
informed institutional conditions “organize and whether responses like Negroponte’s constitute
promote the ‘possibility for’ the engagement of any some paradox or whether they can be explained via
one everyday, reasonably-skilled individual” social entrepreneurs’ understanding of hybrid
(Dorado & Ventresca, 2013, p. 73) such that the goods and the future rights and responsibilities they
likelihood of entrepreneurial action is not depend- associate with addressing them is essential to the-
ent on heroic social entrepreneurs (e.g., Leadbeater, ory and practice if we hope to advise social entre-
1997; Peredo & McLean, 2006; Waddock & Post, preneurs on how they might exit gracefully and
1991; Westley, 1991) but enabled by everyday without fear that doing so will leave their benefici-
reflective practitioners (e.g., Evans, 1995; Rodrik, aries, customers, and communities vulnerable to
2008; Schon, 1983, 1987; Tendler, 1997). neglect or exploitation by less benevolently moti-
A social entrepreneur engaged in SE because of vated competitors.
dissonant loyalty may experience distrust and an Considering the value of alternative tools, such
attitude of skepticism about the motives of compe- as cases, to paradox studies (Andriopoulos &
titors. For example, Negroponte could have Lewis, 2009), our ethnography of the Safe Water
believed Microsoft and Intel were responding for Africa program examines social enterprise as
because of increasing awareness resulting from output-maximizing behavior and, thus, as a poten-
OLPC’s entrepreneurial actions. Instead of, or in tial conduit for development in LDCs. However,
addition to, feeling the attachment to OLPC that given the potential for myriad “understandings” of
could make his exit emotionally difficult, Negro- hybrid goods and the prioritizations of the rights
ponte could simply have been skeptical of what and responsibilities associated with them, our eth-
Microsoft and Intel’s actions would be once OLPC nographic account asked three interrelated research
was no longer around. For example, their entry questions: How do social enterprises and their sta-
could have been a form of predatory pricing keholders make sense of hybrid goods? How
intended to eliminate the demand for OLPC’s do these understandings affect the social

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 251

entrepreneurs’ attitudes and SEs’ actions (both ini- PLC, Guinness Ghana Breweries Limited (GGBL),
tially and over time)? And, how do these attitudes Nigerian Bottling Company (NBC), the Interna-
and actions affect both the SE and its stakeholders’ tional Finance Corporation (IFC), WaterHealth
understandings of their future rights and responsi- International (WHI), and WaterHealth Ghana
bilities? In doing so, we offer insight into the (WHG), an extension of WHI founded in 2008.
nature of the emotional attachment experienced by Global Environment & Technology Foundation
the internal and external stakeholders of SE and (GETF), a nonprofit organization with expertise in
question whether it is necessarily the frivolous multilateral management, was tasked with govern-
obstacle to graceful social entrepreneurial exit that ing the complex partnership and ensuring represen-
it is often portrayed to be by the functionalist con- tation of each party’s interests.
ception of social enterprise. Ultimately, WHG would be responsible for
installing WaterHealth centers funded and publicly
sponsored by SWA. These small modular struc-
Methods tures, which operate as privately financed micro-
utilities, house purification equipment to treat
The Safe Water for Africa program
locally available water and produce WHO-quality
According to the WHO/UNICEF Joint Monitoring water that is available on site or pumped to addi-
Program for Water Supply and Sanitation, “the tional distribution points, depending on the size of
water and sanitation position in West/Central Africa the community. WHG selects communities of least
is of particular urgency, as the region has the highest 5,000 members based on need (defined as a lack of
under-five mortality rate of all developing regions” water within a half-kilometer radius), economic
(WHO/UNICEF, 2012) (https://www.unicef.org/ potential, and other technical considerations. The
wcaro/english/overview_4554.html). Impoverished organization then works alongside selected commu-
communities in this region continue to depend on nities to: identify a center location (community-
unsafe and unreliable sources, such as unprotected donated land that is centrally located and near a
wells or springs, rivers or ponds, vendor-provided source of both surface water and electricity); install
water, tanker truck water, or bottled (and sachet) the center; determine appropriate usage fees; and
water for all water needs. The United Nations hire local station operators. Following installation,
announced the “early” achievement of Millennium WHG provides ongoing technical support and reg-
Development Goal 7.C: “to halve, by 2015, the pro- ular water quality monitoring for at least 10 years
portion of the population without sustainable access to before transferring ownership of the $50,000 center
safe drinking water and basic sanitation,” (http://www. to the community.
un.org/millenniumgoals/environ.shtml) but data across Overall, the participants, objective, and context
West Africa does not exhibit this trend, challenging of the SWA partnership make it an ideal case for
the operational sustainability, reliability, and scalability examining the research questions presented earlier.
of water improvement efforts to date (The World The partnership consists of an emerging local SE
Bank, 2016). Despite this troublesome situation, West and an array of stakeholders working to advance
Africa’s GDP in recent years has grown more than the provision of a hybrid good (water) in LDCs
45% faster than the global average (African Economic where market and government failures are
Outlook, 2016), making the region as economically commonplace.
promising as it is socially challenging.
This dynamic made West African countries an
attractive environment for a water-focused strategic
Data Collection and Analysis
partnership, anchored by two MNCs with a com-
mercial history and growing interests in the region. The lead author (henceforth I) was first introduced
As such, in 2011, The Coca-Cola Company along to the SWA program through a colleague in 2012.
with Diageo PLC (Guinness) announced the SWA At this time, my colleague and Curtis (Curt)
program. The partnership would bring together The A. Ferguson, an Indiana University alumnus and
Coca-Cola Company (TCCC), The Coca-Cola TCCC’s President of North African and Middle
Company Africa Foundation (TCCAF), Equatorial East (MENA) Business Unit, were working to cre-
Coca-Cola Bottling Company (ECCBC), Diageo ate a program at Indiana University on behalf of

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
252 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

TCCC for students from the Middle East and North donation of land for the centers, and signatures in a
Africa. Following Curt’s description of TCCC’s legal agreement that would allow ground to be bro-
various initiatives and inquiry of whether anyone ken for WaterHealth centers in their communities.
would be willing to write a case about SWA for After business was conducted, we interviewed eve-
TCCC, my colleague connected TCCC’s efforts to ryone involved concerning the process. This was
discussions about social entrepreneurship and an all-day affair, and each day the two of us rode
development that she and I had engaged in over with the WHI employee in the same pickup truck,
several years. She introduced me to Curt in the discussing the experience with him for hours while
Spring of 2012. After recording a video interview commonly stuck in traffic. Afterward, we met with
of Curt describing SWA, he and I discussed the Diageo and Coca-Cola executives in Lagos, Nige-
project for a couple of hours, and Curt invited me ria, as well as with a number of local politicians. In
to study what was happening at SWA. addition to observations and interviews, numerous
Fieldwork occurred in August and November documents and video were provided by Coca-Cola,
2012 in Ghana and Nigeria. First, I spent 3 days Diageo, WHG, and GETF concerning all aspects of
interviewing executives and employees from The the SWA partnership.
Coca-Cola Africa Foundation (TCCAF), Guinness Together, the team and I interviewed a total of
Ghana Breweries Limited (GGBL), The Diageo 152 individuals from every identifiable stakeholder
Foundation, WaterHealth Ghana (WHG), public group involved in some degree with the SWA part-
water utilities, and municipal government officials nership. These included 25 executives from the
regarding the partnership. I then spent 4 days MNCs, their foundations, and their related bottling
accompanying the WHG team in the field as a companies, seven managers and employees of the
participant-observer as they investigated potential SE, 31 “power brokers” (including chiefs, assem-
sites for their next locations. Four team members blymen, market mothers, and other members of the
then joined me in Accra, Ghana, for an additional water boards) from various communities in which
week of inquiry, during which we visited six the centers were located, 65 customer-beneficiaries
WaterHealth centers around Accra, observed of the centers, eight non-users of the centers, four
WHG’s monthly meeting with the community, and government officials, five managers of municipal
then interviewed chiefs, assemblymen, members of water providers, and two employees of NGOs and
the water board, customers of the centers, and agencies such as USAID, WADA, etc. Together,
members of the community who were not custo- this fieldwork yielded more than 200 hr of inter-
mers at the time. In addition, the team interviewed views that produced 102 pages of interview tran-
nurses and patients in local clinics and children in scripts, field notes, and/or summaries of individual
schools where WHG had conducted educational findings. These individual findings, along with
campaigns about the health benefits of “Dr. Water” 87 archival documents and 314 min of video, were
as well as employees of Equatorial Coca-Cola Bot- then compiled to yield a 48-page, single-spaced
tling Company (ECCBC) about their water sustain- collective case summary detailing our findings.
ability practices. Neither the team nor I experienced any restriction
In November 2012, I returned to Accra with a whatsoever regarding the stakeholders we could
new assistant. The two of us interviewed execu- approach, nor did we receive any oversight or edi-
tives from Coca-Cola, Diageo, and USAID and torial pressure regarding the content of the case.
revisited a number of the centers. After 3 days, we As lead author, I engaged in an ongoing process
then departed to Lagos, Nigeria, where we accom- of data analysis, facilitated by reviewing: (a) my
panied, Denish Samanta, assistant manager of busi- own field notes and memos from field observations
ness feasibility for WaterHealth International, who summarized at the end of each day; (b) the field
had been brought in from India to establish Water- notes, memos, and summaries of each team mem-
Health centers in Nigeria on behalf of the Safe ber documented each day and at the end of each
Water for Africa program. We shadowed him for researcher’s visit; and (c) the many documents pro-
4 days as he visited five communities and met with vided by members of the SWA partnership before,
chiefs, assemblymen, market mothers, public offi- during, and after fieldwork was conducted
cials, and other decision makers (with formal and (Emerson, Fretz, & Shaw, 2001). These materials,
informal power) to solicit their participation, along with interviews, were then used to develop a

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 253

descriptive case on the program. I sought feedback to be protected as a matter of gratitude from benefi-
concerning its reliability and validity, first from ciaries, loyalty from customers, or goodwill from
various stakeholders interviewed and/or involved in stakeholders for having served the community
the SWA partnership and then from individual when no one else would; (e) these feelings of enti-
team members involved in the primary data collec- tlement prompt social entrepreneurs to encourage
tion via fieldwork. All the researchers and key part- others to share them in accordance with the norm
nership stakeholders reviewed the case of reciprocity; (f ) if enough external stakeholders
independently, verifying facts and identifying share these feelings, they then become social
major phenomenological themes (e.g., case-specific expectations institutionalized in the form of moral
dilemmas, issues, or concerns). These themes were norms (notions of fairness); (g) if institutionalized,
used to begin the process of toggling back and then the same prosocial motivation that encouraged
forth between relevant theory and the data typical the noble creation of social value may ironically be
of qualitative and ethnographic research (Barker, used to justify the preclusion of new competitors
1993; Hammersley & Atkinson, 2007). offering similar or even superior solutions; and
From this analysis, I developed an analytical (h) such preclusion, depending on the motives of
description of the general character of social entre- those competitors, could induce or prevent the
preneurship as it became manifest during SWA’s institutionalization of a suboptimal path of
experience with WHG, which we present later in development.
this article. To help ensure the validity of this ana- Together, these links produce a possible paradox
lytical conceptualization and its attendant claims, I in which the same prosocial motivation used to ini-
cross-checked interview data with field notes and tiate social enterprise and, thus, institutional devel-
observations, interviews with direct and indirect opment via value creation (Phase I) eventually
stakeholders, and relevant hard data (TCCC press serves to frustrate institutional development via
releases, WHG center site reports, community land value capture (Phase III) because of a shift in the
agreements, GETF partnership documents, etc.). SE and its stakeholders’ attention away from cor-
Finally, I reviewed the analysis, claims, and con- recting an injustice happening to others and toward
ceptualizations with the second author, a colleague preventing a perceived injustice about to happen to
familiar with social entrepreneurship in LDC con- them (Phase II). Before and after Phase II, proso-
texts but not familiar with or participating in the cial motives are concerned with fairness, but the
setting (Adler & Adler, 1987), as much of ethno- focus of this plight slowly shifts from what the SE
graphic data “remains underexplored” and second- is providing its beneficiaries to what it is getting
ary analysis may yield new insights and from them in return.
interpretations (Bryman, 2008).

Findings The Development Paradox of Prosocial


Motivation
The result of our analysis is a process model of the Our research revealed that beliefs about what the
development paradox of prosocial motivation at SE’s strategies and actions should be varied consid-
SWA (Figure 1). We find that: (a) different dimen- erably depending on stakeholder motives for partic-
sions of hybrid goods are salient to different stake- ipation, expectations of the venture, and
holders depending on whether their interests align understandings of the underlying nature of the
primarily with those of donors or “investors;” hybrid goods problem. Conflict along these three
(b) this saliency encourages the marketing mix of dimensions was socially negotiated among the sta-
the SE to favor value creation over value capture; keholders involved to reach temporary compro-
(c) a marketing mix favoring value creation mises via the four “P”s of marketing: product,
requires some sacrifice (e.g., land, capital, revenue) price, placement, and promotion. Contrary to
of value capture by the social entrepreneurs and expectations, however, partners’ motives were
other stakeholders; (d) the sacrifice of value capture often the very antithesis of the objectives that drive
elicits a psychological state of entitlement such that their own organizations. For instance, MNCs often
internal stakeholders expect their right to compete wanted greater emphasis on value creation at the

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
254 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

Human + Charity-Oriented,

Rights Institutionalization
Aspect of Output-
of a Suboptimal
Hybrid Maximizing
Path of
Goods Behavior of
Development
Problem Social Enterprise

+ – +
Emphasis on Emphasis on Norms or Laws
Value Creation Value Capture that Preclude New
– Competitors

+ – – +
+
Donors–e.g. “Investors”– Stakeholder
MNCs, e.g., Social Entitlement to
Charities Entrepreneur, Value Capture
Employees,
Shareholders

Phase I Phase II Phase III


Figure 1. The development paradox of prosocial motivation.

expense of value capture and advocated for an land agreements are for 10 to 15 years. We need to
emphasis of the health benefits of safe water, lower reach payback by then, preferably much sooner.”
prices, and location in more rural settings where In addition, we found that donors had some dif-
larger segments of the underserved reside. Thus, ficulty accepting their new role and the potential
both Coca-Cola and Diageo favored penetration agency problems arising from it. Before SWA, the
pricing, charging a low price to generate large sales MNCs had enjoyed full managerial control as
volume and maximum market share (Saaty & Var- direct providers of charitable services, namely free
gas, 2012). Hamish Banks, director of public water. For example, in 2009, TCCAF had intro-
affairs and communication for the Middle East & duced the Replenish Africa Initiative (RAIN) in
North Africa division of TCCC notes, “We are not response to the severe water challenges faced by
out to maximize profits with this. It is our goal to the nearly 300 million Africans living without
grant as many people access to safe water as possi- access to clean water. Similarly, in Nigeria, Diageo
ble. We want them using it for all their water PLC had made especially significant strides with
needs: drinking, cooking, bathing…everything.” its “Water of Life” program, which completed
SEs, by contrast, often wanted greater emphasis 22 mini-water works projects costing approxi-
on value capture, even at the expense of value crea- mately $2 million each and serving more than
tion, and tended to advocate for emphasis of the 1 million people in households across the country.
“Dr. Water” brand, higher prices, and location in Unlike WaterHealth centers, however, these struc-
suburban locales promising more potential custo- tures were permanent and sustained entirely by
mers. They favored a pricing strategy that was Diageo, which charges nothing for the water it
closer to skimming—setting the highest possible produces.
price to maximize profit in the shortest possible With their participation in SWA, TCCC and
time—while still remaining cognizant of their Diageo PLC were now donors in a third-party SE
social objective. As Denish Samanta, WaterHealth that provided hybrid goods with a nominal fee.
International’s assistant manager of business feasi- They had influence, but not full control. Con-
bility, pointed out, “SWA wants to charge the same versely, the SE now managed both sponsored and
in Nigeria as Ghana. That is just unreasonable. The unsponsored WaterHealth centers, such that
costs are much higher here. For this to be feasible, resource dependency issues with donors had to be
the price of the water will have to be higher. These considered in Ghana, a country where WHI had

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 255

already been operating as WHG prior to SWA. that there may be potential to lower prices, increase
Additionally, SWA was fully backing WHI’s entry demand, and serve more beneficiaries without nec-
into Nigeria, a situation likely to further increase essarily harming the operational viability of the
the partnership’s influence over WHI’s efforts in center, especially if storage capacity could be
both Ghana and Nigeria. increased inexpensively.
In this article, we unpack these findings and dis- TCCC was hoping to increase demand for the
cuss their implications for theory development in water (and, thus, use of the facilities) by advocating
social entrepreneurship. a reduction in price. As Hamish Banks put it,
“What good is access to safe water if no one can
afford it?” It was clear that TCCC saw demand for
safe water as highly elastic, pointing out that
Phase I: Stakeholders’ Objectives and the access, not revenue, was their primary motive for
Charitable Orientation of the SE’s involvement. Therefore, value capture was seen as
Marketing Mix
necessary, but subservient to the non-negotiable
As a social enterprise, WHG was organized to value-creating activity of providing the poor access
focus on addressing social needs by engaging in to affordable safe water.
entrepreneurial processes (Mair & Noboa, 2006; For its part, WHG was resistant to lowering
Meyskens et al. 2010; Perrini & Vurro, 2006; Shaw prices for fear that doing so would not increase
et al., 2002) to achieve its primary purpose of demand, merely delay breakeven and exert down-
creating social value (Austin et al., 2006; Short, ward price pressure on their non-SWA-sponsored
Moss, & Lumpkin, 2009; Zahra, Gedajlovic, Neu- sites (which did not enjoy the same degree of
baum, & Shulman, 2009; Zahra, Rawhouser, donor support and, thus, potential for subsidiza-
Bhawe, Neubaum, & Hayton, 2008). In other tion). As noted by Mawunyo Puplampu, general
words, WHG was seeking to bring an operationally manager of WHG, “Convenience, not safety, drives
sustainable business solution to a social problem many of the purchasing decisions we see around
(Grimes et al., 2013). Nonetheless, the hybrid Accra. That’s why we have to get the message out
nature of water meant that numerous organizations that clear water is not necessarily safe water and
from different sectors were offering solutions of that hygiene helps prevent disease.”
varying quality. For example, municipal govern- Indeed, cost consciousness was not the customer
ment agencies around Accra were always seeking concern WHG originally anticipated it to
to catch up with the growing demand for tap water; be. Customers appeared to have a perceptual map
profit-seeking firms and individuals were charging in place such that water from plastic sachet bags
market prices for water of varying quality, ranging was classified in the beverage category, which
from plastic sachets to raw water from the aquifer commanded higher premiums (approximately
that was accessed via borewells; nonprofit organi- 20 pesewas per 0.5 L unit), whereas water from
zations were providing it through structures that WHG was classified in the commodity category,
were haphazardly located and sporadically main- along with water from boreholes, which com-
tained; nature even provided it for free during rainy manded much lower prices (approximately 5 pese-
season; and of course, SEs, such as WHG, were was per 20 L container). Safety appeared to
seeking to offer safe water at “cost plus” (Neck, command little, if any, premium in the commu-
Brush, & Allen, 2009; Townsend & Hart, 2008). nities around Accra. Knowing this, WHG was
Value creation, value capture, and output skeptical whether lower prices would truly have
maximizing behavior. Early in our research the effect on demand that TCCC believed they
(August 2012), SWA had introduced six Water- would. WHG was in this for the long haul and
Health centers in Ghana and was struggling with knew that value capture was necessary to ensure
what, if anything, to do about the underutilization viability. As Puplampu noted, “We do more harm
of production capacity at each site. None were than good if the community becomes dependent on
operating anywhere near the 65,000 L production us, and we end up having to relocate because we
capacity of which they were capable. This sug- cannot afford to keep the facility open.”
gested that the marginal cost of producing addi- An ongoing question of where to locate new
tional liters of water could be relatively low and facilities both within and outside of Ghana was

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
256 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

bringing the underutilization of production capacity dividends for its own productive purposes. Agafo-
to a head. Was the fact that the water was safe and now (2015, p. 1048) elaborates:
prevented waterborne illness the primary value of
the product, or was it simply the fact that it was a “In the multi-stakeholder approach devel-
source of water? Whereas the former understanding oped by EMES, an unresolved tension per-
favored categorization of the hybrid good as a pri- sists between productive and distributive
vate good, the latter favored categorization of it as roles, along with the possibility of dividend
a human right. As a private good, water is best distribution. Although Borzaga and Solari
rationed by markets (Agafonow, 2015), assuming (2004) admit that social enterprises pro-
there are enough customers with the willingness duce private goods, the perceived social
and ability to pay the SE’s offering price utility that they nonetheless bear seems to
(McMullen, 2011). As a human right, however, weaken the market’s rationing function. In
water might lend itself better to distribution the same vein, Borzaga and Tortia (2007)
through government agency, charity, SE with admit a move toward a productive role at
highly subsidized prices, or other organizational the expense of advocacy and redistribution,
forms capable of meeting people’s needs regardless but they also claim that social enterprises
of disposable income. Thus, an understanding of allocate resources on the basis of solidarity
water as a private good favored a marketing mix in and reciprocity excluding the exchange of
which the key product differentiator was safety and equivalents, which paradoxically charac-
promoted through educational campaigns about the terizes the redistributive role that they con-
health benefits of the “Dr. Water” brand. In addi- cede is being left behind. Finally, Campi
tion, prices were set higher, which encouraged the et al. (2006) admit a move toward the mar-
preference for locations near Accra, where disposa- ket, but they also encourage the production
ble income was higher but the threat of new com- of public goods, which fails to meet the
petitors was ever-present. In contrast, an rationing criteria required to achieve mar-
understanding of water as a human right favored a ketability and value creation. However,
marketing mix in which the key product differenti- social enterprises can produce public
ator was simply the absence of affordable alterna- goods, thanks to quasi-markets that render
tives. As a result, prices were set lower, which non-excludable goods marketable. This is a
encouraged the preference for more rural locations policy option that, although considered by
where disposable incomes were lower, alternatives Aiken (2006) and Bode, Evers, and Schulz
were few or nonexistent, and the threat of new (2006) may render quasi-markets unworka-
competitors was minimal. ble in the case of public procurement with
Clearly, this marketing mix had implications for the state constituting a monopsony. In any
the value that each site could create and capture event, quasi-markets for social enterprises
and that SWA, as a whole, could provide over need more research.”
time. The more charitably minded the stakeholders
involved in SWA, the more they tended to favor a As Agafonow (2015, p. 1050) notes, “early
marketing mix that sought value creation at the research on social enterprises reveals that business
expense of value capture. Such sacrifice of value affairs can aim to keep prices as low as possible to
capture, however, adversely affects the SE’s ability foster consumption by a target disadvantaged popu-
to create value over the long term. This introduces lation. At the same time prices are set high enough
an unresolved tension between the productive and to protect the financial sustainability of the enter-
distributive roles of social enterprise (Agafonow, prise, such that it can comply with budgetary con-
2015). Assuming that WHG was right and reduced straints. Thus, social enterprises set prices lower
prices were indeed unlikely to increase demand, than their for-profit peers to maximize output rather
then reducing prices in the name of water’s per- than profit.” Both TCCC and SWA endorsed this
ceived social utility would effectively distribute notion of producing “more output than would com-
dividends to customers, whereas maintaining petitive firms at the given market price” (Gassler,
higher prices would allow the SE to retain those 1986, p. 78). Indeed, most of SWA’s stakeholders

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 257

agreed that WHG should “price their output lower it were an expense for his/her respective organiza-
than their for-profit counterparts and use surpluses tion, not an investment. Goodwill from the commu-
to expand production beyond what for-profits nity was certainly desired, but the donors expressed
would deem profitable, reducing profit margins for awareness of the indirect nature of this feedback
the sake of vulnerable consumers, even as they loop and the potential that social returns—no mat-
remain cognizant of a break-even point” ter how good for the community—may not lead to
(Agafonow, 2015, p. 1049). Disagreement, how- financial returns for the donors involved. As Ham-
ever, revolved around how aggressively WHG ish Banks from TCCC articulated, “Feel good stor-
should be pursuing this behavior. While all social ies about how our centers have enabled little girls
entrepreneurs were unified in their desire to create to go to school instead of fetching water all day are
social value, the degree to which each was willing nice, but what [TCCC] is hoping to get from this
to sacrifice value capture to achieve this end partnership is some way to determine whether our
appeared to vary according to the saliency of the charitable efforts are truly making a difference and
human rights aspect of the hybrid good. to what extent. Can we point to these facilities and
Donor or “investor?” Two camps of social show that thousands of people who did not have
entrepreneurs had emerged in SWA, which we safe water before, now do? Can we quantify the
have designated as donor or “investor,” depending number of waterborne illnesses that were prevented
on their primary motive for involvement in the as a result? If so, maybe we can move beyond hop-
partnership. Donors, such as TCCC, Diageo PLC, ing that we are helping and actually know that
TCCAF, and ECCBC, were participating in SWA we are.”
primarily out of charitable motives. Their focus Thus, value capture was important to donors, but
was on value creation. SWA promised to leverage primarily as a means of measuring and facilitating
the MNCs’ charitable reach by capturing some of the value these MNCs had traditionally provided
the value it created, thereby facilitating the poten- through charity. Return on this charity in the form of
tial for sustainable solutions and rapid expansion. community goodwill was hoped for, but it remained
As Philippe Ayivor, public affairs and communica- a loose expectation at best. Social value creation as
tions director, Equatorial Coca-Cola Franchise, opposed to financial value creation had been their
noted, “I grew up witnessing development projects focus. Hence, water was conceived primarily as a
come into Ghana, introduce an expensive solution, human right to be provided by SWA via charity. If
and leave only to have that solution break down a revenue from nominal fees supported this objective,
few years later, with no budget to repair it. Ghana even better, but commitment was to the problem
is full of abandoned boreholes in need of service.” (e.g., lack of access to safe water), not the method
Perhaps just as troubling to him had been “good used to solve it (e.g., viability of the centers).
enough” solutions, such as pit latrines that “people In contrast, “investors” included managers,
from developed countries might scoff at using employees, and customers of the social enterprise
while recommending them without hesitation to because each of these stakeholders expected a
Ghanaians because of the idea that they were a gift direct return on their investment in WHG. Social
and an improvement over what was already there.” entrepreneurs received the credit for the profit rea-
Ayivor did not know what the ideal solution to lized by the SE, even if, owing to the non-divi-
West Africa’s water problems would be, but he had dend-granting nature of SE, they were not entitled
some sense of what it would look like if he saw it: to the profit itself (Yunus, 2010). SE managers and
it would consist of a self-sustaining business model employees received wages and promotion opportu-
using world-class technology that was careful to nities in a growing venture, whereas customers
respect the dignity of the people it served. With its received water at less than market prices because
focus on charity supported by a sustainable busi- of the output-maximizing behavior of the SE. Each
ness model, WaterHealth centers appeared to fit of these “investors” was seeking some return on
the bill. the investment of their time, talent, and treasure.
Donors viewed value capture as a means to the As a result, they exhibited a greater emphasis on
end of sustainable value creation, such that value value capture than donors, who viewed their
capture was considered subservient to value crea- involvement primarily as an expense, albeit a
tion. Each donor was approaching SWA as though necessary one.

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
258 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

Like donors, these SE “investors” were commit- human right and pushed for locating sites in rural
ted to social value creation. Because of their expec- settings, but the SE had held fast to its site criteria.
tations, however, they favored long-term over Price, placement of facilities, and promotion, how-
short-term value creation should trade-offs between ever, were not fully indicative of an understanding
the two become necessary. For example, Nathaniel of water as a private good either. Price was set on
Kwesi Somuah, responsible for site feasibility anal- the lower end of the spectrum and, despite signifi-
ysis at WHG, noted that, “If we lower our prices, cant opportunity for both vertical and horizontal
we significantly increase the time until payback. integration, WHG had declined. They were not
We also run the risk of angering neighboring com- willing to pipe water to individual homes nor pack-
munities. We charged 15 pesewas for 20 L of age and deliver water in plastic sachets. Moreover,
water in Pakro and only 10 pesewas for 20 L of they had continued to promote the health benefits
water in Nsakina because of the material costs of safe water through education awareness pro-
associated with inflation. Nsakina was built before grams in schools and at monthly water board meet-
Pakro. Both sites charge well below market, but ings. Thus, despite the fact that: (a) different
still there were grumblings in Pakro about the dif- dimensions of hybrid goods were salient to differ-
ference. These communities talk. Our SWA donors ent stakeholders depending on whether their inter-
are always pushing us to lower our prices, but that ests aligned primarily with those of donors or
would impact our other sites as well, and most are “investors;” and (b) this saliency encouraged the
not as well supported as the SWA sites.” degree to which the marketing mix of the SE
Pressure for price reductions also came from favored value creation over value capture, SWA
assemblymen and chiefs on behalf of themselves had arrived at a hybrid venture model that existed
and the customer-beneficiaries they represented, somewhere between a dual objective social venture
but there were exceptions. The village chief of boasting equal concern for its social and financial
Pakro acknowledged, “WaterHealth has to pay its missions at one end and an output-maximizing
costs, like electricity and building costs.” Similarly, social enterprise at the other.
the Water Board Chairman of the Asukawan com-
munity in the Volta Region clearly understood and
communicated the need for the site to cover its
operating costs, noting, “This is our center, which Phase II: Self-Sacrifice of Value Capture and Its
Corresponding Sense of Entitlement
we will eventually own, but it cannot be main-
tained unless we charge for the water. People As the marketing mix became more charitable, it
understand, but they still complain that it’s too became more reliant on stakeholders sacrificing
much. At the same time, I see them pay as much their selfish interests in the name of helping others.
for a sachet bag as they would for an entire bin Debate exists over whether such sacrifices are an
[of WHG water] just because the bag is cold and act of altruism (Batson, 1990; Batson et al., 1997;
easy to carry.” Miller et al., 2012; A. Smith, 1976) or enlightened
Phase I concluded with WHG and SWA setting self-interest (Chiles, Tuggle, McMullen, Bier-
the product price in a manner more consistent with man, & Greening, 2010; Cialdini, Brown, Lewis,
a market penetration strategy than a market skim- Luce, & Neuberg, 1997; Maner et al., 2002;
ming strategy, choosing to peg the price of “Dr. McMullen, 2010, 2015), but a marketing mix
Water” closer to the raw water from boreholes than favoring value creation over value capture requires
to the premium prices associated with beverages. some sacrifice of land, capital, or revenue and,
Still, the price was nowhere near low enough to thus, some form of prosocial motivation, which
maximize the unused capacity of the 65,000 L/day, Grant (2008, p. 49) defines as “the desire to expend
suggesting that considerable potential for more effort to benefit other people.”
output-maximizing behavior existed. The selected Customer-beneficiaries were required by WHI to
price and location also revealed that negotiation donate the land on which the center would be
between parties had arrived at an understanding of located. As the proximity of the community
water as neither purely a human right nor purely as became more urban, informal property rights gave
a private good. As with price and production, way to formal property rights, and power shifted
SWA donors had advocated a view of water as a from chiefs to individual members of the

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 259

community, intensifying the negotiation process. what that person feels he or she can expect from
This process had gone relatively smoothly in others. One’s sense of entitlement is intimately
Accra, Ghana, where the informal power of chiefs linked with one’s narcissism; like narcissism, it can
still held sway, but it was proving arduous in the be healthy or pathological, exaggerated or underde-
more densely populated Lagos, Nigeria, where the veloped. Kriegman (1983) and Levin (1970) sug-
process sometimes took months. My assistant and I gest that an individual’s attitude of entitlement falls
shadowed Denish Semanta, assistant manager of into one of three global categories: (1) excessive
business feasibility at WaterHealth International, entitlement; (2) normal or healthy entitlement; and
through half a dozen communities throughout (3) restricted entitlement.”
Lagos as he met with assemblymen, chiefs, market As Bishop and Lane (2002) note, individuals
mothers, and various officials of municipalities to high in entitlement insist—be it through some form
identify potential site locations and to explain of amends or revenge—on being given the repay-
repeatedly what the individuals were being asked ment they see as deserved. Thus, psychological
to donate and, more importantly, what they were entitlement might best be described as “those rights
being asked to sign—the land agreement. Typi- which one feels justified in bestowing upon one’s
cally, the land identified as ideal for a site location self” (Meyer, 1991, p. 223).
was practically worthless and, owing to its central- A sense of entitlement was not limited to the
ity within the community, was often being used as customer-beneficiaries; donors as well as man-
a dump. Yet, individuals would occasionally try to agers and employees of the SE expressed an
hold the community hostage in hope of receiving expectation of reciprocity for their sacrifice as
compensation or personal privilege—e.g., free well, though it was often subtle among donors.
water—in exchange for signing the agreement, An annoyance or irritation with complaints over
only to find their efforts thwarted by the charitable product pricing, coupled with the inconsistencies
nature of the centers and its policy against such in water preferences (i.e., complaining about
side deals. 15 pesewas for 20 L of WHG water while paying
When land was donated reasonably quickly similar prices for a 0.5 L of cold tap water in a
(as was the case in Ghana), with it came a sense of sachet bag), led to repeated comments among
entitlement to lower prices, even when those prices donors and SE employees that customers had
were well below those of local businesses selling unreasonable expectations about product pricing
the same product. As one customer-beneficiary put and delivery. Many customer-beneficiaries would
it, “We donated the land and still the prices are so complain that the product was inconvenient and
high.” When asked whether the 3% of disposable too costly (despite being significantly lower than
income he was now spending on water from the treated alternatives), pointing to neighboring com-
WaterHealth center was not a dramatic improve- munities who enjoyed lower prices and suggest-
ment over the 40% of disposable income that he ing that they were being exploited in comparison.
had previously spent on water trucked into the This was particularly frustrating to donors, who
community, he added, “Yeah, but those were busi- expected gratitude in the form of goodwill for
nesses.” Clearly, WHI’s requirement that the com- their subsidies, as opposed to grumblings of
munity donate the land had triggered categorization exploitation. After all, financial records demon-
of the center as a charity, not a business, and with strating subsidization were made available to any-
that categorization had come a sense of entitlement one interested and in attendance during monthly
to free or heavily subsidized goods. water board meetings.
“Entitle,” according to Meyer (1991, p. 223), is Finally, there was evidence that SE managers
defined as “to qualify a person to do something; to and employees harbored a sense of entitlement as
give a claim to; to give a right to demand or well. Relatively wealthier customers were pester-
receive; as, his labor entitles him to his wages.” ing WHG to make their product more convenient
Though the term can have negative connotations, with perpetual inquiries about when they might
there is nothing inherently negative about entitle- expect piping to individual homes or delivery ser-
ment. Meyer (p. 223) notes: “A sense of entitle- vices. Such requests were not consistent with
ment pertains to a set of attitudes about what a either the “investors’” or donors’ understandings
person feels he or she has a right to, and about of water as a human right. In fact, these requests

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
260 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

painted a picture of water not only as a private 2001). Distributive justice involves the fairness of
good, but as a private good governed by the dic- outcome distributions or allocations as determined
tates of luxury, not necessity. This customer- using an equity rule where people calculate the
beneficiary entitlement to perpetual improvement, ratio of one’s contribution or “inputs” (education,
despite an unwillingness or inability to pay market intelligence, experience) to one’s outcome and then
prices, was frustrating to SEs already sacrificing compare that ratio with that of a referent other
value capture for value creation. One WHG (Adams, 1965)—i.e., did one get their just des-
employee, a native Ghanaian who will remain serts? In contrast, procedural justice involves the
nameless, whispered a variant of “beggars cannot fairness of the procedures used to determine out-
be choosers” while travelling in a van with the come distributions or allocations (Colquitt et al.,
lead author from one site to the next. He was 2001)—i.e., was one treated justly?
clearly irritated by a somewhat aggressive, Violations of fairness as understood through a
middle-aged woman whom the lead author had human rights lens prompted stakeholders to act
just finished interviewing. She had been complain- either (a) because of personal conviction that bene-
ing rather loudly about the lines that form in front ficiaries were not receiving equal access to the
of the centers in the mornings and evenings and water they needed to survive and to which they
how WaterHealth had ignored her repeated were entitled according to natural law and/or
requests for more vantage points. The WHG (b) because of an unarticulated fear that society
employee pointed out that every one of those van- may blame them as an MNC for depriving others
tage points cost about $15,000 and somewhat dis- of their human rights. Though neither the donors
missively noted that if not for WaterHealth, she nor the “investors” believed they were responsible
would be spending all day walking back and forth for the conditions of the beneficiaries they were
to the river to fetch untreated water. It was clear seeking to help, they were nonetheless aware of the
from his inflection that he thought she should con- possibility that others might not share that percep-
sider herself lucky that WaterHealth had selected tion and seek to hold them accountable. Accounta-
a site as close to her home as it had. He felt that bility, according to fairness theory (Folger &
WHG deserved her gratitude, not her contempt. Cropanzano, 2001), has three interrelated compo-
When I pointed out that customers always want nents: (a) existence of an unfavorable condition;
more for less, he immediately responded, “She (b) an event that must be due to the volitional, dis-
should know that the center is charging the least it cretionary actions of the target person whose
can to operate and still cover its costs, but people accountability is assessed; and (c) harmful actions
see Coca-Cola or Guinness on the sign [as a spon- that are responsible for negative conditions that
sor of the site] and expect everything to be free.” violate a normative standard of justice, such as
The sentiments expressed by customer-benefici- equality, need, or distributive justice (Adams,
aries, donors, and “investors” all communicated a 1965; Leventhal, 1976).
sense of entitlement. Ideas about entitlement typi- The less intimately familiar the stakeholder was
cally involve judgments about fairness. According with the customer-beneficiaries of SWA, the more
to the social psychology of justice, “people may be they focused on the violation of their human rights,
legally or morally entitled to certain outcomes advocated for the beneficiaries’ entitlement to safe
based on who they are and what they have done” water in the name of equality, and expressed con-
(Exline, Baumeister, Bushman, Campbell, & Fin- cern over whether it was procedurally just that “lit-
kel, 2004, p. 895). Justice, in turn, is typically tle girls should have to spend their entire day
defined in comparison with a prevailing philosophi- fetching water from the river” rather than going to
cal system (Colquitt, Conlon, Wesson, Porter, & school.
Ng, 2001) and socially constructed in the sense that Remediation of any perceived injustice required
an act is considered to be just if most individuals SEs and their stakeholders to make sacrifices that
perceive it as such (Cropanzano & Greenberg, could enable entrepreneurial action under condi-
1997). Thus, justice in organizational settings often tions that did not justify action based on financial
focuses on the antecedents and consequences of incentives alone. For donors, these prosocial
two types of subjective perceptions: (a) distributive motives were a form of organizational altruism,
justice and (b) procedural justice (Colquitt et al., which can exist financially at the organizational

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 261

level in the form of CSR (Clarkson, 1995) or social interested in value capture, but this value capture
value creation (Miller et al., 2012). Cropanzano appears to be more social than financial in nature
and Mitchell (2005, p. 279) note, “Altruism is a (Miller et al., 2012) and, thus, likely to elicit a
rule whereby we seek to benefit another person strong sense of reciprocity. That is, SE donors sim-
even at an absolute cost to ourselves. Over the ply seek more credit or social approval than SE
years, much debate has been held in social psychol- “investors” for their actions on behalf of others. For
ogy as to whether such a phenomenon is even pos- the social entrepreneur, this can be tied closely to
sible (e.g., Batson, 1991). However, contemporary ego and even “drive them to follow unethicalprac-
research seems to support Meeker’s (1971) conten- tices." Zahra et al. (2009, p. 528) add, "This egoistic
tion that altruistic motives share a place beside streak, therefore, may lead some social entrepre-
other exchange rules (for reviews, see Bat- neurs to believe that any actions taken to fulfill their
son, 1995).” ambitions are ethically justified (Longnecker
As interactions with customer-beneficiaries et al., 1988).”
increased, however, social entrepreneurs tended to Such egoistic entitlement appeared to be emerging
become more aware of the criticism they were among the employees of WHG in the form of a per-
receiving from these customer-beneficiaries. As a ceived right to protectionism in the name of distribu-
result, both “investors” and donors exhibited a shift tive justice. As one employee of WHG noted,
in their focus from altruistic advocacy of benefici- “We’ve barely demonstrated that the model works,
aries in the name of compassion or equality to jus- and now we have to fight off competition on every
tifying their own choices and actions on behalf of front. Everyone wants a piece of the action, but if we
WaterHealth and SWA in the name of procedural fail, where will everyone be? I’ll tell you where:
justice. Moreover, as the level of a social entrepre- worse off than before.” This statement was delivered
neur’s investment increased, so did his/her expecta- with the same normative vehemence that a grand-
tion of reciprocity in the name of distributive mother might tell her granddaughter that she should,
justice—i.e., sacrifice on another’s behalf should “Dance with the one who brought ya!” Thus, we
be acknowledged and repaid in kind, be it with found that a marketing mix favoring value creation
gratitude, loyalty, etc. required some sacrifice (e.g., land capital, revenue)
Reciprocity is an exchange rule that takes three by the SE and its stakeholders and that this sacrifice
forms. The first is as a transaction pattern of inter- of value capture elicited a psychological state of enti-
dependent exchanges. As such, reciprocity is tlement such that stakeholders expected their right to
understood as an exchange that does not include compete to be protected as a matter of gratitude from
explicit bargaining. The second and third forms of beneficiaries, loyalty from customers, or goodwill
reciprocity—a folk belief and a moral norm—are from external stakeholders for having served the
often confused. As a folk belief, reciprocity is con- community when no one else would.
sidered a cultural mandate, in which those who do
not comply are punished. In contrast, as a moral
norm, reciprocity is a standard that describes how Phase III: Mission Accomplished or Suboptimal
Path of Development
one should behave, and those who follow these
norms are obligated to behave reciprocally. The As of November 2012, the demand for conven-
key difference between a norm and a folk belief is ience was increasing rapidly around Accra thanks
that norms involve what philosophers refer to as an to economic growth and rapidly rising living stan-
“ought” quality. Even though the norm of reciproc- dards in Ghana. Combined with the growing popu-
ity is a universally accepted principle (Gouldner, lation of Accra, this fueled a demand for the piping
1960), the degree to which people and cultures of water directly to individual households. The
apply the principles varies (Cropanzano & Mitch- willingness and ability to pay for this service, how-
ell, 2005). It appears that the same may be said of ever, greatly outpaced the public utilities’ ability to
SEs and their stakeholders. provide these services. As a result, managers of
Unlike donors, “investors” make a personal sacri- public water utilities were feeling pressure to pro-
fice with the intent of capturing some of the finan- vide services before receiving the tax revenues
cial value they create (Hockerts, 2015; Mair & needed to expand current water treatment facilities.
Noboa, 2006; Miller et al., 2012). Donors are also This pressure facilitated a willingness among

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
262 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

managers of public utilities to collaborate with positive, productive, and essential to WHG’s site
WHG in meeting some of this demand. Because of selection process. Given the demand for individual
this willingness, WHG was able to successfully piping, the operational viability of the centers would
approach Ghana Water Company, Ltd. (GWC) as be greatly undermined if GWC expanded into a
an urban partner and Community Water and Sani- community in which WHG already had a presence.
tation Agency (CWSA) as a rural partner. Although modularity of the centers reduced this
Although WHG, GWC, and CWSA all served exposure, relocation was not costless, nor were the
the same need, availability of and access to clean assessment and community negotiations required to
water, Jonas Kakariba Jabulo, manager of GWC, select a location in the first place. For these reasons,
pointed out that GWC could provide access only to WHG confronted a dilemma when selecting sites
64% of the people within its jurisdiction who around Accra. Whenever the community was large
needed it. Additionally, while GWC was charged enough to meet WHG’s density criteria (approxi-
with providing water to urban centers of 5,000 peo- mately 5,000 people within a kilometer of the cen-
ple or more, there were communities as large as ter), it was also large enough to expect eventual
8,000 that were simply beyond its capacity. Thus, service from GWC. This left WHG in a dilemma of
GWC saw WHG as a complementary provider, but either continually relocating their sites to the subur-
Jabulo believed that GWC would eventually have ban “frontier” of the city where large populations
to regulate WHG to assure the public that the water lack access to safe water or responding to the
met the standard of the municipality. Moreover, demands of customers and the urging of public util-
because WHG’s micro-production facilities were at ity managers to provide piping to individual homes.
a substantial cost disadvantage relative to the large- The kind of detached, objective decision making
scale facilities of public water utilities, WHG was needed to arrive at a decision to relocate upon mar-
unlikely to be perceived as a competitive threat by ket entry by GWC was simply incongruent with
the public utilities, no matter how many centers the sense of entitlement evoked by the sacrifices
WHG might introduce. Bordering on condescen- needed for SEs and their stakeholders to create
sion, Jabulo concluded: “People don’t want to fetch social value. Instead, this entitlement was more
water. They want to turn the tap and have it availa- likely to evoke reactions like that exhibited by
ble on demand. Besides, the centers only complete Nicholas Negroponte in response to Intel and
half the loop. People want the wastewater to be Microsoft’s foray into the inexpensive laptop mar-
whisked away as well. The centers don’t do that.” ket. For example, when first hearing of Jonas Jabu-
Managers from both the SWA donor partners and lo’s comments, Richard Kweku Ahiagble,
WHG did not take Jonas Jabulo’s comments about corporate citizenship manager for Guinness Ghana
future regulation or the centers’ shortcomings lightly. Breweries, Ltd. (a subsidiary of Diageo, PLC) was
All parties involved in the SWA partnership had a clearly agitated, stating: “These municipalities
long history of taking strong stances against bribery, always welcome us because they know we will
and each had encountered instances in the past where take some of the heat off of them for not providing
public officials sought to use regulation as an instru- services to these communities, but they do not
ment of extortion. Because the WaterHealth centers always give us the courtesy of informing us of their
were still relatively few in number, WHG had plans even when we explicitly seek their counsel
remained below the radar of corrupt and opportunis- about where best to locate to avoid redundancies.
tic public officials. Unfortunately, the increased pub- Their assumption that we will simply relocate once
lic attention that created opportunities also had a they decide to offer service to a community is irri-
tendency to generate threats as well. Consequently, tating and, quite frankly, arrogant.”
as its presence and profile rose, WHG feared an Similarly, Hamish Banks of TCCC, expressed
increase in ostensibly benevolent concern for the concern at Jabulo’s comments recalling another
public’s welfare and the need for greater discernment project involving a public official’s attempt at
in discriminating between legitimate concern for the extortion once TCCC had committed to building a
public, such as Jonas Jabulo’s, and harassment for school for girls. Indeed, potential for extortion
private gain from corrupt officials. under the guise of the public interest was what had
To date, however, communication between partly motivated WHI’s decision to design the cen-
WHG and the public water utilities has been ters as modular as opposed to permanent structures.

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 263

Entitlement attitudes were even stronger among As more and more people began to share these
SE employees, who viewed new organizational feelings, they showed signs of becoming social
entrants such as business competitors with the same expectations institutionalized in the form of moral
disdain that donors exhibited toward “arrogant” norms (notions of fairness). As one of the assem-
municipal water supplies. The question of “Where blymen from Asukawan put it: “CWSA has been
were they when we began all of this?” was not promising us service forever. They are supposed to
uncommon. Such logic was regularly expressed as provide [tap water] once a community has 5,000
justification for the belief that the community people, but this area has to be at 7 or 8,000 people
should boycott such alternative water sources and now. Coca-Cola and WaterHealth have stepped in
rally around “their” center. In fact, in some to help, but all CWSA does is drop by occasionally
instances, WHG was encouraging members of the to act like any day now they might finally deliver
water board to employ this rhetoric when explain- on their promise. If they did, the center would
ing to the community why beneficiaries should use probably go out of business and have to move.
water from the centers. Where would that leave us? Not everyone can
While the rhetoric rang true for business compe- afford tap water, but I do not know if the center
titors, especially in Lagos, Nigeria, where an would have enough customers if some people got
armed guard accompanying the lead author service from CWSA. I know that frustrates people
explained that up to 40% of his family’s disposa- on the board. WaterHealth is trying to help, but the
ble income went to bottled water trucked into his government is not helping.”
community, the same could not be said of munici- Such “us” verses “them” rhetoric was only begin-
pal water supplies. Public providers were not only ning to emerge, but it was clear that the annoyance
more convenient, but truly less expensive than and irritation that WHG and the stakeholders of
WaterHealth, owing to the economies of scale they SWA were feeling toward the government was
enjoyed. To the extent the community embraced beginning to be adopted by the power brokers in the
this rhetoric, they could indeed preserve a local communities. Much to WHG’s chagrin, how-
community-owned sustainable source of safe water ever, it had yet to permeate the community. Conse-
from being undermined by fly-by-night competi- quently the customer-beneficiaries were not yet
tors from the private sector or thieves who might willing to sacrifice much in the way of price at the
plunder it. However, they also ran the risk of pre- low-end or convenience at the high-end in the name
cluding truly superior alternatives to WaterHealth of supporting a community-owned source of safe
in favor of a suboptimal path of development. water. Few customer-beneficiaries were zealous
Moreover, this path could become institutionalized users of the water, with many still using it only for
as municipalities seeking the path of least resist- drinking or cooking, but not bathing.
ance simply skipped over communities being pla- Therefore, despite WHG’s emerging and some-
cated by WHG to provide services to the squeaky what ironic efforts to prevent new competitors from
wheels lacking such suboptimal services. entering, results had been mixed, with power bro-
Thus, we found that these feelings of entitlement kers more on board than customers. Momentum
prompted social entrepreneurs to encourage others to was growing, however. If WHG were to succeed in
share them in the name of reciprocity. For example, persuading the public that new providers of water
one customer-beneficiary of WHG noted, “I tell my should be precluded from entering the market in the
family and friends to use Dr. Water for everything. name of some misguided sense of distributive jus-
Not only will it keep them from getting sick, but we tice, then customer loyalty had the potential to
need to keep the center here. Coca-Cola helped build become a moral norm that, if institutionalized, could
[the center], but the community donated the land. encourage a suboptimal path of development. It is
Eventually we will own [the center]. The more that this possibility to which we turn our final thoughts.
people use it, the faster that will happen.”
This customer-beneficiary statement is almost
verbatim from the pitch that WaterHealth Interna- Conclusion
tional gives to countless communities in LDCs as
they do site analyses and preparatory work to Social entrepreneurship theorists typically justify
secure land agreements. the need for social entrepreneurship as a solution to

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
264 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

a public goods problem that is caused by a combi- considered so essential to addressing an otherwise
nation of market failure and government failure. unfilled institutional void, as little more than an
They propose that social entrepreneurship is a tem- aberration. It is as though only a handful of social
porary patch to an institutional void. Because of entrepreneurs have been afflicted with a case of
their prosocial motivation, social entrepreneurs altruism, socially beneficial but personally detri-
intervene to introduce solutions that enable institu- mental. Any expectations of reciprocity that this
tional, social, and economic development that prosocial motivation may trigger in the social
would not occur based on financial incentives entrepreneur are dismissed as irrational expecta-
alone. These social entrepreneurs remove the bar- tions that are of no concern to no-nonsense custo-
riers that have prevented others from entering the mers and stakeholders. Instead, prosocial
market. Thus, through their actions (made possible motivation is considered an anomalous concern for
by prosocial motivation), social entrepreneurs others that enables, at best, a temporary reward for
reveal to others, who may lack any prosocial moti- the social entrepreneur until the overwhelming
vation whatsoever, how they might profit by serv- majority of selfish actors realize the potential for
ing the needs and wants of previously marginalized value capture and descend like locusts to consume
and forgotten customers. this propitious niche.
Social entrepreneurs do not have to be aware of But what if the prosocial motivation believed to
the role they play for this functional theory to be enable social entrepreneurship—whether in the
valid. Quite the contrary: if the theoretical predic- name of compassion, justice, fairness, “dissonant
tions we have outlined unfold unbeknownst to loyalty” (Dorado & Ventresca, 2013), or a similar
social entrepreneurs, then the emotional attachment notion of social solidarity—is not treated as an
of Nicholas Negroponte or the frustrations commu- aberration unique to social entrepreneurs? What if
nicated by the stakeholders of SWA would be com- it is instead considered a characteristic of the
monplace. Anecdotal evidence from science and human condition? Given the documented ubiquity
the arts suggests that this may indeed be the case. and power of the norm of reciprocity (Cialdini,
Pioneers who work in obscurity for years advan- 2007), it seems highly unlikely that the norm’s
cing a cause often express frustration as less nobly effects would govern only the actions and expecta-
motivated competitors enter the market to reap the tions of social entrepreneurs. If other-regarding pre-
spoils or claim the glory. Evidence of frustration, ferences are the rule and not the exception, then we
however, does not negate the validity of a function- might expect that other stakeholders will share the
alist understanding of SE. SEs can still serve the social entrepreneur’s frustration with “Johnny-
function of filling institutional voids, thereby elimi- come-latelies,” “Carpetbaggers,” or “Fly-by-night”
nating the need for its function, without social competitors who enter the market only when “the
entrepreneurs ever being aware that the conse- getting is good.” If stakeholders return the favor
quence of doing so is obsolescence. In time, the and do indeed respond in kind to meet the social
social entrepreneur might abandon his/her SE as no entrepreneur’s expectations of reciprocity, then pro-
longer viable or he/she may allow mission drift in social motivation has the potential to do much
order to adapt to the changing wants and needs of more than simply enable SE; it also has the poten-
customer-beneficiaries. In the latter case, the SE tial to preclude the entry of competitors—for good
evolves into either a business or a charity in or bad—by eliciting customer loyalty or beneficiary
response to the dissipation of the institutional void gratitude to the SE. In some cases, preclusion may
that it was originally created to fill. In such scenar- even rest on moral justifications of fairness accord-
ios, social entrepreneurs would not declare their ing to the equity rule such that stakeholders share
efforts “mission accomplished.” Instead, they the social entrepreneur’s belief that he/she should
would choose to adapt—reluctantly if not be entitled to reap at least some of what he/she has
enthusiastically—to the constraints of an evolving helped sow.
entrepreneurial ecosystem in hopes of organiza- Such mutual sacrifice has been heralded by the
tional survival. popular press as both the key to the good life
Though plausible, the functionalist understand- (Colson, 2005) and the cause of its demise (Rand,
ing of SE suffers a major inconsistency in its expla- 1964). In the social sciences, Ostrom (1999, 2014)
nation. It treats the prosocial motivation, has pointed out that such mutual sacrifice can

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 265

enable an escape from tragedy of the commons sce- rights that become private goods after a minimal
narios, while others have shown that, under alterna- threshold is provided. Should any person be
tive circumstances, it can create an “Abilene expected to feel—much less demonstrate—
Paradox” (Harvey, 1988)—a “Gift of the Magi”-like gratitude for being granted access to something that
scenario in which a suboptimal outcome is caused is rightfully his/hers? What if the party granting
by a mutually misguided sacrifice of one’s own him/her access is also the one responsible for deny-
interests based on erroneous assumptions of others’ ing him/her access in the first place? Communist
interests. philosopher Slavoj Žižek (2009) suggests that this
To date, social entrepreneurship theory has is one of the great ironies of our capitalist system.
underestimated the power of the norm of reciproc- We praise entrepreneurs for philanthropy when the
ity. By doing so, researchers are left to interpret the wealth they have accumulated required the use of
social entrepreneur’s desire for gratitude as an irra- factors that the less fortunate should have had first
tional desire that will fall by the wayside as claim on anyway. Thus, the poor are expected not
customer-beneficiaries pursue their own selfish only to support a system in which burglary is
interests for more convenient or less expensive endorsed, but they are encouraged to praise the
sources of water, even at the community’s expense. burglar for the benevolence of returning some of
Under this scenario, we might expect WaterHealth the treasure he/she has stolen from them.
to experience a fate similar to the “mom and pop” Declarations of water as a human right give
shops made extinct by Wal-Mart’s entry into rural some credence to the spirit of Žižek’s overstated
communities. Wal-Mart has been accused of preda- critique of entrepreneurial capitalism. In doing so,
tory pricing wherein, after running the competition they should also encourage MNCs to pause to con-
out of business, they close their local store and sider some hidden dangers associated with trading
consolidate into a single megastore serving a 100- in their long-standing charitable approach to CSR
mile radius (Greenwald, 2005). Even customer loy- for more recent developmental forays into sustaina-
alty could not compete with lower prices as indivi- bility, especially in LDCs. For instance, to what
duals shopped themselves and members of their extent does involvement in solving the water chal-
community out of jobs in a retailing tragedy of the lenges of Ghana signal culpability in creating those
commons scenario. problems? Do customer-beneficiaries see Coca-
There are, however, two major differences Cola as part of the solution or part of the problem?
between the customer-beneficiaries of WaterHealth To what extent does Diageo’s involvement in
and the patrons of the local “mom and pop” shops SWA communicate that the MNC is somehow
in downtown rural America. The WaterHealth responsible for a lack of service that should have
customer-beneficiary is part owner of the center been provided by, and otherwise would have been
and part of a tight-knit community that is highly expected from, municipal water utilities? As WHG
subject to social norms. Such tight-knit commu- provides the solution, they become increasingly
nities amplify the effects of social norms, like the responsible for the discontent consumers feel about
norm of reciprocity, and the grip these norms have water as evidenced by the insatiable demands that
on constituents’ actions. If the norm of reciprocity WHG was fielding for more and more
is strong enough, it could help prevent the type of convenience.
predatory scenarios of which Wal-Mart has been Thus, future research may benefit by examining
accused and which Negroponte likely feared was whether the norm of reciprocity among customer-
Microsoft’s and Intel’s ulterior motive for their beneficiaries applies only to parties that these
newfound interest in the inexpensive laptop customer-beneficiaries do not deem responsible for
market. the problem they are solving. How effective is this
Customer-beneficiaries must feel gratitude for norm at precluding entry by would-be competitors?
the norm of reciprocity to apply, but deeper reflec- Is there a point where the price of loyalty or distri-
tion suggests that assumptions of gratitude may not butive justice is simply considered to be too high?
only be unrealistic; they maybe downright ridicu- Does this vary by income? Does it vary by the het-
lous. As we pointed out earlier, most of the goods erogeneity of the community? Does the mostly
provided by social entrepreneurs are not technically symbolic ownership of the center have the same
public goods, but instead “hybrid goods”—human effect on stakeholder loyalty as the more tangible

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
266 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman

shares or dividends that say, a cooperative, might attachment of social entrepreneurs to their social
enjoy? If an SE is charging for the products they enterprises may be all that stands between
provide, is it even reasonable to expect gratitude or consumer-beneficiaries and the high long-term cost
loyalty? Are customer-beneficiaries of SEs ever of low short-term prices.
grateful or does the fact that they are paying some- If one goal of a “true social entrepreneur” is to
thing for the product automatically put them in a “invite competition instead of resisting it” (Santos,
value-seeking mind-set? If they are grateful, how 2012, p. 346), exploitive scenarios like predatory
long does that last? Is there a point at which the SE pricing also raise a number of concerns and ques-
is simply taken for granted as part of the competi- tions pertaining to life after the social entrepreneur
tive landscape, regardless of whether it is subsidiz- has filled the void. For instance, should social
ing prices or not? In other words, does goodwill entrepreneurs merely invite competition or should
from programs like SWA have a shelf life that they strive to invite the right competition? What
accrues mostly to the excitement of start-up, with are the scenarios in which social entrepreneurs
the benefits-to-costs ratio associated with the SE should, for the betterment of their customer-benefi-
inverting over time? If so, does this affect strategic ciaries, actively resist competition? More specifi-
decisions concerning the marketing mix? cally, what role should they play in vetting or
SE may indeed be consistent with Santos’ preventing those from the private and public sector
(2012) positive theory of social entrepreneurship that follow their lead but do not maintain an
and other functionalist accounts of social enter- emphasis on value creation or share the same disso-
prise, offering the temporary patch so desperately nant loyalty? What vetting or preventative strate-
needed to help society transcend the institutional gies do they utilize and how do they synergize or
void created by a combination of market failure balance these efforts with the day-to-day, opera-
and government failure. Tracey, Phillips, and Jarvis tional demands of their organization?
(2011) tell the story of Aspire, a social enterprise In conclusion, our research suggests that proso-
that targeted the underlying causes of homeless- cial motivation plays a role in encouraging SE, but
ness, such as basic skills for employment, but shut that its role is unlikely to stop there. Instead, we
down after 6 years. Although the organization find that prosocial motivation could paradoxically
operationally failed, their social enterprise model contribute to the potential for suboptimal develop-
“constituted a distinct strategy for tackling home- ment under certain conditions, such as those in
lessness” (Tracey et al., 2011, p. 69) and was sub- which social entrepreneurs sacrifice much to help
sequently adopted by hundreds of organizations, others, especially if those others are grateful to the
successfully altering and improving how this issue social entrepreneur for his/her help because they
was addressed in the United Kingdom. In many know he/she was neither responsible for their pre-
ways, this is the ideal “SE as temporary institu- dicament nor obligated to help them escape
tional patch” scenario. However, our findings sug- it. Thus, it is our hope that by making social entre-
gest that social entrepreneurs may be unlikely to go preneurs aware that their prosocially motivated
quietly into the night. In other words, social entre- actions can generate a sense of entitlement in them-
preneurs may fill this void, making themselves selves and a sense of obligation in others, research
obsolete in the process, but that does not mean they may help social entrepreneurs avoid suboptimal
will exit gracefully nor necessarily that they development traps, whether it is encouraging the
should. Most have invested much of themselves preclusion of competitors who offer superior long-
into their SEs and, like their employees, may be term solutions from entering the market on one
dependent on it for income, purpose, and status. If hand or it is exposing a community to predatory
the March of Dimes continued even after finding pricing by exiting too quickly on the other hand.
the cure for polio, the sole purpose for which it
was created, why should we expect social entrepre-
neurs to magnanimously exit the field upon proving References
that enough value can be captured to establish a
market for hybrid goods? Moreover, if their contin- Adams, J. S. (1965). Inequity in social exchange.
ued involvement could prevent predatory pricing Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 2,
scenarios like those discussed earlier, the emotional 267–299.

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 267
Adler, P. A., & Adler, P. (1987). Membership roles in sustainable? In M. Nyssens (Ed.), Social enterprise: At
field research (Vol. 6). Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE the crossroads of market, public policies and civil soci-
Publications. ety (pp. 238–258). London, U.K.: Routledge.
African Economic Outlook. (2016). Statistics. Retrieved Borzaga, C., & Solari, L. (2004). Management challenges
from http://www.africaneconomicoutlook.org/en/ for social enterprises. In C. Borzaga & J. Defourny (Eds.),
statistics The emergence of social enterprise (pp. 333–349). New
Agafonow, A. (2014). Toward a positive theory of social York, NY: Routledge.
entrepreneurship. On maximizing versus satisficing Borzaga, C., & Tortia, E. (2007). Social economy organiza-
value capture. Journal of Business Ethics, 125(4), tions in the theory of the firm. In A. Noya & E. Clarence
709–713. (Eds.), The social economy: Building inclusive econo-
Agafonow, A. (2015). Value creation, value capture, and mies (pp. 23–60). Paris: OECD.
value devolution: Where do social enterprises stand? Boudreaux, D. (2016). Water is not a public good.
Administration & Society, 47(8), 1038–1060. Retrieved from Cafehayek.Com/2016/04/water-is-not-a-
Aiken, M. (2006). Towards market or state? Tensions and public-good.Html
opportunities in the evolutionary path of three UK Bryman, A. (2008). Social research methods (3rd ed.).
social enterprises. In M. Nyssens (Ed.), Social enter- Oxford, U.K: Oxford University Press.
prise: At the crossroads of market, public policies and Burrell, G., & Morgan, G. (2017). Sociological paradigms
civil society (pp. 259–271). London, U.K.: Routledge. and organisational analysis: Elements of the sociology
Andriopoulos, C., & Lewis, M. W. (2009). Exploitation- of corporate life. New York, NY: Routledge.
exploration tensions and organizational ambidexterity: Campi, S., Defourny, J., & Gregoire, O. (2006). Working
Managing paradoxes of innovation. Organization Sci- integration social enterprises. In M. Nyssens (Ed.),
ence, 20(4), 696–717. Social enterprise: At the crossroads of market, public
Austin, J., Stevenson, H., & Wei-Skillern, J. (2006). policies and civil society (pp. 29–49). London, U.K.:
Social and commercial entrepreneurship: Same, differ- Routledge.
ent, or both? Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Chell, E. (2007). Social enterprise and entrepreneurship:
30(1), 1–22. Towards a convergent theory of the entrepreneurial
Barker, J. R. (1993). Tightening the iron cage: Concertive process. International Small Business Journal,
control in self-managing teams. Administrative Science 25(1), 5–26.
Quarterly, 38(3), 408–437. Chiles, T. H., Tuggle, C. S., McMullen, J. S.,
Batson, C. D. (1990). Affect and altruism. In B. S. Moore Bierman, L., & Greening, D. W. (2010). Dynamic crea-
& A. M. Isen (Eds.), Affect and social behavior (pp. tion: Extending the radical Austrian approach to entre-
89–125). Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. preneurship. Organization Studies, 31(1), 7–46.
Batson, C. D. (1991). The altruism question: Toward a Cialdini, R. B. (2007). Influence: The psychology of per-
socio-psychological answer. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence suasion. New York, NY: HarperCollins.
Erlbaum. Cialdini, R. B., Brown, S. L., Lewis, B. P., Luce, C., &
Batson, C. D. (1995). Prosocial motivation: Why do we Neuberg, S. L. (1997). Reinterpreting the empathy–
help others? In A. T. Tesser (Ed.), Advanced social psy- altruism relationship: When one into one equals one-
chology (pp. 332–381). New York, NY: McGraw-Hill. ness. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,
Batson, C. D., Sager, K., Garst, E., Kang, M., 73(3), 481–494.
Rubchinsky, K., & Dawson, K. (1997). Is empathy- Clarkson, M. E. (1995). A stakeholder framework for ana-
induced helping due to self–other merging? Journal of lyzing and evaluating corporate social performance.
Personality and Social Psychology, 73(3), 495. Academy of Management Review, 20(1), 92–117.
Battilana, J., & Dorado, S. (2010). Building sustainable Collins, J. D., McMullen, J. S., & Reutzel, C. R. (2016).
hybrid organizations: The case of commercial microfi- Distributive justice, corruption, and entrepreneurial
nance organizations. Academy of Management Journal, behavior. Small Business Economics, 47(4), 981–1006.
53(6), 1419–1440. Colquitt, J. A., Conlon, D. E., Wesson, M. J., Porter, C.
Battilana, J., & Lee, M. (2014). Advancing research on O., & Ng, K. Y. (2001). Justice at the millennium: A
hybrid organizing–insights from the study of social meta-analytic review of 25 years of organizational jus-
enterprises. Academy of Management Annals, 8(1), tice research. Journal of Applied Psychology, 86(3),
397–441. 425–445.
Bishop, J., & Lane, R. C. (2002). The dynamics and dan- Colson, C. W. (2005). The good life. Carol Stream, IL:
gers of entitlement. Psychoanalytic Psychology, 19(4), Tenderly House Publishers.
739–758. Cowen, T. (Ed.) (1988). The theory of market failure: A
Bode, I., Evers, A., & Schulz, A. (2006). Work integration critical examination. Fairfax, VA: George Mason
social enterprises in Europe: Can hybridization be University Press.

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
268 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman
Crocker, D. A. (2008). Ethics of global development: persistence, performance, and productivity. Journal of
Agency, capability, and deliberative democracy. New Applied Psychology, 93(1), 48–58.
York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Greenwald, L. (2005). Wal-Mart: The high cost of low
Cropanzano, R., & Greenberg, J. (1997). Progress in price [Motion Picture]. United States: Retail Project.
organizational justice: Tunneling through the maze. Grimes, M. G., McMullen, J. S., Vogus, T. J., & Miller, T. L.
International Review of Industrial and Organizational (2013). Studying the origins of social entrepreneurship:
Psychology, 12, 317–372. Compassion and the role of embedded agency. Academy of
Cropanzano, R., & Mitchell, M. S. (2005). Social Management Review, 38(3), 460–463.
exchange theory: An interdisciplinary review. Journal Hammersley, M., & Atkinson, P. (2007). Ethnography:
of Management, 31(6), 874–900. Principles in practice. London, U.K.: Routledge.
Dahlsrud, A. (2008). How corporate social responsibility Harvey, J. B. (1988). The Abilene paradox: The manage-
is defined: An analysis of 37 definitions. Corporate ment of agreement. Organizational Dynamics, 17(1),
Social Responsibility and Environmental Management, 17–43.
15(1), 1–13. Hirschman, A. O. (1958). The strategy of economic devel-
Dean, T. J., & McMullen, J. S. (2007). Toward a theory opment. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
of sustainable entrepreneurship: Reducing environmen- Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, voice, and loyalty:
tal degradation through entrepreneurial action. Journal Response to decline in firms, organizations, and states.
of Business Venturing, 22(1), 50–76. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Dorado, S., & Ventresca, M. J. (2013). Crescive entrepre- Hockerts, K. (2015). Determinants of social entrepreneur-
neurship in complex social problems: Institutional con- ial intentions. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,
ditions for entrepreneurial engagement. Journal of 41(1), 105–130.
Business Venturing, 28(1), 69–82. Hoogendoorn, B. (2016). The prevalence and determinants
Drayton, W. (2002). The citizen sector: Becoming as of social entrepreneurship at the macro level. Journal of
entrepreneurial and competitive as business. California Small Business Management, 54(S1), 278–296.
Management Review, 44(3), 120–132. Ite, U. (2004). Multinationals and corporate social respon-
Ebrahim, A., Battilana, J., & Mair, J. (2014). The govern- sibility in developing countries: A case study of Nige-
ance of social enterprises: Mission drift and accounta- ria. Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental
bility challenges in hybrid organizations. Research in Management, 11(1), 1–11.
Organizational Behavior, 34, 81–100. Karnani, A. (2014). Corporate social responsibility does
Emerson, R. M., Fretz, R. I., & Shaw, L. L. (2001). Partici- not avert the tragedy of the commons. Case study:
pant observation and fieldnotes. In P. Atkinson, A. Coffey, Coca-Cola India. Economics, Management, and Finan-
S. Delamont, J. Lofland, & L. Lofland (Eds.), Handbook cial Markets, 9(3), 11–23.
of ethnography (pp. 352–368). London, U.K.: SAGE Kautonen, T., Tornikoski, E. T., & Kibler, E. (2011).
publications. Entrepreneurial intentions in the third age: The impact
Evans, P. B. (1995). Embedded autonomy. Princeton, NJ: of perceived age norms. Small Business Economics,
Princeton University Press. 37(2), 219–234.
Exline, J. J., Baumeister, R. F., Bushman, B. J., Kent, M., & Ignatius, A. (2011). Shaking things up at
Campbell, W. K., & Finkel, E. J. (2004). Too proud to let Coca-Cola. Harvard Business Review, 89(10), 94–99.
go: Narcissistic entitlement as a barrier to forgiveness. Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. (1997). Why focused strategies
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87(6), 894. may be wrong for emerging markets. Harvard Business
Fan, G. H., & Zietsma, C. (in press). Constructing a Review, 75(4), 41–48.
shared governance logic: The role of emotions in Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. (2000). The future of business
enabling dually embedded agency. Academy of Man- groups in emerging markets: Long-run evidence from
agement Journal. Chile. Academy of Management Journal, 43(3), 268–285.
Folger, R., & Cropanzano, R. (2001). Fairness theory: Jus- Kirkpatrick, D. (2008a, January 4). Negroponte on Intel’s
tice as accountability. Advances in Organizational Jus- $100 laptop pullout. Fortune Magazine.
tice, 1, 1–55. Kirkpatrick, D. (2008b, May 16). With Microsoft, OLPC
Gassler, R. S. (1986). The economics of nonprofit enter- may finally succeed. Fortune Magazine.
prise: A study in applied economic theory. Lanham, Kraatz, M. S., & Block, E. S. (2008). Organizational
MD: UniversityPress of America. implications of institutional pluralism (Vol. 840,
Gouldner, A. W. (1960). The norm of reciprocity: A pre- pp. 243–275). London, U.K.: The Sage Handbook of
liminary statement. American Sociological Review, Organizational Institutionalism.
25(2), 161–178. Kriegman, G. (1983). Entitlement attitudes: Psychological
Grant, A. M. (2008). Does intrinsic motivation fuel the and therapeutic implications. Journal of the American
prosocial fire? Motivational synergy in predicting Academy of Psychoanalysis, II, 265–281.

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
Social Entrepreneurship and the Development Paradox 269
Krugman, P. (2016, January 25). Michigan’s great stink. McMullen, J. S., & Warnick, B. J. (2016). Should we
The New York Times. require every new venture to be a hybrid organization?
Lambooy, T. (2011). Corporate social responsibility: Sus- Exploring the limits of a world of blended value. Jour-
tainable water use. Journal of Cleaner Production, nal of Management Studies, 53(4), 630–662.
19(8), 852–866. Meeker, B. F. (1971). Decisions and exchange. American
Leadbeater, C. (1997). The rise of the social entrepreneur. Sociological Review, 36(3), 485–495.
London, U.K.: Demos. Meyer, W. S. (1991). A case of restricted entitlement.
Leventhal, G. S. (1976). The distribution of rewards and Clinical Social Work Journal, 19(3), 223–235.
resources in groups and organizations. Advances in Meyskens, M., Robb-Post, C., Stamp, J. A., Carsrud, A. L.,
Experimental Social Psychology, 9, 91–131. & Reynolds, P. D. (2010). Social ventures from a
Levin, S. (1970). On the psychoanalysis of attitudes of resource-based perspective: An exploratory study asses-
entitlement. Bulletin of the Philadelphia Association for sing global Ashoka fellows. Entrepreneurship Theory
Psychoanalsis, 20, 1–10. and Practice, 34(4), 661–680.
Lewis, M. W. (2000). Exploring paradox: Toward a more Miller, T. L., Grimes, M. G., McMullen, J. S., &
comprehensive guide. Academy of Management Review, Vogus, T. J. (2012). Venturing for others with heart
25(4), 760–776. and head: How compassion encourages social entrepre-
Longnecker, J., McKinney, J., & Moore, C. (1988). Ego- neurship. Academy of Management Review, 37(4),
ism and independence: Entrepreneurial ethics. Organi- 616–640.
zational Dynamics, 16(3), 64–72. Mitchell, R. L. (2007, November 26). One laptop per
Mair, J., & Martí, I. (2006). Social entrepreneurship child: Built for failure. ComputerWorld.
research: A source of explanation, prediction, and Montgomery, A. W., Dacin, P. A., & Dacin, M. T. (2012).
delight. Journal of World Business, 41(1), 36–44. Collective social entrepreneurship: Collaboratively
Mair, J., & Martí, I. (2009). Entrepreneurship in and around shaping social good. Journal of Business Ethics, 111(3),
institutional voids: A case study from Bangladesh. Jour- 375–388.
nal of Business Venturing, 24(5), 419–435. Neck, H., Brush, C., & Allen, E. (2009). The landscape of
Mair, J., Martí, I., & Ventresca, M. J. (2012). Building social entrepreneurship. Business Horizons, 52(1),
inclusive markets in rural Bangladesh: How intermedi- 13–19.
aries work institutional voids. Academy of Management North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and
Journal, 55(4), 819–850. economic performance. New York, NY: Cambridge
Mair, J., & Noboa, E. (2006). Social entrepreneurship: How University Press.
intentions to create a social venture are formed. In J. Mair, North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic
J. Robinson, & K. Hockerts (Eds.), Social entrepreneur- change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
ship (pp. 121–135). New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. Ostrom, E. (1999). Coping with tragedies of the commons.
Maner, J. K., Luce, C. L., Neuberg, S. L., Cialdini, R. B., Annual Review of Political Science, 2(1), 493–535.
Brown, S., & Sagarin, B. J. (2002). The effects of per- Ostrom, E. (2014). Collective action and the evolution of
spective taking on motivations for helping: Still no evi- social norms. Journal of Natural Resources Policy
dence for altruism. Personality and Social Psychology Research, 6(4), 235–252.
Bulletin, 28(11), 1601–1610. Peredo, A. M., & McLean, M. (2006). Social entrepre-
McMullen, J. S. (2010). Perspective taking and the heteroge- neurship: A critical review of the concept. Journal of
neity of the entrepreneurial imagination. In R. Koppl, S. World Business, 41(1), 56–65.
Horwitz & P. Desrochers (Eds.), What is so Austrian Perrini, F., & Vurro, C. (2006). Social entrepreneurship:
about Austrian economics? (pp. 113–143). Bingley, U.K.: Innovation and social change across theory and practice.
Emerald Group Publishing Limited. In J. Mair, J. Robinson, & K. Hockerts (Eds.), Social
McMullen, J. S. (2011). Delineating the domain of devel- entrepreneurship (pp. 57–85). New York, NY: Palgrave
opment entrepreneurship: A market-based approach to Macmillan.
facilitating inclusive economic growth. Entrepreneur- Perrini, F., Vurro, C., & Costanzo, L. A. (2010). A
ship Theory and Practice, 35(1), 185–193. process-based view of social entrepreneurship: From
McMullen, J. S. (2015). Entrepreneurial judgment as opportunity identification to scaling-up social change in
empathic accuracy: A sequential decision-making the case of San Patrignano. Entrepreneurship and
approach to entrepreneurial action. Journal of Institu- Regional Development, 22(6), 515–534.
tional Economics, 11(03), 651–681. Raman, K. R. (2007). Community—Coca-Cola interface:
McMullen, J. S., Bagby, D., & Palich, L. E. (2008). Eco- Political-anthropological concerns on corporate social
nomic freedom and the motivation to engage in entre- responsibility. Social Analysis, 51(3), 103–120.
preneurial action. Entrepreneurship Theory and Rand, A. (1964). The virtue of selfishness. New York,
Practice, 32(5), 875–895. NY: Penguin.

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263
270 J. S. McMullen and B. J. Bergman
Randall, A. (1993). The problem of market failure. In R. culture, structure, and process. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford
Dorfman & N. S. Dorfman (Eds.), Economics of the University Press.
environment: Selected readings (pp. 144–153). New Townsend, D. M., & Hart, T. A. (2008). Perceived institu-
York, NY: W.W. Norton. tional ambiguity and the choice of organizational form
Rodrik, D. (2008). One economics, many recipes: Globali- in social entrepreneurial ventures. Entrepreneurship
zation, institutions, and economic growth. Princeton, Theory and Practice, 32(4), 685–700.
NJ: Princeton University Press. Tracey, P., Phillips, N., & Jarvis, O. (2011). Bridging
Ryan, R. M., & Deci, E. L. (2000). Self-determination the- institutional entrepreneurship and the creation of new
ory and the facilitation of intrinsic motivation, social organizational forms: A multilevel model. Organization
development, and well-being. American Psychologist, Science, 22(1), 60–80.
55(1), 68–78. Waddock, S. A., & Post, J. E. (1991). Social entrepreneurs
Saaty, T. L., & Vargas, L. G. (2012). New product pricing and catalytic change. Public Administration Review,
strategy. In Models, methods, concepts & applications 51(5), 393–401.
of the analytical hierarchy process (pp. 159–169). New Webb, J. W., Ireland, R. D., Hitt, M. A., Kistruck, G. M.,
York, NY: Springer Science & Business Media. & Tihanji, L. (2011). Where is the opportunity without
Santos, F. M. (2012). A positive theory of social entrepre- the customer? An integration of marketing activities,
neurship. Journal of Business Ethics, 111(3), 335–351. the entrepreneurship process, and institutional theory.
Schon, D. (1983). The reflective practitioner: How profes- Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 39(4),
sionals think in action. New York, NY: Basic Books. 537–554.
Schon, D. (1987). Educating the reflective practitioner. Westley, F. (1991). Bob Geldof and live aid: The affective
San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass. side of global social innovation. Human Relations,
Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic devel- 44(1), 1011–1036.
opment. Brunswick, NJ: Transaction. WHO/UNICEF Joint Monitoring Programme for Water
Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and Supply and Sanitation. (2012). A snapshot of drinking
democracy. New York, NY: Harper Torchbooks. water and sanitation in Africa—2012 update. Prepared
Shaw, E., Shaw, J., & Wilson, M. (2002). Unsung entre- for the African Ministers’ Council on Water (AMCOW)
preneurs: Entrepreneurship for social gain. Durham, as a contribution to the Fourth Africa Water Week.
U.K.: University of Durham Business School. 14–15 May 2012, Cairo, Egypt.
Short, J. C., Moss, T. W., & Lumpkin, G. T. (2009). Worstall, T. (2016, January 25). Krugman on Flint Michigan:
Research in social entrepreneurship: Past contributions But public water supplies aren’t public goods. Forbes.
and future opportunities. Strategic Entrepreneurship Yunus, M. (2010). Building social business. New York,
Journal, 3(2), 161–194. NY: Public Affairs.
Smith, A. (1976). The theory of moral sentiments. Zacharakis, A. L., McMullen, J. S., & Shepherd, D. A.
Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Classics. (2007). Venture capitalists’ decision policies across three
Smith, N. C. (2003). Corporate social responsibility: countries: An institutional theory perspective. Journal of
Whether or how? California Management Review, International Business Studies, 38(5), 691–708.
45(4), 52–76. Zahra, S. A., Gedajlovic, E., Neubaum, D. O., &
Smith, W. K., & Lewis, M. W. (2011). Toward a theory Shulman, J. M. (2009). A typology of social entrepre-
of paradox: A dynamic equilibrium model of organiz- neurs: Motives, search processes and ethical challenges.
ing. Academy of Management Review, 36(2), 381–403. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(5), 519–532.
Tendler, J. (1997). Good government in the tropics. Zahra, S. A., Rawhouser, H. N., Bhawe, N.,
Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Neubaum, D. O., & Hayton, J. C. (2008). Globalization
The World Bank. (2016). MDG progress status. Retrieved of social entrepreneurship opportunities. Strategic
from http://datatopics.worldbank.org/mdgs/ Entrepreneurship Journal, 2(2), 117–131.
Thornton, P., Ocasio, W., & Lounsbury, M. (2012). The Žižek, S. (2009). First as tragedy, then as farce. Brooklyn,
institutional logics perspective: A new approach to NY: Verso.

Copyright © 2017 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 11: 243–270 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1263

You might also like